• No results found

The Impact of Chinese Loans on Good Governance in Latin America

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "The Impact of Chinese Loans on Good Governance in Latin America"

Copied!
103
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

Leiden University

Faculty of Governance and Public Affairs

MSc in Public Administration

9 June 2016

The Impact of Chinese Loans on Good Governance

in Latin America

Master Thesis

Author: Giulia Valentini

Supervisor: Dr. A. Afonso

Second Reader: Dr. A.L. Dimitrova

(2)

Table of Contents

1. Introduction……….2 2. Theoretical Framework………...8 2.1 Literature Review……….8 2.2 Conceptual Framework………20 2.2.1 Key Concepts………...20

2.2.2 Main Hypothesis and Competing Hypotheses………28

3. Research Design……….…31 3.1 Operalisation of Concepts………...31 3.1.1 Dependent Variables……….31 3.1.2 Independent Variable………35 3.1.3 Extraneous Variable……….35 3.2 Research Approach……….36 3.3 Case Selection……….39 3.4 Research Method……….47 3.5 Limitations………..50

4. Data Analysis and Results………52

4.1 Data Collection and Analysis……….52

4.1.1 Dependent Variable 1: Voice………...52

4.1.2 Dependent Variable 2: Performance………...56

4.1.3 Dependent Variable 3: Accountability……….63

4.1.4 Dependent Variable 4: Fairness………..72

4.1.5 Extraneous Variable: National Regulations………...77

4.2 Results………...82

5. Conclusion………....…………...85

(3)

1. Introduction

In 2014 China surpassed the United States as the world’s largest economy in terms of purchasing power parity according to the IMF (Bird 2014, pars.1,3). Its economic success is particularly remarkable considering that less than four decades earlier it was still one of the world’s poorest countries (Zhu 2012, p.103). From 1979 to 2014, China experienced an impressive GDP growth average of 10%, which is only now slowing down to around 6-7% (Morrison 2015, p.1; The Economist 2015a, par.1).

The origins of China’s economic ascent can be traced back to the program of economic reforms introduced by Deng Xiaoping in 1978. Following the Cultural Revolution, the Chinese government adopted a policy of Gaige Kaifang or ‘reform and opening up’, intended to strengthen its legitimacy through strong economic growth and higher living standards (Zhu 2012, p.110). To begin with, a new system of incentives for agricultural production was introduced, enabling farmers to sell part of their produce at market prices (McMillan et al. 1989, p.785). Then, various special economic zones were established along the coast, intended to promote competition, foster technological innovation and attract foreign investment through a more liberal regulatory environment (Stoltenberg 1984, p.639). Gradually, a variety of reforms was introduced over the years, which effectively relaxed the central government’s control over economic policy-making: state-owned enterprises were given over to local governments and permitted to operate at market prices, individuals were allowed to start their own businesses and price controls were abolished in stages. Additionally, trade barriers and tariffs were gradually removed, as China shifted its economy towards an export-led growth strategy (Morrison 2015, p.4).

These economic reforms set the basis for China's economic rise by boosting productivity and large-scale capital investment. The increase in productivity came as a result of the more efficient reallocation of resources formerly controlled by the central government, the rise of market-oriented non-state enterprises, and the external competition brought about by the opening of the economy. As for large-scale capital investment, it was made possible by the increase in

(4)

efficiency following the economic reforms, which "boosted output and increased resources for additional investment in the economy" (Morrison 2015, p.7).

Together, these two factors contributed to China’s vertiginous economic rise, the effects of which have been felt not only domestically, where over 800 million people have been raised out of poverty, but also globally (World Bank 2016, par.1). China’s international trade has expanded significantly, in the form of high exports of low-cost products, which have increased global manufacturing competition, and a strong demand for raw materials, which have maintained global commodity prices high (Plumer 2014, par.2; The Economist 2015b, par.1). Furthermore, it is now an important source of investments and loans for rich and poor countries alike (Friedman 2011, par.9). In short, China has become a major economic power and a “key driver of the world economy” (Associated Press 2016, par.12).

The rise of China has had a particular impact on the developing world, both indirectly, through the emergence of an alternative development model, and directly, in the form of its growing economic influence over these countries resulting from an increase in trade relations and in the provision of aid, loans and investment. The present research will focus on China’s impact in one region in particular: Latin America.

While China has been providing development assistance to Latin America since the 1960s, until recently it was relatively insignificant, limited to a few countries and ideologically-driven (Chen & Chen 2014, par.3)(Chen & Su 2014, par.12). Since the beginning of the 21st century, however, financial and economic ties have expanded at considerable speed. China's economic boom has increased its demand for raw materials such as oil, copper and soybeans, as well as for markets for its manufactured goods, both of which Latin America has been able to provide. Therefore, while there are various other dimensions to China’s current relations with Latin America, for instance China's desire to increase its geopolitical influence and its ideological ties to countries such as Venezuela, their deepening relationship is driven mainly by economic concerns (Ferchen 2012, pars.4-5).

(5)

China’s economic ties with the region consist mainly of trade, investment and loans. Between 2000 and 2013, Latin America’s trade with China grew at an average of 27 percent per year, rising from $12 billion to $289 billion (Elson 2014, p.44; Pineo 2015, par.4). This year China is expected to become the region’s most important trading partner after the United States, overtaking the European Union (Coyer 2016, par.3). It already is the largest trading partner of Brazil, Chile and Peru and the second largest of Argentina and Venezuela (Pineo 2015, par.5). Additionally, China has established free trade agreements with Chile (2006), Peru (2010) and Costa Rica (2011) (Pineo 2015, par.15).

Although less important than trade, investment and loans are also a significant component of Sino-Latin American relations. When it comes to China’s investments in the region, these have reached an annual average of $10.7 billion during the last five years, and are expected to increase in the future. Most of these investments come from state-owned firms and tend to concentrate on specific sectors, with 57 percent of them financing commodity extraction (Dussel Peters 2015, p.9). As for loans, since 2005 China has lent nearly $100 billion to Latin America (Elson 2014, p.45). Lending by China was at its highest in 2010, when Chinese loans to the region were equivalent to those from the World Bank, Inter-American Bank and Export-Import Bank of the United States combined, but has since then decreased (Elson 2014, p.45). These loans tend to go to countries with limited access to alternative sources of funding, such as Venezuela, which alone has received around half of China’s loans to the region. Furthermore, they are often tied to specific projects and repaid in kind through oil sales (Elson 2014, p.45).

