• No results found

Microeconometric essays on migration, trust and Satisfaction

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Microeconometric essays on migration, trust and Satisfaction"

Copied!
174
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

Tilburg University

Microeconometric essays on migration, trust and Satisfaction

Bellemare, C.

Publication date:

2004

Document Version

Publisher's PDF, also known as Version of record

Link to publication in Tilburg University Research Portal

Citation for published version (APA):

Bellemare, C. (2004). Microeconometric essays on migration, trust and Satisfaction. CentER, Center for

Economic Research.

General rights

Copyright and moral rights for the publications made accessible in the public portal are retained by the authors and/or other copyright owners and it is a condition of accessing publications that users recognise and abide by the legal requirements associated with these rights. • Users may download and print one copy of any publication from the public portal for the purpose of private study or research. • You may not further distribute the material or use it for any profit-making activity or commercial gain

• You may freely distribute the URL identifying the publication in the public portal

Take down policy

If you believe that this document breaches copyright please contact us providing details, and we will remove access to the work immediately and investigate your claim.

(2)

.1.

TILBURG *1 11T * UNIVERSITY

(3)

•1 •

UNIVERSITEIT * * VAN TiLBURG *

BIBLIOTHEEK TILBURG

(4)

Microeconometric

Essays on

Migration,

Trust, and

Satisfaction

PROEFSCHRIFT

ter verkrijging vandegraad van doctor aan de Univer-siteit van Tilburg,op gezag vande rectormagnificus, prof. dn F.A. van derDuynSchouten, in het openbaar

te verdedigentenoverstaan van een door het college

voor promotiesaangewezen commissie in de aula van

de Universiteit op

vrijdag 28 mei 2004 om 10 :15 uur

door

CHARLES BELLEMARE

(5)
(6)

A France et Fran ois pour m'avoir donnd le gout de la vie et de la recherche

A lean-Fran ois,

(7)

Acknowledgements

Thisthesiscontains most of the work I pursued during my

four

years stayin Tilburg.

Over thistime period,manyindividuals contributed either directly or indirectly to the writing ofthis thesis.

First of all, Ihavegreatly benefited from

my

collaboration

with Arthur

vanSoest who supervised my work from the verystart, andhasco-authored thefinalchapter of

this thesis. I thank him for havingencouraged me topursue my ownresearchideas, andfor having given so much of his time, guidance, and words

of

encouragement.

Arthur's joy

toinstructothers, and his disinteresteddedication tohis students, sets an example

which I will try

to emulateallthrough myacademic life.

Duringthefirstsemester ofmystudies, I wasconfronted withthe technicalaspects of econometrics for which I was not reallyprepared. Making this transition

would

have beenmore difficult without the help ofBetrand Melenberg. The extra evening

lectures he gave me on thewhite board of my office willhavegreatlyimproved my understanding ofthefieldof econometrics. Bertrandco-authored the lastchapter of this thesis, and I amdelighted thatheaccepted to join

my

thesiscommittee.

Special thanks gotheother members ofmy thesis committee, Claude

Montmar-quette,ChristianDustmann, and Jan van Ours.

My

discussions with them have shaped the way I

think

about economic problems. I am especiallygratefulto Claude

Montmar-quette

for

havingintroduced me toexperimentalandbehavioraleconomics while I was working attheCIRANObefore entering the Ph.D.program

in

Tilburg. Hisenthusiasm

forthesefields has beenasourceofgreatinspiration. I look forwardtocollaborate with

him and his team at theCIRANO inthe years to come.

I am grateful to CentER and to theDepartment ofEconometricsfor havinggiven me

the possibility topresent my workat numerous conferences,workshopsandsummer schools. I have gained muchfromtheseexperiences,both personallyand

profession-ally. I would also liketothank Marcel Das and all the teamatCentERdatafor having

(8)

Viii

My

stayin'Illburg hasbeenhighlighted by my

joint

venture

with

Steffan Berridge in runningtheinfamousMieredikhof Hotel. Memorable cocktail parties and backyard

fires have helped us andfellow students to remain cheerfulthrough the cold winter

nights

of

111burg. I willespecially remember Steffan's

mild

chilies, his barbecue

black-out, and his special way

of

havingwhiskey.

My visit

toChina with him and Tu Qin

has left me withawealth

of

memories. It has beenapleasure to know him and I am honored thatheaccepted to be one ofmyparanymphs.

I would also like tothank my twooffice mates, JoostDriessen and in particular

Pierre-Carl Michaud, for stimulating conversations anddebates.

My

thanks extend

to all thePh.D. students and friends in

lilburg,

with

specialmention to Pierre-Carl, Antonis, David, TuQin, Youwei, Dantao, Steffan and Vera, who have allhelped me

balance mylife between workand leisure.

It does not take much reflection torealize how much ourachievements in life

de-pend on thesupport given to us by our family. Leavingmy

parents and brother has unquestionably been the most

difficult part of

mystudies abroad. I rejoicemyself in the thoughtofcoming back home, and it is

with

great emotion that I dedicatemythesis to them.

Finally,Sabine hasshared mylife throughoutthe

writing of

this thesis. Her care,

comfort,andpresence,

will

remain themost importantheritage of my timein Tilburg.

Charles Bellemare

(9)

Contents

Acknowledgements Vii

Contents ix

1 Overview ofthethesis 1

2 IdentificationandEstimationofEconomicmodelsof Outmigration usingPanel Attrition 9

2.1 Introduction . . . , . . . , , , , . . , . . . 9

2.2 Identificationof outrnigrationparameters . . . 12

2.3 Parametricmodelandestimationmethod . . . 16

2.4

Data... 20

2.5 Results and simulations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22

2.6 Conclusions . . . ... 29

Appendixto Chapter 2 30

3 A Life-Cycle Model of Outmigration and EconomicAssimilation of Immi-grantsin Germany 41

3.1 Introduction . . . .4 1

3.2 Economic

m o d e l. . . 45

3.3 Estimation procedure . .. .. . . ... . .. . . .. 49

3.4 Background and Data . . . 56

3.5 Estimationresults for thestructuralmodel . . . .. . . . .. 58

3.6 Conclusions . . . 66

Appendixto Chapter 3 68

(10)

X

4 OnRepresentativeTrust 81

4.1 Introduction . . . .8 1 4.2 TheExperimental Design and the

Sample ... 85

4.3 ResultsonTrust . . . . . .

. . 88

4.4 Results on

Trustworthiness . . . 95

4.5 Results onParticipation .

. . . .9 9

4.6 Discussion and

Conclusions . . . , . . . 100

Appendix

toChapter4 103 5 Semi-ParametricModels for Satisfaction withIncome 115 5.1 Introduction . . . , . 115 5.2 Models, EstimationTechniques,and SpecificationTests . . . 117

5.3 Data and

Variables . . . 125

5.4 Results . . . .

. . . 127

5.5 Conclusions...···

131

Appendix

toChapter5 132

Bibliography 143

(11)

List

of

Tables

2.1 Panelattrition forWest-German andImmigrantsamples1985-1999. . . 31

2.2 Descriptive statistics for West-German and Immigrant samples, 1985

and 1999 . . . 32

2.3 Unemployment Rate per Wave and Land1985-1999 . . . . . . . . . . 33

2.4 Covariancestructure of thetimevariant and timeinvariantcomponents 34

2.5 Estimation resultsfor o u t m i g r a t i o n. . . 35

2.6 Estimation resultsforincome andwork equations . . . . . . 36

2.7 Simulation

Results . . . 37

3.1 Descriptive

statistics, 1985 and 1999 . . . . . . . 69

3.2 Estimation results of thestructural

model ... 70

3.3 Panelattrition

for

West-German andImmigrantsamples1985-1999. . . . 71

3.4 Simulatedmigration

durations . . . 72

3.5 Estimation results of the reducedform model ... 73

4.1 Descriptive

statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 108

4.2 Sender

results . . . . . . . . . . 109

4.3 Responder results

-

Tobitestimator . . . 110

4.4 Responder results-STLS-estimator . . . 111

5.1 DescriptiveStatistics of thesample . . . 133

5.2 LM SpecificationTestsOrderedProbit . . . 134

5.3 Estimation Results, ExtendedSpecification . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 135

5.4 EquivalenceScales . . . 136

(12)

