• No results found

The development of the income distribution in the Netherlands after the Second World War: A Markovian approach

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "The development of the income distribution in the Netherlands after the Second World War: A Markovian approach"

Copied!
40
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

Tilburg University

The development of the income distribution in the Netherlands after the Second World

War

Mustert, G.R.

Publication date:

1974

Document Version

Publisher's PDF, also known as Version of record

Link to publication in Tilburg University Research Portal

Citation for published version (APA):

Mustert, G. R. (1974). The development of the income distribution in the Netherlands after the Second World

War: A Markovian approach. (EIT Research Memorandum). Stichting Economisch Instituut Tilburg.

General rights

Copyright and moral rights for the publications made accessible in the public portal are retained by the authors and/or other copyright owners and it is a condition of accessing publications that users recognise and abide by the legal requirements associated with these rights. • Users may download and print one copy of any publication from the public portal for the purpose of private study or research. • You may not further distribute the material or use it for any profit-making activity or commercial gain

• You may freely distribute the URL identifying the publication in the public portal

Take down policy

If you believe that this document breaches copyright please contact us providing details, and we will remove access to the work immediately and investigate your claim.

(2)

i

7626

1974

47 IT

' B~etemming

~i'I~.t~SC~-ihIF'I~EAlBL~REAU

BiSLIOTHi:.EK

Ns.