Chinese lending is predominantly concentrated on financing energy and infrastructure projects (Dussel Peters 2015, p.10). These loans are therefore particularly beneficial to Latin America, a region which has historically suffered from underinvestment in infrastructure to the detriment of its competitiveness “in aspects such as productivity, trade, foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows, income inequality and population health” (Gordon 2012, par.4). As the 2000s commodity boom comes to an end, Chinese loans have thus provided a much needed fiscal space for Latin American countries to continue improving their infrastructure despite falling export revenues, identified by the IMF as a key priority for maintaining growth during the global financial crisis (Gallagher, cited in Dominguez 2015, pars.12-14; Harrup 2016, par.1). At the

(6)

same time, many of the projects financed by China have been beset by problems linked to “social and political instability, environmental disputes, labor controversies, and disputes with local communities” (Dussel Peters 2015, p.10). Furthermore, Chinese loans to Latin America should be understood as unofficial components of China’s broader ‘One Belt, One Road’ strategy, an ambitious global infrastructure investment project aimed at maximising China’s geopolitical influence and access to resources (Chanda 2015, pars.2,11). Therefore, there are doubts as to whether these projects will contribute to the region’s long-term development “beyond serving as conduits for commodity flows”(Dussel Peters 2015, p.11).

The effects of China’s rise as a major loan provider in Latin America are likely to extend beyond the economic sphere. A defining feature of Chinese loans is that, unlike those provided by Western lenders, they come with no conditions attached. Since the 1980s, the international development assistance regime has been characterized by the practice of conditionality, that is, making development loans and aid contingent on the implementation of certain economic and/or political reforms in the recipient country (Babb & Carruthers 2008, p.13). At first, conditionality was understood mainly in economic terms, in the form of the stabilisation and structural adjustment programs of the IMF and World Bank (Selbervik 1999, p.12). These programs sought to fundamentally transform developing countries’ economies in accordance with the neoliberal economic orthodoxy of the Washington Consensus, through market-friendly policies such as privatisation, trade liberalisation and reduction of public spending (WHO n.d., pars.1-2). However, since the 1990s the concept of conditionality has been expanded to include political reforms aimed at improving good governance in recipient countries (Selbervik 1999, p.13). Therefore, most multilateral lenders now make their loans conditional on the implementation of reforms promoting “effective participation in public policy-making, the prevalence of the rule of law and an independent judiciary, institutional checks and balances through horizontal and vertical separation of powers, and effective oversight agencies” (Santiso 2001, p.5).

In contrast, China’s does not attach conditionalities to its loans, a policy it justifies in terms of its commitment to the principles of non-interference and respect for sovereignty (Ferchen et al. 2012, par.4). Consequently, there are concerns over the possibility that the rise of China as a major lender might undermine the international community’s attempts to promote

(7)

good governance in developing countries, leading to a more undemocratic and corrupt world (Kaplinski et al., 2007; Manning, 2006; Naim, 2009).

This leads us to our research question: What is the impact of Chinese loans on good governance in Latin America? The present study will conduct a comparative case analysis of three development projects in Latin America, one financed through Chinese loans and two financed through loans from the international financial institutions. The projects will be assessed in terms of four key dimensions of good governance: voice, performance, accountability and fairness. The aim of the research is therefore to compare the level of good governance of Chinese development projects vis-à-vis IFI-funded development projects so as to determine whether the increase in number of projects financed through Chinese loans will have a negative, neutral or positive impact on good governance in Latin America.

The research will contribute to current academic debates surrounding the implications of the rise of China for the developing world. For various scholars the emergence of China as a major lender will be beneficial for developing countries, providing them with an alternative to the highly intrusive loan programmes of the international development agencies and enabling them to pursue economic development on their own terms (Brautigam 2009; Gallagher et al. 2012; Kaplan 2015). However, for others China follows an exploitative, mercantilist strategy which will entrench dependency on commodity exports and harm long-term development (Farnsworth 2011; Jenkins 2012; Konings 2007; Ortiz 2012). Furthermore, they argue, China's provision of loans without conditionalities will weaken good governance in the developing world by removing the financial incentives for change provided by the IFIs' conditional loans (Kaplinski et al. 2007; Manning 2006; Naim 2009). Therefore, the present study will attempt to contribute to this debate by providing empirical evidence on the consequences of China’s loans in terms of good governance in Latin America. Furthermore, by focusing on Latin America in particular, the research will address a significant gap in the relevant literature, which so far has concentrated on China’s influence in Africa and, when it comes to its influence in Latin America, has given more attention to trade relations than to development loans (Gallagher et al. 2012, p.3).

(8)

The present study will be divided into five chapters. In the second chapter, the research’s theoretical framework will be presented. It will begin with a review of the literature on good governance and Sino-Latin American relations, followed by a definition of our key concepts, good governance and development loans. Finally, the chapter will present our main hypothesis and competing hypotheses. The third chapter will outline the research design. It will first operationalise our two key concepts into four dependent variables, corresponding to the four dimensions of good governance, and one independent variable, the identity of the main external lender, as well as introduce an extraneous variable, national regulations. Then, it will provide an overview of our research approach, the Most Similar Systems Designs, followed by a section on the case selection. Finally, it will introduce content analysis as a research method and conclude by presenting a set of potential limitations to our methodology. The fourth chapter will present and analyse the data collected. Finally, the fifth chapter will conclude the thesis by summarising the results of the study and suggesting possibilities for further research.

(9)

2.Theoretical Framework

In the present chapter we will introduce the research’s theoretical framework. The chapter will begin by presenting a literature review of the academic discussion surrounding the thesis’ main topics: good governance and China’s role in Latin America. Then, it will introduce and define its key concepts: good governance and development loans. Finally, it will present the thesis’ main hypothesis and its competing hypotheses.

2.1 Literature Review

Good Governance

The concept of good governance has its origins in the development literature of the late 1980s and the 1990s, a period which saw a renewed interest in the role of the state and its institutions among development scholars (Grindle 2010, p.4). This shift in attitudes was cemented by the publication of the World Bank’s 1997 World Development Report, subtitled The State in a Changing World. The report placed the state at the forefront of development thinking by highlighting its role as an important actor in the promotion of economic development. It therefore ushered in a clear break with the anti-statism which had dominated the previous decades (Weiss 2000, p.803). Since then, the concept of good governance has gained immense popularity among development scholars and practitioners and it is now widely employed by most international organisations (Gisselquist 2012, p.5).

However, despite its long-standing and widespread use, there continues to be a lack of consensus on the definition of good governance, a problem noted by most works published on the subject (Doornbos 2001, p.94; Gisselquist 2012, p.2; Grindle 2010, p2-3; Keefer, 2009, p.439). Although politically powerful, the idea of good governance has been marred by decades-old “conceptual and operational battles” (Weiss 2000, p.806).