List of

Figures

2.1 Logmonthlyearnings andworkpropensities-Germans andimmigrants 38

2.2 Simulation

Results . . . 39

3.1 Proportions

of

immigrants

working

inGermany,not

working

and attri-tion per time period,

1987-1999. . . . . . . . . 74

3.2 Goodness of fit of themodel ... 75

3.3 Simulateddistributions fortheforward looking

model . . . 76

3.4 Simulateddistributions forthemyopic looking

m o d e l. . . 77

4.1 Distribution

of

experimentaltrust. . . . 112

4.2 Returnratio

of

responders for eachunitsreceived, strategymethod. . . 112

4.3 Estimateddensity

of

potentialreturns oninvestments . . . 113

5.1 Simulated rejection probabilities Fan and Li (1996) test . . . 137

5.2 Distribution

of

satisfaction

with

income . . . 137

5.3 Distribution of loghousehold incomebyhousehold size . . . 138

5.4 Nonparametricregressionofsatisfaction

with

income onlogincome by

household size . . . 138

5.5 Non-parametricestimate oflink function, with95%uniformconfidence bands.Ichimura'sSLS;specification 2 . . . 139

5.6 Non-parametricpartpartiallylinearmodels . . . 139

5.7 Non-parametricpartgeneralizedpartially linearmodels . . . 140

(13)
(14)

Chapter 1

Overview of

the thesis

This thesis presentsfouressayswhich illustratetheprocessof makingmicroeconomic inferencesoneconomicallyrelevant parameters characterizing

individual

welfare and decisionmaking using

individual

andhousehold data.Thisprocess isusually thought of asathreestepapproach, whichstartsbydrawingoneconomictheoryto focus on the parametersofinterest.Giveneconomically relevant parameters havebeendefined, the second step of theprocessconsists of obtainingan "ideal" datasetwhich is rich

enough to

identify

and estimatetheseparameters. Itisoften the caseineconomics and

otherobservational sciences that this"ideal" data set isnot available,whichcanoften jeopardizeidentification of some or all parameters. In thiscase, researcherstypically trytocircumventtheproblembyeitherimposingassumptions onindividualbehavior,

or bygettingbetter data. Ofcourse, in theformercase,thecredibility oftheinferences depend on the realism andfalsifiability oftheassumptions made,whilethefeasibility ofthelatterapproach depends onwhether or not onecanactuallycollect richer data. Once identification hasbeenachieved, thefinalstep consistsof using existing or new estimatorsin orderto extract therelevantinformation from thedata. Becauseseveral estimators,under different set

of

assumptions,cansuccessfully extractthis informa-tion, empirical researchers havea degree offreedom to choose the model which is

estimated. Fortunately, economictheoryoften restricts the setofpossible econometric models, andmodeltesting procedures and goodness of

fit

evaluationscansometimes be used to test the

validity

of maintainedassumptions,providing a waytoincrease the

reliability oftheinferences made.

The essays in thisthesis arepresented asindependent chapters, and analyze the characteristics anddecisionrulesof immigrants wholeavetheirhost country, evaluate

(15)

2 Chapter 1. Overview of the thesis

the determinants of trust andtrustworthiness for different sub-groups ofthe

popula-tion, and estimate household equivalence scales. Ineachchapter,identification of the

economic parametersofinterestisachieved either byimposingrealistic and falsifiable

assumptionson

individual

behavior, or

by

collecting better data. Taken together,these

essaysdevelop a widerangeofeconometric modelsin orderto estimate the

parame-tersofinterest,fromdiscretechoicestaticand panel data models, tostructural dynamic programmingmodels, nonparametric models, and semiparametricmodels. Although

issuesof identificationandestimationarediscussed inallessays,theirrelativeweight

differsacrosschapters.

The firsttwo chapters deal

with

outmigration,defined as thedeparture of

immi-grantsfrom their adoptivehomeland.During thelastdecade,economists have increas-inglybecome aware that outmigration is not onlya world widephenomena, but the

magnitude oftheoutflows insomecasesbe sizeable. WithinEurope, the case of

Ger-many stands outprominently, withanestimated halfa

million

immigrantsleaving the

countryevery year (OECD,2001).Understandingthemotivations

for

thesedepartures

is animportant input for policy makers whomust forecastoutflows

of

immigrants in orderto adjusttheir immigration policies to fitthefutureneedsof theirlabor markets, and to assess the economic performance of immigrants who remain in the country. Several theories havebeenproposed toexplainthesemovements, someof which pre-dict thattherelativelysuccessfulimmigrantsleavetheir adoptivecountry,whileother

theoriespredict that most ofthe departures areby unsuccessfulimmigrants. Some-what surprisingly,there hasbeen

little

structuralinference on the preferences, tastes, and other primitivescharacterizingimmigrants which would allowtovalidatethese theories, helpusunderstand the typeof immigrants whichself-select themselves out of the country,and

would

enableinteresting policyexperiments. Given thatthe

param-eters ofinterestare clearlydefined, the lack ofinferences can betraced back to data

limitations. The body ofdatatypicallyavailable toconducttheseinferences usually

consists ofasampleof immigrants, reinterviewed in subsequentyears. This type of

surveydata rarely containsindicators of immigrantsdepartures. Instead, what is em-piricallyobserved isattrition fromthe panel,caused eitherby immigrantdepartures or by non-response of the nondeparting immigrants. Thus, thedata fails todirectly

identify

the parametersofinterest, and gatheringthe missing information

would in

many instancesbeprohibitivelycostly.

(16)

im-3

posed on

individual

decisionmaking in order tononparametricallyidentifyseveral

important economic parameters characterizing the performance

of

outmigrants, no-tably theconditional outmigration probability, theconditional

work

probability, and

theconditional expected labormarketearnings

of

outmigrants. Theassumption

re-quired isthe existenceof immigrants whose observable characteristics are such that

their outmigration probability isclose to zero. Equally important,becausepanel

at-trition is, contraryto outmigration,always observable in surveydata, these results open up thepossibility tomake inferenceswhich werenotpreviouslypossible due to

data limitations. Toextract theparametersofinterestfrompanel attrition, the

chap-ter presentsa

limited

dependent variable model forpanel data

with

randomeffects,

wherelabor marketearningsareestimatedjointly with both workand outmigration equations. An importantaspect of theempirical model is that itallows to test the key

identification assumption inasimpleway. Indeed, the results indicate thata

substan-tial number of immigrants haveanoutmigration probabilityclose to zero. The main

results fromtheempiricalanalysis show that outmigrants arenegativelyselected in terms of labor marketearnings and

work

propensities. Throughoutthe sample pe-riod, we find that the gap ineconomic performanceof immigrants who remained in Germanyand thosewho outmigrated was sizeable,

with

outmigrants having work probabilitiesand expected labormarketearnings respectively 18% and30%lower than immigrantswho remain inGermany. Finally, the estimated outmigration rate in the

samplepopulationisfound toberoughly 3% per year.

