• No results found

Efficiency in the Brazilian stock market : is the São Paolo stock exchange semi-strong form efficient?

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Efficiency in the Brazilian stock market : is the São Paolo stock exchange semi-strong form efficient?"

Copied!
31
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

 

 

 

Efficiency  in  the  Brazilian  stock  market  

Is  the  São  Paolo  stock  exchange  semi-­‐strong  form  efficient?  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Economics  and  Finance  

University  of  Amsterdam  

 

 

 

 

 

 

Bachelor  Thesis  

Harriëtte  ten  Brinke  

6132030  

19

th

 of  June  2014  

(2)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Abstract  

This  thesis  focuses  on  semi-­‐strong  form  efficiency  in  Brazil,  namely  the  São  Paolo  stock   exchange.  In  a  semi-­‐strong  form  efficient  market  prices  of  securities  reflect  all  publicly   available  information,  such  as  past  prices  and  prospects.  An  event  study,  with  the  event   being  stock  splits  between  2000  and  2011,  is  conducted  to  test  for  efficiency.  CAPM  is   used  as  the  expected  return  model.  Using  a  sample  of  18  companies’  returns  in  various   sectors,  cumulative  abnormal  returns  for  the  market  are  not  significantly  different  from   zero.  This  indicates  semi-­‐strong  form  efficiency.  

(3)

Table  of  contents  

  Abstract                       1     1.  Introduction                     3         2.  Literature  review                      

  2.1  Brazil  as  an  emerging  economy               4

  2.2  Equity  market  in  Brazil                 5  

  2.3  Efficient  Market  Hypothesis               6  

  2.4  Forms  of  efficiency  and  its  early  empirical  results         8     2.5  Criticism  regarding  the  Efficient  Market  Hypothesis         10     2.6  The  implications  of  efficiency  in  emerging  economies         13     2.7  Evidence  on  efficient  capital  markets  in  emerging  economies     14     2.8  Efficient  capital  markets  in  BRIC  countries           15  

  3.  Data                       17                       4.  Methodology                     20     5.  Empirical  results                     23    

6.  Limitations  and  recommendations               26  

 

7.  Conclusion                       27  

 

8.  References                       28  

(4)

1.  Introduction  

Over  the  last  decades,  Brazil  has  experienced  tremendous  economic  growth.  The   country’s  government  is  very  keen  on  attracting  investors  and  maintaining  a  high   growth  rate.  Current  president  Roussef  stated  that,  addressing  captains  of  industry  and   bankers,  emerging  economies  such  as  Brazil  ‘’have  the  biggest  investment  

opportunities’’  (Follath  &  Hesse,  2014).    

One  of  the  contributors  to  a  high  growth  rate  can  be  an  efficient  capital  market.   Efficiency  in  the  market  supports  efficient  resource  allocation,  which  in  turn  leads  to   higher  economic  growth  (Huang,  Khurana  &  Pereira,  2009).  As  for  India,  another   emerging  economy  and  fellow  BRIC  country,  the  World  Bank  announced  in  its  

development  report  of  2013  that  if  India  were  to  allocate  its  resources  more  efficiently,   economic  growth  could  rise  60  percent  (Jha,  2013).  

 

It  is  therefore  interesting  to  study  efficiency  in  the  stock  market  in  relation  to  a  country   that  has  experienced  high  growth,  like  Brazil.  The  semi-­‐strong  form  of  efficiency  in  the   São  Paolo  stock  exchange  will  be  studied  in  this  thesis,  by  conducting  an  event  study.   This  event  study  involves  the  announcement  of  stock  splits  for  a  multitude  of  companies   listed  on  the  exchange.    

 

First,  the  existing  literature  will  be  reviewed.  The  focus  is  on  Brazil  itself,  the  Efficient   Market  Hypothesis  (EMH),  its  critics,  and  the  implications  of  the  EMH  for  emerging   countries  plus  relevant  evidence.  The  next  two  sections  will  elaborate  on  the  data  used   for  the  event  study  and  the  methodology  in  conducting  the  study.  The  Capital  Asset   Pricing  Model  is  used  as  an  expected  returns  model  in  order  to  obtain  abnormal  returns.   The  empirical  results  show  that  the  average  and  cumulative  abnormal  returns  for  

individual  companies  and  the  market  exhibit  no  value  significantly  different  from  zero  at   appropriate  significance  levels.  Therefore,  it  cannot  be  rejected  that  the  Brazilian  market   is  semi-­‐strong  form  efficient.  However,  declaring  semi-­‐strong  form  efficiency  might  be   too  extreme.  Reasons  behind  this  will  be  discussed  in  ‘Limitations  and  

recommendations’.    

 

 

 

(5)

2.  Literature  review  

2.1  Brazil  as  an  emerging  economy  

Brazil  experienced  one  of  the  highest  economic  growth  rates  in  the  mid-­‐twentieth   century,  but  the  debt  crises  of  1980  and  1990  did  stagnate  this  growth.  After  the  2003,   growth  rate  picked  up  again,  to  about  five  percent  in  2004  (Thomas,  2006).    

Brazil  was  attained  the  status  of  an  emerging  economy  under  the  power  of  president   Lula,  with  his  presidential  term  starting  in  2003.  Foreign  investors  were  attracted  and   the  central  bank  was  given  higher  autonomy  to  separate  political  decision  making  from   decision  making  out  of  an  economic  perspective  (Carrasco  &  Williams,  2012).  

Emphasis  on  infrastructure  is  one  of  the  policies  supporting  the  emergence  of  Brazil.   With  the  ‘Growth  Acceleration  Plan’,  commencing  in  2007,  infrastructure  is  improved  to   facilitate  economic  growth.  Decent  infrastructure  leads  to  social  inclusion  so  that  

everyone  can  participate  in  the  economy  (Carrasco  &  Williams,  2012).  

The  attraction  of  foreign  investors  was  facilitated  in  several  ways.  Import  tariffs  have   been  lowered  to  make  it  attractive  for  foreign  companies  to  sell  their  products  in  Brazil.   High  interest  rates  and  high  returns  associated  with  rapid  growth  have  stimulated   foreign  direct  investment.  The  level  of  foreign  investment  is  not  set  to  a  maximum  or   minimum,  unlike  many  other  countries.  The  stock  exchange  of  São  Paolo  was  made  up  to   standard  with  the  markets  around  the  world,  with  information  on  disclosure  

requirements  for  listing  on  the  exchange.  The  availability  of  information  creates   confidence  of  foreign  investors  (Carrasco  &  Williams,  2012).  