(10)

The good governance debate was initiated and has been dominated by the international development agencies, each of which has its own definition of the concept (Wouters & Ryngaert 2004, p.4). For the World Bank, good governance is “the combination of transparent and accountable institutions, strong skills and competence, and a fundamental willingness to do the right thing”, which together “enable a government to deliver services to its people efficiently” (Wolfowitz 2006, cited in World Bank 2007, p.1). For the UNDP, good governance “refers to governing systems which are capable, responsive, inclusive, and transparent” which entails “meaningful and inclusive political participation” (Clark 2011, pars.2-3). The African Development Bank defines governance as “a process referring to the manner in which power is exercised in the management of the affairs of a nation, and its relations with other nations” and good governance as the presence in the aforementioned process of “accountability, transparency, combating corruption, participatory governance and an enabling legal/judicial framework.” (African Development Bank 1999, p.2).

In any case, we can say that definitions of good governance tend to make reference to either a government’s level of responsiveness to its citizens and ability to maintain the rule of law, or to the extent to which political institutions provide the proper incentives for government officials to do so (Keefer 2009, p.440). In other words, some scholars analyse good governance in terms of outcomes and others analyse good governance in terms of processes, although many definitions cross this divide.

Most descriptions of good governance provide a list of its core components or principles. Gisselquist (2012) identifies seven components which tend to appear across donor agencies’ working definitions of good governance. These are: “(1) democracy and representation, (2) human rights, (3) the rule of law, (4) effective and efficient public management, (5) transparency and accountability, (6) developmentalist objectives, and (7) a varying range of particular political and economic policies, programmes, and institutions (e.g., elections, a legislature, a free press, secure property rights)” (Gisselquist 2012, p.8). From this description it becomes evident how good governance has become an extremely vague and general term. While this contributes to its political power, it weakens the concept’s usefulness to academic analysis. As Grindle phrases it, good governance has fallen prey to the phenomenon of “idea inflation” (2010, p.2). The

(11)

consequences of this are confused analysis, inappropriate and counterproductive policy advice and eventually disillusionment with the concept itself as it inevitably fails to deliver in practice (Grindle 2010, p.9). Additionally, Doornbos argues that its ambiguity opens the concept to exploitation by actors who might use it as a “political tool” to justify decisions taken for other, less disinterested reasons (2001, p.104).

Various solutions are provided to the problems of ambiguity and idea inflation. Grindle advances the idea of “good enough governance”, that is, a move towards a minimalist conception of good governance which would strip it down to include only those elements which are absolutely essential for development to occur (Grindle 2010, p.14). Alternatively, Gisselquist suggests that academic researchers should disaggregate their analysis and focus on each component of good governance individually (rule of law, accountability etc.). This would furthermore enable them to engage with the already extensive literature covering each of these principles on its own (Gisselquist 2012, p.2).

The literature on good governance draws its theoretical basis mainly from the new institutionalist strand of economics, which asserts that “institutions matter and that different institutional structures in governments will yield different results” with regards to economic development (Andrews 2008, p.397). Within this theory, Douglass North’s Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance has been by far the most influential text for good governance thinking (Gisselquist 2012, p.10; Grindle 2010, p.4). North defines institutions as “the rules of the game in a society or, more formally, (...) the humanly devised constraints that shape human interaction” (1990, p.3). In his book, he sought to explain the reasons behind the great divergence between developed and developing countries. Following a comparative analysis of Latin America and the United States, North came to the conclusion that the institutional framework of a country is a key determinant of its developmental trajectory (Abbasi, 2015). He argued that institutions serve the function of reducing uncertainty in economic transactions and remedy market failures (Tridico 2004, p.9). Therefore, weak institutions explain the lack of economic development in the Third World.

(12)

In addition to new institutionalism, Max Weber’s theory of bureaucracy has also served as a source of inspiration for some good governance scholars (Andrews 2008, p.381). Weber’s work focused on bureaucratic institutions, which he argued were the most efficient type of organisation due to their rationality, standardised procedures, and technical expertise (Rockman n.d., pars.1-2). In any case, the theoretical foundations of good governance are decidedly underdeveloped. For instance, Andrews is critical of the “limited references to theory in the good governance literature” which furthermore, with the exception of North’s ideas, “are not consistent, referencing modernist Weberian models at some junctures, post-modern new public management at others” (2008, p.397).

Besides the definition of the concept, a second important debate among good governance scholars focuses on its link with economic development. Most scholars agree that good governance is a worthy goal in itself. However, there is disagreement on whether good governance can also be considered a prerequisite for economic development or not. Indeed, these concerns stand at the very root of the concept’s creation. Following the failure of structural adjustment programs in preventing widespread economic crises in the Third World in the 1970s and 1980s, the international financial institutions began to look for explanations. Their conclusion was that weak institutions and corruption in developing countries had prevented successful reform implementation and therefore economic growth (Kjaer 2014, p.1). To use Grindle’s term, good governance became a “fig leaf” for the failure of the IFIs’ policy advice (2010, p.5).

Among supporters of the good governance-development link we have first of all the World Bank. In its 1989 report Sub-Saharan Africa: From Crisis to Sustainable Growth, the organisation asserts that “sound macroeconomic policies and an efficient infrastructure” are by themselves not enough to ensure economic growth. Instead, they have to be accompanied by good governance measures which will foster an environment conducive to private sector initiative and entrepreneurship (World Bank 1989, p.xii).

This argument is supported by Kaufmann, Kraay and Zoido-Lobatón’s (1999) cross-sectional analysis of good governance and development in over 150 countries. Kaufmann et al.

(13)

construct six aggregate indicators measuring six dimensions of good governance: voice and accountability, political instability and violence, government effectiveness, regulatory burden, rule of law, and graft. After analysing the performance of developing countries in each of these dimensions, they find a “strong causal relationship from good governance to better development outcomes such as higher per capita incomes, lower infant mortality, and higher literacy” (Kaufmann et al 1999, p.1).

Keefer (2009) also argues that good governance has a positive impact on development. Furthermore, he makes an important contribution by noting that different components of good governance have a different influence on development. For example, while government credibility and the security of property rights have a strong positive impact on development, the link weakens when it comes to voice and accountability. Therefore, he concludes that future research would benefit from focusing on each component of good governance separately (Keefer 2009, pp.439-440).

Similarly, Resnick and Birner (2006) assert that good governance does have a positive impact on development, but that the causal relationship varies among its dimensions. While dimensions of good governance which relate to “a sound decision-making environment for investment and policy implementation” (ie. rule of law and political stability) contribute to economic growth, their impact on poverty reduction is unclear. Conversely, while dimensions of good governance which contribute to “transparent political systems” (ie. civil liberties and political freedom) contribute to poverty reduction, their impact on economic growth is unclear (Resnick & Birner 2006, p.iii).

