• No results found

The  influence  of  member  countries’  mind-­‐set  on  European  Union  financial  regulation  changes  from  2007-­‐2012

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "The  influence  of  member  countries’  mind-­‐set  on  European  Union  financial  regulation  changes  from  2007-­‐2012"

Copied!
50
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

Tessa  de  Roo   Cornelis  Trooststraat  26-­‐3   1072  JG  Amsterdam   S1641697   t.de.roo.1@student.rug.nl   T:  06-­‐50446214   Supervisor:  R.L.  Holzhacker   11-­‐09-­‐2014      

The  influence  of  member  countries’  mind-­‐set  on  

European  Union  financial  regulation  changes  

(2)
(3)

Introduction  

The  economic  crisis  that  hit  the  world  in  2007  was  one  of  the  severest  in  recent   history.  Even  now  in  2014,  many  years  after  its  start,  we  are  still  dealing  with  the   aftermath   of   this   financial   catastrophe.   Politicians   and   scholars   alike   failed   to   predict  this  major  event  and  the  major  effect  it  has  had  on  national  markets  and   policies   and   on   cross-­‐border   institutions   and   cooperation.   The   countries   in   the   Eurozone  were  also  not  left  unaffected  by  the  financial  turmoil.  Housing  one  of  the   largest  financial  markets  in  the  world,  the  countries  of  the  Eurozone  took  a  heavy   hit.  Many  institutions,  which  were  previously  thought  to  be  “too  big  to  fail”,  had  to   be   nationalized   or   relied   heavily   on   state   support   for   their   survival.   Although   present  day  financial  institutions  seldom  are  active  in  only  one  European  country,   in  Europe  the  crisis  was  initially  dealt  with  on  a  national  level.  But  it  was  clear  that   to  truly  battle  such  a  large-­‐scale  event,  a  solution  had  to  be  found  at  the  EU  wide   level.    

(4)

financial  regulation  process  with  the  following  research  question:  To  what  extent   did  mind-­‐set  changes  in  the  Eurozone  countries  affect  the  EU  financial  regulation   process  between  2007  and  2012?  

In   this   thesis   we   define   mind-­‐set   as   the   way   European   countries   look   at   the   financial   regulatory   process:   their   attitude   towards   this   subject.   Interests   of   countries  do  not  only  influence  this  mind-­‐set,  but  also  by  ideas  states  have  about   regulations.  This  will  be  elaborated  on  in  the  theory  section.    

 

Social  and  scientific  significance    

We  do  not  aim  to  make  a  value  judgement  about  the  regulation  itself;  economists   have   already   conducted   much   research   into   this   topic.   For   International   Political   Economists   it   is   much   more   interesting   to   look   at   the   regulation   process.   What   effect  did  the  change  in  mind-­‐set  about  financial  regulation  had  on  the  process  of   regulation?  Existing  literature  into  this  process  has  mainly  centred  on  the  role  that   material   factors,   like   national   economic   interests,   have   played.   Most   IPE   scholar   have  made  use  of  theories  that  adhere  to  Rationalism,  therefore  ignoring  the  social   aspect   of   International   Relations.   Research   that   has   taken   into   account   the   more   social  side  of  IR  has  mainly  examined  the  shared  ideas  of  different  coalitions  that   exist  in  the  European  Union.    

(5)

 

Methodology  

To  answer  the  main  research  question  we  will  use  three  sub-­‐questions  to  assist  us:    

1. In  what  way  did  financial  regulation  in  the  European  Union  change   between  2007  and  2012  and  how  did  this  change  come  to  be?  

2. What   different   mind-­‐sets   are   present   in   the   countries   of   the   Eurozone?  

3. What  role  did  the  mind-­‐sets  play  in  the  policy  process?    

To   answer   the   first   sub-­‐question   we   will   discuss   the   policy   process   before   the   crisis   by   examining   the   dominant   mind-­‐set   and   the   evolution   of   financial   policy   within   the   EU   between   2007   and   2012.   To   determine   which   mind-­‐sets   were   presents   during   these   years   we   will   compare   three   countries   of   the   Eurozone   in   three   case   studies.   The   countries   we   have   chosen   for   this   comparison   are   the   Netherlands,   Germany   and   Spain.     These   three   were   chosen   because   they   each   represent   a   different   regulatory   system;   they   have   different   frameworks   of   supervision  for  example.  Furthermore  they  are  different  sized  countries  (Germany   being   one   of   the   largest   en   Netherlands   one   of   the   smallest   countries   in   the   EU)   and   hold   different   power   positions   within   the   EU.   The   Netherlands   is   one   of   the   oldest  members,  as  is  Germany  and  this  country  is  also  a  big  and  powerful  player.   Spain  on  the  other  hand  joined  the  Union  at  a  later  time  and  for  long  time  was  a  net   beneficiary.   These   three   countries   were   choses   because   they   represent   a   cross   section   of   the   European   Union.   After   we   have   determined   which   mind-­‐sets   were   present   during   the   period   examined,   we   will   draw   a   conclusion   on   the   influence   these  mind-­‐sets  had  on  the  regulations  process.    

 

Theoretical  framework  

(6)

elaborate   on   how   the   theory   is   going   to   be   applied.   In   short,   this   next   part   will   establish  the  framework  on  which  the  analysis  will  be  build.  