The  US  financial  crisis  of  2008  did  have  some  effect  on  Brazil’s  GDP,  but  was  short-­‐lived.   Brazil’s  exposure  to  mortgage-­‐backed  securities  and  dependence  on  trade  with  

developed  countries  was  low  (Carrasco  &  Williams,  2012).    

The  ongoing  efforts  by  the  government  to  create  a  more  favorable  debt  level  and  

reforms  of  social  security,  labor  markets  and  taxation  could  improve  growth  prospects.   However,  a  crucial  factor  is  the  improvement  in  income  distribution;  the  poor  need   access  to  financial  services  in  order  to  achieve  productivity  growth.  When  more  people   are  added  to  the  growth  process,  the  strength  and  sustainability  of  growth  will  increase   (Thomas,  2006).  

 

When  compared  to  the  world’s  economic  growth,  measured  by  annual  percentage   change  in  GDP,  Brazil  on  average  either  has  a  higher  growth  rate  or  just  below  the  

(6)

worlds  rate.  One  exception  is  2012,  where  Brazil’s  GDP  growth  rate  is  1,5  percent  lower   relative  to  the  world’s  growth  rate.  The  following  graph  represents  this1.  

 

Annual  GDP  growth  of  the  world  and  Brazil  (in  %)  

   

2.2  Equity  market  in  Brazil  

The  major  stock  exchange  in  Brazil  is  the  Bolsa  de  Valores,  Mercadorias  e  Futuros  de  São   Paolo  (BM&F  Bovespa).  The  BM&F  Bovespa  can  be  considered  a  small  stock  exchange;  it   has  an  average  of  500  listed  companies  and  is  largely  dependent  on  international  

investors.  However,  in  2010  it  did  rank  11th  of  the  world  stock  exchanges  with  a  market   capitalization  of  US$1545  million  (Sandoval,  2012).  

Stocks  of  mining,  oil,  biofuel  and  gas  companies  make  up  a  large  part  of  the  exchange.   The  stock  exchange  is  more  volatile  than  stock  exchanges  in  developed  countries,   exhibiting  more  risk  but  also  more  opportunities  to  gain  (Sandoval,  2012).  

The  economic  activities  by  mining,  oil  and  metallurgy,  financial  and  construction  firms   are  most  important  for  the  Brazilian  stock  market,  indicated  by  an  asset  graph  

established  by  Sandoval  (2012)  in  which  connections  between  companies  are  made  at   different  distances.  Distance  measures  how  uncorrelated  two  returns  are  from  one   another.  Sandoval  finds  that  for  the  smallest  value  of  distance,  firms  in  the  above   mentioned  sectors  connect.  Adding  more  distance,  more  sectors  are  present  with  

                                                                                                                1  Source:  www.worldbank.com  

(7)

accompanying  firms  connecting,  but  the  sectors  mining,  oil  and  metallurgy,  financial  and   construction  have  the  most  connections.  

 

2.3  Efficient  Market  Hypothesis  

The  Efficient  Market  Hypothesis  (EMH)  was  first  introduced  by  Eugene  F.  Fama  (1970).   An  efficient  market  is  a  market  in  which  prices  always  fully  reflect  all  available  

information  and  stock  prices  are  unpredictable.  The  definition  of  ‘all  available  

information’  is  connected  to  the  form  of  efficiency,  which  will  be  discussed  in  the  next   section.    

First,  one  must  define  what  ‘fully  reflect’  actually  means.  Fama  distinguishes  three   approaches:  

With  every  ‘Expected  Return  Model’,  the  expected  price  for  a  security  at  a  given  time  is   equal  to  the  price  of  the  same  security  in  a  preceding  time  period,  adjusted  for  the   equilibrium  expected  return,  given  all  available  information.  The  fact  that  one  can  

express  the  conditions  of  market  equilibrium  in  terms  of  expected  equilibrium  returns  is   an  assumption,  but  this  assumption  is  needed  to  empirically  test  the  EMH.    This  

assumption  also  leads  to  a  ‘fair  game’;  when  expected  prices  include  all  available   information,  the  actual  price  will  be  equal  and  thus  rules  out  any  abnormal  returns.   The  Submartingale  Model  describes  that  an  expected  price  for  a  security  in  a  future   period,  conditional  on  the  information  known  in  the  current  period  is  greater  than  or   equal  to  the  price  in  the  current  period.  Expected  returns  in  the  future  period,  given  all   available  information  in  the  current  period,  would  therefore  always  be  non-­‐negative.   This  implies  that  expected  profits  of  buying  and  holding  in  the  future  period  and  trading   based  only  on  the  information  are  equal.    

The  Random  Walk  Model  states  that  a  full  reflection  of  available  information  suggests   that  returns  are  independent  and  identically  distributed  (i.i.d.).  This  model  is  an  addition   to  the  Expected  Return  model,  as  it  focuses  more  on  stochastic  properties  of  returns   (Fama,  1970).  

 

Fama  (1970)  recognizes  that  a  full  reflection  of  all  available  information  might  be  a  bit   extreme:  

(8)

‘’Though  we  shall  argue  that  the  model  stands  up  rather  well  to  the  data,  it  is  obviously   an  extreme  null  hypothesis.  And,  like  any  other  extreme  null  hypothesis,  we  do  not   expect  it  to  be  literally  true’’.  (p.  388)  

 

Fama  (1991)  reviews  the  work  on  EMH  twenty  years  after  initial  introduction.  He  finds   that  the  notion  of  ‘market  efficiency’  faces  two  problems:  there  are  information  and   transaction  costs  and  there  is  a  joint-­‐hypothesis  problem.  For  prices  to  reflect  all   available  information,  information  costs  must  be  zero.  In  reality  these  costs  are  always   positive,  hence  the  extreme  version  of  market  efficiency  must  be  false.  However,  the   EMH  excluding  these  costs  can  serve  as  a  benchmark  for  the  adjustment  of  prices  to   different  kinds  of  information.  The  joint-­‐hypothesis  problem  arises  from  the  fact  that  the   market  efficiency  is  jointly  tested  with  an  asset-­‐pricing  model.  However,  Fama  argues   that  this  does  not  mean  that  the  joint-­‐hypothesis  problem  makes  empirical  work  

uninteresting.  He  states:  ‘’The  empirical  literature  on  efficiency  and  asset-­‐pricing  models   passes  the  acid  test  of  scientific  usefulness.  It  has  changed  our  view  about  the  behavior   of  returns,  across  securities  and  through  time.’’  (p.  1576)  

Fama  (1991)  now  focuses  on  tests  for  return  predictability,  event  studies  and  tests  of   private  information,  instead  of  returning  to  the  forms  of  efficiency  introduced  in  his   earlier  work.  