KII ~: N~`LiF.KE

HOG~Sr.:HGOL

TII~AUPG

G. R. Mustert

The development of the income

distribution in the netherlands

after the second world war

A markovian approach

~~~ ~ a' , ~-c 1..C3t ~L-r.,J~ ~í'~ r~?'-!. ~~~ -! ~ i.~,.J"í~i-~ ''~C' ;;.. !.'' ~ t!~-;? . a~ . ~ ~E:i t ., ... `p'~ ~,:

Research memorandum

-`- ~-s ~~ J,.;!

- ~

f~

imiiiaiimiiiiuiiuiiiiumiiaiiiiiuiiii

TILBURG INSTITUTE OF ECONOMICS

(3)

D

K.U.B.

(4)
(5)

- 11

;-Introduction

Recently I investigated the development of income inequality in the Netherlands during the years 1950-1967 [1]. The lack of ánd the deficiencies in the available empirical data pro-hibited from indicating directly the main sources of the de-crease of the income inequality which could be noticed. I had to introduce a stochastic model to indicate the nature of the events which could have generated the noticed decrease. An inquiry into the nature of the relevant events which took place during the studied period made it possible to identify the main sources of the noticed decrease.

(6)

1. The income ineguality in the Netherlands after WO II.

The 1950 frequency distribution of income tax payers according to their income is the first rather complete one after WO II and the 1967 distribution is the most recent available one now. Except for 1951, 1956 and 1961 such a distribution is available for each year between 1950 and 1967. Because of changes in the income definition and the way of classification it is not possible to compare these distributions which each other from year to year with a reasonable degree of accuracy. Therefore in the first instance the 1950 distribution was com-pared with the 1967 one as though both distributions are

completely comparable with each other but the interpretation of the results was performed with great reserve.

For mainly technical reasons the Theil coëfficient [2], [3] was chosen as measure of inequality. The inequality measured in that way turned out to be about 16~ lower in 1967 than it was in 1950. Although the average income rose from about f 3.000,-- to about f 10.000,-- and there is a strong gradua-tion in the income tax the inequality of the incomes exclusive income taxes did not fall more than the inequality of the in-comes inclusive income taxes.

Some mutually exclusive subsets of income tax payers could be distinguished. About three quarters of the fore-mentioned 16g could be located in the subsets of the industry workers, the service workers and the subset of the retired people. Another partition in subsets made it possible to locate about two

fifth of the 16~ in the age category of 65 years and older, which category is in practice the same as the subset of the retired people.

(7)

3

-higher levels of education. The influence of that phenomenon on the relative position of income earners was not yet noti-ceable during the studied period. With respect to the payment of the sources one has to distinguish the general level of payment and the structure of particularly the wages. Events with respect to the general level of payment have not influen-ced significantly the income inequality. With respect to the wage structure there have been two phenomena which can have been of interest: the so-called minimum wage and incidental wage increases with equal amounts irrespective of the already achieved income level. As far as the income transfers concerns

one has to distinguish the taxes, the social securities and the so-called social provisions. The indirect taxes are not of interest for the spendable income and we saw already that

the direct taxes have not influenced the income inequality during the studied period. The social provisions are certainly

of interest but they have a supplementary nature. Because the level to which is supplemented is such that the receiver is not liable to taxation the social provisions stay out of sight, i.e. out of the income statistics and out of the noticed 168. Of the social securities the insurances for loss of wages and sickness are not of great interest. The influence of the so-cial securities on the income inequality has mainly been res-tricted to the general old age security (A.O.W.), the general widow and orphans security (A.W.W.) and the children's allo-wance (A.K.W.).

(8)
(9)

2. A model of the development of the income distribution. Income distribution is the process of distributing the added value of some production process or another among those who are~entitled to receive a certain income. The forces which govern this process are so varied and complicated that each

theoretical model of this process is unrealistically simpli-fied or very complicated, apart from the difficulty to iden-tify the parameters of such a model from the available empiri-cal data. But income distribution is also the frequency

dis-tribution of income earners according to their yearly income. It is possible to construct a relatively simple model of the development of the income distribution in this sense. The

influence of the process of the income distribution on the development of the frequency distribution has then to find expression in the assumptions underlying the model.

The set of income earners is distributed over a number of, say n, income classes. The distribution of the income earners over the n classes is given for T successive years. So the number of income earners fit) (i-1,2,...n; t-1,2,...,T) that is in class i at the end of year t is given. If for each t(t-1,2,...,T) all f(t) (i-1,2,...,n) are divided by

