• No results found

Economic growth, liberalization and the environment

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Economic growth, liberalization and the environment"

Copied!
35
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

Tilburg University

Economic growth, liberalization and the environment

Smulders, J.A.

Published in:

Encyclopedia of Energy Economics

Publication date: 2004

Document Version Peer reviewed version

Link to publication in Tilburg University Research Portal

Citation for published version (APA):

Smulders, J. A. (2004). Economic growth, liberalization and the environment. In C. Cleveland (Ed.), Encyclopedia of Energy Economics Elsevier.

General rights

Copyright and moral rights for the publications made accessible in the public portal are retained by the authors and/or other copyright owners and it is a condition of accessing publications that users recognise and abide by the legal requirements associated with these rights. • Users may download and print one copy of any publication from the public portal for the purpose of private study or research. • You may not further distribute the material or use it for any profit-making activity or commercial gain

• You may freely distribute the URL identifying the publication in the public portal Take down policy

(2)

Forthcoming in: Cutler Cleveland (ed) “Encyclopedia of Energy”, Volume 2, 53-64, Elsevier 2004

Economic growth, liberalization, and the environment

Sjak Smulders

Tilburg University

Glossary

Definition

I. Interactions between the economy and the environment

A. Economic growth and resource use

B. Externalities. markets and incentives

II. Trends in economic growth and resource use

A. Trends in economic growth

B. Trends in energy and materials

C. Cross country differences in resource intensities

III. Explaining the link between growth and resource use

A. The environment-income relationship

B. The role of environmental regulation

IV. International trade and the environment

A. The pollution haven hypothesis

B. Is trade beneficial?

(3)

V. Environmental regulation and productivity

A. The cost of environmental regulation

B. General equilibrium effects

C. In search of “Double Dividends”

(4)

GLOSSARY

Comparative advantage. A country has a comparative advantage in a particular good

if the ratio of costs to produce this good, relative to the cost to produce another good,

is lower than the same cost ratio in other countries. Comparative advantage is the

basis for trade: countries gain if they export the good they produce relatively most

efficient.

Economic growth. Steady increases in GDP.

Energy intensity. Energy supply divided by GDP.

Externality. A situation in which market transactions affect persons who are not

involved in the transaction directly (i.e. not through market prices).

GDP Gross domestic product. The sum of all output produced by economic activity

within a country. GNP (gross national product) includes net income from abroad, e.g.

rent, profits.

General equilibrium. A situation in which all markets in the economy are in

(5)

Market equilibrium. A situation, characterized by a certain volume of trade and a

price of a certain good, such that no market party wants to change behavior: no seller

of the good wants to increase or decrease supply, no consumers wants reduce or

increase demand.

OECD countries. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. The

Northern American and Western European countries, Greece, Turkey, and Mexico.

Real price. Relative price of a commodity in terms of another (basket of)

commodities. GDP is often measured in real prices (also labeled “at constant prices”)

to eliminate the effects of inflation (where inflation is the upward trend common in all

prices, leading to a downward trend in the purchasing power of money).

Total factor productivity (also: Multifactor productivity). Outputs per unit of input.

Changes in total factor productivity measure technological change, by accounting

(6)

DEFINITION

Economic growth is the steady increase in output produced by economic activity

within a country (GDP). A central question is whether economic growth is compatible

with a non-deteriorating environment and whether the environmental consequences of

economic growth have a major impact on welfare levels derived from growing output

of marketed goods. International trade has grown even faster than national income. It

has been asked whether increased trade has been bad for the environment and whether

it has caused rich countries to relocate their polluting industries to developing

countries. Another important question is how large are the costs associated with

environmental regulation in terms of competitiveness, productivity and employment

This article deals with these questions by reviewing empirical evidence and economic

theory on resource use and economic growth.

I. INTERACTIONS BETWEEN THE ECONOMY AND THE ENVIRONMENT

A. Economic growth and resource use

Statistics on national production levels and indicators of environmental

pressure have been collected the last decades (and reconstructed for the more distant

past) to document the link between economic growth and the environment. The theory

of economic growth and economic theories of natural resources provide explanations

and interpretations of the trends, as well as methods to assess future developments.

The basic approach in most statistical and theoretical analyses is the decomposition of

aggregate production of a nation into, on the one hand, the current state of technology

(7)

inputs are labor (hours worked), capital (produced means of production that can be

used over a certain time period), and natural resources.

Natural resources comprise energy inputs and material inputs. An important

distinction is between renewable and non-renewable resources. Renewable resources

are biotic populations, flora and fauna, which have the potential to grow by means of

natural reproduction. For example, the theory of renewable resources studies fishery

and forestry. Non-renewable resources are minerals of which physical supplies do not

grow on a for humans relevant time scale. Examples are metals (like aluminum,

copper, gold) and fossil fuels (like oil, coal, natural gas).

The basic characteristic of natural resources is that they cannot be produced,

but they serve as an essential input in production. A higher rate of resource usage

implies faster depletion of the available stock of the resource. In this sense resource

inputs differ in a fundamental way from other inputs used in production such as labor

and capital: labor is not used up and man-made capital can be accumulated. Another

important difference is that the available resource stock itself may directly affect

welfare as an amenity (non-use value). Resource economics studies the trade-off

between extraction of the resource for current consumption and conservation for later

dates. Environmental quality can also be considered as an input in the aggregate

production process. Pollution is an inevitable by-product of production. Pollution can

be seen as a degradation of environmental resources, like clean air and soil.