There  has  been  a  change  of  focus  in  tests  for  return  predictability,  from  a  short  horizon   to  a  long  horizon.  The  evidence  on  the  existence  of  predictability  in  returns  is  growing;   there  seems  to  be  variation  of  expected  returns  through  time.  This  leads  to  a  joint-­‐ hypothesis  problem:  is  this  variation  rational  or  do  stock  prices  behave  irrationally  and   deviate  from  fundamental  value?  Moreover,  the  supposed  predictability  might  be   spurious,  due  to  data  mining  or  just  simply  based  on  chance  (Fama,  1991).  

If  the  event  date  and  price  movement  can  be  determined  accurately,  Fama  (1991)  sees   the  issues  with  an  equilibrium-­‐pricing  model  as  a  ‘’second-­‐order  consideration’’  (p.   1607)  for  event  studies.  Therefore,  evidence  obtained  from  event  studies  is  less   impacted  by  the  joint-­‐hypothesis  problem.  Recent  evidence  is  largely  supportive  of   efficiency,  as  the  price  adjustment  to  firm-­‐specific  information  occurs  quickly  (Fama,   1991).  

New  evidence  on  private  information  is  in  line  with  earlier  evidence  that  insiders   possess  private  information  that  is  not  reflected  in  a  stock  price.  The  test  whether  

(9)

investors  actually  possess  private  information  is  associated  with  the  assessment  of   abnormal  returns  for  a  long  period.  This  leads  again  to  a  joint-­‐hypothesis  problem,   because  abnormal  returns  can  be  a  sign  of  either  inefficiency  or  a  failing  pricing  model     (Fama,  1991).  

 

2.4  Forms  of  efficiency  and  its  early  empirical  results  

The  Efficient  Market  Hypothesis  recognizes  three  forms  of  efficiency,  the  weak-­‐,  semi-­‐ strong  and  strong  form  efficiency  (Bodie,  Kane  &  Marcus,  2011).  

 In  a  weak-­‐form  efficient  market  stock  prices  reflect  all  information  found  in  past   trading,  such  as  prices  and  volume.  This  past  trading  data  has  little  to  no  cost  to  obtain   and  thus  is  available  to  everyone  (Bodie,  Kane  &  Marcus,  2011).  Weak-­‐form  efficiency  is   consistent  with  the  Random  Walk  Model.  Bachelier  (1900)  first  tested  this  model  in  his   paper  about  speculation  and  found  that  the  prices  of  commodities  do  follow  a  random   walk.  

The  work  of  Kendall  (1953)  involved  studying  whether  time-­‐series  of  19  US  industrial   share  prices  in  the  period  1928-­‐1938  show  any  serial  correlation.  He  concluded  that  the   stocks  show  very  small  serial  correlation.  But,  Kendall  claims:  ‘’Such  serial  correlation  as   is  present  in  these  series  is  so  weak  as  to  dispose  at  once  of  an  possibility  of  being  able   to  use  them  prediction.’’  (p.  9)  This  is  in  line  with  the  weak  form  of  EMH.    

 

The  semi-­‐strong  form  efficiency  hypothesis  entails  that,  in  addition  to  past  trading  data,   the  prospects  of  a  company  are  also  embedded  in  the  share  price;  all  publicly  available   information  is  reflected  in  the  price.  It  focuses  on  the  speed  of  price  adjustment,  given   the  occurrence  of  an  event.  These  events  are,  for  instance,  announcements  of  stock  splits   or  annual  earnings  announcements.  A  multitude  of  events  can  occur  and  for  each  event  a   test  must  be  carried  out  separately.  Each  separate  test  will  then  add  to  the  validity  of  the   Martingale  Model,  that  is,  expected  price  for  a  security  in  a  future  period,  conditional  on   the  information  known  in  the  current  period  is  equal  to  the  price  in  the  current  period   (Fama,  1970).    

The  pioneers  in  testing  for  semi-­‐strong  form  efficiency  are  Eugene  F.  Fama,  Lawerence   Fisher,  Michael  C.  Jensen  and  Richard  Roll  (1969).  Their  paper  focuses  on  the  

(10)

from  1927  up  to  the  end  of  1959,  they  investigated  returns  for  940  splits  for  stocks   traded  on  the  New  York  Stock  Exchange  (NYSE).  

Results  were  as  follows:  the  cumulative  abnormal  return  increases  substantially  in  the   time  period  prior  to  the  split,  but  after  the  split  there  is  no  further  movement.  The  fact   that  the  cumulative  abnormal  returns  increase  before  the  stock  split,  might  be  due  to  a   changing  view  on  future  earnings  potential  of  the  company,  or  leakage  of  information   but  has  not  so  much  to  do  with  the  stock  split  itself.  When  the  date  of  the  announcement   of  the  split  was  used  in  the  research,  rather  than  the  split  date,  results  did  not  differ.   They  conclude:  ‘’the  evidence  indicates  that  on  average  the  market’s  judgment   concerning  the  information  implications  of  a  split  are  fully  reflected  in  the  price  of  a   share  at  least  by  the  end  of  the  split  month  but  most  probably  almost  immediately  after   the  announcement  date.’’  (p.  20)  

When  using  annual  income  number  announcement  dates  in  relation  to  the  movement  of   stock  prices,  Ball  and  Brown  (1968)  found  that  for  261  companies  listed  on  the  NYSE  in   the  period  1946  to  1966,  abnormal  returns  considerably  move  during  the  period  before   the  announcement.  The  movement  is  upwards  for  ‘good  news’  announcements  and   downwards  for  ‘bad  news’.  Their  explanation  for  this  is  timeliness.  Annual  income   numbers  are  given  in  annual  reports,  but  the  content  within  these  reports  are  by  then   already  addressed  by  more  prompt  sources  of  media.  This  already  known  information   accounts  for  85  to  90  percent  of  the  annual  report.  

 

Strong-­‐form  efficiency,  as  the  name  already  suggests,  is  the  strictest  view  on  efficiency.   It  builds  on  the  two  former  forms  of  efficiency  and  adds  that  in  addition  to  public   information,  information  only  available  to  insiders,  i.e.  private  information,  is  reflected   in  stock  prices  (Bodie,  Kane  &  Marcus,  2011).    