fit) f f2t) f... t f~t) the result is a relative frequency distribution of the income earners over the n classes for each t. The relative frequency pit) (i-1,2,...,n; t-1,2,...,T) is the fraction of the income earners in class i at the end of year t. In vectornotation the relative frequency distribution of year t is given by (P(t))i -(pit),p2t),...,pnt)). The relative transitionfrequency of an income earner who is in class i at the end of year t(t-1,2,...,T-1) and in class j at the end of year t f 1 is given by pij (i,j-1,2,...,n). It is assumed that the relative transition frequency pij depends on the class i of the income earner at the end of year t and is constant from year to year.

(10)

income earner at the end of year t in such a way that p.ij depends indeed on the class i of the income earner at the end of year t but not on the way and the time the income ear-ner reached class i then the development of the relative fre-quency distribution over time can be discribed by a stationary

single fiarkovchain.

The object of study, an arbitrary income earner, is called the system. The system always is in one of n possible classes. The system can make a transition to another class. We say then that a process takes place. If a chance mechanism has influen-ce on the transitions the proinfluen-cess is called a stochastic pro-cess. If the transitions take place on discrete times the

sequence of successive classes of the system is called a chain. If the chance mechanism depends on the classes which were al-ready reached by the system the chain is called a Markovchain.

If the chance mechanism only depends on the class which was lastly reached by the system the Markovchain is called a sing-le Markovchain. If the chance mechanism is constant over time the Markovchain is called a stationary Markovchain. The pro-babilities of the process are conditional propro-babilities: p.ij is the probability of a transition to class j under the condition that the system is in class i before the transition

is made. The probabilities pij can be summarized in a matrix ~ of transitionprobabilities. Each element of such a matrix

is non-negative and the sum van the elements of each row is equal to one. Such a matrix is called a stochastic matrix.

Instead of the sequence of successive classes of an income earner we can also consider the seguence of successive pro-bability distributions of the class of an income earner. If p~t~i is the probability of an income earner in class i at the end of year t then P~t~ is the probability distribution of an

income earner at the end of year t. Given the probability distribution at the beginning of the first year, P~o~, and

(11)

(P(1),P(1),...,P(1)) - (p(o).P(o)....,P(o))

i z n i z n

or in matrix and vector notation by:

(p(1))1 - (P(o))', n

pii piz ... Pin pzi Pzz ... Pzn

pnl pnz " ' pnn

The probability distribution at the end of the next year is given by:

(p(z))1 - (p(1))1, n

or:

(P(z))1 - (P(u))i'J~~

By complete induction it follows that:

(P(t))1 - (p(t-~))l.í~ - (P(t-z))1~~ - .

. - (P(o))1.J t

The development of the income distribution will now be descri-bed by means of the probabilistic model of the stationary

sïngle Markovchain. In the remainder of this section we follow D.G. Champernowne [4]. If we assume that the income scale has

been divided in a denumerable number of income classes

(12)

num-ber of income earners is constant over time and equal to N. Each year new income earners appear and old ones disappear. So we suppose that a new income earner corresponds with each disappearing one.

With r~spect to the chance mechanism we suppose that its in-fluence on the frequency distribution can be represented by a matrix J of transitionprobabilities with elements

pij (i,j-1,2,...), the probability that an income earner in class i will be in class j next year. The form of the matrix of transitionprobabilities is given by:

1 2 3 4 . 1 2 ~ - 3 4 P11 Plz p13 p14 . P2 1 P2 2 P2 3 P2 4 p31 P32 p33 P34 P4 1 P4 2 P4 3 P4 4

Because the jumps of an income earner from year to year are generally rather small we define a new matrix,f~ of transition-probabilities with elements

(13)

9 -1 2

J~ - 3

4 1 2 3 4 r r r r

i o i,i i,z i,3

r r r r z -i 2,0 2,i 2,z r r r r 3 -2 3,-1 3,0 3,1 r r r r 4,- 3 4,- 2 4,- 1 4, 0

In this matrix we want to introduce the essential characteri-stic of the process of the income distribution. Therefore we choose the income classes on the income scale in such a way that each class is characterised by the same relative class width, i.e.for each class the ratio of the class upper bound

(14)

1 1 2 3 4 r r r r 0 1 2 3 r r r r -i o i z r r r r -z -i o i r r r r -3 -2 -1 0

Because the jumps of an income earner from year to year are generally rather small we suppose that no income earner jumps more than one class boundary a year, or: rk - 0 if k ~-1 and k~ 1. If r f r f r - 1 the matrix of transition

pro--i o i babilities is given by:

1 2

,j~ -

3

4 1 2 3 4 1-r r 0 0 i o r r r 0 0 r r r -i o i 0 0 r r -i o

(15)

- 11

-3. The application of the model.