Chapter3presents and estimatesa structural dynamic model whereimmigrants

simultaneouslychoosetheir workandmigration durationsover theirlife-cycle.

Con-trary to existinglife-cycle models,immigrantsareallowed tofaceuncertainty about

their future labor market outcomesall through their migration experience. Because outmigrationis rarely observed at the individual level, structural estimates of

life-cycle models

of

outmigration have yet tobeformallytested.This chapter draws on the identification results ofthepreviouschapter and extends the approach toadynamic programmingsetting. This allows to make direct structural inferencesonoutmigration

life-cyclebehavior

without

havingto observeoutmigration and to testthe

validity of

several existinglife-cycle theories. Our findings confirmthe hypothesis recently put forward intheliteraturethatoutmigration isnotentirely driven byearnings

differen-tials. Specifically, we findthatimmigrants whofeelintegrated inthe Germansociety,

(17)

na-4 Chapter 1. Overview of the thesis tive country are less

likely

tooutmigrate. The results ofthis chapter also

highlight

the importanceof incorporating the

work

decisionalong withthemigration duration

decisionof immigrants,afeaturepreviously ignored intheoutmigration literature. It is found that both immigrants with relatively low and highlabormarketexperience

haveagreater overallutilitytooutmigrate, whichsuggests aUshaperelationbetween

labor marketexperience and theoverall

utility

to outmigrate. The decreasein overall outmigration

utility

starting from lowlevelsofexperienceisconsistent

with

increas-ingpsychologicalcosts associatedwith outmigration,keeping earnings constant. The convex increase

in

overall outmigration

utility

predicted to occurbeyond25years of

labor marketexperienceisconsistent

with

progressivelylowerpsychological costs of outmigrationanddiminishingreturns to labormarketexperience in the host country.

Theseresults are interestinggiven that most of the outmigration literature has

ana-lyzed outmigration

within

anearningsdifferential paradigm which, byconstruction, orient policy recommendations towards measures aimed atinfluencing theearnings

differentialbetween the host and thenew destination. Theresults of this chapter do not rule outtheimportantrole playedby labormarket earningsin determining migration durations. However, they doindicate thatthe shape of themigration duration distri-bution isalsodetermined by pastworkdecisions,indicating that much canbegained

fromananalysisin whichlaborsupply decisionsareendogenously determined. The

chapteradditionallypresentsaseriesof policysimulations aimed atevaluating how

themigration duration distribution of immigrants is affectedby government policy

aimedatspeedingup economic integration of newly arrived immigrants. Itisfound

thatmeasuresaimed atimprovingaccess to thehostlabor

market

improving

acquisi-tion

of

language skills, andlump-sum taxation willhave

little

impact ofthemigration duration distribution ofarepresentative immigrant, buthavesubstantialinfluence of migration durationdecisions of

low

incomeimmigrants.

In chapter 4, the economic parameters

of

interest arethedeterminantsof

individual

trust andtrustworthinesspropensities. Compared to theprevioustwo chapters,

iden-tification oftheseparametersisachieved, notby imposinga

priori

assumptions on the

individual

decision maker, butbyusingbetter data in the form ofa randomsample oftheDutch population who playanexperimentalgamemeasuring

individual

trust andtrustworthinesspropensities, bothof which havebeenshown tobestrongly corre-lated

with

economicgrowth.Theidentificationapproachisnovel in many respects and

(18)

5

experiments which uses a sample

of

subjectswhich are representative ofa nation's

population. Substantial heterogeneity

in

trust and trustworthinessbehaviorisfound intheDutch population. Of particularinterest are the rolesplayed bythe education level and the ageofsubjects. The chaptershows that both ofthesebackground

char-acteristics playan important role in determiningtrust andtrustworthiness, although

they affect trust and trustworthiness in very different ways. While the inverted U

shaperelation between trust and ageusually

found in

the literature is also present

in our data,

with

trust increasinguntil the age of 30and decreasingbeyond that, the relationbetween trustworthiness and ageisfound to beU shaped,

with

trustworthi-nessdecreasing until the age of 30, andrisingagain beyondthat point. Theeducation patterns are also very different. We find an inverted-Ushaperelationbetween edu-cation and trust, and a U shaperelationshipbetween education andtrustworthiness. Suchopposite influencesofbackground characteristicsarepuzzlinginsofar as it is

typ-icallyassumed that trust andtrustworthiness go hand inhand,which

would

suggest

that botharedeterminedin similar ways. Asa secondmain contribution, the chapter presents a new andsimple wayto compare theinformationalcontent ofbothrevealed (experimental) and stated (survey) trust measures. The literature has until now

as-sessedthe

validity

ofsurvey trust questionsby testingwhether or nottheypredicted

well

experimentaltrust. One of themainmessages ofthe chapter is that thismethod of validation hasbeen given too muchattention, primarilybecausethepredictive power

of surveymeasuresisintimately linked tothe sample used, the amount ofbackground

informationavailable on the subjects, and theexperimental design. Itisshown that by carefullyselecting samples and designs, experimentersincreasetheir odds of finding

either a low or high predictive power ofthesurveytrustmeasure. Thus,despite that

contrary totheexisting literaturethesurvey trustmeasure used in this chapter predicts well trust intheexperiment, this is not takenasevidencevalidating the use of survey

trust questions. Withregards to theinformationalcontentbothmeasurescarry on the

determinants oftrust,thedifferencesarecompelling. Itisshownthateducation has an

inverted-Ushaperelation

with

experimental trust while it does notcorrelate at all with

answers to the statedtrustquestion. Incontrast,religioncorrelates wellwithanswers tothestated trust question, but not at all

with

experimentaltrust.

Instark contrast, chapter5 presents aexample where statedresponsesprovide a

simple solutiontoidentificationproblemswhichcannotbeovercome using data on

(19)

6 Chapter 1. Overview of the thesis

incomewhichshouldbegiven toahousehold withaspecific compositionofadults and

childrentoreach the samelevelofwelfare thanareference household.Thesequantities are important for public policyconcerningwelfarebenefits andchildallowances, and

have also been used to analyze incomeinequality

within

and between countries and

forthe analysis

of

poverty.Thetraditionalapproach to estimationofequivalencescales usesconsumerdemandsystems,relyingonvariation inexpenditure on commodities

acrossfamilieswith differentcomposition. PollakandWales (1979)andBlundell and

Lewbel(1991) demonstrated that consumer demand data alone is notrichenough to nonparametrically identifythelevel of the equivalence scales. In this chapter, the

fail-ure to identify levels using revealed consumption choices is overcome using stated

responses to questions on satisfaction with income, which directly reveal a cardinal

measureofconsumerutility. Statedanswers to such questions provide empirical

re-searchers with a discrete and ordered response variable,usually

analyzed using

or-deredprobitand linearregression models. The emphasis of the chapter is to recover

estimates ofthelevelofequivalencescalesforGerman householdsusingabroad range

ofestimation procedures, from the usualorderedprobitandlinearregression models,

to more recent nonparametric andsemiparametricmodelswhichweaken parametric

assumptionsof linearand ordered probit regression models. Given the broad range

ofpossible estimators, the chapter uses consistent waysof testing each underlying model assumption against generalforms

of

mis-specification. Themain findings of the chapter arethatorderedprobitmodelsarerejected,whileseveralsemiparametric estimators are not. Despite this, estimates of the equivalencescales arefound to be

ro-bustacrossmodels. Finally, itisfound thatequivalencescalesmonotonicallyincrease

with

thenumber of children for low and

middle

income households, butarefound to be relatively flat for highincome households.