Beck-­‐Dudley  and  Stephens  (1989)  found  that  if  an  individual  investor  is  aware  of   information  before  it  is  publicly  announced,  the  investor  could  make  excess  returns.   However,  there  is  a  limited  timeframe  for  this  strategy.  This  study  was  based  on  Wall   Street  Journal  columnist  R.  Foster  Winans,  who  wrote  the  ‘Heard’  column,  basically  a   gossip  column  concerning  stocks  traded  on  Wall  Street.  He  would  then,  between  October   1983  and  February  1984,  give  the  contents  of  his  column  to  stockbroker  Brent  before  it   was  published,  so  Brent  could  profit.  With  the  use  of  an  event  window  around  the   publication  date  and  calculating  the  expected  return,  real  returns  and  the  difference  in  

(11)

those  returns  for  the  window  (the  abnormal  return),  Beck-­‐Dudley  and  Stephens  found   that  one  could  only  achieve  the  excess  returns  if  information  is  available  to  the  

individual  four  to  five  days  prior  to  announcement.  When  one  would  buy  a  stock  the  day   before  announcement  and  sell  in  the  one  to  two  days  following  the  purchase,  one  would   not  profit  as  much.  This  is  because  the  information  has  now  already  reached  the  other   investors.  Beck-­‐Dudley  and  Stephens  state  that  the  possession  of  specific  private   information  can  result  in  profits  for  an  insider  or  specialist.    

 

2.5  Criticism  regarding  the  Efficient  Market  Hypothesis  

In  the  early  2000’s  the  Efficient  Market  Hypothesis  started  becoming  less  widely   accepted.  The  belief  that  stock  prices  are  partially  predictable  was  gaining  popularity   among  statisticians  and  economists  (Malkiel,  2003).    Some  of  the  anomalies  found  in   EMH  will  be  discussed  in  this  section.  

   

Lo  and  MacKinley  (1999)  used  1216  weekly  observations  retrieved  from  the  CRSP   database  for  a  period  over  twenty  years  and  found  significant  positive  serial  correlation   for  holding  period  return.  This  study  used  returns  instead  of  excess  returns,  but  argues   that  the  results  would  not  differ  had  they  used  excess  returns.  However,  the  fact  that   stock  prices  do  not  follow  a  random  walk  does  not  mean  they  reject  the  Efficient  Market   Hypothesis.  There  is  momentum  in  the  stock  prices,  meaning  that  good  or  bad  recent   performance  of  a  stock  continues  over  time  (Bodie,  Kane  &  Marcus,  2011).  However,  Lo   and  MacKinlay  (1999)  discuss  that  more  explicit  models  of  price-­‐generating  

mechanisms  are  needed  in  order  to  conclude  that  if  prices  do  not  follow  a  random  walk,   the  market  is  inefficient.  

Behaviorists  attribute  momentum  to  underreaction.  When  investors  underreact  to  an   announcement,  it  leads  to  positive  serial  correlation.  The  total  impact  of  an  

announcement  takes  time  to  be  reflected  in  the  stock  price,  due  to  investors  who   underreact  initially  (Malkiel,  2003).  

Malkiel    (2003)  does  not  diminish  the  existence  of  momentum  in  stock  prices,  but  does   claim  that  any  pattern  of  this  kind  cannot  create  an  investment  strategy  yielding  excess   returns.  Buying  stock  with  positive  serial  correlation  most  certainly  can  generate   relative  positive  returns,  but  can  also  generate  relative  negative  returns,  which  was  the   case  for  the  period  during  the  late  1990s  to  2000.  

(12)

 

Another  anomaly  (and  behavioral  critique)  is  found  in  the  long-­‐run  return  reversals  of   stock  prices.  When  investors  are  overconfident  in  their  ability  to  predict  stock  prices   with  the  use  of  valuation  parameters,  a  relative  large  weight  is  given  to  a  low  probability   of  a  return  (Kahneman  &  Tversky,  1979).  De  Bondt  and  Thaler  (1990)  found  that  when   analyzing  the  forecasts  of  analysts  on  the  NYSE  between  1976  and  1984  and  comparing   to  stock  returns,  predicted  changes  were  more  volatile  than  actual  changes.  They  found   this  to  be  consistent  with  overreaction;  this  overreaction  will  then  reverse  itself  as   prices  reach  their  fundamental  values  again.  

With  this  pattern,  a  strategy  could  be  implemented  that  would  involve  buying  stocks   with  unfavorable  forecasts,  and  sell  when  the  reversal  has  happened,  also  known  as  a   contrarian  strategy  (Malkiel,  2003).  

However,  this  does  not  necessarily  mean  markets  are  inefficient.  Instead  of  attributing   the  reversal  to  a  behavioral  bias,  Malkiel  (2003)  argues  that  the  reversal  might  come   from  the  volatility  and  mean-­‐reverting  characteristics  of  interest  rates.  Increasing   interest  rates  decrease  bond  prices,  which  then  in  turn  increases  stock  prices.  The  same   principle  holds  for  decreasing  interest  rates.    

The  implied  profit  one  can  make  when  following  the  strategy  mentioned  above  is  also   not  a  given.  Fluck,  Malkiel  and  Quandt  (1997)  could  not  reject  that  excess  returns  can  be   made  from  following  a  contrarian  strategy.  They  took  a  sample  of  1000  firms  and  

ranked  their  Price/Earnings  ratio  (P/E  ratio)  and  Price/Book  ratio  from  low  to  high.  The   firms  with  low  ratios,  and  thus  out  of  favor,  did  on  average  yield  higher  excess  returns.   The  time  period  assessed  was  10  years,  from  1979  until  1988.  They  also  carried  out   their  analysis  in  an  out-­‐of-­‐sample  timeframe,  adding  six  more  years.  In  this  timeframe,   the  high  returns  still  prevailed.  Therefore,  it  is  not  clear  whether  the  positive  abnormal   result  of  a  contrarian  strategy  is  attributable  to  picking  the  unfavorable  stocks  or  to  an   inappropriate  risk  measure.  

 

Dividend  yields  also  seemingly  have  some  predictive  power  with  respect  to  future   returns.  When  comparing  dividend  yields  of  the  S&P  500  index  to  the  subsequent  ten-­‐ year  return,  for  a  period  from  1926  to  2001,  low  dividend  yield  on  the  index  resulted  in   a  low  return  on  the  index,  whereas  a  high  dividend  yield  resulted  in  a  high  return   (Malkiel,  2003).  