B. Externalities, markets, and incentives

Economic growth is the result of growth in inputs and increases in the

productivity of the inputs – that is, changes in technology. Economics further explains

(8)

are traded in factor markets. Prices match demand and supply and provide consumers

and suppliers with information and incentives. Population growth, for example, raises

the potential working force and the supply of labor inputs in the economy rises. This

fuels growth if wages adjust so that the growing working force is employed in

production. With more labor in production, capital can be operated at a higher

productivity level. This increase in the return to capital induces fuels investment in

new capital so that also growth in capital inputs fuels output growth. Similarly, the

demand for materials and energy increases. If these are available in limited supply,

their prices rise, which provides incentives to develop technologies that save on their

use. Thus while growing scarcity of inputs may itself impose a drag on growth, it may

also induce technological change which fuels economic growth.

Markets provide a powerful coordination mechanism. In sectors of the

economy where the demand for resources like materials or labor is high, prices rise

and this attracts resources to these sectors, away from other sectors. Thus resources

tend to be allocated in those sectors where they are in largest demand. The high

demand reflects a high willingness to pay for the resources and implies that their

value is considered to be large. This explains why the market mechanism in principle

can enhance efficiency and welfare in the economy.

The market can only coordinate social preferences (demand for certain goods

or services) and (technical) possibilities and resource endowments in a

welfare-maximizing way, if prices reflect these preferences and possibilities. This requires,

first, that the owners of production factors (the inputs like labor, capital and materials)

can charge a price that reflects their production cost, and, second, that consumers can

express their willingness to pay. For many environmental goods, these preconditions

(9)

air or climate. Pollution entails a cost to society, but not a cost to the polluting

producers. Waste can be disposed freely, but imposes a cost on society. When

economic activity – that is, a market transactions – imposes costs or benefits on

persons who are not involved in the transaction directly, externalities are said to be

present. Externalities cause markets to function imperfectly and welfare to be

impaired. This is why environmental policies may improve welfare. These policies

have to correct environmental externalities, for example by making firms pay for the

pollution costs they impose on society.

We can now be more precise to define the cost of pollution for society. From

an economic perspective, pollution (and, similarly, environmental degradation or

resource depletion) is costly to the degree that it causes externalities. Because the

value of environmental quality is not reflected in the prices in the economy, the

economic decisions that are based on these prices give rise to more pollution than

society finds optimal.

The ideal (optimal) environmental regulation imposes measures to eliminate

all external costs of pollution, that is, it makes all parties in society internalize all

social costs of pollution. In such a situation, welfare is maximal, but pollution is not

necessarily (and very unlikely) at the technical minimum. Although depletion of

natural resources and polluting consequences of production are by definition bad for

the environment, they are not necessarily bad for welfare. They provide the inputs for

production of valuable things. As long as the benefits from increases in production

outweigh the costs of environmental degradation, economic growth enhances welfare.

In the remaining sections of this article, we study how economic growth,

international trade, and environmental regulation affect the environment and welfare.

(10)

environment have to be made comparable to changes in economic production, which

requires a valuation method to put values on environmental improvements. Since this

is not only a hard, but also subjective task, we also look at the physical effects, by

which I mean the impact on pollution, pollution concentration and resource stocks

measured in physical terms. This is the conservationist perspective, to be contrasted

with the economic approach that deals with welfare effects.

II. TRENDS IN ECONOMIC GROWTH AND RESOURCE USE

A. Trends in economic growth

In the period between 1820 and 1995, total world production (GDP) has

grown on average at an annual rate of 2.2 per cent, which amounts to a more than 40

fold increase over a mere 175 years. This rate of change is unprecedented: in the 1800

years before this period world GDP increased less than 7 fold. Per capita economic

growth has been enormous also the last century. With current world population at

about 5.5 billion, 5 times as big as in 1820, per capita GDP is now almost 8 times

bigger than it was 175 years ago.

Differences among countries are large. In 1988, output per worker in the US

was more than 30 times higher than output in Subsahara Africa. Developing countries

often have per capita income levels that are less than 10 per cent of US levels (e.g.

India 9 per cent, China 6 per cent, in 1988). Per capita income in Western Europe is

on average 30 per cent lower than in North America, but income gaps are now smaller

than four decades ago. Typically, among the richer countries, there is convergence in

(11)

B. Trends in energy and materials

Economic growth directly translates into growing demand for energy

resources and materials, since they are necessary inputs in production. However, in

the process of growth, some energy resources or materials may be substituted for

others so that not all of them are used at an increasing rate. Technological change has

allowed many sectors of the economy or even entire economies to produce at a lower

overall energy intensity.

Primary energy supply in the OECD countries was roughly 50 percent higher

in 1999 than in 1971, but GDP rose faster. Indeed, from 1960-2000, energy use is

decoupled from economic growth, at least in the EU, Japan and the US (at annual

rates of 0.4, 0.2 and 1.4 per cent, respectively). The oil shortages in the 1970s induced

energy conservation programs. Also the growing relative importance of services

relative to manufacturing caused energy efficiency to rise. In recent years, growth in

energy use has accelerated due to increased transport and electricity use in service

sectors. Trends in materials use vary considerably over different materials. Iron and

steel have grown slower than GDP, paper use has grown in line with GDP, but

plastics and aluminum have grown faster than GDP.