Not all scholars agree that good governance contributes to development. According to Khan, good governance reforms cannot promote development because of “structural and fiscal constraints” in poor countries which “prevent the achievement of significant improvements in the good governance capabilities” (2009, p.8). Furthermore, there is the danger that good governance reform might redirect attention and resources away from measures which more directly promote economic development (Khan 2009, p.15). Therefore, he concludes that developing countries should first focus on a “growth-enhancing governance agenda”, which will

(14)

then enable them to successfully improve good governance (Khan 2009, p.9). Similarly, Kurtz and Schrank argue that it is far more probable that it is economic development which produces good governance, rather than the other way around (2007, p.539).

Finally, the good governance agenda more generally has been the target of criticisms, which can be divided into two categories.

First of all, some scholars criticise the imposition of a one-size-fits-all model. For instance, Andrews argues that the good governance model has limited replicability: its various elements can lead to unexpected or even counterproductive results when applied to developing countries because “every context has prevailing structures that need to be built upon or given time to evolve” (2008, p.394,397). Furthermore, there exists great institutional variation even among the developed states which are frequently cited as examples of good governance. For example, Sweden, Denmark and the United States all have high-quality health and education; however, while in Sweden and Denmark the government is greatly involved in these sectors, in the United States it plays a relatively smaller role (Andrews 2008, p.385). In a similar vein, Messick’s (1999) analysis of the introduction of rule of law reforms in developing countries exposes the potentially negative consequences of one-best-way governance models. He discovers that “the sudden introduction of a formal mechanism to resolve legal disputes can disrupt informal mechanisms without providing offsetting gains” (Messick 1999, p.118).

The second criticism concerns good governance’s ties to economic neoliberalism. According to Demmers et al., good governance is a component, together with market liberalisation and democratisation, of the broader political project of worldwide neoliberalisation (2004, p.2). Therefore, instead of acting as a "genuine medicine against the illnesses caused by the free market agenda", the good governance agenda is "a placebo with possibly lethal consequences" (Demmers et al. 2004, p.2). Similarly, Gathii argues that the concept of good governance favours political and procedural rights to the detriment of socio-economic rights because “neo-liberal economic reform actually undermines the promotion of democracy through its stringent requirement on governments to cut back on social expenditures in areas such as

(15)

health, education, worker benefits and rights among others” (1999 p.213, as cited in Reif 2013, p.65).

To summarise, good governance is a highly contested concept, which generally refers to a government’s level of responsiveness to its citizens, either at the process level or at the outcomes level depending on the specific definition. It was first introduced by the international development agencies, which continue to dominate the discussion. Although most scholars agree that good governance is a worthy goal in itself, disagreement exists on whether it has also a positive impact on development. Finally, some scholars are critical of the good governance agenda due to its imposition of a one-size-fits-all model and to its ties to neoliberalism.

China in Latin America

China’s growing economic influence in the developing world through the provision of development aid and loans with few conditionalities attached has sparked considerable academic debate. The discussion is divided into two broad sides, one portraying China as a threat to the economic development and political stability of developing countries, the other as a benevolent development partner (Alden 2007, p.111). In this section, an overview of the academic debate surrounding China’s emergence as a major donor and investor will be provided. It will begin by assessing the literature concerned with the impact on the developing world in general, to then move on to that focusing on the impact on Latin America in particular.

China possesses a growing economic presence on the developing world, exerted through various channels: bilateral trade, foreign direct investment, development aid, and even migration (McCormick 2008, p.76). According to McCormick, its impact on developing countries can be categorized into four types: on growth, on distribution, on governance and on the environment (2008, p.76). In other words, we can say that China’s economic presence in the developing world produces an economic impact (growth and distribution) and a political impact (governance and the environment). This broader categorisation coincides with the two main criticisms levied by the relevant literature against China’s economic presence in the developing world.

(16)

First of all, various scholars argue that China’s growing economic ties with developing countries is reinforcing their dependency on the export of natural resources as a source of income, thereby preventing them from pursuing the economic diversification necessary to promote long-term sustainable development. For instance, Konings describes how, whereas China’s imports from Africa are predominantly raw materials, in return it “exports the full gamut of its manufactured goods”, which range from textiles to high tech products (2007, p.357). As a result, cheap Chinese imports are displacing local products, undermining local African manufacturing industries (Konings 2007, pp.255-257). Similar concerns are raised by Zafar, who argues that the competition provided by growing imports of Chinese manufactured goods might “hinder economic diversification in Africa and contribute to deindustrialization” (2007, p.126). Furthermore, he predicts that Chinese investments in the extractive industries will provide no significant contribution to local job creation or human capital development - nor, for that matter, to “the continent’s long-term economic development” (Zafar 2007, pp.121, 126). Even Alden’s generally positive account of Sino-African relations admits that Africa’s long-term development will require a transformation of actual trade dynamics (2007, p.113). Finally, according to Coxhead similar dynamics are visible in Southeast Asia, where, due to the combined effects of China’s export boom and its demand for primary products, several countries are experiencing a reconfiguration of their economies favouring low-skill manufacturing and natural resource extraction to the detriment of high-value added production (2007, pp.1100, 1115).

An additional argument provided by critics of China’s economic impact, of particular relevance to the aims of this thesis, is that China’s investment in developing countries’ extractive industries has an indirect negative impact on good governance. Kaplinski et al. note that historically in most African countries the exploitation of large mineral resources has fueled corruption and authoritarianism, resulting in declining standards of living for the majority of the population. Therefore, they argue that a “generic trend towards commodity production and mineral rents as a consequence of China’s growing need for material inputs” will probably “exacerbate some forms of poor governance” (Kaplinski et al. 2007, p.41). Similarly, for Zafar Chinese aid and investment could pose a threat to good governance in Africa because of the “potential Dutch disease implications”, a term used to refer to the various negative side-effects of commodity booms on a country’s economy and institutions (2007, p.103).