Collectively, these essayspresent waystoovercomeidentification problems in

mi-gration, experimental economics, and measurementofhousehold equivalencescales. Ineach chapter,illustration ofthe approachesrequired that theybeapplied either to veryspecific countries,institutionalsettings, and choice environments. However, the usefulnessofthese essays goes beyond theseapplications, andprovidemeans for a

significant number of extensions. Theidentification strategy proposedin chapter 1

opens up thepossibility todoresearch onthe economicsof outmigration in practically any country with anongoing panel surveying immigrants. Because

outmigration is

aworldwidephenomena, this avenueoffutureresearch is

(20)

or-7

der to improve our understanding ofthe flows of human capital takingplace across

the globe. Moreover, because this strategy is relatively general, itcaneasily be ap-plied to analyze any form of migration movements, fromthe departures ofnatives, to movementsofindividualswithinacountry Theresults presented in thefirst two

chapters of this thesis show that such extensions haveapromising future. The thesis also showed that one cannowsuccessfully makepopulationinferences onbehavior in

experimentalgames. Whilethe thesishasshown that inferences based onsurvey

re-sponses can insomecasesdiffer remarkably fromthose basedon revealed preference data collectedfrom experiments, it has alsobeen shown thatsurveydata remains a useful source toidentifyeconomic parameters related to measuresofhousehold sat-isfaction. More generally, it ishoped that this thesis has alsodemonstrated that the combinationofsurvey andexperimentalmethods has thepotentialtoprovideuseful

insights in many differentgames,settings, andpopulations, which

will

undoubtedly

(21)
(22)

Chapter 2

Identification

and

Estimation of

Economic

models

of Outmigration

using

Panel

Attrition

2.1 Introduction

The widespread and often sizeableflows

of

immigrants leaving theiradoptive home-lands,which we

will

refer toasoutmigration,have recently received a lotofattention. The case of Germany is a particularly revealingexample, withan estimated yearly outflow of halfa

million

immigrants over thelast decade (OECD,2001). Several the-ories have beenput forward to motivate outmigrationmovements. Theories based

on earningsdifferentialsbetween the current and newdestination (Harrisand Todaro,

1970),higher marginal

utility

of

consumption in thehome country (Djajic and

Mil-bourne, 1988),highreturns tohumancapitalinvestments in thehost country

(Dust-mann, 1993), information dissemination(Stark, 1995),credit market rationing in the native country (Mesnard, 2001), and several sociological factors suchas

family

uni-fication, health satisfaction, feelingsofbeing integrated insociety (Stark, 1998) , and the qualityandproductivity ofanimmigrant'ssocialnetwork(e.g. Carrington, Detra-giache and Vishwanath, 1996).

Thesetheories do not

trivially

predict a specificcomposition of departing

immi-grants. Itcould be the caseforexamplethateconomically successfulimmigrants with

arelatively higher marginal

utility

of consumption in their native country might opt

to leave despiterelatively lowerearnings inthatcountry,while persistently

(23)

10 Chapter2. Identification ofOutmigration

ful

immigrantsmight find aworthwhile to keepon searchingforbetter labor market prospects and move to anew destination. The lack ofaclear-cut theoreticalprediction

concerning theeconomic performance

of

outmigrants complicates the design of im-migrationpolicieswhichareoftentailoredaround thenotion thatlabor market

equi-libriums may be affectedby outmigration flows of non-randomlyselectedworkers. Careful forecasting ofthequality ofthemigration flows isthusnecessary

if

immigra-tion policies are to meetthe futureneeds of the labor market. Additionally, recent

theoretical andempiricalevidencehassuggestedthatmeasuresofeconomic progress

of immigrants in theirhost country canbeadversely affectedbyselectiveoutmigration

(Schultz, 1998, andEdin, LaLonde, andAslund,2000).Policies aimed atimproving the

labormarket integration ofitsimmigrant population may thus alsobemisguided if it

reliesonthesepotentiallybiased measuresof immigrant assimilation.

In thischapter, weareinterestedintestingcompetingexplanationsof outmigration

decisions while at the same timeassessing therobustnessofmeasuresofeconomic

as-similationtooutmigrationflows. We do sobyestimatingalimited-dependentvariable panel data model where labor market earnings,workdecisions, andoutmigration de-cisionsarejointlydetermined and depend on earningsdifferentials, family unification, creditmarketrationing,health satisfaction, and feelingsof beingintegrated in the host

society. Unobservable characteristics such as animmigrant's ability orthequality and

productivity ofhis socialnetworkareincorporated inthemodelasindividualspecific

unobserved heterogeneity components. The generalerror structure ofthe model al-lows totestwhether outmigrants areself-selected in terms

of

labor marketearnings andin terms of

work

status. Themodel alsoallowstoassess theimpactof outmigra-tion selecoutmigra-tiononestimates ofmeasuresofeconomic assimilationrates. Compared to existing empiricalmodelsof outmigration(seebelow),ourmodel hastheadvantage

of both incorporating thedecision to work in a natural wayand characterizing the relationshipbetweenworkstatus andoutmigration.

Estimation of our modelrequires panel data onimmigrants followed over a rela-tively longperiod of time. As Dustmann(2002)recentlypointed out,interesting

(24)

iden-Section2.1.

Introduction 11

tify

the economic parameters characterizing the performanceof outmigrants

without

observingoutmigrationdecisions. Jassoand Rosenzweig(1990)

identify

thedirection of outmigrationearningsselectivityby comparingtheskill composition ofspecific

co-horts over time. Hu (2000) andLubotsky(2000)estimate the parameters of the earnings functionof immigrants who remain inthecountry,controlling for non-random outmi-gration selectivity by matchingcross-section data setsand

longitudinal

socialsecurity

earnings records. Theseapproaches are not

without

their own limitations-they do not

identify

thelevelofearningsofoutmigrants,censusand earnings records often have

little information on boththehuman capital level and sociological characteristics of migrantswhicharerequired to testoutmigrationtheories 2, they do not easilyallow migration duration decisions to depend on unobserved characteristics suchas inher-ent ability orthequality ofanimmigrant'ssocialnetwork which,at leaston theoretical grounds,areimportantdeterminantsof migration durations.

Inthis chapter, we presentconditions under whichtheoutmigration probability,

the

work

probability, andthe expected labor market earnings

of

outmigrants are,

con-ditionallyon observable characteristics,nonparametrically identified fromsurvey data

with

sampleattrition.The cornerstone ofour identificationapproach consistsof using

panelattrition asaproxyvariable for outmigration,and subsequently separating

at-trition which is not duetooutmigrationmovements from realoutmigrationdecisions.

Ourapproach overcomes several of the shortcomings

of

earlier approaches used to

identifythe economic performanceof outmigrants.First,ourapproach is toour knowl-edgethefirstonewhich hasthepotentialtoprovide nonparametric identification of the economic performance and movementsof outmigrants.Second,becausethe approach

proposed uses survey panel data instead ofcensus data, unobserved heterogeneity

can easily beintroduced in themodel. Third, the approachis general enough to be applied toany

country with

an ongoing panelof immigrants (examplesofcountries

withsuch panelsareCanada, Mexico, Germany, and the United-States.) and can be

easily extended to estimatemanydifferenttypesofeconomic modelsof outmigration.