The concern is that growing energy and materials use results in scarcity of

resources and imposes a threat to future growth. Stocks of virgin ores decline. The

stock of materials embedded in products grows, leaving less available for recycling. If

growth fuels demand for resources and supply becomes smaller, prices can be

expected to rise. Yet, most price indicators do not reflect growing scarcity. The prices

of most commodities have declined since 1960. Here, prices are measured in real

(12)

economists have concluded that resource scarcity will not limit growth, at least not

during the coming decades and not if we consider scarcity of those resources that are

traded in well-developed global markets, like most minerals and energy resources.

Falling prices may reflect technological progress, which allows mining at

lower cost, or exploration of new resource deposits. According to most economic

theories, this is likely to be a temporary phenomenon and in the long run prices of

non-renewable resources are expected to rise over time. This does not necessarily

imply, however, that future growth will no longer be fuelled by lower costs of energy

and materials, since technological change, as well as exploration and development of

new economically useful resources, may overcome scarcity limits.

The growing use of certain energy resources and materials has severe impacts

on the natural environment. In general, economists agree that free market forces do

not serve very well society’s demand for environmental amenities or conservation of

natural resources for which markets are illegal, incomplete, or do not exist (like water

and air quality, rare species, biodiversity, ecosystem services). Emissions of CO2 from

fossil fuel combustion pose major threats to air pollution and climate. Despite the

decoupling of energy use from economic growth in the developed economies and

despite the decline in the carbon content per unit of energy used, total CO2 emissions

have risen in almost all countries in the last decades. In large developing countries

like India, China and Brazil, absolute CO2 emissions have risen very rapidly. In

contrast to the OECD experience, their CO2 emissions per unit of GDP have risen at

fast rates (up to 2.6 percent per year, in India 1971-1998).

Other major threats to the environment come from the use of hazardous

industrial waste, emissions and toxic chemicals, which are used in the production

(13)

regulation, emissions from production activities (industry) have actually declined.

However, waste and emissions from consumption activities are growing. Municipal

waste and hazardous waste have increased in recent decades in developed countries,

at a rate faster than population and faster than GDP.

C. Cross country differences in resource intensities

Differences in energy used per unit of GDP are large. In Northern America per

capita energy use is more than twice per capita energy use in Japan, France or UK and

about 1.5 times that in Germany and Australia. The differences mainly arise because

of differences in per capita income and differences in energy used per unit of output.

Differences in the structure of production (in terms of the relative importance of

industrial production sectors) are hardly responsible for the differences in per capita

energy use.

III. EXPLANING THE LINK BETWEEN GROWTH AND RESOURCE USE

A. The environment – income relationship

Economists have tried to identify underlying mechanisms in resource use and

growth trends. A central question is how environmental pressure changes with

economic growth. One hypothesis is the so-called Environmental Kuznets Curve

(EKC) hypothesis, according to which environmental pressure or resource use first

increases with GDP, but – after a certain threshold income level – declines with per

(14)

emissions. The evidence is mixed: the EKC shows up, but only for some pollutants

and not in all countries.

In the typical approach, pollution in the major cities (or other measurement

stations) of a set of countries is compared and related to the level of income in these

cities. If pollution rises with the level of income but also declines with the square of

the level of income, the EKC holds.

The EKC is found for water pollutants and for air pollutants like SO2,

suspended particulate matter (dark matter as well as heavy particles), NOx and CO.

These pollutants cause health problems close to the place where they are emitted (i.e.

these are local pollutants), while their impact occurs simultaneous with emissions (i.e.

these are short-lived or flow pollutants). The EKC is generally rejected for municipal

waste, CO2 and aggregate energy consumption: these variables monotonically

increase with the level of income in a cross-section of countries. Since it is the

accumulation of municipal waste in landfills – rather than the annual flow – that

imposes environmental pressure, it is a stock pollutant. CO2 is partly a local flow

pollutant, but its main impact is through concentration of CO2 in the atmosphere on

the global climate (i.e. it is a global pollutant as well as a stock pollutant). Other

evidence on the main global stock pollutants and environmental indicators is only

indirect. For example, wilderness land is monotonically declining with the level of

income, which is a crude measure of the negative relation between income and

biodiversity loss.

B. The role of environmental regulation

Thus, the common pattern is that local pollutants and flow pollutants are more

(15)

The main driving force behind the lower pollution levels in richer countries decline is

policies to reduce pollution. In richer countries, citizens are willing to pay more for

improvements in environmental quality and succeed in convincing their local and

national governments to impose the necessary regulation to reduce urgent pollution

problems. Since the effect of reducing local flow pollutants has the most visible

effects for the constituencies of the local authorities, regulation mainly aims at these

rather than at global or stock pollutants. The latter affect other regions or future

generations, respectively, but not so much the authorities’ electorate. In this

interpretation, environmental improvement only occurs when environmental

regulation becomes more stringent in richer economies. That is, environmental

problems are not solved “automatically” by economic growth. Growth will be

accompanied by reductions in pollution only if a number of conditions is fulfilled.

First, when becoming richer, people must care more about environmental

quality. There is no strong evidence in favor of this claim. For example, in developing

countries, environmental quality and availability of natural resources is often much

more crucial for households than in developed countries. Yet, within developed

countries, willingness to pay for improvements in health rise with income. As a result,

richer citizens may be more in favor of costly measures to reduce pollutants with

direct health impacts.