(17)

The second main criticism leveled against China’s economic involvement in the developing world concerns the negative political impact caused by its provision of development aid and loans without conditionalities. According to Naim, China represents a threat to good governance worldwide by providing what he defines as “rogue aid”, or unconditional development assistance which is “nondemocratic in origin and nontransparent in practice” (2009, par.4). By providing aid without requiring any human rights or good governance policy reforms in return, China is undermining the efforts of Western development agencies to promote these values. It is therefore hurting the citizens of the countries it lends to and creating a world which is “more corrupt, chaotic, and authoritarian” (Naim 2009, par.11). This argument is supported by Kaplinski et al. (2007), who aim to demonstrate how China is weakening good governance in the developing world by citing the cases of Sudan, Angola and Zimbabwe, where, following Western donors’ withdrawal or refusal of aid due to concerns over corruption and human rights violations, China stepped in as an alternative donor, effectively removing any financial incentive for change. Similarly, Manning argues that the availability of non-conditional aid and loans could not only delay reforms, but also entrench “poor standards of governance and accountability” (2006, p.381). Finally, even Pehnelt (2007), who presents an otherwise relatively sympathetic account of China’s behaviour in Africa, accepts this criticism. According to him, as a late-comer to international commodity markets, China has higher “opportunity costs of morality”: it cannot afford to discriminate among its potential clients on the basis of humanitarian concerns (Pehnelt 2007, p.7). Consequently, “Chinese engagement enables African governments to reject demands made by the IMF, the World Bank and other donors for enhancing transparency, implementing anti-corruption strategies, and furthering their democratization efforts” (Pehnelt 2007, p.8).

To summarise, China’s economic engagement with the developing world has been the subject of criticisms from a variety of scholars, which can be subdivided into the dependent development argument and the unconditional aid argument. We will now turn to the other side of the debate, presenting an overview of the positive accounts offered by the relevant academic literature on the subject, as well as their responses to the previous arguments.

(18)

First of all, Brautigam (2009) presents the emergence of China as a major donor as a positive development. She describes Sino-African economic relations as a “win-win approach” characterized by the prioritisation of investment partnerships over paternalistic aid; by the engagement of investment, trade and technology in the service of development; and by the mutually beneficial provision of credit in exchange for natural resources and contracts for Chinese businesses (Brautigam 2009, p.311). Another supporter of China’s economic relationship with the developing world is Woods, who argues that its aid recipients and trade partners "are enjoying higher growth rates, better terms of trade, increased export volumes and higher public revenues" (2008, p.1208). Similarly, for Kelley “Chinese investment in infrastructure and modernizing industry has the potential to kick-start stagnant African growth and begin a new era of economic development” (2012, p.41). Furthermore, if the right policies are adopted by Chinese and African governments, this economic growth could propel African countries out of the “resource curse” and into the path of sustainable development (Kelley 2012, p.41).

Scholars on this side of the debate are skeptical of accounts which portray China as entrenching dependent development in the Third World. For Brautigam, the competitive pressure created by China’s manufacturing exports is offset by Chinese investment into local industries. Contradicting Zafar (2007), she describes how these investments are creating employment for local workers (2009, p.308). As for the negative impact of the “resource curse” on good governance described by Kaplinski et al. (2007) and Zafar (2007), Brautigam argues that since Chinese loan agreements usually tie resource revenues to specific development projects, Chinese banks could in fact act as “agencies of restraint” on African leaders, reducing rent-seeking behaviour (2009, p.307). Su et al. (2016) similarly discredit the dependent development argument. Based on an empirical analysis of systematic data from 135 developing countries from 1995 to 2007, they conclude that there is no evidence in the developing world of a link between an increase in China’s economic presence and a decline in economic growth and manufacturing (Su et al. 2016, p.33).

As for the criticism that China’s unconditional loans have a negative impact on good governance, Woods admits that they pose a challenge to the development aid regime’s standard-setting efforts (2008, p.1212). However, for Woods there are two problems with this argument.

(19)

First of all, it overestimates the effectiveness of traditional donors’ conditional aid and loans in promoting good governance, as “conditionality alone does not improve standards” (Woods 2008, p.1212). Secondly, she reminds us that China’s rise as a major donor is partly fueled by developing countries’ disillusionment with traditional donors’ imposition of conditionalities, perceived as excessively complicated and “misaligned with their priorities” at best, and undermining their national sovereignty at worst (Woods 2008, p.1217). Similarly, Brautigam argues that “where the West regularly changes its development advice, programs and approach in Africa (...), China does not claim to know what Africa must do to develop”, noting that policy conditionalities are now being criticised even by Western economists (2009, p.308).

China’s relationship with the developing world has generated considerable academic discussions. However, up until now the debate has been dominated by accounts of Sino-African relations. China’s impact in Latin America has produced a very limited although growing amount of academic literature, despite the impressive speed at which trade, investment and aid flows between the two have grown over the past fifteen years. Furthermore, most scholars have concentrated on trade relations rather than development aid or loans (Gallagher et al. 2012, p.3). The literature on China’s economic relations with Latin America can be divided along the same lines as the literature on its relationship with the developing world in general, with China portrayed as either a development partner or an exploitative power.

According to Kaplan, China’s non-conditional lending enables Latin American governments to “increase national-level policy flexibility by removing the budget constraint traditionally imposed by the IMF and global markets” (2015, p.ii). Greater budgetary autonomy is particularly beneficial to the region’s left-leaning governments, who depend on fiscal stimulus to provide greater employment, higher wages and social benefits for their citizens (Kaplan 2015, p.2). Therefore, China provides Latin American countries with the opportunity to increase their independence from external interference and pursue economic development on their own terms. Furthermore, Gallagher et al. argue that Chinese loans are beneficial for Latin America’s long-term development because they tend to focus on infrastructure and industrial projects rather than “the latest Western development fads” (2012, p.1).

(20)

However, other scholars provide a more negative account by presenting China as following an exploitative, mercantilist strategy which will increase economic dependency and harm development in Latin America. According to Jenkins (2012), trade relations between China and Latin America are highly asymmetrical and defined by the same core-periphery dynamics which have undermined the region’s development for centuries. Similarly, Ortiz (2012) argues that Latin America is becoming increasingly dependent on exports of primary resources to China, which is problematic for its long-term economic development. Finally, according to Farnsworth, China pursues a “transparently mercantilist strategy” in the region, which is threatening the manufacturing sectors of countries such as Mexico and Brazil (2011, par.6,12). Furthermore, its loans are decreasing “the ability of the United States and other Western nations to promote labor and environmental protections, human rights and the rule of law in Latin America” (Farnsworth 2011, par.43).

To conclude, China’s economic presence in the developing world has attracted the attention of numerous scholars, divided between those who view China as an exploitative power and those who view it as a development partner. However, thus far the academic literature on China’s impact in Latin America has been very limited, especially with regards to development aid and loans. Studies of China’s international economic relations would benefit from giving greater attention to this underdeveloped research area in the future.

2.2 Conceptual Framework

2.2.1 Key Concepts

The present section will introduce the two key concepts of the research: good governance and development loans.