Through   the   years   scholars   have   developed   many   different   theories   for   explaining  the  European  financial  integration  process.  We  will  discuss  some  of  the   main  approaches  to  illustrate  the  academic  debate  on  this  topic.  Héritier  sees  the   policy  process  that  creates  regulation  as  a  competition  between  the  most  powerful   and   most   regulated   states.   These   states   have   very   diverse   economic   interest   and   they   seek   to   enhance   their   competitive   position.   In   other   words,   they   seek   to   maximize  their  benefits,  because  European  regulation  that  is  similar  to  their  own   not  only  cuts  down  on  costs  but  also  gives  them  an  advantage.  Therefore  the  policy   process   is   a   patchwork   of   these   diverse   national   interests   and   regulatory   traditions.  Story  and  Walter  took  a  similar  approach.  These  scholars  saw  financial   integration  in  the  EU  as  a  “battle  of  the  systems”  where  states  want  to  set  rules  in   line  with  their  domestic  regulatory  approach.  These  approaches  thus  see  the  state   as  a  unified  actor  that  always  seeks  to  maximize  its  benefits  and  use  that  viewpoint   of  explaining  integration.1  

Another   approach   that   has   attempted   to   explain   the   European   financial   policy   making   process   is   institutionalism.   Institutionalism   sees   the   creation   of   institutions   as   a   way   for   states   to   minimize   their   transaction   costs   and   increase   information   flows   and   monitoring.   Thus   by   joining   in   an   institution   states   maximize   their   benefits.   Blyth   examines   two   main   variations   of   this   theory:   rational   and   historical   institutionalism.   These   represent   the   ideational   turn   in   International   Political   Economy.   Unfortunately   this   turn   did   not   represent   a   real   extension  of  the  existing  research  programs.  Instead  the  addition  of  ideas  was  used   to   solve   theoretical   problems   and   thus   ideas   were   a   secondary   method   of   explanation   in   existing   theories.   Neither   rational   nor   historical   institutionalism   attempted  to  explain  ideas  independently  and  they  do  not  see  ideas  as  determining   the  outcome  of  a  policy  process.2  

                                                                                                               

1  Adrienne  Héritier,  ‘The  accommodation  of  diversity  in  European  policy-­‐making  and  its  outcomes:  

regulatory  policy  as  a  patchwork’  Journal  of  European  Public  Policy  3  (1996)  149-­‐167,  aldaar   150,164;  Lucia  Quaglia,  ‘Completing  the  Single  Market  in  financial  services:  the  politics  of   competing  advocacy  coalitions  European  Union  Studies  Association  (EUSA)  conference  2009  5.  

2  Mark  M.  Blyth,  ‘Any  more  bright  ideas?  The  ideational  turn  of  comparative  political  economy’  

(7)

These   approaches   all   come   from   a   main   paradigm   within   IR:   rationalism.   Traditional  rationalist  theory  considers  the  world  to  be  predominantly  material  in   nature.   This   material   worldview   entails   that   political   actions   of   actors   are   not   influenced   by   the   way   they   see   the   world.   The   resources   they   hold   and   their   relative  position  in  comparison  to  other  actors  determine  how  actors  behave  in  the   international   playing   field.   Therefore   rationalists   see   the   world   to   be   very   predictable   and   full   of   calculable   risks   and   certainties.   Because,   when   economic   actors  have  determined  their  position  and  what  is  best  for  them,  thus  where  their   interests  lie,  they  will  always  act  according  to  these  preferences  and  make  rational   choices   based   on   these   calculations.     IPE   scholarship   has   come   to   a   comfortable   status  quo  regarding  this  subject  and  has  focused  too  much  on  rationalist  theories,   developing   a   blind   spot   for   alternatives.   But   only   looking   at   the   materialistic   aspects   leaves   many,   mostly   empirical,   questions   unanswered.   Governments   and   actors   have   surprised   traditional   IPE   scholars   by   acting   contra   to   rational   expectations.  Different  actors  can  act  very  differently  in  similar  situations,  because   of  the  way  they  interpret  the  world  around  them.3  

  An  optic  that  opposes  this  rationalistic  worldview  is  Constructivism.    This   optic  contradicts  that  social  processes  do  not  affect  actors  in  the  international  field.   The  core  of  Constructivism  is  that  the  economic  world  is  shaped  by  ideas  that  are   collectively   held   by   actors.   The   way   in   which   governments   or   economic   actors   interpret   the   world   around   them   is   not   similar   in   all   cases.   All   varieties   in   what   objects  mean  to  agents,  how  they  see  the  complex  and  interdependent  world  they   act   in   and   analyse   it   matter   too   much   to   just   ignore,   as   rational   theories   do.   According  to  Constructivism,  government  officials  and  economic  actors  in  society   rarely   interpret   the   world   around   them   purely   in   material   terms.   How   they   interpret  all  processes  and  cope  with  interdependence  in  the  international  arena  is   reflected  in  their  societal  identities.  That  is  why  different  actors  are  able  to  act  very   differently  than  is  to  be  expected  according  to  rational  theories  and  interest.4  

                                                                                                               

3  Rawi  Albadel,  Mark  Blyth,  Craig  Parsons,  Constructing  the  International  Economy  (Ithaca;  2010)  1-­‐

3;  Peter  J.  Katzenstein,  Stephen  C.  Nelson,  ‘Reading  the  right  signals  and  reading  the  signals  right:   IPE  and  the  financial  crisis  of  2008’  Review  of  International  Political  Economy  20  (2013)  1101-­‐1131,   aldaar  1102-­‐1107;  Barry  Axford,  Gary  K.  Braining,  Richard  Huggings  e.a.  Politics.  An  Introduction   (New  York;2006)  492.  

(8)

   As   it   comes   to   International   Political   Economy   scholarship,   neither   Rationalists  nor  Constructivists  have  succeeded  in  predicting  the  crisis.  And  while   they  both  sides  provide  useful  theories  and  approaches  for  looking  at  the  economic   playing  field,  it  would  be  a  mistake  to  conclude  that  one  of  them  has  discovered  the   only  right  way  of  looking  at  the  world.  Albadel,  Blyth  and  Parsons  argue  that:    

“Forgetting   the   aspect   of   how   discourses   and   identities   both   empower  and    disempower   agents   leads   to   a   materialist   reductionism  that  can  only  narrow  what  we  know  about  the  world.   Taking   constructivism   seriously   as   a   mode   of   explanation   in   political   economy   illuminates   much   more   than   it   obscures.   It   broadens  our  vision  and  our  ambition,  precisely  at  a  time  when  we   need  both,  inside  and  outside  the  academy.5  

 