(13)

Yet,  Malkiel  (2003)  again  refutes  this  seemingly  predictable  pattern  and  thus  

inefficiency  by  relating  the  movement  of  stock  prices  to  interest  rates.  With  high  interest   rates,  stock  prices  tend  to  be  high  and  dividend  yield  is  lower.  When  the  interest  then   decreases,  the  stock  prices  inevitably  also  decrease.  

Malkiel    (2003)  states:  ‘’ Consequently,  the  ability  of  initial  yields  to  predict  returns  may   simply  reflect  the  adjustment  of  the  stock  market  to  general  economic  conditions’’  (p.  7)    

The  implication  that  firms  with  high  P/E  ratios  yield  low  returns  and  low  P/E  ratios   yield  high  returns,  based  on  the  same  sample  as  above,  would  also  imply  some  type  of   predictability  regarding  valuation  parameters.  However,  when  taking  for  example  June   1987  where  the  P/E  ratio  was  relatively  high  and  the  dividend  yield  relatively  low,  the   total  return  on  the  S&P  500  was  a  lot  higher  than  compared  to  the  corresponding  values   obtained  by  the  study  of  the  index.  Given  this  difference  in  results,  Malkiel  suggests  that   one  must  be  very  careful  in  using  these  ratios  as  a  prediction  for  future  returns  (Malkiel,   2003).  

 

Fama  and  French  (1993)  find  evidence  that  small  firms  have  higher  average  returns   than  large  firms  and  that  the  higher  the  book-­‐to-­‐market  equity  ratio  a  firm  has,  the   higher  average  returns  will  be.  They  ranked  each  firm  in  the  NYSE  into  quintiles  and   used  25  stock  portfolios  based  on  size  and  book-­‐to-­‐market  equity  ratio.  The  premium   for  size  increases  excess  returns  0,46%  per  month.  The  premium  for  the  book-­‐to-­‐market   ratio  yields  0,40%  per  month.    

 When  using  the  factors  excess  market  return,  Small  minus  Big  (SMB)  relating  to  firm   size  and  High  minus  Low  (HML)  relating  to  the  book-­‐to-­‐market  equity  in  a  regression  on   excess  returns,  they  found  both  the  beta  on  SMB  and  the  beta  on  HML  explain  the  

variation  in  excess  return.  This  model  is  also  known  as  the  three-­‐factor  model.  Both  SMB   and  HML  serve  as  risk  premiums,  as  they  are  not  dependent  on  the  market  beta.  The   authors  argue  that  SMB  and  HML  are  risk  factors  that  are  not  captured  by  the  Capital   Asset  Pricing  Model,  instead  of  it  being  signs  of  inefficiency  (Fama  &  French,  1993).    

Behavioral  financial  economists  also  argue  that  the  existence  of  market  crashes  is  a  sign   of  inefficiency.  With  fundamental  elements  of  valuation  not  changing  in  the  time  of  the   crash  of  1987,  they  believe  this  crash  can  solely  be  explained  by  psychological  factors,  

(14)

implying  there  is  no  rational  explanation  for  the  sharp  decrease  in  stock  values  (Malkiel,   2003).  

However,  Malkiel  (2003)  suggests  a  few  rational  factors  that  could  have  led  to  those   decreases.    Long-­‐term  Treasury  bond  yield  increased  by  1,5%  prior  to  the  crisis  and  risk   perceptions  also  rose.  Rate  of  return  on  a  stock  consists  of  the  yield  on  the  Treasury   bond  plus  a  risk  premium,  and  with  the  two  latter  increasing,  rate  of  return  on  a  stock   must  also  increase.  If  the  expected  growth  rate  of  the  stock  and  cash  dividends  remains   the  same,  this  higher  rate  of  return  can  only  be  achieved  by  a  declining  price.  

 

The  occurrence  of  ‘bubbles’,  prices  rising  above  intrinsic  value  and  continuing  to  rise   (Bodie,  Kane  &  Marcus,  2011),  is  seen  by  behaviorists  as  another  sign  of  prices  not  being   rational.  In  hindsight,  it  is  clear  when  a  bubble  occurred,  but  in  the  period  itself  not  so   much.  Investors  may  have  believed  they  have  acted  rationally.  In  the  case  of  the  Dotcom   bubble,  projections  on  growth  of  the  Internet,  and  companies  affiliated  with  this,  were   unsustainable.  But  at  the  time  being,  these  forecasts  were  not  seen  as  extreme  (Malkiel,   2003).  

There  was  no  clear  arbitrage  strategy  during  this  bubble;  even  if  one  were  to  disagree   with  the  forecasts,  one  could  not  be  entirely  sure,  since  all  signs  did  point  to  growth.   (Malkiel,  2003).  And  even  if  one  were  to  act  upon  ones  contrarian  beliefs,  there  would   still  be  costs  of  short  selling,  difficulty  obtaining  stocks  to  sell  short  and  the  possibility   that  you  are  right,  but  the  adjustment  to  correct  prices  happens  outside  your  time   window.  Markets  can  stay  irrational  longer  than  you  can  stay  solvent  (Bodie,  Kane  &   Marcus,  2011).  

 

2.6  The  implications  of  efficiency  in  emerging  economies  

An  efficient  market  contributes  to  efficient  resource  allocation.  Investments  in  assets   such  as  know-­‐how,  plant  and  equipment  move  with  prices  of  financial  assets.  If  stocks   were  mispriced,  and  thus  inefficient,  resources  would  be  systematically  misallocated.     On  the  one  hand,  overinvestment  in  companies  with  overpriced  securities  can  create   bubbles,  as  the  price  deviates  from  its  fundamental  value.  On  the  other  hand,  companies   with  underpriced  securities  cannot  invest  as  much  as  wanted,  because  cost  of  raising   capital  is  too  high  (Bodie,  Kane  &  Marcus,  2011).  

(15)

When  the  cost  of  obtaining  information  about  companies  is  too  high,  capital  may  not   flow  to  its  highest  value  use  (Levine,  1997).  Hence,  resources  are  not  allocated  efficient   and  could  slow  down  growth  (Huang,  Khurana  &  Pereira,  2009).  

Urrutia  (1995)  notes  on  the  emerging  markets  of  Argentina,  Brazil,  Chile  and  Mexico:     ‘‘these  emerging  markets  are  potentially  important  contributors  to  the  growth  and   development  of  the  economies  of  their  countries’’  (p.  300).  

 

2.7  Evidence  on  efficient  capital  markets  in  emerging  economies  

Magnusson  and  Wysick  (2002)  researched  weak-­‐form  efficiency  in  Africa’s  capital   markets.  Monthly  data  for  eight  African  emerging  markets  was  used  and  compared  to   stock  markets  in  developed  and  other  emerging  economies:  the  US,  Asia  and  Latin   America.  Data  series  prior  to  1998  were  used,  with  the  observations  depending  on  the   availability  of  the  data,  so  timeframes  vary  per  market.    