Second, only if the costs of reducing pollution do not rise too much with

national income, citizens vote for pollution reduction. Technological change is

important in this respect. On the one hand, cleaner production processes have been

developed, which mitigates the cost of pollution reduction. On the other hand, some

new production processes and the production of new goods require more energy and

(16)

transport makes the economies heavily dependent on electricity and fossil fuels so that

reductions in energy use have a big cost in terms of loss of production. This may

explain why electricity and fossil fuels use does not decline with income, despite

concern about the environment.

Third, actual environmental policies need to reflect societies preferences for

environmental quality. Indeed, in countries with relatively high degree of political and

civil freedom, environmental problems decline more rapidly with income. In countries

with high indicators of corruption, natural resource depletion is faster.

Pollutants differ in terms of their (health) impact, the degree to which they are

local and short-lived, and the cost of reduction. As a result, when comparing

emissions of different pollutants in a particular country, some may rise and others

may fall with income. That is, the Kuznets curves – if they exist at all for the

pollutants at hand – overlap. It implies that while environmental quality improves on

account of the reduction in one pollutant, aggregate measures of environmental

quality may deteriorate because this pollutant is replaced by other pollutants. This

may be a problem in particular since stock pollutants replace short-lived pollutants,

which amounts to a shift of the environmental burden to future generations. Similarly,

Kuznets curves of different countries overlap. While rich countries reduce emissions

of a certain pollutant, poor countries may at the same time increase emissions in their

growth process. Thus, pollution is shifted from rich to poor places. As a result, the

existence of an EKC for a certain pollutant does not guarantee that worldwide

environmental quality improves over time. This phenomenon is particularly important

because the poor countries, which tend to increase emissions with production, account

for a much larger share in the world economy than the rich one and some of them are

(17)

IV. INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND THE ENVIRONMENT

A. The pollution haven hypothesis

The evidence on the EKC points out that national environmental policies

differ between high-income and low-income countries and that as a result of income

growth pollution in the North may be reduced over time at the cost of increasing

pollution in the South. There have been concerns that this process is reinforced by

international trade of goods and by foreign direct investment between North and

South. More stringent environmental policies in the North force pollution-intensive

industries located in the North to raise their prices relative to the prices charged by

firms in the South. Consumers in the North may then profitably import more goods

from the South and firms in the North may profitable relocate their plants to the

South. This claim on the effects of differences in stringency of environmental

regulation is labeled the “pollution haven hypothesis”.

Empirical evidence for the pollution haven hypothesis is not very strong. The

hypothesis has been tested in various (mainly indirect) ways. Typically, in a first step

polluting industries are identified, based on their emissions per unit (dollar) of output,

or pollution control costs as a fraction of value added. At the top of these rankings we

find industries like iron and steel, nonferrous metals, mining, pulp and paper,

industrial chemicals, petroleum refineries, rubber and leather products. In a second

step, the performance of these sectors in different countries is related to the country’s

(18)

differences. Stringency is either measured as an index based on law and regulation, or

a measure of pollution control expenditures.

Within the US, polluting industries tend to export smaller volumes, start fewer

new plants, and attract less investment in states with more stringent environmental

regulation than in states with more lenient environmental regulation. Among different

countries, the effects of differences in environmental regulations are harder to trace.

Overall, industrial countries have reduced their share in world trade of goods from

polluting industries relative to developing countries over the last decades. However,

there is no evidence that this trend is mainly due to differences in environmental

regulation or due to international trade. The pattern of growth in these countries may

be caused by a shift to pollution-intensive industries (as a movement along the

upward sloping part of the EKC). Moreover, the industrial countries remain the

largest exporters in the most polluting industries. Hence, we must reject the claim that

internationally most pollution is created in countries with lax environmental

standards. The main explanation behind this finding is that other factors than

environmental regulation are much more decisive in determining production cost or

location advantages. The share of compliance costs for environmental regulation in

total cost is small relative to the cost savings that can be gained from the availability

of skilled workers able operate advanced technologies, access to large consumer

markets, and political stability. Polluting industries sometimes have high transport

costs so that proximity to consumer markets is important. Polluting industries are also

typically capital-intensive and operated by skilled workers. These factors make

developed countries a more attractive location for polluting industries. Hence,

differences between North and South in availability (that is, endowments) of capital

(19)

B. Is trade beneficial?

For given differences in endowments of capital and labor, relatively lax

environmental regulation in some countries, in particular the poorer ones, is likely to

shift some of the dirty industries to the South. The question is whether this is always

undesirable. According a standard economic argument, there may be mutual benefits

from relocation of pollution intensive industries between different countries. For

example, countries with low income but enough space to keep away pollution from its

population may be willing to accept pollution if this can greatly boost income.

High-income countries with high population density care less about increases in High-income if it

comes at the cost of pollution problems. In this case, both types of countries benefit if

pollution is relocated from high-income to low-income countries.

While lax environmental policies in the South seem to burden citizens in the

South with pollution havens, workers in the North may be concerned about the

stringent environmental policies in their countries. The North loses jobs in

pollution-intensive industries and export performance in these sectors falls when these

industries move to the South. However, at the same time, trade with the South allows

the North to improve performance in clean industries, so that again trade creates

mutual benefits for North and South (although these benefits may come only after

some time-consuming – and therefore costly – adjustments in the economy). Indeed,

if the North would not be engaged in trade with the South, environmental regulation

would also result in job losses in polluting industries and shifts to clean industries, but

it would forego the benefits from importing and consuming goods that can be

(20)

a living by exporting goods that can be produced at a comparative advantage in the

North.