Good Governance

As explained in the literature review, the concept of “good governance” is quite difficult to define, as there is no consensus among scholars on its specific meaning nor on its scope. A

(21)

starting point is represented by the distinction between good governance in terms of outcomes and good governance in terms of processes (Keefer 2009, p.440). For the purposes of this research, it is the latter category which is the most relevant. First of all, since China’s economic presence in Latin America is a relatively recent phenomenon, it would be too early to properly assess its impact on good governance in terms of outcomes. Secondly, the thesis’ analysis of development projects will focus on their design, rather than on their results. Consequently, the following definition by the Good Governance Guide is particularly appropriate: good governance is “about the processes for making and implementing decisions. It’s not about making ‘correct’ decisions, but about the best possible process for making those decisions” (n.d., par.1). In other words, good governance refers to the existence of procedures and incentives which ensure that policy-makers are responsive to their citizens and deliver optimal results.

However, as defined above the concept of good governance remains quite ambiguous. What characteristics should the “best possible process” possess? Therefore, for greater precision it is necessary to outline the various components or principles of good governance. For this purpose, the UNDP provides a list of characteristics which are particularly relevant because they appear in most definitions of good governance across the literature (Graham et al. 2003, p.3). The UNDP’s characteristics of good governance are: participation, rule of law, transparency, responsiveness, consensus orientation, equity, effectiveness and efficiency, accountability and strategic vision (UNDP, 1997). However, in practice some of these characteristics tend to overlap and affect each other. To address this issue, Graham et al. group the UNDP’s characteristics into five broad principles of good governance: Legitimacy and Voice, Performance, Accountability, Fairness and Direction (2003, p.3). Therefore, in its analysis of good governance the present research will adopt Graham et al.’s set of principles, which will now be introduced in greater detail.

The first principle of good governance is Legitimacy and Voice (from now on shortened to Voice). This principle has two components: participation and consensus orientation. Participation requires that all citizens “have a voice in decision-making”, whether directly or through representatives (Graham et al. 2003, p.3). It is based directly on the Universal Declaration of Human Rights (UDHR) right to political participation (Art.21) and indirectly on

(22)

the right to freedom of speech (Art.19) and the right to freedom of association (Art.20) (UN, 1948). Participation is vital because it enables citizens to engage in shaping processes and institutions which have a direct impact on their lives, while at the same time allowing governments to “tap new sources of idea, information and resources when making decisions” (Caddy 2001, par.4). As for consensus orientation, it consists of taking into account the views of all groups in society with the aim of reaching a broad consensus which balances their various interests (Graham et al. 2003, p.3).

The second principle of good governance is Performance, which has two components. The first is effectiveness and efficiency, which refers to processes which “produce results that meet needs while making the best use of resources” (Graham et al. 2003, p.3). The second is responsiveness, which is present when “ institutions and processes try to serve all stakeholders” (Graham et al. 2003, p.3). However, since this second component seems to overlap with some of the others (ie.consensus orientation, accountability and equity), it will be omitted in this research.

The third principle of good governance is Accountability. This principle has two components: accountability and transparency. Accountability requires that decision-makers are subject to the oversight of the public (Graham et al. 2003, p.3). This entails both answerability, or the provision of justification for their actions, and enforcement, the power to sanction decision-makers for misbehaviour. There are two forms of accountability: horizontal and vertical. Horizontal accountability is the oversight exercised by governmental institutions over one another. Vertical accountability is the oversight exercised by citizens and civil society over decision-makers. Despite this division, it is important to note that some mechanisms of horizontal accountability, for example parliaments, can also play a role in vertical accountability, and viceversa (Stapenhurst & O’Brien 2005, p.1). As for transparency, it refers to the “free flow of information” (Graham et al. 2003, p.3). Information about state institutions and their initiatives must be available to the general public and especially to those directly affected by them; furthermore, the information must be easy to access and to understand (Graham et al. 2003, p.3).

The fourth principle of good governance is Fairness. Its two components are equity and rule of law. Equity requires that “all men and women have opportunities to improve or maintain

(23)

their wellbeing” (Graham et al. 2003, p.3). This component is enshrined in the Universal Declaration of Human Rights, which states that “all human beings are born free and equal in dignity and rights…” (Art.1), “without distinction of any kind, such as race, colour, sex, language, religion, political or other opinion, national or social origin, property, birth or other status” (Art.2) (UN, 1948). As for rule of law, it consists in the fair and impartial application of “well-established and clearly written rules, regulations, and legal principles”, particularly those concerning human rights (Voigt 2013, p.xv)(Graham et al. 2003, p.3). It is based on the UDHR’s Article 7 (“All are equal before the law”), Article 10 (“Everyone is entitled in full equality to a fair and public hearing by an independent and impartial tribunal…”), Article 5 (“No one shall be subjected to arbitrary arrest, detention or exile”) and Article 17 (“No one shall be arbitrarily deprived of his property”)(UN, 1948).

The fifth and final principle of good governance is Direction. Its main component is strategic vision, which requires that government officials have a strong long-term commitment to good governance and human rights which shapes and determines their decision-making (Graham et al. 2003, p.3). However, since this principle is suitable for the national and/or institutional levels of analysis but not quite as relevant for the project level of analysis, it will not be included in our research.

Development Loans

Global development finance is characterised by a complex architecture involving various state and non-state actors. Financial flows to developing countries can occur through private or official channels. Private flows include foreign direct investment (FDI), worker remittances, portfolio equity, and private debt and grants. More relevant to the present research are official flows, which can be further subdivided between Official Development Assistance (ODA) and Other Official Flows (OOF) (Brautigam 2011, p.204).

Based on the standardised definition of the OECD Development Assistance Committee, official development assistance (ODA) can be defined as funds provided by official agencies to developing countries with the main aim of promoting the welfare and economic development of

(24)

the recipient country (Brautigam 2011, p.203; OECD 2008, p.1). These must be “concessional in character” and contain “a grant element of at least 25 per cent (calculated at a rate of discount of 10 per cent)” (OECD 2008, p.1). There are two forms of ODA: grants and concessional loans. Concessional loans differ from regular market loans in that they offer more generous terms, whether through lower interest rates or longer grace periods (OECD 2003, n.p.).

As for other official flows (OOF), these include military aid, export-facilitating bilateral transactions, subsidies or other forms of funding which support the private investments in recipient countries of companies from the donor country, and loans which are not concessional or which do not have a grant element of at least 25% (Brautigam 2011, p.204).

In this research, the umbrella term ‘development loans’ will be utilised to refer to all loans provided to developing countries by official institutions which contribute to some extent to the development of the recipient country. It therefore includes both ODA loans and OOF loans: they can be concessional or non-concessional and have any percentage of grant element. Furthermore, this concept will be subdivided into two subcategories: development loans from China and development loans from the IFIs, to which we now turn.

While most donor countries provide some degree of bilateral assistance through their own agencies, it is the international financial institutions (IFIs) which sit at the heart of the global development assistance regime. Foremost amongst them are the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the Bretton Woods institutions established at the end of the Second World War to maintain global economic stability.