Three  forms  of  a  random  walk  were  distinguished.  RW3  states  that  prices  are  

uncorrelated.  RW2  adds  to  RW3  by  stating  that  price  changes  are  independent  and  non-­‐ identically  distributed;  past  volatility  does  not  predict  future  volatility.  RW1  is  again  an   addition  to  RW2,  where  prices  are  independent  and  identically  distributed;  past  prices   predict  neither  future  prices,  nor  future  volatility  (Magnusson  &  Wysick,  2002).  

Cote  d’Ivoire,  Botswana,  Kenya,  Mauritius,  Nigeria  and  South  Africa  do  conform  to  RW3,   but  not  RW2  and  RW1.  Zimbabwe  and  Ghana  conform  to  none  of  the  three  forms  of  a   random  walk.  When  compared  to  the  market  in  the  US,  African  markets  do  not  match   the  level  of  efficiency  in  the  US,  whose  market  conform  the  RW1.  Africa  compares   favorably  to  Latin  America  and  Asia  in  terms  of  efficiency.  Several  of  these  African  and   Latin  American  countries,  however,  only  are  efficient  in  the  RW3  form  when  returns  are   measured  in  US  Dollar,  but  are  not  weak-­‐form  efficient  when  returns  are  measured  in   home  currency,  implying  that  it  are  the  international  investors  creating  efficiency   (Magnusson  &  Wysick,  2002).  

 

Urrutia  (1995)  studies  weak-­‐form  efficiency  in  Argentina,  Brazil,  Chile  and  Mexico,  as   these  emerging  equity  markets  can  have  an  important  supporting  role  to  economic   growth  and  development  of  said  countries.  For  these  four  countries,  monthly  stock   index  prices  are  used  in  a  sample  from  December  1975  to  March  1991.  In  order  to  test   for  a  random  walk  in  prices,  Urrutia  uses  a  variance-­‐ratio  method  of  Lo  and  MacKinlay.  

(16)

If  a  time  series  is  a  pure  random  walk,  the  variance  of  returns  grows  proportionally  with   the  holding  period.  He  rejects  the  random  walk  for  all  four  countries,  as  the  variance   does  not  grow  proportionally  and  variances  larger  than  one  are  a  sign  of  positive  return   autocorrelation.  When  performing  a  runs  test,  a  test  for  independence  of  returns,  which   does  not  rely  on  the  assumption  returns  are  normally  distributed,  independence  is  not   rejected  for  all  four  countries.  Hence,  Argentina,  Brazil,  Chile  and  Mexico  are  weak-­‐form   efficient.  The  existence  of  autocorrelation  can  just  be  an  indicator  of  economic  growth,   instead  of  being  a  sign  of  inefficiency  in  these  equity  markets.  

 

In  addition  to  the  findings  above,  Claessens,  Dasgupta  and  Glen  (1995)  studied  return   predictability  in  twenty  emerging  markets,  with  a  few  of  these  markets  also  included  in   the  studies  mentioned  above.  The  countries  studied  are:  Argentina,  Brazil,  Chile,  

Colombia,  Greece,  India,  Indonesia,  Jordan,  Republic  of  Korea,  Malaysia,  Mexico,  Nigeria,   Pakistan,  Philippines,  Portugal,  Taiwan,  Thailand,  Turkey,  Venezuela  and  Zimbabwe.   They  also  used  the  variance-­‐ratio  method  for  monthly  data  of  returns  of  twenty  

countries  in  the  Emerging  Market  Data  Base,  with  a  sample  period  varying  per  market,   but  all  time  series  end  in  1992.  They  find  high  returns  and  standard  deviations,  

generally  higher  than  in  industrial  economies.  Significant  positive  autocorrelation  is   found  for  nine  economies  (Chile,  Colombia,  Greece,  Mexico,  Pakistan,  the  Philippines,   Portugal,  Turkey  and  Venezuela)  and  compared  to  industrial  countries;  seven  emerging   markets  have  higher  autocorrelation.  There  is  a  significant  high  degree  of  predictability   of  returns,  but  the  authors  are  not  able  to  attribute  this  to  those  markets  being  

inefficient,  as  it  can  also  be  the  result  of  varying  risk  premiums,  large  structural  changes   in  the  markets  or  regime  switching  effects,  where  the  ex  post  returns  are  higher  than  ex   ante  returns.    

 

2.8  Efficient  capital  markets  in  BRIC  countries  

Brazil,  Russia,  India  and  China,  a  group  known  as  BRIC  countries,  are  the  four  largest   emerging  economies.  The  share  of  these  countries  in  world  output  was  46%,  lower  than   in  previous  periods,  where  it  has  exceeded  50%.  However,  the  BRIC  countries  did  rank   in  the  world’s  top  ten  economies  of  2008  (Gay,  2008).    

(17)

Gay  (2008)  studied  whether  macroeconomic  factors  like  the  foreign  exchange  rate  and   oil  price  explain  stock  market  returns  between  1999  and  2006  for  the  four  BRIC  

countries.  He  did  not  find  a  significant  relationship  between  those  two  variables  and   stock  market  returns.  Moreover,  when  performing  a  Durbin-­‐Watson  test,  the  

autocorrelation  was  not  present  for  Brazil,  Russia  and  China  at  the  five  percent  

significance  level.  When  the  case  of  India  was  further  tested  for  autocorrelation  using  a   Q-­‐test,  autocorrelation  turned  out  not  be  significant  for  India  either.  With  no  

relationship  between  present  and  past  returns,  Gay  suggests  the  BRIC  countries  are   showing  signs  of  weak-­‐form  efficiency.    