Thus  Constructivism  should  not  be  regarded  as  an  alternative  for  Rationalism  or  as   a  handy  addition  to  complete  material  processes.  Neither  theory  gives  the  breath   and  depth  that  is  necessary  to  analyse  the  complex  modern  day  financial  world.6  

Helleiner  and  Pagliari  7  argue  that  in  post  crisis  research  scholars  have  focused  too  

much   on   explaining   the   strengthening   of   official   international   standards.   In   their   research  they  focus  on  the  weakening  of  these  standards  and  of  fragmentation  and   decentralization.   Katzenstein   and   Nelson  8  argue   in   favour   of   social   optics   to  

explain   why   the   materialist   school   of   IPE   has   failed   so   badly   in   predicting   and   explaining   the   crisis.   According   to   the   authors,   such   a   view   brings   the   depth   of   vision   necessary   to   explain   the   complex   event.   And   finally,   Marsh9  warns   against  

the  rejection  of  the  importance  of  materialist  factors  in  explaining  post  crisis  event.  

                                                                                                               

5  Rawi  Albadel,  Mark  Blyth,  Craig  Parsons,  ‘Re-­‐constructing  IPE.  Some  Conclusions  Drawn  from  a  

Crisis”  in:  Constructing  the  International  Economy,    Rawi  Albadel,  Mark  Blyth,  Craig  Parsons  ed.   (Ithaca;  2010)  227-­‐239,  aldaar  238.  

6  Rawi  Albadel,  Mark  Blyth,  Craig  Parsons,  ‘Re-­‐constructing  IPE.  Some  Conclusions  Drawn  from  a  

Crisis”  in:  Constructing  the  International  Economy,    Rawi  Albadel,  Mark  Blyth,  Craig  Parsons  ed.   (Ithaca;  2010)  227-­‐239,  aldaar  231-­‐232;  Peter  J.  Katzenstein,  Stephen  C.  Nelson,  ‘Reading  the  right   signals  and  reading  the  signals  right:  IPE  and  the  financial  crisis  of  2008’  Review  of  International  

Political  Economy  20  (2013)  1101-­‐1131,  aldaar  1109,  1120.  

7  Eric  Helleiner,  Stefano  Pagliari,  ‘The  End  of  an  Era  in  International  Financial  Regulation?  A  Post  

Crisis  Research  Agenda’  International  Organization  65  (2011)  169-­‐200.  

8  Peter  J.  Katzenstein,  Stephen  C.  Nelson,  ‘Reading  the  right  signals  and  reading  the  signals  right:  

IPE  and  the  financial  crisis  of  2008’  Review  of  International  Political  Economy  20  (2013)  1101-­‐1131.  

9  David  Marsh,  ‘Keeping  Ideas  in  their  Place:  In  Praise  of  Thin  Constructivism’  Australian  Journal  of  

(9)

According  to  the  author,  it  is  the  relationship  between  material  and  social  factors   that  is  important  and  should  be  considered  when  examining  events.10  

  The  debate  between  Rationalists  and  Constructivists  is  marked  as  one  of  the   great  debates  in  International  Relations  theory.  This  debate  is  mainly  centred  on   ontology;  they  reflect  different  assumptions  about  the  world.  The  interesting  factor   about  Constructivism  is  that  it  takes  the  middle  ground  between  Rationalism  and   Critical   Theory.   Constructivism   does   not   deny   the   importance   of   interest,   but   it   denies   that   interests   are   fixed   and   can   be   taken   for   granted.   The   debate   thus   is   centred   about   the   role   of   ideas   and   institutions   in   determining   interests.   Rationalists   deny   this   role   and,   as   mentioned   earlier,   see   interests   as   remaining   similar  when  once  they  are  established.  Constructivists  try  to  explain  how  interests   are  constructed  in  the  context  of  interstate  interaction.  11  

Drawing  on  this  previous  research  and  the  debate  within  IR,  we  want  to  use   a   method   that   combines   two   major   paradigms   in   International   Relations   theory.   We  want  to  focus  on  the  combination  of  ideas  and  interests.  How  do  they  influence   one  another?  What  is  the  importance  of  ideas  in  formulating  interests?  What  role   do  both  play  in  constructing  mind-­‐set?  Therefore  we  will,  in  our  theory,  draw  on   an  approach  by  Quaglia.12  She  argues  the  mind-­‐set  of  countries  towards  financial  

regulation  is  shaped  by  three  criteria  that  are  a  combination  of  ideas  and  interest,   and  thus  of  Rationalism  and  Constructivism.  These  three  criteria  are:  

 

I. National  regulatory  framework  

II. Configuration  of  national  financial  systems  and  their  competiveness     III. Belief  system  about  financial  regulation  

 

In  this  thesis  we  understand  national  regulatory  framework  to  be  the  set  of  rules   that   exist   in   a   country.   Configuration   of   national   financial   systems   and   their                                                                                                                  

10  David  Mars,  ‘Keeping  Ideas  in  their  Place:  In  Praise  of  Thin  Constructivism’  Australian  Journal  of  

Political  Science  44  (2009)  679-­‐696,  aldaar  682-­‐684.    

11  Barry  Axford,  Gary  K.  Braining,  Richard  Huggings  e.a.  Politics.  An  Introduction  (New  York;  2006)  

492;  Jill  Steans,  Lloyd  Pettiford,  Introduction  to  International  Relations.  Perspectives  &  Themes   (Essex;  2005)  182-­‐187.  

12  Lucia  Quaglia,  ‘Completing  the  Single  Market  in  financial  services:  the  politics  of  competing  

(10)

competiveness   is   defined   as   the   economic   situation   in   a   country   at   the   time   and   belief  system  is  the  set  of  ideas  that  are  dominant

.  

The  relationship  between  mind-­‐ set  and  these  three  criteria  is  that  they  make  up  the  set  of  attitudes  that  is  mind-­‐set   in   the   European   Unions   between   2007-­‐2012.   These   three   criteria   is   what   we   believe  in  this  thesis  mind-­‐set  consists  of.  Two  of  the  criteria  are  Rationalist  and   one  is  Constructivist.    This  relationship  is  schematically  provided  in  Figure  1.      