In general, differences in environmental regulation may reflect differences in

social costs to deal with pollution and form a true basis for mutually beneficial trade.

However, if national environmental regulation ignores the average citizen’s

preference for pollution and fails to reflect the social costs of pollution, trade is no

longer always mutually beneficial. This is why large multinational corporations have

been criticized when they negotiate concessions with elite governments and exploit

their monopoly power. However, hard evidence on unbalanced benefits and costs

from the activities of such firms is not available.

Other situations where trade not necessarily leads to mutual gains occur when

pollution is transboundary, that is when pollution from one country harms citizens of

other countries. Since national governments are not likely to take into account these

pollution spillover effects, they tend to set pollution regulation too lax. For all

countries to gain from trade, environmental regulation in each country should reflect

the cost of pollution not just to own citizens, but to the world community as a whole.

Thus, when SO2 emissions in UK hardly affect British citizens but cause forests in

Scandinavia to die, the UK may be tempted to impose lax regulation of SO2

emissions, thus creating a comparative advantage in SO2-intensive goods and

boosting export of these goods. This trade would harm Scandinavia.

A final situation of harmful international trade may arise when countries have

strategic reasons to set overly-lax or overly-stringent environmental policies. Some

environmentalists have feared that governments set environmental policies overly lax.

Governments may have an incentive to accept environmental standards that are lower

(21)

industry a cost advantage over foreign firms, and thus make higher profits. (This has

been labeled “ecological dumping”). However, if many governments try to protect

their polluting industries in this way, they may all fail in a “race to the bottom”: the

lax standard in one country is offset by the response in the other country to also lower

environmental regulation. Only if firms’ location choices and cost levels are

sufficiently responsive to differences in environmental standards, national

governments can use environmental policies as a strategic instrument against other

countries. In the past, the lack of strong evidence for pollution havens has been

interpreted as evidence against significant firm responses to environmental stringency

and the fear for strategic use of environmental policy seemed ungrounded. Recently,

however, evidence of firm responses become stronger so that strategic environmental

may still be reasons for concern.

C. Is trade good for the environment?

Although we have no hard evidence on the magnitude of the net benefits (or

costs) of trade in polluting goods, and there is no strong evidence on large effects of

environmental regulation on trade and foreign direct investment, we have some

detailed analyses of the effects an increase in world trade has on pollution in different

countries. Trade has significant effects on pollution, but often more trade implies a

cleaner environment.

World trade has intensified enormously the last decades. Between 1973 and

1998, world merchandise exports and global foreign direct investment have grown at

annual rates of 9 and 14 per cent respectively. This expansion of trade cannot be held

responsible for increases in world pollution. The share of dirty products in world trade

(22)

imports in GDP) to closed economies (countries with little foreign trade), statistical

analysis shows that open economies have less pollution per unit of GDP (other things

equal). Open economies tend to adopt clean technologies more rapidly.

Trade often has a beneficial impact on the environment because of the

interaction between comparative advantages and adjustment of environmental

regulation. High-income countries tend to have higher environmental standards. High

income countries can also, however, produce pollution-intensive (which are often

skilled-labor or capital-intensive) products at a relatively low cost thanks to access to

advanced technology, and large endowments of skilled labor and capital. It implies

that high-income countries have a comparative advantage in producing

pollution-intensive goods. When they liberalize trade, they tend to export more of these goods.

Thus, world trade becomes greener since trade shifts production of polluting goods to

countries where environmental standards are higher. Moreover, international trade

increases income, which leads to a policy response since richer countries tend to

impose more stringent environmental regulation. Thus, also countries with lower

incomes tighten their environmental regulation. Multinational firms adopt

environmental practices overseas that are (partly) determined by environmental

regulations in their home countries, under pressure of consumer actions and for fear of

loss of reputation.

Although evidence on an aggregate level suggests that international trade is

benign to the environment, in certain areas trade has serious adverse impact on the

environment. Certain types of pollution or natural resource use remain unregulated

and it is in these areas that trade give rise to concerns. A first example is transport.

The growth in world trade has been accompanied with increases in transport

(23)

associated with transport are not fully reflected in regulation so that welfare losses

and excessive pollution may stem from the increase in transport. Since the costs of

transport cross borders, appropriate policies require international coordination, which

is often hard to establish. Secondly, transport involves the problem of invasive

species: the accidental or intentional introduction of harmful non-indigenous species

of plants and animals can damage environmental resources. The cost of screening and

quarantines is often prohibitive. Thirdly, the concentration of agriculture in certain

locations without appropriate regulation puts stress on biological diversity with

potential loss of soil quality in larger regions in the longer run. It destroys habitat of

species and may lead to extinction of theses species and loss of biodiversity.

V. ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION AND PRODUCTIVITY

A. The cost of environmental regulation

Environmental regulation aims at improving environmental quality but may

come at the cost of jobs, productivity, or other undesirable economic effects. To

justify environmental regulation on economic grounds, it should be shown in a

cost-benefit analysis whether the cost-benefits are large enough to incur the costs. In some

cases, the costs are found to be small or even negative, that is, there are benefits to be

reaped not only in terms of environmental improvement but also in other fields.

Estimates of the total costs of environmental regulation vary enormously between

different studies.

The traditional argument is that environmental regulation imposes costs on

(24)

administration of the regulation. Firms are burdened with costs because, first, they

have to install and operate pollution control equipment, intensify monitoring, and face

higher administrative burdens. Second, under certain types of regulation, they may

face pollution charges, expenditures on buying pollution permits or quotas, or fines in

so far they emit more than the quotas that are allocated to them. Third, depending on

the degree that they pass through costs to prices, they see demand for their output fall

and suffer from lower profits.