 

Interestingly,  different  results  were  found  by  Majumder  (2012)  when  comparing  BRIC   markets  with  the  US  market.  Majumder  utilizes  the  Hurst  exponent  to  test  for  

dependence  of  a  time  series.  Any  value  different  from  0,5  indicates  dependence  in   returns.  Three  time  series  for  the  five  countries  were  tested  for  independence.  The  first   time  series  covers  the  entire  sample  period  2001  to  2011,  the  other  two  are  sub  sets  of   the  first;  pre  crisis  time  series  ending  in  2007  and  during-­‐and-­‐post  crisis  time  series   starting  in  2007.  He  found  that  for  the  total  sample  all  five  markets  exhibited  

inefficiency.  India  and  China  were  relatively  efficient  pre  crisis,  but  not  in  the  second   period.  Russia’s  market  was  inefficient  in  all  three  time  series.  Brazil’s  market  exhibited   inefficiency  pre  crisis,  but  became  relatively  efficient  during  and  post  crisis.  This  shows   that  the  label  ‘efficient’  very  much  depends  on  the  time  period  assessed.  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(18)

3.  Data  

An  event  study  will  be  performed  in  order  to  analyze  the  semi-­‐strong  form  efficiency  of   the  Brazilian  capital  market.  To  create  uniformity  among  results,  stock  splits  are  chosen   as  the  ‘event’.  For  the  companies  included,  these  splits  are  mostly  2-­‐for-­‐1.  In  the  total   sample  of  companies  split  factor  ranges  from  5-­‐for-­‐4  to  39-­‐for-­‐1.    

 

Selection  of  stocks  

To  capture  the  broad  range  of  the  market,  this  study  will  focus  on  companies  by  industry   classification.  From  the  Brazil  50  index  (IBrX  50),  companies  from  each  industry  are   chosen,  if  they  meet  further  criteria.  In  total  there  are  25  industries  for  the  São  Paolo   stock  exchange,  also  known  as  BM&F  Bovespa.  

Criteria  for  inclusion  in  the  event  study:   1. A  stock  split  has  occurred.  

2. Only  one  stock  split  is  present  in  the  estimation  window  and  event  window   combined.  These  windows  will  be  further  discussed  in  the  section  Methodology.   The  occurrence  of  a  single  split  in  these  windows  simplifies  the  analysis  and   limits  the  bias  in  the  results,  as  it  is  now  the  only  event.  

3. No  earnings  announcements  have  been  made  during  both  the  estimation  and   event  window.  Again,  this  ensures  limited  bias,  as  announcements  can  be  seen  as   other  types  of  events.    

4. Availability  of  data.  Prices  and  dates  need  to  be  available.  

For  the  25  industries  and  25  related  companies,  18  companies  meet  the  criteria  

mentioned  above.  This  leaves  a  sample  of  stock  prices  for  those  18  companies,  which  all   have  one  single  stock  split  in  the  sample  period.  

For  companies  that  had  more  than  stock  split  that  met  the  criteria,  the  most  recent  one   is  chosen  to  perform  an  event  study  with.  This  keeps  the  time  frame  relatively  small  and   more  focused  on  efficiency  in  recent  history.  Overall,  the  data  ranges  from  2000  to  2011.   The  event  dates  were  found  on  the  website  of  the  stock  exchange,  as  the  date  on  which   the  split  was  agreed  upon2.  Earnings  announcements  and  announcement  dates  for  stock   splits  were  crosschecked  using  Reuters3.  Stock  prices  were  retrieved  from  Datastream.  

                                                                                                                2  Source:  www.bmfbovespa.com    

(19)

An  overview  of  the  included  companies  (sorted  on  Ticker):                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                   3  Source:  www.reuters.com  

Industry   Company   Ticker   Event  Date  

Consumer  Non-­‐Cyclical  /  Food   Processors  

BRF   BRFS3   31/03/2010  

Basic  Materials  /  Chemicals   Braskem   BRKM5   20/10/2003  

Financial  /  Real  Estate   BR  Malls   BRML3   23/09/2010  

Utilities  /  Electric  Utilities   Cemig   CMIG4   26/04/2007  

Construction  and  

Transportation  /  Engineering  

Cyrela  Brazil  Realty   CYRE3   07/12/2006  

Basic  Materials  /  Steel  and   Metallurgy  

Gerdau   GGBR4   30/05/2008  

Consumer  Cyclical  /  Textiles,   Apparel  and  Footwear  

Cia  Hering   HGTX3   29/10/2010   Consumer  Non-­‐Cyclical  /   Diversified   Hypermarcas   HYPE3   30/12/2009   Financial  /  Financial   Intermediaries  

Itau  Unibanco     ITUB4   27/08/2007  

Consumer  Cyclical  /  Retail   Lojas  Renner   LREN3   03/10/2006  

Consumer  Non-­‐Cyclical  /   Cleaning  Products  

Natura  Cosmeticos   NATU3   29/03/2006  

Telecommunications  /  Fixed   Line  Communications   Oi   OIBR4   12/09/2000   Consumer  Non-­‐Cyclical  /   Retail  Distribution   Companhia  Brasileira   de  Distribuicao   PCAR4   30/07/2007  

Oil  ,Gas  and  Biofuels   Petrobras   PETR4   24/03/2008  

Diversified   Localiza  Rent  a  Car   RENT3   24/04/2007  

Utilities  /  Water  Utilities   SABESP   SBSP3   30/04/2007  

Financial  /  Holdings  -­‐   Diversified  

Ultrapar   UGPA3   10/02/2011  

(20)

Selection  of  market  index  

For  the  market  index,  the  Bovespa  Index  is  used.  It  is  a  value-­‐weighted  index,  currently   consisting  of  72  companies.  It  is  a  total  return  index,  existing  for  42  years.  This  ensures   sufficient  data  for  the  time  period  assessed  is  available.  Index  values  were  retrieved   from  Datastream.  

 

Selection  of  the  risk  free  rate  

The  SELIC  rate  is  used  as  the  risk  free  rate.  This  is  the  overnight  interbank  exchange   rate.  Datastream  recommends  SELIC,  as  the  Brazilian  Government  Bonds  are  not  risk   free4.  The  rate  was  retrieved  from  Datastream.  

   

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

                                                                                                                4  Source:  extranet.datastream.com    

(21)

4.  Methodology  

An  event  study  will  be  performed  to  test  for  semi-­‐strong  form  efficiency.  This  event   study  focuses  on  abnormal  returns.  The  methodology  follows  the  work  of  Kothari  and   Warner  (2007).  Abnormal  returns  are  obtained  by  subtracting  predicted  excess  returns   from  actual  excess  returns.  Predicted  excess  returns  are  obtained  by  the  use  of  the   Capital  Asset  Pricing  Model  (CAPM).  Estimated  returns  for  the  event  window  are  based   upon  an  estimation  window.  

 

First,  the  estimation  window  and  event  window  are  established.  Both  window  sizes  are   chosen  a  bit  arbitrarily,  since  there  is  no  particular  standard  for  window  size  in  the   literature  on  event  studies.  For  the  estimation  window,  120  trading  days  are  chosen.   This  number  of  trading  days  is  suggested  by  MacKinlay  (1997).  