 

Figure  1:  Theoretical  framework  

 

To  operationalize  this  theory  we  have  derived  four  factors  from  the  three  criteria   that  we  are  going  to  use  to  compare  the  three  case  studies.  These  four  factors  are:  

 

a. National  regulatory  tradition  

b. Effect   of   the   crisis   on   the   economy   of   the   country   (state   of   the   national   economy)  

c. Political  mood  

d. Believe  system  about  EU  financial  integration    

(11)

influence   on   the   regulatory   and   financial   integration   process.   What   differs   this   approach   from   existing   theories   on   EU   financial   integration   is   that   ideas   are   examined   as   an   individual   factor   that   can   influence   interests.   Therefore   we   will   focus  on  the  interplay  between  the  two  in  the  following  analysis  section.    

Analysis  

We  will  start  the  analysis  by  examining  the  regulation  process.  To  fully  understand   the  changes  that  were  made  during  the  2007-­‐2012  period  we  will  start  by  giving  a   short   overview   of   the   history   of   European   financial   regulation.   This   will   help   establish  the  framework  as  it  was  before  2007.  After  that  a  short  background  of  the   financial  crisis  and  why  existing  regulation  was  not  sufficient  to  prevent  it  will  be   given.   Finally   the   regulation   process   and   changes   in   the   period   central   to   this   thesis  will  be  discussed.  Key  element  in  this  discussion  will  be  the  combination  of   Rationalist  and  Constructivist  elements.  

As  it  comes  to  supervision  and  financial  regulation  in  general,  in  1977  the   European   Community   established   the   First   Banking   Directive.   This   early   policy   paper   laid   down   important   ground   rules   for   the   financial   sector   that   have   dominated   European   financial   regulation   up   until   the   crisis   in   2007.   The   most   important   of   the   principles   provided   by   the   directive   is   the   principle   of   home   country  control.  This  means  that  if  a  financial  corporation  has  branches  in  two  or   more   countries,   the   duty   of   supervising   this   institution   lies   with   the   country   in   which   it   is   headquartered.   Supervision   of   banks   was   thus   not   organized   on   a   supranational  level,  but  on  a  national  level.  The  directive  did  however  obligate  the   different  national  supervisors  to  cooperate.  13    

  Almost  two  decades  after  the  First  Banking  Directive  the  regulatory  process   in  the  European  Union  led  to  its  final  destination;  the  single  banking  market  that   came  into  effect  as  from  1st  of  January  1993.  With  the  implementation  of  the  single  

market,  the  ground  rules  did  not  change.  Supervision  was  still  the  responsibility  of   the   member   states,   not   of   the   European   Central   Bank.   When   it   came   to   financial   regulation,   the   integration   process   in   the   EU   could   be   characterized   by   minimal   interference.   The   European   Commission   set   minimal   standards   by   issuing   directives,  which  the  member  states  then  had  to  implement  into  national  law.  This                                                                                                                  

13  Gillian  G.H.  Garcia,  Maria  J.  Nieto,  ‘Banking  crisis  management  in  the  European  Union:  Multiple  

(12)

caused  some  significant  differences  in  ways  of  supervising  banks.  The  Commission   did   however   state   that   there   had   to   be   mutual   recognition   among   the   member   states  of  each  other’s  agreements  and  control  systems.  This  measure  had  to  ensure   the  quality  of  supervision  throughout  the  Union.14  

  In   2001   a   committee   of   wise   men   under   the   chair   of   Lamfalussy   issued   a   report  with  a  new  approach  to  the  development  of  financial  regulation  in  the  EU.   One   of   the   measures   that   was   taken   after   this   report   was   the   creation   of   the   Committee  of  European  Banking  Supervisors  (CEBS)  in  2004.  This  committee  was   composed   of   senior   representatives   of   bank   supervisory   authorities   and   central   banks  of  the  European  Union  and  found  legal  basis  in  decision  2004/15/EC  of  the   Commission.   The   duties   of   CEBS   were   to   enhance   cooperation   between   member   states  in  the  field  of  supervision  and  to  provide  a  platform  for  information  to  be   exchanged.   Furthermore   the   committee   had   to   contribute   tot   the   consistent   application   of   the   Commissions’   directives   and   play   an   advisory   role   in   the   decision-­‐making  of  the  Commission.15  

  The  Lamfalussy  process  was  especially  important  and  well  know  as  the  key   factor   in   the   rulemaking   process   for   the   financial   sector   in   the   European   Union.   The  policy  process  has  four  different  levels:  

 

Level   1:   This   level   starts   at   the   European   Commission,   which   has   an   important   function   by   identifying   the   need   for   new   regulations.   The   Commission   holds   the   sole  right  to  initiate  the  financial  rule  making  process.  

Level   2:   This   level   is   the   implementation   of   directives   into   national   law   or   the   execution  of  new  EU  regulations.  

Level  3:  At  level  three  the  supervisory  organs  advise  the  EC  about  the  applicability   of  the  rules  in  practice  

Level   4:   To   close   the   circle,   at   this   level   the   Commission   checks   on   the   implementation  and  execution  of  regulation.16  

 

                                                                                                               

14  Gillian  G.H.  Garcia,  Maria  J.  Nieto,  ‘Banking  crisis  management  in  the  European  Union:  Multiple  

regulators  and  resolution  authorities’  Journal  of  Banking  Regulation  (2005)  5;  Reinoud  Rini,  La  

responsabilité  des  autorités  de  surveillance  bancaire  en  Europe  (Lausanne;  2007)  93-­‐94.  