The total burden on polluting firms depends much on firm characteristics and

the employed technology. Estimates of direct costs of complying with environmental

regulation vary from less than one percent of GDP in 1972 to more than 2.5 percent at

the end of the 1990s in the US and slightly lower figures in Western Europe. Across

industries, petroleum and coal industries faced pollution control capital expenditures

up to one quarter of total capital expenditures, while for industries in rubber and

plastics production the number was only 2 per cent.

More crucial from an economic perspective is that the burden of regulation

depends on the design of the regulation; in particular on the flexibility firms have to

choose their own way to comply with the regulation. At the one extreme, the regulator

prescribes the technology the firm has to use or the pollution control actions it has to

take, leaving little flexibility to the firms. At the other extreme, the regulator allows

firms to emit up to a specified emissions allowance and leaves it to the firm’s

discretion by what means to reduce emissions as well as whether to trade pollution

allowances with other firms (system of marketable pollution permits). Compared to

the former type of regulation (the command-and-control approach), the latter type of

regulation (the market-based approach) minimizes the costs of regulation. First, it

(25)

will have an incentive to do so. Second, it gives incentives to firms that can reduce

emissions at lowest cost to do most of the reduction and sell their pollution

allowances to other firms. Thus, total pollution control costs are minimized.

Alternative market-based instruments are charges (taxes) proportional to emissions.

Up to now, market-based instruments have been applied less frequently than

command and control instruments, but their importance grows. Successes with

marketable permits have been established with respect to reductions of lead content in

petrol, air pollutants and sulphur dioxide emissions in particular. Estimates of the cost

savings potential of moving from command-and-control to market-based instruments

range from 50 to 90 percent.

Sometimes regulated firms find zero cost options to comply with more

stringent environmental regulation, or even make profits out of it. Case studies have

documented situations in which the reductions of materials or toxic chemical use for

environmental reasons saved enough on the firm’s expenditures on inputs to easily

pay back the investment cost of adjusting the production process. Even without

environmental regulation, the investment would have been justified, since it allowed

for a real efficiency improvement.

It is unlikely that these situations systematically arise, since managers of firms

are supposed to look for opportunities to improve efficiency and exploit them even

without intervention by environmental regulators. Thus, when firms maximize profits

and regulation constrains their choice of technologies, the smaller choice menu must

lead to fewer opportunities to operate at certain profit levels and regulation is costly.

This conclusion is unlikely to change if we acknowledge the limits to profit

maximization because of informational and managerial problems. No doubt,

(26)

managers’ span of control is insufficient to assess and eliminate all of them. Because

of the small share of environment-related costs, managers may systematically ignore

environment-related inefficiencies. Then, environmental regulation may make

managers more focused on cost savings potentials related to pollutants and materials

use. However, it may come at a cost by turning away their attention from other

inefficiencies so that on balance it is unlikely that environmental regulation can

systematically – that is, economy-wide –improve overall efficiency.

Opportunities for cost savings have been explored by engineering, or

“bottom-up”, studies. These studies start from an emissions reduction target for the economy

as a whole and then identify all the technological measures by which this target can be

achieved. For each of them, the researcher estimates the cost incurred by firms and

adds these up to an economy-wide total. Often the numbers are surprisingly low,

suggesting that technological opportunities abound to improve the environment at low

cost. The problem with these studies is that many hidden costs are ignored. Adoption

of new technologies will not only change firms’ emissions, but also product

characteristics and quality, employment structure, and input demand. It requires

adjustments beyond the simple installation of pollution control equipment. The entire

production and marketing process may be affected.

The alternative method to assess pollution control costs, sometimes labeled the

“top-down” approach, starts from a statistical (and econometric) analysis of the

relationship between production costs and environmental regulation, and between

emissions and regulation across industries. The statistical results are used to make a

projection how costs are affected by a hypothetical change in emissions, which

corresponds to the policy target. This requires building a stylized model of the entire

(27)

statistical results on how markets work and react to policy changes. These “top-down”

studies suggest much higher costs of environmental policy than bottom-up studies.

Hence, adjustment costs are substantial. A drawback of this method is that it

necessarily relies on historical data on firms’ reactions to regulation and that it cannot

incorporate the details of available new technologies to meet the environmental target.

The results are also quite sensitive to the modeling structure and assumptions made.

Econometric techniques have also been used to estimate the effects of

environmental regulation on employment. One would expect to find a negative

correlation between stringency of environmental regulation and employment changes

in pollution-intensive industries. Most studies find small effects when relating

environmental regulation across US states to employment. Often the correlation

between employment in dirty industries and environmental regulation is even

positive. The main explanation is that we should not expect a causal relation from

environmental stringency to employment, but rather view both employment and

regulation as being determined simultaneously by economic and political factors.

States with a strong economy, high productivity of their industries and high income

can afford –and may actually prefer – more stringent regulations than poorer states; at

the same time the former states may experience strong employment growth as a result

of the favorable economic conditions.