The described model requires frequency distributions over classes with the same relative class width. The distributions which have been published by the Dutch Central Bureau of Sta-tistics (Table A.1) do not meet the needs of the model. There-fore we transform the given distributions to distributions over the classes: ~ 2, 2- ~ 4, 4- ~ 8, 8- ~ 16, 16- ~ 32, 32- ~ 64, 64- ~ 128 and ~ 128, where the relative class width is equal to two and the class boundaries are given in thous-ands of Dutch guilders. The frequencies of the three lower classes can be found in the published statistics. The deter-mination of the frequencies of the five higher classes is

performed by means of the Pareto curve. For each given class boundary xi the number yi of earners of an income ~ xi is calculated. The relation of log xi and log yi can be approxi-mated by a straight line for the higher incomes (cf. Fig. 1).

thousands of earners 10.000F of an income ~ x 1967 1 9 l x, income in thousands 10 100 of Dutch guilders Fig. 1

(16)

For all years the coëfficients of the linear relation for the incomes greater than 8.000 guilders have been estimated by means of the method of least squares. For those incomes the

frequencies over the given classes according to the linear relation have been calculated. To get an indication of the quality of this approximation each calculated frequency has been substracted from the corresponding given frequency and the absolute value of this difference has been divided by the given frequency. For each year the mean value of this relative absolute deviations has been calculated (Table A.2). The mean value over all years is equal to 0,0392. So the mean deviation is less than 4~. The frequencies of the five higher new clas-ses have been calculated by means of the linear relations. So we got frequency distributions which meet the requirements of the model (Table A.3).

The supposition that the development of the frequency distri-bution can be described by means of a single Markovclain im-plies that the expecbed distribution ~ X(t}1) of year t t 1 can be generated by the matrix ~ of transition probabilities and the distribution X(t) of year t according to:

~ X(tfi) - ,I~~X(t).

The values of the transition probabilities have been chosen in such a way that the difference of the actual distribution X(t}1) and its expectation ~ X(t}1) is minimized. Therefore we minimized the sum of the inproducts of the vector of

dif-ferences with itself over all available pairs of successive years. By the lack of distributions for the years 1951, 1956 and 1961 we have got eleven such pairs and so we minimized:

E(X(tti) -~~X(t))1 (X(tfi) -,i~.~X(t)).

t

(17)

- 13

-to one and that the transition probabilities are non-negative: r t r t r - 1,

-i o i

r , r , r ~ 0.

-i o i

-This estimation method is known as the restricted least squares method [5]. The problem can be solved by means of an algorithm for quadratic programming.

There remains one problem. We supposed that the number of in-come earners is constant from year to year but in fact this number was growing. But we do not know the number of new in-come earners and the number of inin-come earners who disappeared. We only know the difference of both numbers. So we maintain the supposition that each disappearing income earner is suc-ceeded by a new one and we only modify the described procedure

for the net increase u(t) of the number of income earners in year t. We suppose that a new income enters the system with probability sj (j-1,2,...) in class j. The expected

distribu-tion of year t f 1 is then generated by:

~x(ttl) -.~i~X(t) } u(t}1)S,

where:

S' -(s , s, s, s, s, s, 0, 0) .

1 2 3 4 5 6

To reduce the number of parameters we suppose that a new in-come is less than 64 thousand guilders.

The estimation problem is then given by:

min

E(x(tti)-c~~x(t)-u(tfi)S)1 (x(tti)- ~~x(t)-u(tti)S)

t

(18)

r t r t r - 1, -i a i s f... f s - 1, 1 6 r , r, r, s,...,s ~ 0. -1 0 1 1 6

-This problem was solved by means of the simplexmethod for sol-ving quadratic programming problems [6]. The optimal values of the transition and entering probabilites are given by:

r - 0,91646955 0 r - 0,08353045 i s - 0 i s - 0 z s - 0,55083559 3 s - 0,44916441 4 s - O 5 s - O. 6

For eleven years the expected distribution can be generated by the estimations of the probabilites and the distribution of the preceding year (Table A.4). To get an indication of the descriptive power of the model the relative absolute deviations of the generated distributions have been calculated (Table A.5). The mean value of these deviations over all years is equal to 0,0908. So the deviation is about 9~ and the descriptive power of the model can be considered reasonable great.

(19)

15

-of this model application. The percentage -of the wage increases corresponds to the rate of inflation and rise of the labour productivity. Because both rates are not constant from year to year the stationarity assumption can hardly be satisfied to a reasonable extent. The new incomes are also influenced by in-flation and labour productivity and so the probability of en-tering the system in a certain class can hardly be expected to be the same from year to year. Therefore we modify the

trans-formation of the given income distributions to distributions over the new set of income classes in such a way that the

in-fluence of inflation and the rising labour productivity is ex-cluded.

(20)

Table 1

The multiplying factors.

(1): factors to exclude the influence of inflation;