15  EC  Decision  2004/15/EC  

(13)

  Another   important   instrument   on   the   field   of   international   financial   regulation   is   the   Basil   Committee   on   Banking   Supervision   (BCBS).   This   is   a   worldwide   organ   where   supervisory   organs   from   all   over   the   world   unite.   The   BCBC   was   created   in   1974   to   better   the   quality   of   supervision   by   international   cooperation,   by   sharing   information   and   by   setting   minimum   standards.   The   committee   is   most   known   for   the   Basel   I   and   Basel   II   agreements.   These   are   guidelines  for  capital  requirements  for  banks.  Slightly  less  known,  but  certainly  not   less   important   are   the   Basel   Core   Principles   for   the   efficient   and   effective   supervision   of   banks.   When   it   comes   to   the   criteria   of   capital   requirements,   all   member  states  of  the  EU  use  the  Basel  agreements  as  minimum  standards.17  

  The   situation   within   the   EU   before   the   crisis   of   2007   can   be   best   characterized   as   not   transparent.   There   were   minimum   standards   in   some   important  fields,  but  when  it  came  to  regulation  and  supervision  many  differences   existed  within  the  member  states.  There  was  no  central  European  organ  that  could   adequately  reply  in  case  of  a  crisis  situation.18  When  we  look  at  the  social  identity  

of  Europe  as  a  whole,  it  is  divided  into  two  opposing  coalitions.  These  two  groups   of  countries  have  different  belief  systems  about  financial  regulation  on  a  European   scale   and   the   transference   of   powers   to   the   EU.   We   identify   a   Southern   and   a   Northern   coalition.   The   Northern   one   is   formed   by   the   United   Kingdom,   the   Netherlands   and   the   Scandinavian   countries   and   can   also   be   referred   to   as   the   market-­‐making   coalition.   The   Southern   group   composes   of   France,   Belgium   and   the  Mediterranean  countries  and  is  also  referred  to  as  the  market-­‐shaping  one  of   the   two   coalitions.19  The   market-­‐making   coalition   advocates   principle-­‐based  

regulation   that   is   light-­‐touched   and   competition   friendly.   The   countries   in   this   coalition  are  pro  liberalisation  of  the  market  and  endorse  competition  and  market   efficiency.  They  believed  in  market  governance  and  consultation  of  the  industry  in                                                                                                                  

17  In  het  spoor  van  de  crisis  De  Nederlandsche  Bank  (Amsterdam;2010)  99-­‐101;  Jean  Pisani-­‐Ferry,  

Andre  Sapir,  ‘Banking  Crisis  Management  in  the  EU;  an  early  Assesment’  Economic  Policy  2010  341-­‐ 373  aldaar  348.  

18  Gillian  G.H.  Garcia,  Maria  J.  Nieto,  ‘Banking  crisis  management  in  the  European  Union:  Multiple  

regulators  and  resolution  authorities’  Journal  of  Banking  Regulation  (2005)  6;  David  Green,  ‘The   Relationship  between  Micro-­‐Macro-­‐Prudential  Supervision  and  Central  Banking’  Financial  

Regulation  and  Supervision.  A  Post-­‐Crisis  Analysis,  Eddy  Wymeersch,  Klaus  J.  Hopt,  Guido  Ferrarini  

ed.  (Oxford;  2012)  59-­‐61.  

19  Lucia  Quaglia,  ‘Completing  the  Single  Market  in  financial  services:  the  politics  of  competing  

(14)

rule   making.   The   Southern,   market-­‐shaping   coalition   believed   in   consumer   protection   through   rule-­‐based   strict   regulation.   Financial   stability   is   key   and   the   public   authorities   are   at   the   steering   wheel,   far   from   involvement   of   the   institutions  on  the  market.  Germany  has  traditionally  switched  sides  between  this   coalitions,  being  somewhere  in  the  middle  ground.20    

Before  the  crisis  the  dominant  mind-­‐set  shaping  financial  regulation  in  the   European   Union   can   be   best   described   as   in   favour   of   letting   the   market   run   its   course   and   having   as   little   regulation   as   possible.   It   was   clear   that   the   market-­‐ making   coalition   was   clearly   winning.   A   clear   sign   of   this   success   was   the   completion  of  the  single  market  and  the  rules  adopted  prior  to  the  financial  crisis,   such   as   minimal   standards.   This   caused   there   to   be   a   lot   of   differences   between   countries  in  financial  regulation  and  supervision.  Therefore,  although  the  countries   of  the  Eurozone  were  interconnected  in  many  ways,  the  regulatory  framework  was   still  incomplete  in  many  ways.  There  are  two  important  reasons  why  the  coalition   of   mostly   Northern   states   was   most   successful   before   2007.   These   reasons,   the   evolution   of   the   policy   environment   and   a   process   of   learning,   were   interconnected.   During   the   start   of   the   2000s   the   single   European   currency   was   introduced,   realigning   economic   interests   of   the   EU   countries   and   giving   more   power  to  the  Northern  coalition.  Furthermore  this  increased  financial  integration   and  caused  there  to  be  increased  competition  between  the  Euro  countries  and  the   United  States.  As  completing  the  single  market  now  was  a  priority,  a  competition   friendly   approached   seemed   the   way   forward,   as   such   there   was   a   learning   process.  21    

If   we   examine   the   situation   before   the   crisis   it   is   clear   that   a   further   integration  of  financial  regulation  was  in  the  best  interest  of  the  countries  in  the   Eurozone.  Because  of  the  introduction  of  the  Euro  in  2002  the  economic  interests   of  the  states  realigned.  Further  integration  would  lower  costs  and  create  a  stronger                                                                                                                  

20  Lucia  Quaglia,  ‘Completing  the  Single  Market  in  financial  services:  the  politics  of  competing  

advocacy  coaltions’  European  Union  Studies  Association  (EUSA)  conference  2009  4.  