B. General equilibrium effects

To assess the over-all costs of environmental regulation, we have to measure

not only how it directly imposes costs on a regulator and regulated firms, but also how

it affects other items on the government’s budget and how it affects customers and

(28)

other: a consumer buys goods from firms and gets her income from (another) firms,

pays taxes to governments, which subsidize firms and provide infrastructural goods

for firms. Hence, regulating certain firms may affect the entire economy through these

linkages. Such indirect effects are labeled general equilibrium effects, as they reflect

the effects after all markets in the economy have reacted and adjusted such that a new

equilibrium in the economy as a whole results.

The linkages between economic activities may sometimes mitigate the cost of

environmental regulation, and sometimes reinforce them. When regulated firms have

cut back their polluting activities, they buy less from their suppliers and these

experience loss in sales, too. However, other firms may gain. Regulated firms may

need to buy specialized equipment to control pollution, so firms selling this

equipment gain. When regulated firms pass on their higher costs into higher prices,

their customers switch to other producers. Hence, firms likely to gain from regulation

are those that supply goods that customers view as a suitable substitute for the

regulated firms’ goods.

The overall cost of environmental regulation is the sum of all gains and losses.

The indirect gains are not likely to fully offset the direct costs for one obvious reason.

Regulation aims at reducing pollution, and this requires reductions in polluting inputs.

If the economy as a whole has to cut back on inputs, total output is likely to fall, too.

This effect may be reinforced over time, through effects on investment. Investment in

new capital goods fuels growth in the economy. The return to investment is likely to

be smaller if new capital goods have to be run with less energy or polluting inputs, so

that the incentive to invest is crowded out through more stringent environmental

(29)

The economy-wide impact of environmental regulations can only be estimated

– rather than directly measured – since we cannot observe how the economy would

have evolved in the absence of the regulation. Estimates therefore heavily depend on

the model that is used for the estimation. Based on standard macroeconomic or

growth-theoretic models, estimates of the total cost are in the same order of

magnitude as the direct pollution control costs, about two percent of GDP. Some

researchers have noticed that the surge in regulatory costs coincides with the growth

slowdown in the 1970s. Yet, all calculations show that only a very small portion of

the slowdown can be attributed to environmental regulation.

C. In search of “Double Dividends”

Despite the fact that environmental regulation amounts to restricting inputs in

the economy and is therefore likely to reduce output, counterarguments have been

advanced that environmental regulation may bring about large gains. The key

argument is that environmental policy shifts economic activity away from polluting

sectors to other sectors in which the contribution of economic activity to welfare is

larger. Hence, while regulation forces the economy to cut polluting inputs, it may

raise total output by improving the average efficiency at which inputs are employed.

1. Removal of inefficient subsidy and tax programs

Efficiency gains can arise from environmental regulation if efficiency differs between

sectors, in particular if efficiency in polluting sectors is lower than in clean sectors.

Normally, differences in efficiency are competed away by market forces, but

(non-environmental) regulation may distort these market forces and create sectors where

(30)

OECD agricultural output is heavily subsidized so that high-cost/low-productivity

agricultural activities in these countries remain viable. This support creates

inefficiencies and the tax revenue could be better spent from an efficiency point of

view. The widespread use of energy subsidies to firms also creates support for low

productivity energy-intensive production. If these subsidies are abolished and

replaced by environmental regulation that reflects, for example, the adverse impacts

of pesticide on soil and water quality or those of energy use on world climate,

efficiency gains can be large by shifting economic activity away from inefficient

farming and energy-intensive industries.

2. Environmental tax reform

Gains from environmental regulations have also been claimed to be feasible

when they can be combined with reductions in certain taxes. On the one hand,

governments have relied on taxes on labor and capital to fund their budgets. These

taxes may reduce the incentive to participate in the labor market or to invest in capital,

so that the taxes distort markets and create inefficiently low levels of employment and

investment. On the other hand, environmental taxes (charges on emissions, auctioning

off of pollution permits) not only give incentive to address environmental problems

but also raise revenue.

Indeed, the first important insight from the theory of public finance theory is

that it is better to “recycle” the revenues from environmental taxes through reductions

in distortionary taxes than to use them to fund the general government budget.

However, the second insight is that replacing distortionary taxes on labor and capital

by revenue-raising environmental taxes will reduce the efficiency of the tax system

(31)

first dividend) is not likely to be offset by a cheaper way for the government to raise

taxes (which would give a second – non-environmental – dividend). The reason is that

a switch from taxing labor and capital to taxing pollution narrows the base on which

the taxes can be levied. Capital and labor income each constitutes a much larger

fraction of total income than the share of pollution in total cost. As noted above,

environmental taxation reduces inputs in production and forces firms to spend more

on pollution control. This reduces output and income in the economy, the tax base

becomes smaller and the government raises less tax revenue from non-environmental

taxes. The revenues from environmental taxes are insufficient to make up for the loss

of revenues from non-environmental taxes.

In practice, the replacement of non-environmental taxes by revenue-raising

environmental taxes may yield a double dividend if the existing tax system is highly

inefficient along other, non-environmental dimensions (for example if capital is

excessively taxed relative to labor). In this case, the tax system can be improved even

without the introduction of environmental taxes, but vested interests or distributional

concerns may prevent these tax reforms. Results from economic simulation models

suggest that gains from the combination of environmental taxation and tax reform

may yield substantial benefits in practice, but not for all groups in society. The major

challenge is to find out ways to compensate losers from tax reform, without providing

the wrong incentives. For example, workers and capital owners in polluting industry

are likely to be hurt by environmental tax reform; but compensating them for losses

should not reduce their incentive to invest funds and to find alternative employment

outside the polluting industry.