The World Bank is an international organisation which provides loans to developing countries with the aim of reducing global poverty (The Bretton Woods Committee n.d., par.3). It offers two types of loans: investment loans, which help finance the goods, work and services of projects promoting economic and social development; and adjustment loans, which help finance policy and institutional reform. These are provided through two channels: the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD) and the International Development Association (IDA) (World Bank n.d.[a], section 5). World Bank lending follows a specific procedure. First,

(25)

loan negotiations are conducted between the Bank and the recipient country, in which the objective, outputs and operational plan of a specific development project or program are determined. The loan is then approved and it is up to the recipient country to implement the project, with the continuous supervision of the World Bank, which at the end evaluates the project’s results. Furthermore, “all loans are governed by operational policies, which make sure that operations are economically, financially, socially and environmentally sound” (World Bank n.d.[a], section 5).

As for the IMF, it is an international organisation which provides financial assistance to countries who find themselves unable to secure sufficient funds through capital markets to repay their external debt while maintaining appropriate reserve levels. Its loans help them “tackle balance of payments problems, stabilize their economies, and restore sustainable economic growth” (IMF n.d., par.2). While the World Bank provides funding for local development projects, the IMF focuses on macroeconomic issues (IMF n.d., par.3). It is not a development bank nor an aid agency, so its loans are given out on the condition that recipients repay them expediently and implement in exchange a series of Structural Adjustment Policies (SAPs) (Heakal n.d., par.12). While the World Bank generally lends to developing countries, with more favourable conditions for the poorest of them, the IMF offers financial assistance to all its members (Driscoll 1996, pars.11-12). However, in the past few years its role as a provider of development assistance has expanded. In 2010, it established the Poverty Reduction and Growth Trust, which offers concessional loans to low-income countries through three channels: the Extended Credit Facility, the Standby Credit Facility and the Rapid Credit Facility (IMF 2016, p.1). In 2015, the IMF expanded developing countries access to concessional loans. More recently, it “adopted a strategy to support concessional lending of about $1.8 billion a year over the longer term…” (IMF 2016, p.1).

The Inter-American Development Bank is another IFI of particular relevance to Latin America. It is a multilateral development institution based in the United States which provides financial assistance to countries in Latin America and the Caribbean. Its aim is to support sustainable development in the region through the provision of loans, grants and technical assistance for projects related to health, education, infrastructure and other areas (IDB n.d.[a],

(26)

par.1). The Bank provides financing for development projects through two credit windows: Ordinary Capital and the Fund for Special Operations (FSO). The Ordinary Capital provides loans with more generous terms than market loans, available to all countries, while the FSO provides loans with extremely low interest rates and extended repayment periods, available only to the region’s poorest countries (State Secretariat for Economic Affairs & Swiss Agency for Development and Cooperation 2015, p.2)

In recent years, China has increasingly come to challenge the traditional donors’ monopoly over international development assistance. The Chinese government provides three forms of official development assistance: grants, interest-free loans and concessional loans (Brautigam 2011, p.204). However, the majority of China’s international development assistance is composed of various OOF-like financing instruments: export credits, OOF-type loans, overseas investment support and multilateral financing mechanisms (Snell 2015, pp.11-12, 23). China’s OOF-type loans can be subdivided into three categories. The first is non-ODA concessional loans, which contain a grant element lower than 25 percent and can be tied to the purchase of Chinese goods and services. The second is nonconcessional loans, which are loans with a commercial interest rate. The third is resource-backed loans, which are loans “repaid through the sale of natural resources to donor entities; can be concessional, earmarked for infrastructure projects, and/or tied to exports” (Snell 2015, p.12). Most of China’s international development assistance is provided by China Eximbank and China Development Bank, while China’s Ministry of Commerce oversees the provision of grants and interest-free loans (Brautigam 2011, p.204).

Causal Relationship: Development Loans and Good Governance

Various scholars have identified policy conditionalities as the intermediary link creating a potential causal relationship between development lending and good governance. Conditionalities are a “set of strategies that the donor can employ to induce political and economic changes in recipient countries” (Selbervik 1999, p.12). The practice of political conditionality emerged in the 1990s and is distinct from the older economic conditionality in that it requires the implementation of political reforms in exchange for aid and loans. These reforms are usually linked to the goal of promoting good governance, human rights and/or democracy (Selbervik 1999, p.13).

(27)

Proponents of political conditionality argue that conditional development loans can have a positive impact on good governance. For instance, the World Bank’s 1998 report Assessing Aid: What Works, What Doesn’t, and Why called for a more selective approach to development assistance based on countries’ commitment to political reform. According to the the World Bank, this would enable donor agencies to create the incentives for wider good governance reform among developing countries (World Bank 1998, pp.118-119). Since then, most bilateral and multilateral aid agencies have adopted the practice of conditional lending, through which good governance has become an objective of the development assistance regime (Singh, 2003).

However, there are also those who argue that development loans with political conditionalities fail to promote good governance and in some cases can even discourage it. First of all, conditionalities fail to create the incentives to improve good governance because sustainable, long-term political reform cannot be externally imposed or bought when there is domestic opposition or unwillingness (Killick 1998, p.163; Santiso 2001, p.8; Stiglitz 1999, p.591). Secondly, the imposition of conditionalities can negatively impact good governance by undermining sovereignty and replacing domestic democratic processes (Santiso 2001, p.9; Stiglitz 1999, p.591). Finally, development lending can sometimes create a dependency which fosters corruption in recipient countries. Therefore, there is the concern that an overreliance on conditional loans might actually be counterproductive for the promotion of good governance (Melese n.d., par.13; Santiso 2001, p.9).

China differs from the IFIs and other traditional donors in that it provides loans to developing countries with little or no conditionalities attached, which it justifies in terms of respect for sovereignty and the principle of non-intervention (Brant 2011, par.3). An alternative, more straightforward explanation is that China’s reluctance to promote good governance in other countries is the natural consequence of its own lack of progress in this area. China has managed to achieve significant levels of economic development without similar gains in terms of human rights or the rule of law. Therefore, the Chinese government’s prioritisation of economic rights over civil and political rights at home has been extended to its lending policies abroad (Condon 2012, pp.12-12). Similarly, it is not surprising that its clients are not required to implement

(28)

anti-corruption reforms, considering that “anti-corruption is still commonplace within Chinese businesses themselves” (Condon 2012, p.7).