21  Lucia  Quaglia,  ‘The  “Old”  and  “New”  Politics  of  Financial  Service  Regulation  in  the  EU’  

Observatoire  Social  Europeen  research  paper  2(2010)  7;  Elliot  Posner,  Nicolas  Véron,  “The  EU  and  

financial  regulation:  power  without  purpose?”  Journal  of  European  Public  Policy  17  (2010)  400-­‐415,   aldaar  401,  410;  Hans-­‐Jurgen  Bieling,  “Social  Forces  in  the  Making  of  the  new  European  Economy:   The  Case  of  Financial  Market  Integration”  New  Politcal  Economy  8  (2003)  203-­‐224,  aldaar  206-­‐216;   Geoffrey  R  D  Underhill,  ‘The  political  economy  of  (eventual)  banking  union’  in:  Banking  Union  for  

(15)

bloc   in   the   battle   against   other   large   financial   markets.   It   seems   therefore   that   interests   were   an   important   motivation   for   creating   the   single   market.   In   the   creation   of   this   market   ideas   are   not   to   be   overlooked   however.   As   described   before,   the   type   of   regulation   choses   was   a   clear   win   of   the   states   in   favour   of   a   market-­‐making   approach.   The   rules   created   were   light-­‐touched   and   left   many   important   elements   (like   supervision   of   institutions)   at   the   mercy   of   individual   countries.  Of  course  one  could  argue  that  these  less  strict  measures  were  also  in   the  best  interest  of  these  countries.    With  favourable  conditions  states  could  lure   large  international  financial  firms  to  their  markets.  The  situation  that  was  created   in   Europe   before   2007   was   therefore   a   consequence   of   interplay   between   ideas   and  interests.    

    The  financial  crisis    

Everything   changed   in   2007.   The   world   now   finds   itself   in   the   biggest   financial   crisis   up-­‐to-­‐date.   The   European   Union   did   not   manage   to   prepare   for   this   crisis.   This  was  largely  due  to  a  failing  supervision.  Many  scholars  and  institutions  have   since  examined  why  supervision  failed.  To  understand  the  regulation  process  that   followed  and  to  support  the  following  case  study  section,  we  will  have  to  shortly   pay  attention  to  these  studies.  This  section  will  therefore  give  an  overview  of  the   most  important  reasons  mentioned  for  this  failure.    

(16)

explain   that   the   entire   concept   of   regulation   and   supervision   that   was   used   was   out-­‐dated.  With  the  fast  moving  and  changing  capital  market,  just  setting  standards   was   not   sufficient   anymore.   There   was   a   lack   of   a   pro-­‐active   approach   that   included  on-­‐sight  monitoring  of  financial  institutions.22  

  The  pressure  that  supervising  institutions  felt  from  policy  makers  and  the   market  as  a  whole  is  another  reason  Palmer  and  Cerutti  present  for  their  failure.   This   had   a   direct   connection   with   the   mind-­‐set   at   the   foundation   that   was   mentioned  before.  It  was  believed  that  it  was  not  the  supervisors’  task  to  intervene   in  the  overall  business  strategies  of  banks.  The  principles  of  deregulation  and  free-­‐ market   were   very   important   before   the   crisis   and   governments   often   wanted   to   stimulate   the   financial   sector   in   their   country.   This   led   to   pressures   to   make   the   business  climate  more  hospitable  to  compete  with  other  member  countries  of  the   EU.   As   a   consequence   the   authors   state   that   supervisory   institutions   were   often   competing  to  make  regulations  as  favourable  as  possible,  to  attract  financial  firms.   This  put  the  supervisors  in  a  strange  position.  Private  actors  had  enormous  power   and   influence   and   could   force   policy   changes,   for   example   reducing   capital   requirements.   This   resulted   in   substantial   weakening   of   prudential   rules   and   of   supervisory   quality.   Often   supervisory   institutions   did   not   have   a   strong   enough   legal  basis  to  be  fully  independent  or  have  independent  and  strong  leadership.  This   made  the  institutions  a  target  of  the  pressure  of  politicians.  As  a  final  argument  the   authors   state   that   there   was   often   suboptimal   cooperation   among   supervisors.   This   was   especially   the   case   with   large   financial   actors   that   operated   in   many   different   countries.   The   individual   supervisory   organs   often   did   not   see   the   consequences  their  actions  had  for  the  system  as  a  whole.23  

  In   the   paper   ‘The   Making   of   Good   Supervision:   Learning   to   Say   “No”’   Jose   Vinals  and  Jonathan  Fiechter  contribute  to  the  debate  a  few  more  reasons  for  the   supervisory  failure.  The  authors  first  make  an  argument  that  is  in  line  with  Palmer   and  Cerutti’s  argument  that  supervisory  institutions  were  not  pro-­‐active  enough.   According  to  Vinals  and  Fiechter  they  stayed  too  much  on  the  side-­‐lines  and  had  a   misplaced  confidence  in  the  market  to  lead  itself.  Institutions  did  not  sufficiently                                                                                                                  

22  John  Palmer,  Caroline  Cerutti,  ‘Is  there  a  need  to  rethink  the  supervisory  process?’  Reforming  

Financial  Regulation  and  Supervision:  Going  back  to  Basics,  World  Bank,  15  June  2009,  1,  15-­‐17.  

23  John  Palmer,  Caroline  Cerutti,  ‘Is  there  a  need  to  rethink  the  supervisory  process?’  Reforming  

(17)

react   to   the   changing   financial   environment   and   it   becoming   more   international   and  complicated.  They  did  not  look  far  enough  into  the  future  in  some  cases  and   did  not  fully  understand  risks  that  were  taken  and  what  the  consequences  would   be.24  Furthermore   the   authors   argue   that   the   supervisors   did   not   look   at   the  

system  as  a  whole.  They  concentrated  on  the  institutions  under  their  control,  but   did   not   look   at   other   parts   of   the   system.   They   did   not   see   the   influence   their   decisions   had   and   vice   versa   did   not   recognize   the   impact   of   other   parts   of   the   system   on   their   situation.   When   the   situation   became   critical,   the   supervising   institutions  did  not  take  action  quick  enough  to  prevent  things  from  getting  out  of   hand.25  

  The  causes  of  the  financial  crisis  are  an  interesting  combination  of  interests   and   ideas.   As   mentioned   in   the   starting   section   of   the   analysis,   the   regulatory   system  before  2007  was  a  win  of  the  ideas  of  free  market  rule.  However,  this  also   coincided  with  the  interests  of  the  countries  having  these  ideas.  They  wanted  less   stringent  rules  to  not  harm  their  financial  sector  and  attract  financial  firms,  thus   benefiting  them  economically.  Its  hard  to  define  exactly  what  was  the  main  driver   for  this  process;  the  ideas  of  the  interest.  They  seem  mutually  dependent,  affecting   each  other  and  creating  a,  in  hindsight,  very  dangerous  situation.  When  examining   the   causes   of   the   crisis   it   is   plain   to   see   that   some   risks   were   grossly   underestimated.   This   underestimation   came   from   a   set   of   ideas   (believing   in   the   market)  and  was  fed  by  economic  interests.    