An example ofthis flexibility is our abilityto analyze theinteractionbetween earnings, work,and outmigration decisions ina unifiedframework which wasnot previously possible

without

observing actualmigrationdecisions. Finally, the estimator proposed

is simple to apply, andissimilar in

spirit

to estimators proposed to deal

with

(25)

12 Chapter 2. Identification of Outmigration

We estimate our model using thepublic use file of the GSOEP. We use data on

native Germans as a reference group to compute earningsassimilation rates for our

immigrantsample. We show how theavailability ofasampledrawn from thenative population has theadditionaladvantageof providinganatural way to test some of the identifyingassumptions ofthemodel.Weestimate the annualoutmigration rate in our

sample toberoughly 3% per year over our time horizon. Our simulation results

indi-catethataveragelog earnings

of

outmigrantsremainedroughly18%lowerthanthose

of immigrantstayers,aclearindication that outmigrantsaredrawn fromthebottom of the incomedistribution. Moreover,outmigrants areshown to have

work

probability

25% to45%lower than thatofimmigrantstayers over theperiodconsidered. Finally, we do not find thatassimilationrates areparticularlysensitivetooutmigration, which

contrastswithexisting resultsfound inthe literature.

The rest of this chapter isorganizedasfollows. Section2.2presentsourapproach

to identifytheeconomic parametersofinterest. Section2.3presents the econometric model used tomodel outmigration in conjunction with the

work

decision and labor marketearnings. Section 2.4presents the data used in the chapter. Section2.5 discusses

theempirical results of the model and tests for thepresenceof outmigration bias. It furtherpresents somesimulation results usedtoevaluate the fit ofthemodel and to quantifythe economic performanceof outmigrants.Section2.6concludes.

2.2 Identification of outmigration

parameters

Each immigrant ofapopulation living in thehostcountryischaracterized in agiven

time period by thevector (w, p, ru, x, z,s) wherew denoteshispotential labor mar-ketearningsconditionalon characteristics x, p isabinary variable takinga value of 1

whentheimmigrant worksandwhose outcomeisconditioned onavectorof observ-able characteristics z, ru isabinary indicator takingavalue of 1 when theimmigrant

outmigrates in the next time period andwe conditionthis outcome onavector of

char-acteristics s. Wedefine X as the vector of all distinctelements of (x, z, s). We are

interested in makinginferences on Pr (p = 1 lru = 1,

X),

conditional

work

probability

of an outmigrant, and on E {wlp = 1, ru = 1, X},theconditionalexpectedearnings of outmigrants. Theinferentialproblem consistof identifyingthesequantities when,

in-steadofobservingoutmigration,we observea

proxyvariablero,panelattrition, which

(26)

Out-Section2.2.Identifcation results 13 migrationand

attrition

arerelatedbecause animmigrant wholeavesthecountry must

also leavethe panel

with

probability 1.3

We illustrate theidentificationproblems for thecasewhere we want tomake

infer-enceson E{wlp = 1, ru =

1.X}.

However,allresults extenddirectlytoidentification of

Pr (p = liru = 1, X).4 Theconditionalexpected labor marketearningsof immigrants

who leave thepanel in the next timeperiod can be expressed,usingiterated

expecta-tions, as

E{wlp = l.ro = 1,X} = E{wlp =l, r° =l, ru =l,X} ·Pr(ru =llro = 1,X)

+E{wlp = 1,78 = 1,ru = O. X} · Pr(ru = 0170 = 1. X) = E {wlp = 1, ru = 1, X} ·Pr (ru = 1 lro = 1, X)

+E {wlp = 1, ru = 0, X} · Pr (ru = Olro = 1,

X)

(2.1) wherethesecondequalityfollows from the fact that once we know ifanimmigrant left

or not the country, observing whether he left of not the panel doesnotcontain any addi-tional information onthe earnings ofthisimmigrantconditional on X.5 Animmediate

consequenceofequation (2.1) is thatusing panelattrition asaproxyvariablefor

outmi-gration

in itself will

give biased and inconsistent estimates of theconditionalearnings

of outmigrants. This is sobecause the conditionalexpected earnings of immigrants

who leave thepanel will ingeneral beaweightedaverage of theconditionalexpected

earnings of outmigrants mixed withthe conditional earningsof immigrants who

re-main in the host country.Themixing probabilitiescontrol the size of the bias. The key

parameter is Pr (ru = Olr° = 1,

X),

whichrepresents theprobability thatanimmigrant

stays in the thehostcountrygiven that heisobserved to leave the panel. Thehigher this probability, the higher will be the bias.

If

everyimmigrant wholeaves the panel

also leaves thecountry, r°would perfectlymeasureoutmigration, Pr (ru = Olr° = 1, X)

wouldbeequal to zero, and the bias would be zero.

Next, wefollow thesame stepstoderivetheconditionalexpected earnings of im-migrantswho remain inthe panel

E{wlp = 1, ro = O,X} = E{wlp = 1, ru = 1, X}·Pr(ru =llro = O,

X)

(2.2)

+E{wlp = 1, ru = 0,X} ·Pr (ru = Olro = O, X)

Becauseanimmigrantcannotbeobserved to have left thecountrygiven heisobserved

to be in the panel, Pr (ru = 1 Ir° = 0, X) = 0, Pr (ru = 0 Ir° = 0, X) = l and (2.2)

simpli-fies to

(27)

14 Chapter 2. Identification of Outmigration whichindicates thattheconditionalearningsof immigrants who remain inthe panel

coincides withthe expected earningsof immigrants who remain in thehost country, andit follows that E {wlp = 1, ru = 0, X} isnonparametrically identified from data on immigrants inthe sample.Substituting (2.3) in (2.1)weobtain

E{wlp = 1,f = 1,X} = E{wip = 1, ru - 1, X}·Pr(ru =llro = 1, X)

+E{wlp = 1, ro = 0, X} ·Pr (ru = Olro = 1. X)

which canbesolved interms of E {wlp = 1, ru = 1, X},theparameter we hope to

iden-tify,

E{wlp=l, ru=l,X} = E{wlp=l, ro -1, X} ·Wi(X)-1

-E{wlp = 1,t - 0, X}· Wo (X) Wi (X)-1 (2.4)

Equation(2.4)shows that theconditionalexpected earningsofoutmigrants can be ex-pressed as a weighted average oftwo conditional expectationswhichareidentified from the data. Iftheweights canbeidentified, thentheconditionalearnings

of

outmi-grants willbeidentified. ApplyingBaye's rule, theweightsaregiven by

Wo (X) = Pr (ru= Olt =1, X)

= Pr (ro = 1lru = 0, X) Pr (ru = OIX)

Pr (r° = 1 IX) Wl (X) = Pr (ru = 1 lro = 1, X) - Pr (P = 1 1 r u - 1 X)Pr (ru = 1 IX) v ' , Pr ( r°= 1 IX) =1 Pr (ru = 1 IX) Pr (ro= 1IX)

Pr (r° = 1 IX) is identified fromthe attrition data. What remains to beidentified is

Pr (ru IX) and Pr (ro = 11ru = 0, X). Itisclear assumptions mustbeplaced on the data generatingprocesstoidentifytherelationshipbetweentheobservable

attrition

indica-tor r° and the unobservableoutmigrationindicator ru.To

simplify

thenotation, we will

denote a10 (X) E Pr (r° = 1 lru = O.

X)

Using the law oftotalprobability,theattrition

probability canbe expressedin general terms as

Pr (ro = 1IX) = alo (X) + 11 - alo (X)] · Pr (ru =

lIX)

(2.5)

and theprobabilityofremaining inthe sample as

Pr (r° =

OIX) =1- {alo (X) t[l- trio

(X)]

Pr (ru = 1IX)}

(28)

Section2.2.Identification results 15

Several assumptions canbeimposed on the data generatingprocessin orderto

identify

both alo (X)andPr (ru = 1IX).

Assumption Al a10 (X) = alo 2 0

Proposition2.1. If Al holdsandthereexists a X such that Pr (ru = 1 IX) = 0. E {wip = 1, ru = 1, X} is nonparametrically ident(Red.