The  event  window  is  set  at  41  days,  20  days  prior  to  the  event  and  20  days  after.  The   following  figure  shows  the  time  span,  with  day  0  being  the  announcement  of  the  stock   split.  

Estimation  window           Event  window  

 

-­‐140                      -­‐20                            0                            +20    

 

Then,  a  pricing  model  is  established.  For  this  study,  the  CAPM  is  used.  Its  

implementation  is  very  straightforward  and  simple,  but  does  have  some  flaws  (which   will  be  discussed  in  the  Limitations  section).  In  addition  to  its  simplicity,  CAPM  is  chosen   as  a  benchmark  because  it  is  a  widely  accepted  pricing  model  around  the  world.  It  is  the   best  method  available  to  decompose  risk  into  systematic  and  firm-­‐specific  risk.  In   addition  to  that,  there  is  evidence  that  the  central  theory  revolving  around  CAPM,  that   the  market  portfolio  is  efficient,  is  not  far  from  being  valid  (Bodie,  Kane  &  Marcus,   2011).  

 

Returns  are  generated  with  the  following  formula:  

𝑟!" = 𝑃!,!− 𝑃!,!!!   𝑃!,!!!            

(22)

Where:  

ri,t  =  return  on  stock  at  time  t,  for  company  i  

Pi,t  =  adjusted  price  of  stock  at  time  t,  for  company  i  

Pi,  t-­‐1  =  price  of  stock  at  time  t-­‐1,  for  company  i  

Prices  are  not  adjusted  for  dividends  and/or  other  announcements.  The  assumption  is   made  that  dividends  are  already  included  in  the  adjusted  price.  Other  announcements   during  the  time  period  assessed  are  checked  for  and  not  present.  

 

CAPM  is  stated  by  the  following  formula:  

𝑅!,! = 𝛼 + 𝛽 𝑟!,!− 𝑟!,! + 𝜖!,!   𝑅!,! = 𝑟!,! − 𝑟!,!  

Where:          

ri,t  =  return  on  stock  at  time  t,  for  company  i  

rf,t  =  risk  free  rate  (SELIC  rate)  at  time  t   rm,t  =  return  on  market  index  at  time  t   εi,t=  error  term  at  time  t,  for  company  i    

The  alpha  and  beta  are  found  by  performing  an  Ordinary  Least  Squares  regression  on   the  excess  return  of  company  i  with  observations  that  fall  within  the  estimation  window,   between  t=-­‐21  and  t=-­‐140.  

 

The  estimated  alpha  and  beta  are  then  used  to  predict  values  for  excess  return  on  stock   of  company  i  for  the  estimation  window,  between  t=-­‐20  and  t=20.  

These  predicted  excess  returns  are  now  subtracted  from  actual  excess  returns  and  this   gives  the  abnormal  returns,  during  the  event  window.  

 

𝐴𝑅!,! = 𝑅!,!− 𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑑𝑖𝑐𝑡𝑒𝑑𝑅!,!    

Per  company,  the  cumulative  abnormal  return  (CAR)  on  day  +20  is  calculated  and  a  T-­‐ test  is  performed,  to  test  whether  the  average  abnormal  return  is  significantly  different   from  zero.    

(23)

𝐶𝐴𝑅(𝑡!, 𝑡!)! = AR!,! !! !!!!   Where:   t1=-­‐20     t2=20    

The  T-­‐statistic  is  obtained  using  the  following  formula:   𝐶𝐴𝑅 𝑡!, 𝑡!

𝐿 ∗ 𝜎 𝐴𝑅   Where:    

L  =  t2  –  t1  +  1         L=41  for  event  window  

For  the  standard  deviation  of  abnormal  returns,  the  observations  in  the  event  window   are  used.  

 

In  addition  to  this,  the  average  abnormal  return  is  also  tested  for  significance  for  two   other  time  periods.  The  event  window  of  41  days  is  a  rather  large  window;  therefore   smaller  windows  of  11  days  (5  prior  to  event,  5  after)  and  5  days  (2  prior  to  event,  2   after)  are  tested  for  significant  abnormal  return  as  well.  The  same  formulas  as  above   apply.  

 

For  each  company  individually,  the  absolute  value  of  the  T-­‐statistic  will  be  compared  to   critical  values  at  different  significance  levels.  Under  the  H0  hypothesis,  that  markets  are   efficient,  the  average  abnormal  excess  returns  should  not  be  different  from  zero  and   neither  should  CAR.  Otherwise,  significant  abnormal  excess  returns  during  the  event   window  can  be  made,  which  indicates  inefficiency.  

More  formally  stated:  

𝐻!: 𝐶𝐴𝑅 = 0, 𝑚𝑎𝑟𝑘𝑒𝑡  𝑖𝑠  𝑒𝑓𝑓𝑖𝑐𝑖𝑒𝑛𝑡     𝐻!: 𝐶𝐴𝑅 ≠ 0, 𝑚𝑎𝑟𝑘𝑒𝑡  𝑖𝑠  𝑖𝑛𝑒𝑓𝑓𝑖𝑐𝑖𝑒𝑛𝑡  

 

For  the  aggregate  of  companies  the  CAR  is  also  tested,  by  performing  a  regression  on   only  a  constant  and  checking  for  a  value  that  is  significantly  different  from  zero  for  this   constant.  

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

Theos \'erloor teen Strathvaal, Speel gelykop teen Lichtenburg. Theos het Saterdag hul l aaste

Maar het antwoord dat het meeste voor komt, is dat spiritualiteit iets is waar ze altijd mee bezig zijn en niet iets is ‘wat je er extra bij doet’.. Evelien zegt bijvoorbeeld dat

Figure 1 A map of Friedrichshain at the end of the DDR (1990) .... People who were directly involved mostly know exactly what they did on that night. Looking at

But we have just shown that the log-optimal portfolio, in addition to maximizing the asymptotic growth rate, also “maximizes” the wealth relative for one

The aim was to formulate a nano-emulsion and nano-emulgel containing selected statins (fluvastatin, lovastatin, rosuvastatin and simvastatin, separately) for transdermal

Figure D.16: Average cumulative concentration after 12 h for the scopolamine emulgel formulations with or without the use of Pheroid™ after epidermal skin diffusion A

Cumulative abnormal returns show a very small significant reversal (significant at the 10 per cent level) for the AMS Total Share sample of 0.6 per cent for the post event

tie hebben mogelijk gemaakt van belangrijke, ont- vreemde elementen van het decorum, zoals de beide kleine glas-in-loodramen aan de trap naar de tweede verdieping, de klapdeuren