 

After  the  crisis  

We   will   now   turn   to   the   situation   after   the   highpoint   of   the   crisis   to   see   if   the   crucial   mistakes   made   and   flaws   of   the   system   were   changed.   After   the   crisis   a   committee  of  wise  men  headed  by  former  head  of  the  International  Monetary  Fund   Jacques  de  Larosière  was  asked  by  the  European  Commission  to  write  a  report  on   the   financial   regulation   in   Europe.   This   report,   named   after   the   chairman   of   the   committee,  pointed  out  the  flaws  in  the  former  system  of  supervision  of  financial   institutions  in  the  EU  and  called  for  institutionalisation  of  the  supervisory  model.                                                                                                                  

24  Jose  Vinals,  Jonathan  Fiechter,  ‘The  Making  of  Good  Supervision:  Learning  to  Say  “No”’    IMF  Staff  

Position  Note  18  May  2010,  6-­‐7.  

(18)

To  achieve  such  an  institutionalisation,  the  report  recommended  several  reforms   of  the  structure  of  supervision  within  the  Union.26    

  Following   the   advice   given   by   De   Larosière   the   European   Council   in   2009   confirmed   that   a   new   supervisory   system   should   be   established.   The   aim   of   this   new   system   should   be   to   better   the   quality   of   and   ensure   uniformity   in   national   supervising  authorities,  to  create  a  single  rule  book  for  all  financial  institutions  on   the  European  market  and  to  strengthen  the  control  and  oversight  of  cross-­‐border   groups.    Another  important  aim  of  this  systemic  change  was  to  bring  back  stability   in  the  internal  market  and  regain  trust  for  the  establishment  of  a  fully  integrated   European  financial  services  market.  Realising  the  old  framework  had  reached  the   limits   of   its   capability   to   do   so,   the   institutions   of   the   new   European   System   of   Financial   Supervisors   (ESFS)   began   their   work   in   2011.   These   are   the   European   Systemic  Risk  Board  (ESRB)  and  three  European  Supervision  Authorities  (ESA’s):   the   European   Banking   Authority   (EBA),   the   European   Securities   and   Markets   Authority   (ESMA)   and   the   European   Insurance   and   Occupational   Pensions   Authority  (EIOPA).  These  ESA’s  were  created  because  of  the  “  shortcomings  in  the   area   of   cooperation,   coordination,   consistent   application   of   Union   Law   and   trust   between  national  supervisors”.27  

The   ESFS   should   bring   together   “the   actors   of   financial   supervision   at   national  level  and  at  the  level  of  the  Union,  to  act  as  a  network  (…)  the  parties  of   the   EFSF   should   cooperate   with   thrust   and   full   mutual   respect,   in   particular   to   ensure  that  appropriate  and  reliable  information  flows  between  them.”28  

 

In  this  thesis  we  will  focus  on  only  one  of  the  institutions  of  the  European  System   of  Financial  Supervisors:  the  European  Banking  Authority  (EBA).  This  organization                                                                                                                  

26  Gianni  Lo  Schiavo,  ‘The  European  Supervisory  Authorities:  A  True  Evolutionary  Step  Along  the  

Process  of  European  Financial  Integration?”  The  Interaction  of  National  Legal  Systems:  Convergence  

or  Divergence?  Conference  papers  Vilnius  2013,  293-­‐301  aldaar  296;  James  Buckley,  David  

Howarth,  “Internal  Market:  Gesture  Politics?  Explaining  the  EU’s  response  to  the  Financial  Crisis”  

Journal  of  Common  Market  Studies  48  (2010)  119-­‐141,  aldaar  124-­‐126.    

27  Gianni  Lo  Schiavo,  ‘The  European  Supervisory  Authorities:  A  True  Evolutionary  Step  Along  the  

Process  of  European  Financial  Integration?”  The  Interaction  of  National  Legal  Systems:  Convergence  

or  Divergence?  Conference  papers  Vilnius  2013,  293-­‐301  aldaar  294;  Regulation  1093/2010  EU,  24  

November  2010,  Official  Journal  of  the  European  Union  331/12;  James  Buckley,  David  Howarth,   “Internal  Market:  Gesture  Politics?  Explaining  the  EU’s  response  to  the  Financial  Crisis”  Journal  of  

Common  Market  Studies  48  (2010)  119-­‐141,  aldaar  124-­‐126.  

(19)

is  the  replacement  of  the  former  European  Committee  of  Banking  supervisors,  but   is  more  far  reaching  in  its  scope  of  actions.  The  impressive  list  of  the  broad  scope   of  tasks  of  the  Authority  was  laid  out  in  Regulation  No  1093/2010  EU:  

 

“I)  The  Authority  should  act  with  a  view  to  improving  the  functioning  of   the   internal   market,   in   particular   by   ensuring   a   high,   effective   and   consistent   level   of   regulation   and   supervision   taking   account   of   the   varying   interests   of   all   Member   States   and   the   different   nature   of   financial  institutions.  

 

II)  The  Authority  should  protect  public  values  such  as  the  stability  of  the   financial  system,  the  transparency  of  markets  and  financial  products,  and   the  protection  of  depositors  and  investors.  