(2): factors to exclude the influence of rising labour produc-tivity; (3) : (1) x (2) . year (1) (2) (3) 1952 1,000 1,000 1,000 1953 1,000 0,926 0,926 1954 0,962 0,862 0,829 1955 0,950 0,806 0,768 1957 0,874 0,758 0,662 1958 0,854 0,752 0,642 1959 0,854 0,725 0,619 1960 0,826 0,671 0,554 1962 0,792 0,641 0,508 1963 0,760 0,629 0,478 1964 0,717 0,585 0,419 1965 0,685 0,559 0,383 1966 0,650 0,543 0,353 1967 0,628 0,513 0,322

(21)

17

-way as before for the five higher classes with means of the shifted Pareto curves. The frequencies of the three lower clas-ses can be found no longer by adding some frequencies of the given distributions. For these classes the transformation is also performed by means of the Pareto curve. Because this cur-ve is cur-very flat in the beginning and the gicur-ven points of the curve lay very close together in the curvature the first part of the curve can be approximated by a piecewise linear func-tion. The frequencies of the three lower classes have been determined by means of this piecewise linear function. A dis-advantage of this procedure is the lack of an indication of the quality of the approximation. For the higher incomes this quality is exactly the same as before. So we got freguency distributions over the new set of income classes which lack the influence of inflation and rising labour productivity

(Table B.1).

(22)

For the eleven expected distributions which can be generated (Table B.2) the relative absolute deviations have been calcu-lated (Table B.3). The mean value of these deviations over all years is equal to 0,0430. So the deviation is diminished by more than 50~ by excluding the influence of inflation and rising labour productivity. The descriptive power of the model can be considered rather great now.

(23)

19

-4. Conclusions.

With means of the described model the development of the fre-quency distributions can be analysed theoretically. We can modify the characteristics of the process of income

distribu-tion and.see which are the conseguences for the income inequa-lity. So a wage increase in equal amounts reduces the income inequality in a considerable extent. But this reduction is melting away very fast when the increases of the following

years are percentage increases. The process of percentage in-creases is very stable and incidental modifications do not have lasting consequences for the income inequality.

The same conclusion applies to the so-called structural increa-ses of the legally garanteed minimum wages. In general we can conclude that incidental modifications of the process of in-come distribution and modifications with respect to only a part of the income distribution do not have a significant ef-fect on the income inequality. The usual inequality reducing measures will be effective if and only if the process of per-centage increases is replaced by a process of increases in equal amounts, which is highly inequality reducing itself. Because the income tranfers of A.O.W., A.W.W. and A.K.W. are paid in equal amounts to every one who is entitled to receive them they are responsible for the greater part of the decrease of inequality that could be noticed.

(24)

Re:erences

[1[ G.R. Mustert,

Enige statistische aspecten van de inkomensongelijk-heid in Nederland in de jaren 1950-1967, Preadvies voor de Vereniging voor de Staathuishoudkunde,

's-Gravenhage, 1973. [ 2] H. Theil,

Economics and Information Theory, Amsterdam, 1967. [ 31 H. Theil,

Statistical Decomposition Analysis, Amsterdam, 1972. [4] D.G. Champernowne,

A Model of Income Distribution, The Economic Journal, Vol. 63, no. 250, june 1953, pp. 318-351.

[5] T.C. Lee, G.G. Judgé and A. Zellner,

Estimating the Parameters of the Markov Probability Model from Aggregate Time Series Data, Amsterdam, 1970. [6] C. van de Panne and A. Whinston,

Simplicial Methods for Quadratic Programming, Naval Research Logistics Quarterly, vol. 11, 1964,

PP. 273-302.

[7] Zeventig jaren statistiek in tijdreeksen, 's-Gravenhage, 1970, p. 151, col. 41.

[8] Nationale rekeningen 1972, 's-Gravenhage, 1973, p. 103, table 30.

[9] Maandschrift C.B.S., dec. 1970, p. 1356.

(25)

APPENDIX-A.

Table A.1: The income distributions according to the statistics of the Dutch Central Bureau of Statistics.

The boundaries of the classes are given in thousands of Dutch guilders. The relation between the log of the boundary of a class and the log of the number of incomes greater than that boundary has been approximated by a linear relation for the incomes greater than eight thousand guilders. Table A.2: The distributions of the incomes greater than eight thousand

guilders according to the approximation and an indication of the quality of the approximation.

The income distributions have been transformed to a new set of income classes. The frequencies of the three lower classes can be found by adding some of the frequencies of the given distributions and the frequencies of the five upper classes are calculated by means of the approximating linear relations. Table A.3: The income distributions with the new set of income classes. The transition probabilities of the descripted Markov model have been estimated by means of the restricted least squares method.

Eleven distributions can be generated by means of the estimated probabilities and the distribution of the previous year and be compared with the actual distributions.

Table A.4: The distributions generated by the model.