2.2.2 Main Hypothesis and Competing Hypotheses

The present research aims to assess the impact of China’s development loans on good governance in Latin America. However, Chinese lending in this region seems to concentrate predominantly on the extractive and infrastructure sectors (Gallagher et al. 2012, p.2). For this reason, analysing its impact in terms of good governance at the national level might not be appropriate or indeed even possible. Therefore, the research will shift its level of analysis to focus on good governance at the project-level. In other words, the level of good governance of Chinese development projects vis-à-vis IFI-funded development projects will serve as a proxy indicator for the impact of China’s loans on good governance in Latin America. The present section will now introduce the thesis’ main hypothesis and its two competing hypotheses.

Main Hypothesis: China’s loans have a negative impact on good governance

China’s development lending strategy focuses on economic goals and does not contain a good governance component (Naim 2009; Kaplinski et al. 2007; Manning 2006; Penhelt 2007). Consequently, we might expect its development projects to be designed with little concern for participation, transparency, accountability or other principles of good governance. Therefore, we hypothesize that development projects financed by China will have a lower level of good governance than development projects financed by the IFIs. The propagation of development projects with below-average levels of good governance will in turn lower overall good governance standards in the recipient country. As a result, China’s loans will have a negative impact on good governance in Latin America.

Competing Hypothesis 1: China’s loans have no impact on good governance

China is an active member of both the World Bank and the IMF. It is therefore possible that a certain degree of socialisation into global standards of development lending will have occurred as a result of its participation in these institutions. Its development assistance practices

(29)

might thus have been adapted to some extent to those of the traditional donors, if not at the policy and strategy level, then at least at the implementation level.Therefore, it is possible that development projects financed by China will have a similar level of good governance to development projects financed by the IFIs. As a result, China’s loans will have no significant impact on good governance in Latin America.

Competing Hypothesis 2: China’s loans have a positive impact on good governance

The final and least plausible hypothesis is that China’s policy of non-interference might translate into higher good governance at the project level. China disavows the imposition of conditionalities due to its declared commitment to the principles of non-intervention and respect for sovereignty (Condon, 2012). It could therefore be possible that China’s approach to development lending, considered as a transaction between equal partners, might actually result in greater local participation and ownership of the projects’ planification. Therefore, it is possible that development projects financed by China will have a higher level of good governance than development projects financed by the IFIs. The propagation of development projects with above-average levels of good governance will in turn improve overall good governance standards in the recipient country. As a result, China’s loans will have a positive impact on good governance in Latin America

(30)

3. Research Design

To answer our research question, we will conduct a comparative case analysis of three development projects in Latin America, one financed by Chinese loans and two financed by the IFIs’ loans. More specifically, the contracts of each project will be evaluated in terms of good governance, using content analysis as a research method.

In the present chapter, the thesis’ research design will be introduced in greater detail. The chapter will begin with the operationalisation of the two key concepts into four dependent variables, one independent variable and one extraneous variable. Then, it will introduce the thesis’ research approach, the Most Similar Systems Design. This will be followed by a section on the thesis’ case selection. The chapter will then introduce the research method, content analysis. Finally, the chapter will present a set of limitations to our methodology.

3.1 Operationalisation of Concepts

3.1.1 Dependent Variables

The concept of good governance can be transformed into four dependent variables, each corresponding to one of its four dimensions, which are voice, performance, accountability, and fairness. In order to properly assess the projects’ level of good governance we must in turn assign to every dependent variable a set of measurable indicators. We will create two indicators for each dependent variable so as to ensure a balance between the four dimensions of good governance. These indicators will be reflective of the dimension components which were outlined in the previous chapter. The data for the indicators of the dependent variables will be obtained primarily from the analysis of project contracts and secondarily from the analysis of academic and NGO reports.

Since we aim to measure good governance at the project level, our indicators must reflect development projects’ particular governance requirements. However, this presents various

(31)

difficulties, as most pre-existing good governance indicators focus on governance at the national level (ie. the World Bank’s Worldwide Governance Indicators, the OECD’s Sustainable Governance Indicators and the Global Integrity Index). Therefore, to maximise relevance our measurements will be based on the less well-known governance indicators provided in Abrams et al.’s handbook Evaluating Governance. The handbook presents a set of guidelines for participatory assessments of good governance levels in the management of protected areas (Abrams et al., 2003). While not immediately evident, its indicators are appropriate to our research for three reasons. First of all, development projects and protected areas involve similar levels of governance, as they both have a relatively small-scale or local scope. Secondly, they both require governance which strikes a balance between national interests and local stakeholders’ rights. Thirdly, development projects must deal with many of the issues characteristic of the governance of protected areas, such as environmental damage and the rights of local communities. Therefore, the thesis’ good governance indicators will be based on those provided in Abrams et al.’s handbook, with some modifications. We will now explain in greater detail each dependent variable and its indicators.

The first dependent variable is degree of voice. It refers to the extent to which the planning and implementation of a development project were conducted in accordance with the principle of voice. In other words, this variable measures the degree to which decision-makers enabled citizens to participate in the project’s development and strove to reach a balance between the interests of the various stakeholders.

The variable’s first indicator is public participation. It measures the extent to which procedures are in place which ensure decision-makers receive input and feedback from citizens regarding the project. Participation can be direct, for instance through assemblies or voting, or indirect, when a group of citizens is collectively represented by an association, party, NGO or other actor (Abrams et al. 2003, p.31). The variable’s second indicator is presence of checks and balances. It measures the extent to which civil society organisations and an independent media are permitted to “act as a check and balance” on the planification and implementation of a development project (Abrams et al. 2003, p.35). CSOs and the media must be able to openly question and criticise the various aspects of the project’s planification and implementation,

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

Archive for Contemporary Affairs University of the Free State

Appendix A.1 shows the MCMAS specification for the Janitor application mentioned in Section 3: speci- fications for the agent User A.1.1, the agent Janitor A.1.2, and the final part

Bei Umfragen muss jedoch beachtet werden, dass die Ergebnisse durch die Art und Weise der Befragung sowie durch andere, zum Beispiel politische, persönliche und wirtschaftliche

Deze kennis is dus tweeledig: aan de ene kant stelt het voor dat Serviërs zichzelf niet capabel achten om invloed uit te oefenen op een positief verloop van de toekomst, maar aan

Het significante verschil op sociaal aanpassingsvermogen dat eerder is gevonden tussen leerlingen van openbare basisscholen en leerlingen van religieuze basisscholen op de

Bij een huwelijk langer dan 5 jaar zou de toekenning van alimentatie afhankelijk moeten zijn aan de manier waarop echtgenoten hun huwelijk hebben ingericht met betrekking tot

The objective was to determine whether the increased efficiency of structural differentiation, and coordination and integration of dispersed knowledge assets through an

Mechanical analysis of the same cell lines with atomic force microscopy 共AFM兲 in force-distance mode revealed that AFM could distinguish between the benign and malig- nant breast