 

III)   The   Authority   should   also   prevent   regulatory   arbitrage   and   guarantee  a  level  playing  field,  and  strengthen  international  supervisory   coordination,  for  the  benefit  of  the  economy  at  large,  including  financial   institutions  and  other  stakeholders,  consumers  and  employees.  Its  tasks   should   also   include   promoting   supervisory   convergence   and   providing   advice   to   the   Union   institutions   in   the   areas   of   banking,   payments,   e-­‐ money   regulation   and   supervision   and   related   corporate   governance,   auditing  and  financial  reporting  issues.  

 

IV)  It  is  desirable  that  the  Authority  promotes  a  consistent  approach  in   the   area   of   deposit   guarantees   to   ensure   a   level   playing   field   and   the   equitable  treatment  of  depositors  across  the  Union.”29  

 

Article  1  of  the  Regulation  summarizes  these  tasks.  In  short,  the  EBA  had  to   improve  the  functioning  of  the  internal  market,  ensure  the  integrity,  transparency,   efficiency   and   orderly   functioning   of   financial   markets,   strengthen   supervisory   coordination,   promote   equal   conditions   of   competition,   ensure   risks   are   appropriately  regulated  and  supervised  and  better  the  protection  of  costumers.30  

Apart   from   that,   the   European   Banking   authority   was   meant   to   give   independent  advice  on  the  financial  market  situation  in  the  EU  to  Commission,  the   European   Parliament   and   the   European   Council.   The   Authority   was   furthermore   allowed  to  develop  draft  regulatory  standards  and  submit  these  draft  standards  to   the  European  Committee  for  endorsement.  On  the  aspect  of  issuing  guidelines  and   recommendations,  no  approval  of  the  EC  was  necessary  and  the  EBA  could  issue                                                                                                                  

29  Regulation  1093/2010  EU,  24  November  2010,  Official  Journal  of  the  European  Union  331/13-­‐

331/15.  

(20)

these   independently.   Another   task   of   the   Authority   was   to   investigate   possible   breaches  of  the  European  Union  law.  The  organization  could  take  the  initiative  to   do   so   or   can   act   in   on   request   from   another   EU   institution   or   competent   supervisory  institution.  If  the  EBA  constituted  there  to  be  a  breach  of  Union  law  it   can  issue  a  recommendation  to  the  authority  in  question.  If  there  was  still  a  lack  of   compliance,  the  European  Commission  could  then  issue  an  opinion  and  following   this,   the   EBA   can   take   the   necessary   action   to   stop   the   breach   of   law   by   an   institution.31  

In  the  event  of  a  new  crisis  in  the  European  Union,  the  EBA  was  meant  to   facilitate   and,   if   necessary,   coordinate   actions   undertaken   by   the   national   supervisors.   To   do   so,   the   Authority   had   to   be   fully   informed   of   the   financial   situation   at   each   given   moment   in   the   EU.   Therefore,   the   Regulation   on   the   EBA   holds  that  the  relevant  authority  in  each  member  state  must  provide  the  Authority   with  the  information  necessary  to  carry  out  its  tasks.  The  Board  of  Supervisors  and   the   Managing   Board   were   responsible   for   governing   the   new   European   Banking   Authority.   The   members   of   the   Board   of   Supervisors   consist   of   the   head   of   the   national  public  authority  responsible  for  the  supervision  in  each  member  state,  a   representative  of  the  Commission,  a  representative  of  the  ECB,  a  representative  of   the   European   Systemic   Risk   Board   and   a   representative   of   each   of   the   other   European  Supervisory  Authorities.  The  Board  had  to  give  guidance  to  the  work  of   the   Authority   and   is   the   main   decision   making   organ.   From   the   Board   of   Supervisors,  the  members  will  chose  six  of  them  who,  together  with  the  chairman,   will  form  the  Managing  Board  of  the  EBA.  The  Managing  Board  was  responsible  for   ensuring  the  Authority  works  according  to  the  tasks  that  were  designated  to  it  and   is  responsible  for  policy  plans  and  budgetary  matters.32  

Was   this   new   European   supervisory   structure,   which   began   working   in   2011,   a   departure   from   the   old   situation?   Before   the   2008,   the   main   decision-­‐ making   structure   was   the   Lamfalussy-­‐structure.   This   four   level   structure,   as   described  earlier,  came  into  force  in  2001  and  was  meant  to  harmonise  financial   supervision   and   regulation   in   Europe.   When   we   look   at   the   structure   of   the                                                                                                                  

31  Regulation  1093/2010  EU,  24  November  2010,  Official  Journal  of  the  European  Union  331/13-­‐

331/27.  

32  Regulation  1093/2010  EU,  24  November  2010,  Official  Journal  of  the  European  Union  331/37-­‐

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

Meneu and Pardo (2004) investigate for the manifestation of the holiday effect on the Spanish Stock Exchange over the 1990s and find a strong evidence of abnormal returns just prior

Although both EU and Non-EU acquirers will probably create positive bidder shareholder returns when undertaking acquisitions in transition / emerging markets 2 , it is hypothesized

The managerial conclusion is that the European Commission needs to stimulate board gender diversity in Great-Britain and Ireland, because in these countries a more gender diverse

KEYWORDS Migration patterns; ethnic identity; social capital; bonding and bridging; ethnic community; Northwest China.. Introduction: the story of Bai

Throughout this research, it has been shown that there are three different types of discourse that people can use to frame their distrust: postmodern, reflexive and anomic

spectrometry (HR-MS).[18], [19] The Orbitrap mass spectrometer, a relatively new technique to perform HR-MS, is based on a different mass spectrometric mechanism

4 The collected data, according to the above mentioned criteria, entails changes in the following variables: house prices, consumer confidence, housing cost overburden,

GRA-Afrikaans het vinnig bekend geword, maar dit het teen die begin van die twintigste eeu nog nie die taalbehoeftes van die sprekersbolaag bevredig nie. Die vroeë taalmakers