A comparison of the generated distributions with the relevant distributions of Table A.3 gives an indication of the quality of the descriptive power of the Markov model.

i

r

(26)

'OOOE 'ZZLZ 'OOLZ 'bTTZ 'bbLT 'SOST 'ZLbi aio~ pup 'OOi '0660i 'Z600i '0096 '66EL '9b09 '9i6b '8bbb 'OOT - 'OS 'OOZLL 'LbS69 '009E9 '86E8b 'b896E 'S6iEE 'OiT6Z 'OS - 'OZ 'OOOSL 'ZiZ89 'OOSi9 'iESZb 'OZSbE 'L09LZ 'LEEbZ 'OZ - 'ST 'OOOiZZ 'BTTSOZ '00508T 'L69SZi 'OSZiOi '09508 '8090L 'ST - 'Oi 'OOSL6 'bSET6 'OOOZ8 'S89b5 '066Eb 'OL9bE '06iiE 'OT - '6 'OOOObi 'b850ET 'OOOLii '06908 'OE969 'OTSOS 'OTSSb '6 - '8 'OOOZZZ 'Li050Z '00558i '999iZi 'Oi6L6 'OEZ9L 'OL089 '8 - 'L 'OOObLE '0059EE 'OOOZZE 'Sib00Z '0659Si 'OLLOZi 'ObEOii 'L - '9 'OOOSZ9 'OOSSLS '0008b5 'TOS65E 'OELEBZ 'Oii80Z 'OSZZ6i '9 - 'S 'OOOL6L 'OOSE08 '000008 'iLSL99 '0009bS 'OOSOZb '00598E 'S - 'b '000565 '0006E9 'OOOi69 'b8b998 '0056i6 'OOSEb8 '005908 'b - 'E '000595 '000595 'OOOL9S '96L999 'OOObBL '0056E8 '0008L8 'E - 'Z 'OOOi99 'OOSZ89 'OOOb69 'TbTLiL 'OOSESL '00508L '000908 'Z - 'i '0009ZZ 'OOSEZZ 'OOSZbZ 'S6i6TE 'OOSbLE 'OOS955 'OOSLSS 'T - '0

656i 8S6T LS6T 556T b56T E56T Z56i sass2To

(27)

Table A.1: The given income distributions. income Frequencies of the years:

(28)

06i0'0 ESEO'0 6EE0'0 Z860'0 i860'0 08E0'0 96L0'0 68L0'0 0680'0 5580'0 6i00'0 STZO'0 Z6Z0'0 6Zi0'0 ZLTO'0 LE00'0 ZEiO'0 i600'0 Z860'0 9i60'0 90T0'0 6000'0 SE00'0 68T0'0 L9Z0'0 E600'0 ZOEO'0 5650'0 LL00'0 Oi00'0 SOTO'0 L600'0 SOZO'0 ESEO'0 LL60'0

Z6E0'0 TZZO'0

0090'0 98E0'0 'OOT - 'OS i6E0'0 9iZ0'0 'OS - 'OZ 6T90'0 9ES0'0 'OZ - 'ST iEEO'0 T9i0'0 'Si - 'Oï L600'0 9i60'0 'Oi - '6 9Z90'0 E800'0 '6 - '8 :~q uanzb azp sanTEn ZPaz aq~ ~oz3 suOT~E~TXOZddP au~ 3o suoz~einap ani~EZaz au~ ~o sant~n a~ntosqe aqy 'LSOE '8T8Z 'Z6LZ '9TZZ '8Z8T '695T

'Z600i '88Z6 'E688 'i6L9 '6Z55 'iZ96 '80ELL 'ZbOiL '6ïTS9 '008L6 'Z006E 'L68iE '6LZSL 'bii69 '090Z9 'Z8566 '89Z9E 'TOE6Z 'i6EEZZ '8Z6~OZ '6ETT8i '6908ZT '956EOi '9ZZE8 '~6596 'E6588 'OESLL 'i9Z65 'E86Eb '8005E '6ZS8Ei '948iEi '66E6iT 'S68LL '865T9 'L6EL~

'605i azo~ pu~ 'OOT '9LZ6 'OOi - 'OS 'T868Z 'OS - 'OZ 'T695Z 'OZ - 'Si '86LiL 'Si - 'Oi 'T686Z 'Oi - '6 'EEi56 '6 - '8 :~q pa~p~rxozddp aze sass2To ~uPnaTaz au~ 3o saTOUanbaz3 auy L60i'Z- 6ZOi'Z- E650'Z- iSTO'Z- 6800'Z-

9E86'T-6LTL'LT ZSZ9'LT

OZ66'i- - g 9LT6'LT TE86'9T EZ9L'9i 6686'9i 965Z'9T -~

-XHt~ -~ uoi~PTaz zQauij aq~ 3o s~uaioT33aoo auy

656T 856T L56i SS6T 656i E56i Z56i

(29)

Table A.2 (cont.)

Evaluation of the results of the approximation for the years:

1960 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 The coefficients of the linear relation Y- AfBX:

A- 17.9203 18.1302 18.3148 18.7277 18.8701 19.2759 19.423;

B - -2.1013 - 2.0597 - 2.0579 - 2.1004 -2.0723 -2.1554 -2.1537

The frequencies of the relevant classes are approximated by: 8. - 9. 185945. 9. - 10. 118979. 10. - 15. 275313. 15. - 20. 92905. 20. - 50. 95569. 50. - 100. 12512. 100. and more 3802. 320236. 397186. 432467. 502545. 487334. 426409. 157986. 190635. 267217. 323832. 419257. 487441. 369081. 445540. 618466. 754344. 958235. 1114490. 126431. 152723. 208774. 257237. 317115. 369043. 132678. 160410. 214861. 268323. 317921. 370269. 18005. 21803. 28153. 36021. 39727. 46333. 5682. 6892. 8562. 11237. 11499. 13431. The absolute values of the relative deviations of the approximation

from the real values are given by: 8. - 9. 0.0058 0.0915 9. - 10. 0.0351 0.1520 10. - 15. 0.0153 0.0202 15. - 20. 0.0141 0.0432 20. - 50. 0.0105 0.0382 50. - 100. 0.0855 0.0573 100. and more 0.0422 0.0146 The average deviation is given by:

(30)

'Z68L '~SL9 '9ZZLZ 'SEEEZ 'ESiiZi '656EOi 'LOi6ES '660E9~ 'BEOZEiZ 'L66E56i 'L068i9T '059LTLi '69b859 '8559ZL '9ZE666 'EOZL09 L96i 996i

'LEL9 '8605 'L6i6 'Li6E 'E9ZZ '965iZ 'E9L9i '6iTEi '6Z80i '866L

'iE6 azo~ puE '8Zi '869Z '8Zi - '69 'bLiOT '69 - 'ZE 'E606E 'ZE - '9T '6Z8EST '9i - '8 '09iLSL '8 - '6 '005689i '6 - 'Z 'OOSE9Ei 'Z - '0 '06i6896 '96T8096 '0069956 'E8Z08Z6 '668LOZ6 'EL58L06 'SE8ii06 Tp~oy '8i8i 'LL9i '6L9i

'Z009 'LZSS '6iES 'LiBSZ 'ZbLEZ '89iZZ 'E60iii 'Z66i0i '06EZ6 'Oi56L6 'i69~66 'S6E56E '0008i0Z 'LTSOZ6i 'OOSSS8i '00009TT '00060Zi '00085Zi 'OOOL88 '000906 '0059E6

656i 856i L56i

'L6Ei 'Eiii '8S6 '6606 'L9EE 'ZEBZ '8959i 'ESSEi 'OOZii '99699 '96565 'S6Z~6 'EESZLZ '~E56iZ 'LL9ELi

'ESi66Ei 'OEZ680i 'Oi95Z8 '08ZEESi 'OOSEOLi 'OOOE89i '9EE9EOi '0008Zii 'OOOLEET

'EZ806 'Z88iL 'ZZ965 'S6i56 '096iE 'E56i8E '66Z80E '8Z6LZZ 'SOZ88i '~~iLEi '6Z~Z59i '6059LEi '~LBSLOi '605Z88 '80Z909 '899908i 'OOLZZ8i '6E869iZ 'OOEZ8iZ 'b0ii6iZ '6LOSE8 'OOZi98 'i8LL60T 'OOZ~60i '6E5090i '6~OL99 'OOi658 'L99Z69 'OOOE6L 'ii09i8

S96i 696i E96i Z96i 096T :szea~ aqq ;o saiouanbaz3

556i 656i E56i Z56i

azow pue '8ZT '8ZT - '69 '69 - 'ZE 'ZE - '9i '9i - '8 '8 - '6 'b - 'Z 'Z - '0 sasspTo a~ooui sasselo

(31)

Table A.4: The distributions generated by the model. income Frequencies of the years:

classes 1953 1954 1955 1958 0. - 2. 2. - 4. 4. - 8. 8. - 16. 16. - 32. 32. - 64. 64. - 128. 128. and more 1249606. 1225320. 1657687. 1654098. 871383. 968435. 234202. 286197. 48677. 55103. 12590. 13965. 3276. 3531. 1153. 1195. 1033778. 858274. 1655428. 1231145. 1175860. 1828310. 324300. 535838. 68328. 117696. 16977. 28033. 4218. 6726. 1395. 2123. 1959 1960 830321. 81290~. 1179108. 1137196. 1905308. 2008844. 604369. 658995. 130618. 141821. 30279. 32936. 7048. 7657. 2139. 2320. Total 4078573. 4207844. 4280283. 4608146. 4689190. 4802678. income Frequencies of the years:

(32)

66Z0'0 Z9LT'0 Z99Z'0 66E0'0 6EL0'0 LZOZ'0 azo~ pup '8ZT TSZO'0 E~LT'0 OLTZ'0 i6Z0'0 9860'0 695T'0 '8ZT -'69 SOEO'0 BZLT'0 L08T'0 L6Z0'0 60E0'0 ObZT'0 '69 -'ZE TbEO'0 E9LT'0 06ST'0 EOZO'0 ZOTO'0 6860'0 'ZE -'9T TL80'0 609Z'0 OSOZ'0 668T'0 LEOE'0 586E'0 '9T -'8 8T90'0 8550'0 08~0'0 68ZT'0 890T'0 6550'0 '8 -'6 EZLO'0 59T0'0 SZZO'0 L6L0'0 06Z0'0 OSTO'0 '6 -'Z 8E00'0 6E90'0 LZSO'0 SZ00'0 E980'0 6590'0 'Z -'0

sassejo

:suoT~einap anr~Qtaz a~ntosq2 awooui 096T 656T 856T 556T 656i E56i

' :s~eaR auq ao; s}Znsaz aq~ 3 o uor~QnTeng

(33)

Table A.5: An indication of the quality of the model. Evaluation of the results for the years:

1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 income absolute relative deviations:

classes 0. - 2. 0.0169 0.2568 0.1735 0.0068 0.1257 2. - 4. 0.0274 0.1822 0.0306 0.1300 0.0883 4. - 8. 0.0091 0.1484 0.0089 0.0495 0.0088 8. - 16. 0.0012 0.1419 0.1048 0.1155 0.0936 16. - 32. 0.0825 0.0323 0.0407 0.0539 0.0900 32. - 64. 0.0453 0.0393 0.0088 0.1076 0.1057 64. - 128. 0.0439 0.0106 0.0106 0.1733 0.1044 128. and more 0.0422 0.0284 0.0355 0.2646 0.1028 The average deviation is given by:

(34)

zaMOd ani~dizosap au~ ;o ~;iZenb ay~ ;o uoi~EOZpui ue sanTb t~g Zaqey ;o suoiqnqizqszp quenaTaz aqq u~iM suoi~nqiz~srp pa~EZauab au~ ;o uostzEdwoo ~ .Tapo~ au~ ~q pa~EZauab suoT~nqTZ~sip aqy :Z~g aZqey .suot~nqiz~szp ZEn~oa auq u~TM paz2d~oo aq pu2 zEa~ snoinazd au~ ;o uoi~nqizqsip au~ puE saT~TZiqEqozd pa~E~i~sa au~ ;o suEaw ~q pa~ezauab aq uEO suoi~nqiz~srp uanaT~ -poqqa~ sazenbs ~sEat pa~oizqsaz aq~ ;o suea~ ~q pa~e~z~sa uaaq an2u Tapow noxzEw pa~dTZOSap au~ ;o saz~iZiqeqozd uor~TSUez~ auy .sassETo a~oouT ;o ~as Mau au~ u~TM suoi~nqiz~sTp a~oouz auy :T-g aTqey .oo~ ubiu ~zan azau~ st uoi~E~ixozdda aq~ ;o ~~Tjenb aq~ '~eT; ~zan sz anzno ~Eu~ ;o ~zEd zEauT1-uou auq asneoag .azo;aq sE a~es au~ ~T~oexa si anzno o~azEd aqq ;o ~zEd zeauzT aq~ uo uOZ~E~TXOZddE aq~ ;o ~~iT2nb aqy -an~no oqaz2g auq uo squiod buiznoqqbiau oM~ au~ uaaM~aq uoT~Etodza~uT z2auTT e uaaq s2u azauq sassETo zaMO1 aazu~ au~ zog ~sass2jo zaubTu anT; ay~ zo; azo;aq s2 ~eM a~ES aqa At~oExa ui ~no paizzeo uaaq sEq sassejo a~ooui ;o ~as Mau au~ q~iM suoiqnqzzqsip o~ suor~nqTZ~sip uanib au~ ;o uoi~E~zo;su2z~ auy .aa~otd~a zad ~~T~vEnb ~nd~no aq~ ;o aszz au~ pu2 uoi~et;ui ;o aouant;ui auq zo; pa~oazzoo uaaq aneu sassEjo a~oouT au; ;o satzEpunoq auy

(35)

Table B.1: The transformed income distributions. income classes 0. - 2. 2. - 4. 4. - 8. 8. - 16. 16. - 32. 32. - 64. 64. - 128.

Frequencies of the years:

1952 1953 1954 1955 1957 1958 1959 1363500. 1520608. 1519297. 1487643. 1522562. 1563258. 1617178. 1684500. 1668817. 1788469. 1843713. 2037404. 2019475. 2048888. 757160. 690535. 702726. 740531. 792070. 802317. 796912. 153829. 147713. 147556. 156122. 162881. 170746. 173493. 39093. 38030. 37424. 39342. 39511. 40163. 40463. 10174. 9616. 9298. 9733. 9480. 9349. 9407. 2648. 2431. 2310. 2408. 2275. 2176. 2187. 931. 823. 764. 792. 718. 660. 663. 128. and more Total 4011835. 4078573. 4207844. 4280283. 4566900. 4608146. 4689190. income Frequencies of the years:

(36)

'8TL 'ZZ6 'TZ8 '806 'L68 azow puE '8ZT '805Z 'T66Z 'TELZ 'S06Z 'STLZ '8ZT - '69 '96TTT '665Zi '6L9iT 'E90Zi 'LBZTi '69 - 'ZE 'S0966 '6T9Z5 '80005 'OTTOS 'E9696 'ZE - '9T '6T6LTZ '6EETiZ 'fT680Z '65LOOZ 'E0006T '9T - '8

'668696 'ZEL596 'Z60666 'ET6S56 '08L566 '8 - '6 'S6Z6EZZ '06Z99ZZ '06589iZ 'TLOb6TZ '88i99ZZ '6 - 'Z '6Ei80TZ 'Z90060Z '0660LOZ 'TLZ006T 'E69TZ8i 'Z - '0

L96T 996T 596T 696T E96T sassQT~ :sz~a~ au~ 3o saiouanbaz3 a~oouT '8L9Z08b '06T689b '96T809b 'E8Z08Z6 '668LOZb 'ELSSL06 Tp~oy

'699 'T99 '8TL 'f9L 'iZ8 'SZ6 azo~ pue '8ZT 'STZZ '60ZZ 'TOEZ '6EEZ '9S6Z 'ZL9Z '8ZT - '69 'ZOS6 'E6b6 'f956 '89f6 'i896 'ZEZOT '69 - 'ZE 'f9806 '66SOb 'LE86E 'L99LE 'LSZ8E '09f6E 'ZE - '9T 'LZ85LT '49ZELT 'LE959T '06666T 'TL666T 'Z0995T '9T - '8 '99TL08 '6E5908 'L9T06L 'LT890L 'ZLTfOL 'ETL9SL '8 - '6 'LLLZ60Z 'S6ZLEOZ 'OOZOZOZ 'LE0908T 'SZZ6ELT '8TSZOLT '4 - 'Z '999EL9T '06Z6T9T 'EZL6LST '8SEL95T 'Z9Z695T '6~560~T 'Z - '0

(37)

Table B.3: An indication of the quality of the model. Evaluation of the results for the years:

1953 1954 1955 1958 1959 1960 income absolute relative dev~ations:

classes 0. - 2. 0.0730 0.0296 0.0536 0.0105 0.0013 0.0196 2. - 4. 0.0202 0.0275 0.0204 0.0004 0.0057 0.0040 4. - 8. 0.0958 0.0006 0.0455 0.0151 0.0121 0.0206 8. - 16. 0.0602 0.0164 0.0396 0.0299 0.0013 0.0426 16. - 32. 0.0350 0.0223 0.0426 0.0081 0.0020 0.0307 32. - 64. 0.0641 0.0412 0.0376 0.0229 0.0038 0.0284 64. - 128. 0.0989 0.0629 0.0306 0.0572 0.0076 0.0286 128. and more 0.1277 0.0746 0.0368 0.0874 0.0018 0.0142 The average deviation is given by:

(38)

8660'0 588Z'0 660T'0 890T'0 iL90'0 a~o~ Pup '8ZT 6L50'0 Z60Z'0 Z9L0'0 ELLO'0 8650'0 '8ZT -'69 T950'0 68ET'0 6090'0 TE60'0 Z950'0 '69 -'ZE E950'0 OZLO'0 EE60'0 SOiO'0 8950'0 'ZE -'9T T650'0 TSTO'0 bZ00'0 E9Z0'0 OLEO'0 '9i -'8 L9Z0'0 i8T0'0 OL00'0 8Li0'0 88T0'0 '8 -'6 6LE0'0 8iT0'0 LZTO'0 6660'0 SiZO'0 '6 -'Z 66Z0'0 LOZO'0 SSTO'0 6L50'0 OOiO'0 'Z -'0

sasspT~

:suoT~~tnap ani~aTa~ a~nTosqe a~ooui L96i 996T 596T fi96i E96i

(39)

PREVIOUS NUMBERS:

ER 1 1. Krtens') . . . . Het verdelen van steekproeven over subpopulatiea biJ eccountantscontroles.

ER 2 1. P. C. 14eynen') . . . Een toepassing van „importance sampling".

EIT 3 S. R. Chowdhury and W. Vandaele') A bayesian analysis of heteroscedasticity in regres-slon models.