Proof. Given the foregoing discussion, it suffices to establish that theconditions of

theProposition

identify

the weights Wo (X) and Wi (X). From (2.5), it follows that

Pr (r° = 1IX) = 0:10whichidentifies 0:10from

limit

observations satisfying Pr (ru = 1 IX) =

0. Given a lo isidentified, Pr (ru = 1IX)isidentified from(2.6),which implies that the

weights Wo (X) and Wo (X) are bothnonparametrically identified. 0

Proposition 1 shows that

if

attrition which is not duetooutmigrationisrandom in

the population (Al),

all importanteconomic parameters characterizingoutmigration

behavior canberecovered from the data

if

there existsasampleofpermanentmigrants; i.e. immigrantswhoseoutmigrationprobabilityisclose to zero. Inpractice, this does not seem to beastrong requirement, especially

for

western countries wherepermanent

migrationisknownto occur at averylarge scale (OECD, 2001). Note thatinpractice,

Al needs not to hold

if

attrition which isnotrelated tooutmigration does not vary in the population (i.e. ifthevariance V (trio (X)) . 0). This canbeverifiedforexample by

computing marginaleffectsfrom binarychoice regressions onattritionoutcomes for a sampleofindividuals who by construction donotoutmigrate, and test

if

theseeffects

aresmall. Nativesliving in thehostcountry isoneexample ofasamplenotprone to outmigration.

If attrition

which is not duetooutmigrationisbelieved toberelated to observable factors which induce sufficient variation in the attritionprocess across individuals, nonparametric identification oftheeconomic parametersof outmigrantsrequires some

exclusion restriction.

Assumption A2 alo (X) = 0:10 (Xi) 2 0where X = (XH, X6)'

Proposition2.2. IfAZ holdsandthereexists a X; given Xi such that Pr (ru = 11Xl, XS) = 0,

(29)

16 Chapter 2. Identification of Outmigration proof· Fora given X = (X;, X4):a10 (X) = alo (Xl) fromA2.Using Pr (ru = 11Xi, X;) =

0, the subsampleof immigrants

(X;,Xi')'

identifies 0: 10 (Xl ) from (2.5).Given c:10 (Xl) is identified, Pr (ru = 1IX)isidentified from(2.6),which implies thattheweights Wo (X) and Wo (X) are bothnonparametricallyidentified. 0

Partlybecauseattritionandoutmigration are very differentprocesses,finding

real-isticexclusion restrictions whichsatisfy the requirementsof Proposition 2 is not very

restrictive. Usually outmigrationismodelled asalife-cycle event,influenced by poor

labor marketperformance,integrationfeelings, credit rationing in thehomecountry and ageatimmigration. Whether

attrition

which is not duetooutmigrationisrelated

toallthesefactorsseemsa

priori

unlikely, given that part ofthesurvey non-response is

generally based on respondents refusal to continue working with thesurveyagencies.

2.3

Parametric

model

and

estimation

method

In thissection, we develop and estimateaparametric model whichallows us to extract

outmigrationbehaviorfrompanelattrition.The choice ofaparametricmodel is

moti-vated byourdesiretomodelselection into workandoutmigration asadecisionbased

on

individual

specific unobserved heterogeneity. We are not aware ofany existing

semiparametric techniquewhich would allow us toestimatethesystemofequations presented below.

We have a measure of N immigrants in period 1, whereimmigrant i remains in the panel forTi periods. Foreach

immigrant i,

we observe in period t,whether he

pvorks pit, hismonthly labormarketearnings e(wit), and his attrition

status r;, in the

next period. The log ofthepotentiallabormarketearningsisassumed tobegenerated

by aloglinear earnings equation

Wit= 4,0 + Vil +

ElI (2.D

where Bareunknownparameters, Yii isan unobservedtimeinvariant individual spe-cificcomponentofincomewhileElIrepresentsastochasticshock. Theselabor market

earnings areonlyobservable whenan immigrant works. The

work

decision pit is as-sumed tobegenerated byalatentprocess

(30)

Section2.3.Parametricmodelandestimationmethod 17 where 0 are unknown parameters, 11,2 is an unobserved

component of work and 4

representssomestochasticshock to the

work

propensity. Participationisdetermined

by

theobservation rule pit = 1 [pi > 0]. When pit = 1, earnings wit are observed.

Both and Zl can

bethought of capturing immigrantsunobserved

ability

to generate

higherearnings and to find jobs. They can alsobethought ofasincludingunobserved

family background characteristics and preferences for workand leisure. Finally, an immigrant'sunobservableoutmigration propensity r is assumed tobedetermined by

another latentprocess

ri = s;,7 + 4,3 +

2

(2.9)

where 7 are unknownparameters, 4,3 captures the

individual

specific attachment to hisnative country and 4 isa stochastic shock. The

triplet

{,li, 111·'13} isassumed to be observed by theimmigrant who takes it intoaccountwhen makinghis decisions

but it is notobserved by the econometrician. Let

rM = 1 [ri > 0] be

thedecision rule governing thetrueoutmigrationdecision

in

period t +1.Outmigration r;;is

unobserv-able. Inour empirical application, weassume thatAlholds6andexpresstheattrition probability as

Pr (4 = lisit) = a1O + [1 - Kio]I

Pr (r# =

lIsit)

(2.10)

Equation (2.10) is the samplecounter part ofequation (2.5).7

The earnings, work andoutmigrationoutcomes are notlikely tobeindependent of each other. This will notbeindependent if, forexample, immigrants who find work very easily and/or who earn a highincome are more reluctant to outmigrate. The

unobserved heterogeneity components7,1,11,2 and 4,3 canbetreated eitherasfixed

con-stants orasrandomvariables. Themainadvantage of the fixed effect approach is that

it doesnot requirethatincluded explanatoryvariablesbestrictlyexogenous to the un-observed heterogeneity components ('1 , '1 ,'1 )· However, estimationof fixedeffects

in

nonlinearmodels remains todaya sizeablecomplication, with very little guidance

in

the choiceofmodels (see the recentreview

of

Arellanoand Honord, 2001).

A

second

drawback

of

fixed effectestimation is that by treatingthe unobserved heterogeneity componentsasfixed,crossequation correlationswhich drive selection into work and outmigrationbasedon unobservable

individual

characteristics arenotidentified. As

the present chapterismainlyconcerned

with

selectionissues, fixedeffectestimation would limit our insights in the type ofselections present in the data. Wetherefore

in-troducethesedependenciesbyassuming that thestochastictime-invarianteffects are

(31)

covari-18 Chapter2.Identifcation of Outmigration ance matrix 4 p:.25,5, PY,35" 5,

0 = · 4 P2420,20,3

2

. 993

-where

4

denotesthe variances of the unobserved heterogeneity components, and p5·

denotestheircorrelations.8 Thesecorrelationsareindicativeof whether or not

immi-grantsself-selectthemselves into work andinto outmigrationbasedontheir unobserv-able

individual

characteristics.A significantandpositivep .2indicatesthat individuals

who are more likely to work are also morelikely tohavehigherearnings,giveobserved

characteristics. p 1 has,- asimilar interpretation and isindicative of outmigration bias.

This coefficient willbenegative(positive)

if

immigrants who haveahigher

probabil-ity of

outmigratinghavebelow (above)averagemonthlyearnings. Finally, PL can be

interpretedasmeasuring outmigration bias in the

work

decision and whose sign has a

similar interpretation.