(32)

Environmental regulation has short-run costs but long-run gains. These gains

arise primarily in terms of a cleaner environment; they take time to materialize since

the recovery of environmental quality is time consuming. However, as a feedback

effect, a cleaner environment may improve productivity in the economy, which may

offset the economic costs. The most obvious example is the effect on productivity in

sectors that heavily rely on environmental resources. Policies to improve water and air

quality of certain regions may boost the attractiveness of these regions for tourism or

residential development. Hence, profits and productivity of tourism and construction

may rise. Policies aimed at marine resources may also boost fish populations, thus

improving productivity of the fishery. Forest management may give rise to both

environmental benefits and improved yields for forestry.

In general, productivity of sectors or the economy as a whole is measured by

multi factor productivity, which is a measure of the amount of outputs per unit of

inputs. The factor productivity of conventional inputs like labor and capital may

increase if environmental quality improves. Capital equipment and residential

buildings may depreciate less fast if air pollution is less. The productivity of labor

may benefit from health improvements that are induced by better environmental

quality. Less working days are lost if health improves, which increases output per unit

of input. Health care costs fall, which alleviates private and government budgets.

Substantial costs can be avoided if climate change is mitigated, like risks of sea level

rise (which directly affect agriculture, urban areas in coastal regions, and dike

maintenance costs), and the loss of harvest in agriculture due to draughts or changes

in precipitation.

(33)

Summarizing the results above, we may state that most empirical research

suggests that improvements in environmental quality require costly regulation, despite

the various general equilibrium effects on efficiency and productivity that may

mitigate the direct costs of regulation. The focus on costs of environmental regulation

may distract attention from its benefits: these costs are incurred to achieve

environmental benefits. The costs are worthwhile being incurred if the benefits

outweigh the costs in a social cost-benefit analysis.

The social benefits from environmental improvements are often found to be

large, but they are less visible than the costs of environmental regulation. Measuring

the benefits requires putting a value on improvements in environmental quality, in

health, and environmental amenities. When asked in surveys, individuals indicate that

they are willing to give up large amounts of money and income to pay for these

improvements. We can also infer individuals’ valuation of environmental amenities

from the amount of money individuals spend on traveling to locations with

environmental amenities, or the premium people are willing to pay on houses located

near them. The numbers from these studies can be used to construct an aggregate

indicator of the value of environmental improvements, which can then be confronted

to the cost estimates to undertake a social cost-benefit analysis.

The problem that the value of environmental amenities is unobservable (that

there are no market prices) can thus be solved. However, perceptions may still be

biased. Since neither market transactions nor market prices are associated with

environmental goods, the current system of national accounts does not include the

value of environmental goods as it only measures the value of marketed goods. As a

result, the environmental benefits that environmental policies create are not part of

(34)

progress. Attempts have been launched to adjust national income figures so as to

include imputed values of environmental improvements and degradation (see

Bartelmus’ entry in this Encyclopedia). These “green GDP” figures would more

appropriately measure well-being and progress than current GDP figures do. As long

as these adjustments are not standard, there seems to be a trade-off between

environment and growth, while once we take into account the value of environment

for well-being, there is a close positive connection between environment and

economic progress.

FURTHER READING

Bovenberg, A.L. and L.H. Goulder (2002). "Environmental Taxation and Regulation"

in: A. Auerbach and M.S. Feldstein (eds.), Handbook of Public Economics Vol.3,

Chapter 23, North Holland, Amsterdam.

Jaffe, A.B., S.R. Peterson, P.R. Portney, and R.N. Stavins (1995) “Environmental

Regulation and the Competitiveness of U.S. Manufacturing: What Does the Evidence

Tell Us?” Journal of Economic Literature 33, 132-163.

Krautkraemer, J. (1998) “Nonrenewable Resource Scarcity” Journal of Economic

(35)

Lieb, Chr.M. 2003 “The Environmental Kuznets Curve - A Survey of the Empirical

Evidence and of Possible Causes” Interdisciplinary Institute of Environmental

Economics, University of Heidelberg, study 391,

http://www.uni-heidelberg.de/institute/fak18/awi/publications/papers/dp392.pdf

Schulze, G. and H. Ursprung (eds) (2001) International Environmental Economics; a

survey of the issues, Oxford University Press.

R.D. Simpson, M.A. Toman, and R.U. Ayres (eds). (2005) “Scarcity and Growth

Revisited; Natural Resources and the Environment in the New Millennium” The

Johns Hopkins University Press for Resources for the Future.

Smulders, S. (2000) "Economic Growth and Environmental Quality" in: H. Folmer

and L. Gabel (eds) Principles of Environmental Economics, Cheltenham: Edward

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

Copyright and moral rights for the publications made accessible in the public portal are retained by the authors and/or other copyright owners and it is a condition of

Regarding local environmental quality measures, higher income inequality is found to be associated with: less water pollution in developed and developing countries but more

The impact of rational culture on external environmental practices – According to the findings, firms are performance driven and want to achieve environmental

Lastly, we would suggest for future research to investigate the reasons why women on board have a negative effect on environmental disclosure quality and on the probability

The two are equally important and justified, even though they are perceived and reasoned differently depending on the meanings held: emerging economies have a major interest in

Middel I6 liet zowel in de screening bij broccoli enige werking zien en in sla geen werking zien.. Middel L6 liet in de screening bij zowel sla als broccoli geen

Relative decoupling of resources or impacts means that the growth rate of the resources used or environmental impacts is lower than the economic growth rate, so that