EIT 4 Prof. drs. J. Krlens . . . De besliskunde en haar toepasstngen.

ER 5 Prof. dr. C. F. Scheffer') . . . Winstkapitaltsatle versus dividendkapitalisatie biJ het waarderen van aandelen.

EIT 6 S. R. Chowdhury') . . . A bayesian approach In multiple regresston enalysis with inequality constrainta.

EIT 7 P.A. Verheyen ') . . . Investeren en onzekerheid. EIT 8 R. M. J. Heuts en

Walter A. Vandaele') . . . . Problemen rond niet-Itneaire regressie.

EIT 9 S. R. Chowdhury') . . . Bayesian analysis in linear regression with different EIT 10 A.1. van Reeken') . . .

EIT 11 W. H. Vandaele and S. R. Chowdhury') . . . EIT 12 J. de Blok') . . . .

EIT 13 Walter A. Vandaele') . . EIT 14 J. Plasmans') . ER 15 D. Neeleman') . . . EIT 16 H. N. Weddepohl . . EIT 17 EIT 18 J. Plasmana') . . . priors.

The effect of truncation in statistical computation. A revised method of scoring.

Reclame-uitgaven in Nederland.

Medsco, a computer programm for the revised method of scoring.

Altemative production models.

(Some empirical relevance for postwar Belgian Economy)

Multiple regression and serially correlated errors. . . . Vector representatlon of majority voting.

. . The general Itnear aeemingiy unrelated regression problem.

1. Models and Inference.

EIT 19 J. Plasmans and R. Van Straelen') . The general linear seemingly unrelated regression problem.

II. Feasible statistical estimation and an application. EIT 20 Pieter H. M. Ruys .

EIT 21 D. Neeleman') . .

EIT 22 R. M. J. Heuts') . .

A procedure for an economy with collective goods only.

(40)

~ oiwá~~~~u~~~á~~~~~ib

EIT 23 D. Neeleman ~. . . . The classlcal multivariate regreeslon model wlth

singular covariance matrix.

EIT 24 R. Stobbsringh ~. . . . . The derlvation of the optimal Karhunen-Loève coor-dinate functlons.

EIT 25 Th. van de Klundert ~) . . . . Produktie, kapltaal en Interest.

EIT 26 Th. van de Klundert s) . . . . Labour valuea and International trade; a

reformule-tlon of the theory of A. Emmanuel.

EIT 27 R. M. J. Heuts ~) . . . . . . Schattingen van paramaters in de gammaverdeling en een onderzoek naar de kwalitelt van een drletal schattingsmethoden met behulp van Monte

Carlo-methoden.

EIT 28 A. van Schaik ~) . . . A note on the reproductlon of fixed capital In two-good technlques.

EIT 29 H. N. Weddepohl ~) . . . . . Vector representation of majority voting; a revised paper.

EIT 30 H. N. Weddepohl . . . Dualiry and Equilibrium.

EIT 31 R. M. l. Heuts and W. H. Vandaele t) Numerical results of quasi-newton methods for un-constrained function minimization.

EIT 32 Pieter H. M. Ruys . . . On the existence of an equllibrium for an economy EIT 33 .

wtth publlc gooda oniy.

. Het rekencentrum biJ het hoger ondervvlJa.

EIT 34 R. M.1. Heuts end P.1. Rens . . A numerical comparison among some algorithms for

unconstralned non-Iineer function minimization.

EIT 35 1. Krfens . . . . EIT 38 Pieter H. M. Ruys . . EIT 37 1. Plasmans . . . . EIT 38 H. N. Weddepohl . .

ER 39 J. l. A. Moors

EIT 40 F. A. Engering . . .

EIT 4f J. M. A. Kraay . . .

EIT 42 W. M. van den Goorbergh

. . . Systematic Inventory management wlth a computer. . . . On convex, cone-Interlor processes.

.. . Adjustment cost models for the demand of investment . . . Dual sets and duai correspondences and their

appli-cation to equilibrium theory.

. . . On the absolute moments of e normally diatrlbuted random variable.

. . . The monetary multiplier end the monetary model.

. . . The Intemational product Iife cycle concept.

. . Productionstructures and external dlseconomies.

EIT 43 H. N. Weddepohl . . . . . An application of game theory to a problem of choice between private and public tranaport. EIT 44 B. B. van der Genugten . . . A statistical view to the problem of the economlc

lot size.

EIT 45 J. l. M. Evers . . . Linear inffntte horizon programming EIT 46 Th. van de Klundert and

A. van Schaik . . . . On shift and share of durable cap(tai EIT 1974

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

44 Appendix D.2 Empirical results for the regressions on Poverty (povGAP2) – Outliers excluded Outliers excluded Liquid Liabilities PovGAP2 RE Private Credit PovGAP2 RE

I want to research into the mechanism how the transition affects the inequality in these countries and to see the effect of the political economy on

 Natalia Vladimirovna Chevtchik, the Netherlands, 2017 ISBN: 978-90-365-4384-2 DOI: 10.3990/1.9789036543842 Printed by Gildeprint, Enschede, the Netherlands, Cover design by

Additionally, the main themes of this study, such as platform, architecture, or service tend to be overloaded as they are applied distinctively across the different sub-domains

The comparison of the simulated snow albedo evolution with the in situ measurements shows that the parameterizations adopted by Noah, BATS, and CLASS are only able to simulate an

In hoeverre bestaat er een verband tussen de gecommuniceerde identiteit en de gemedieerde legitimiteit van organisaties op social media en in hoeverre spelen het gebruik van

Yu, “Towards Modelling and Reasoning Support for Early-Phase Requirements Engineering,” Proceedings of the 3rd IEEE International Symposium on Requirements

Although such impacts were re- ported in the 1923 Great Kant¯o earthquake and the 1999 Chi- Chi earthquake, careless reconstruction in hazard-prone ar- eas and consequently huge