Finally, we assume that the

vector [el, 4,4]' is i.i.d

normally distributed with

mean 0and covariancematrix

-2 E- -2 aw Pl,2"W pl,3gw

E= · 1 pb

1

where qi isthe variance oflogearnings,

while

the variances of the unobserved stochas-ticshocksentering the workandoutmigrationequations are set to 1for identification

purposes. Contemporaneous correlations between the three stochastic components are

captured bythecorrelation coefficientsP ,2 Pf,3 and p6J·

To simplifythepresentation of thelikelihood function, wedividethe observable characteristics of immigranti into a set Yi = {Pit, 4, wit · Pit } il of dependent

vari-ables, a set Xi = {xit, zit, sit } ii ofexogenous variables, andavector vi = (qil, '1 , 'li)

containingunobservedtimeinvariantheterogeneity. Moreover, we denoteby g(·, ·. · lili)

(32)

Section2.3. Parametricmodel andestimationmethod 19 firststepdensityisgiven by

fc Cy,Ixi,qi; B. 8,7, r, x1O)

Tirff

= Il / / 4 (1- rlt) (1- trio) g(p;„riA, wit;El,li) dr;,

t=i ./Qi, ./Ci,

l

J -00

CO fo

+41 f g(PA, rii, wit:ElI/i)0 J -00dr;t.+-0:10 11 g (PA, r,$, wit; Elqi) dr;, dp;; drvit

The casewhereoutmigration isperfectlyobserved follows bysettinga10 equal to 0.

The sets it anditdefine thedomainofintegration over the wage and

work

spaces and

vary over timeas individualsmakedifferentchoices ineachperiod according to the

following

table

Integrationdomainsin period t Qi: Cit

Work - [0.co)

Not Work (-co, 00) (-co,0]

Income isintegrated out in waveswhere individuals do not work. The integration

domain for the

work

propensity follows from the work decision rule. In thesecond

step, theunconditionallikelihood functionis obtainedby integrating outtherandom

individual

effects over R3

f (yilxi; 4, 0,7,li, Cl,o:10) = f f (yiIX,·,1/i; 4,0,7, E, alo) h (qi; fl) dui JR3

where H denotes the trivariate normal cumulativedistribution function with mean

vector 0 and covariancematrix O.

To solvethenumerical integrationproblem, weapproximate theintegral by a sim-ulated mean:asequence of r = 1,2,..., Ri.i.d.

draws 11)) = (11,1('), 42('),119(')) is taken

fromthemultivariate normal distribution H atagivenvalue of 0.9 For each draw, the

conditional likelihood

function fc

isevaluated. ThepartialMSLestimatorconsists of

replacing f bythesimulated mean

Ell, log R El, fc (Y,IXi,111'); 4,8,7,E,ir,o)11

Theresultingestimatoris inconsistentforfixed R but willbeconsistent ifRtends to

(33)

20 Chapter2.

Identifcation

ofOutmigration likelihood(Train,2003). Finally, wemodellabormarketearnings and

work

decisions

ofGermans usingsimilarspecifications

of

equations (2.7) and (2.8) and estimate the

parameters using thesimulationtechniques described above.

2.4 Data

The data used inthis chapteristaken fromthepublic use file oftheGSOEPandcovers

the 1985-1999period. Until 1990,the GSOEPconsisted of two samples, A and B.

Sam-ple A consistsofhouseholds

with

Germanheads

living

in formerWest-Germany Sam-ple B consists ofansampleof immigrants

living in

West-Germany coming from coun-trieswhichhad signedabilateral migrationagreement

with

Germany inthe 1950s and

1960snamelyGreece,Italy, Spain, Turkey and Yugoslavia.10 Data on speaking fluency,

integrationfeelingsof immigrants, intendedlength of stay and remittances directed to

their

family living

outside Germany were given

in

consecutive waves from1984

until

1987. Starting in 1987, thisinformationwas gathered every other yean

In

order to keep constant the timeperiodbetween observations, we have chosen to keep the8 waves

ofthe panelwhere detailedinformation onimmigrantswas available,eachspanned

by oneyear,starting in 1985 andending in1999. Following theliteraturemeasuring

the economic assimilation rate(e.g. Borjas,1999a),werestrictour attentiontomales

between 18 and64years ofageduringthe1985-1999period. Excluded from the

sam-pleareindividuals whodiedduringtheobservationperiodandindividuals who gave incompleteinformation onany singlevariable enteringtheempiricalmodel in any of

the 8 waves.This leaves us withasample of1987nativeGermans and732immigrants

starting in 1985.

Theidentificationapproach presentedinsection2.2relies on theinformation

con-tainedinpanelattrition. Itbecomesinstructiveto contrast theattrition pattern of our immigrantsample with thatofGermanswhose

attrition

cannotobviouslybeattributed

tooutmigration. Table2.1containsinformation onthenumberofindividualsobserved

along withthepercentage oftheoriginal1985samplewhoremains inagiven wave.11

41.9%ofGermans and 26.7%of immigrants havebeeninterviewedsuccessfully in all

the waves.Theattrition rate inagiven waveisdefined as the percentage ofindividuals not observed inthe given wavebutobserved in thepreceding wave. Over our

(34)

Section 2.4. Data 21

notan issue. Assuming thatthedifferencein attritionrates is due tooutmigration, a

back of the envelopecalculation implies thatwewouldexpect theoutmigration rate in

our sampleof immigrants to be6%every two years, or 3% per year,anumberwhich would be in line

with

thosereported intheliterature(seeBorjas andBratsberg, 1996).

Of course, thiscalculationrelies onthe assumptionthatattrition intheimmigrant pop-ulationwhich is not dueto outmigration is ofcomparablemagnitude to that

of

natives. We will come back to this

in

section2.5whichreportsindirectevidence suggesting that

thisshouldindeed hold

in

Germany.

The top panelof Figure2.1 shows theaverage monthly gross income for work-ing immigrants andGermans over the periodcovered. In 1985, the meanincome of

Germans was 3,357 DM permonthcompared to 2,690 DMpermonth for immigrants, givinganincomeratio of1.25favoringGermans. The mean wagedifferentialremaind

relativelysteadyuntil 1991, afterwhich, the meanincomedifferential widened even more between the twogroups toreach aratio of 1.34 in 1999,

with

Germans

receiv-inganaveragemonthly wage of 5,848DM while immigrantswere receiving 4,348 DM

per month. The divergingeconomic progressofGermans andimmigrantsafter 1991 is alsoreflected in theworkfrequencies. Thebottompanel of figure 2.1 shows the sample frequenciesofindividuals working inthemonthpreceding theinterview. We

can see that

until

1991, laborforceparticipation was very

similar for

both Germans

andimmigrants. After 1991, we observeasteady decline in the

work

frequencies for

bothgroups. During that period, the percentage of immigrants

working

remained

steadily below that ofGermans. The severe drop in

work

frequencies forbothgroups

coincides withthe generaldeterioration ofthelabormarket in the regionsof former

West-Germany. Table 2.3gives the unemployment rate per yearby state. With the

exceptionofBerlin,all provinces experiencedtheirlowestunemployment rate of the

1985-1999period in1991. After 1991,theunemployment ratehasprogressively risen

apart fromaslight fall in 1999 formost provinces.

If outmigration does occur ata systematic time inthe life-cycle, itislikely to

af-fect the age and years since immigration composition of oursample of immigrants.

Table2.2gives variable descriptionsand summary statistics

for

Germans and

immi-grants for the 1985 and1999waves. We see thatbothGermansandimmigrants are, on

average, a little less than40years of age in1985while the average age ofthecohort

(35)

22 Chapter2.Identification ofOutmigration

Germansandimmigrants leftthe panel. Foragiven meanage,Germans have acquired

relatively more yearsofeducation,but relatively lower labor marketexperience than

immigrants.Theaveragenumberofmonthsof labor marketexperienceof immigrants increased byalittle less than32months compared to70monthsforGermans,which is

consistent with the fact thattheproportion of working immigrants relativeto Germans

fell dramatically inthe 1990's.

Most immigrants migrated to Germany early in their productive lives, a fact

re-flected byan average age atimmigration

of

nearly24years,afigureconsistent through-out theobservation periodwhichindicates that mostmigrants wereoldenough to

au-tonomouslydecide to moveto Germany. Boththeevolutionofyearssinceimmigration and immigration yearareconsistent withthe hypothesis that outmigrationoccurs 20

years after migration (OECD, 2001). Theaverage yearof immigration of ourcohort is 1969 in the 1985 wave,butraises to 1979 in the 1999 wave,indicating thattheearlier cohorts are most susceptible to havedropped out ofthepanel. Astheearlier cohorts contain themigrants withthehigher number ofyears sincemigration in 1985, it is not surprising to seethataverageyears sinceimmigrationincreasesrelatively less than the

14 year timespan, passing from 15.75 in 1985 to 19.63 in 1999, indicatingagain that earlier cohortsare those who leftthe panel. Reported feelings onintegration in the

German society and reported speakingfluency improved over time whilehealth satis-factionseemstodeteriorate,thelatter

likely

capturinganagingeffect. Finally, 73% of

immigrantsreportedhavingaspouselivingoutside Gerrnany in1985whileaslittle as 1% still do so in 1999. This result canbeinterpreted in twoways. First, spouses may haveeventually migratedto Germanyduring the time period. Second,

it

might be that

immigrantswhosespousewas

living

abroad were more

likely

to outmigrate.

2.5 Results

and

simulations

Theregressorsincluded inthe earnings andworkequationsareeducation, labor

mar-ket experience,labor marketexperience squared, selfreportedGermanspeaking flu-ency, and the numberofyears sinceimmigrationto Germany. These arethestandard

variables thathave appeared in thisliterature(Borjas, 1999a). Theprovincial

unem-ployment rate in each waveisadded in bothequationsto capture local labor market conditions. Finally, we include time fixed effects in each wave to captureremaining

(36)

ex-Section2.5. Resultsandsimulations 23

clusionrestriction in the

work

equation. Reported health satisfaction isavalid exclu-Sion restriction

if

health problems occur mostly at a time in which an

individual is

more likely to have found astablejob whosecontinuation depends onthe worker's

choices. Theoutmigrationequation includesasregressorswhether or not the wife of

immigrantslivesinGermany,theimmigrantsself reported feelingsofbelonging to the Germans society and theunemploymentrate. Immigrant's who arrive atayoung age

presumably have the highest incentive to investin acquiring countryspecific human capital. This effectiscapturedbyincluding age atarrival

in

Germany.

Immigrants investing in their native countrypresumably havedifferentincentives

to stay in thehost country. The motives oftheseinvestments

will

affecttheir dura-tion ofstay. Immigrantsmay extendtheir stay in thehostcountry

in

ordertofurther

increase theirinvestments in their nativecountry. On the other hand,

if

immigrants

investin starting upabusiness they wish tomanage-asproposedby Dustmann and Kirchkamp (2002), high levels of investments willbeassociated

with

shorter

migra-tion duramigra-tions. Todisentanglebothhypothesis,we include intheoutmigration equa-tionthecumulativeamountofmoneyreturned tothenative countrysince 1984 as a proxy forinvestments. Reported health satisfaction and self-reported expected length

of stayinGermany arealsoincluded, thelater captures anticipatory behavior of

mi-grants,which havebeenshown to affect the acquisitionofcountry specific skills (e.g. Dustmann, 2002b). Time dummies areadded to capture remainingmacroeconomic fluctuations.

In ordertoseparate theimpact ofselection onearnings into a workand

outmigra-tion effect, we firstestimatedan earningsequation

with

randomeffects. Oursecond

specification is abivariatemodelof labormarket earnings and work. We finally es-timated the completemodelor earnings, workandoutmigration. In the latter case,

we experimented withanalternativespecification of theoutmigrationequationwhich contained education,labor market experience and its square, speaking fluency, and

years sinceimmigrationasregressors. A log-likelihoodratio test of the

null

hypothesis

thatthesehumancapital variables have nojointeffectonoutmigration could not be

(37)

24 Chapter2. Identification ofOutmigration

2.5.1

Equation

results

Covariancestructure

We beginour analysis of theresults with a discussion ofthe estimates

characteriz-ingthecovariance structure ofthe unobserved componentswhichareinformative of

theselection mechanisms. Table 2.4presents estimates of the covariance structure. Focusing on the most generalmodelwhich controls for both work and outmigration selection, we findasmallbut significant positive correlationbetween theunobserved

individualheterogeneity of work and earnings(pY.2),indicatingthatindividuals with higher probabilities ofworking are also morelikely tohavehigherearnings. The

cor-relationbetween

individual

time invariantheterogeneityof outmigration and earn-ings (p ,1 is\ W/ -56%while that between outmigration and work <p24 3) is 49.8%, both

.1

significant at the 1% level. Bothcorrelations suggest that individuals with a higher

propensitytooutmigratearethose with bothalower probability of finding work, and alower labor marketearnings,which pointsto negativeoutmigrationselection. When

comparing results withthebivariate model which does not correct

for

outmigration, we find thattheestimatedvalue ofP ,2remainsstable.ResultsforGermansaresimilar to that oftheimmigrant sample, withasmallbut positiveandsignificant

work

selec-tion effect

(ph)

Finally, transitoryshocksbetweenearnings and work,and shocks between workandoutmigration, areall significantly negativelycorrelated,theformer

at -34.2% and thelatter at30.4%while we do not find significantcorrelation between thetransitoryshocks of the earnings andoutmigrationprocesses.

Outmigration

Table 2.5presents theparameter estimates of theoutmigration equation. We find that

immigrantswhosewife lives with them

in

Germany haveasignificantly lower

prob-ability

of outmigrating,reflectingapreferencefor family unity. Immigrantssatisfied

with

theirhealthare significantlyless

likely

tooutmigrate, a finding consistent with

the sociologicalfindingsreportedinStark(1998).Intended length ofstay captures the expectations ofimmigrantsand offersdirectinformation on their remigration inten-tions.Not surprisingly, we findthatmigrants whoexpect to remain longer

in

Germany are alsolesslikelytooutmigrate. Deteriorations ofthelocal labor marketconditions, reflected

in

higherunemploymentrates, haveapositiveandsignificanteffect on the

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

Chapter 2 estimates the long-run effects of informal childcare, provided by grandparents, and formal childcare, provided by kindergarten, on human capital outcomes in China.. To

To check the comparability between WEP and WEN after matching, we perform an equal mean test on the background variables used for matching. None of the variables differs

In the Disclosure treatment in addition to the message sent by the sender the receiver observes the payoffs to the sender for each option but not the payments to himself8. Thus,

Chapter 4 considers spatial autoregressive binary choice panel models with corre- lated random effects, where the latent dependent variables are spatially correlated and

Our results show that the method is sensitive to the choice of the vignette for cognition: DIF- adjusted self-assessments based on vignette c1 are more different from the

Social and Economic Interaction between Minority and Majority People: An Archetypal Model 21 holding per capita supply of labor constant, relatively larger minorities suffer

An extension of the current model to a more structural model in which potential wages in both sectors are modeled simultaneously with labour market state, could be used to

The elements of the (first) structural part on the right hand side of Equation (5) have an important interpretation: Given the validity of the model, they represent the true