• No results found

The  Decoupling  of  the  Canada-­‐US  Business  Cycle

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "The  Decoupling  of  the  Canada-­‐US  Business  Cycle"

Copied!
51
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

             

The  Decoupling  of  the  Canada-­‐US  Business  Cycle  

 

University  of  Groningen  

Faculty  of  Economics  &  Business  

Master  Thesis  International  Economics  &  Business  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Name  Student:  Henk  (H.J.)  Slot   Student  ID  number:  S1995537  

Student  E-­‐mail:  H.Slot@student.rug.nl   Date:  1st  of  July  2015  

(2)

Abstract  

The   aim   of   this   paper   is   to   investigate   the   divergence   between   U.S.   and   Canadian   business   cycles.   Using   aggregate   and   industry   decompositions   it   documents   two   fundamental  changes  that  appeared  since  the  mid  1980s.  U.S.  output  volatility  dropped   while   Canadian   output   volatility   did   not   and   U.S   labor   productivity   turned   countercyclical  while  the  opposite  happened  in  Canada.  This  paper  argues  the  changes   in  these  business  cycle  indicators  are  related  and  are  due  to  a  more  flexible  U.S.  labor   market.   It   finds   stark   contrasts   in   the   institutional   protection   of   employees   and   labor   market  reallocation  abilities  that  explain  both  output  volatility,  as  well  as  cyclical  labor   productivity  differences.  Minor  econometric  evidence  only  provides  evidence  of  similar   employment  fluctuations.    

 

(3)

Contents  

Abstract  ...  2  

I.   Introduction  ...  5  

II.   Literature  Review  ...  8  

III.   Assessing  how  the  business  cycle  in  the  U.S.  and  Canada  have  evolved  ...  10  

III.1  Source  data  ...  10  

III.2  The  great  moderation  ...  11  

III.3  The  shift  away  from  the  procyclical  behaviour  of  productivity  ...  17  

IV.   Labor  market  flexibility  ...  21  

IV.1  Institutional  environment  ...  21  

IV.2  Labor  market  reallocation  ...  23  

IV.3  Estimating  employment  fluctuations  ...  28  

V.   Concluding  remarks  ...  35  

References  ...  37  

(4)

Table  of  Figures  

Figure  1:  Relative  GDP  per  capita  and  Labor  Productivity         6   Figure  2:  10-­‐year  forward  rolling  standard  deviation  of  output         11   Figure  3:  U.S.  cyclical  output  and  productivity             17   Figure  4:  Canada  cyclical  output  and  productivity           18   Figure  5:  Rolling  correlation  output  and  productivity           19   Figure  6:  Trade  union  density                 23   Figure  7:  Long-­‐term  unemployment,  6  months  or  more           25   Figure  8:  Job  finding  probability                 26   Figure  9:  Job  separation  probability               26   Figure  10:  U.S.  and  Canada  permanent  and  temporary  unemployment  rates     27  

Table  of  Tables  

Table  1:  Business  Sector  Growth  U.S.  and  Canada           12   Table  2:  Growth  and  variance  decomposition  from  industry  data  U.S.  and  Canada   16   Table  3:  Correlation  U.S.  and  Canada               19   Table  4:  Productivity-­‐output  correlation  largest  industries         20   Table  5:  ADF  test  on  variables  and  their  first  differences         33   Table  6:  ADF  test  on  residuals                 33  

Table  of  Appendices  

Table  1:  List  of  industries                   40   Table  2:  Productivity-­‐Output  correlations  at  industry  level         41    

Figure  1:  Unemployment  rates                 42  

Figure  2:  Employment  rates                 42  

Figure  3:  Participation  rates                 42  

 

Stata  Output                       43  

(5)

I.

Introduction  

There   is   a   renewed   interest   in   the   literature   on   the   changing   behaviour   of   labor   productivity   over   the   business   cycle.   Historically,   labor   productivity   tends   to   move   procylical,  increasing  in  economic  booms  and  decreasing  during  recessions.  Economists   in  the  1960s  (Oi,  1962;  Solow,  1962)  developed  the  theory,  also  termed  labor  hoarding,   as  an  explanation  for  the  profit  maximizing  behaviour  of  firms.  They  were  reluctant  to   fire   staff   during   recessions   caused   by   the   existence   of   fixed   costs   of   hiring,   firing   and   training   workers   and   therefore   preferred   to   keep   them   employed   (Biddle,   2013).   It   caused  labor  productivity  to  fall  during  recessions  and  increase  when  output  increased,   leading  to  a  positive  correlation  between  labor  productivity  and  output.  As  for  example   outlined  by  Gali  &  van  Rens  (2014),  the  U.S.  correlation  of  productivity  with  output  used   to  be  strongly  positive  up  until  the  1980s,  around  0.8.    

Since   the   mid   1980s   however,   this   pattern   has   changed   considerably.   The   estimates   of   the   productivity   and   output   correlation   dropped   to   a   level   close   to   zero   (Stiroh,  2009;  McGrattan  &  Prescott,  2012;  Gali  &  van  Rens,  2014)  and  differences  with   periods  before  the  1980s  are  highly  significant.  Especially  in  recent  years  of  recession,   research  has  found  a  break  with  the  historical  procyclicality  in  U.S.  labor  productivity.  It   increased   sharply   during   the   2008–2009   recession   while   GDP   plummeted.   According   the  early  theories  productivity  would  have  to  fall  during  these  episodes  of  recessions.  As   actually  the  opposite  has  happened,  and  labor  productivity  has  grown  while  total  output   has  fallen,  debate  has  arisen  on  the  existing  relationship  between  labor  productivity  and   output  and  whether  labor  productivity  has  become  anti  cyclical.    

(6)

2005)   and   financial   sector   innovation   (Dynan,   Elmendorf   &   Sichel,   2006).   While   its   interpretation   is   still   controversial,   there   is   widespread   consensus   among   macroeconomists   on   the   existence   and   rough   timing   of   the   Great   Moderation.   The   change   took   place   in   the   mid   1980s.   Around   the   same   time   the   correlation   between   output  and  labor  productivity  dropped,  suggesting  that  there  could  be  more  than  mere   temporal  coincidence  linking  them.    

These  and  a  significant  amount  of  other  papers  have  all  focused  on  the  U.S.,  but   recent  research  has  lacked  comparison  with  similar  developed  nations.  Canada  in  this   case,   as   a   neighbouring   country,   is   an   interesting   example.   The   Canadian   and   U.S.   economies  are  highly  integrated  through  international  trade  in  goods  and  assets.  Given   their   integrated   nature,   the   two   countries   have   highly   correlated   business   cycles,   and   cyclical   fluctuations   in   the   U.S.   tend   to   have   an   impact   on   Canadian   economic   activity   (Bernard  &  Usalcas,  2014).  For  instance,  the  increased  trade  dependence  between  the   two   countries   has   made   Canadian   unemployment   levels   highly   vulnerable   to   cyclical   behaviour  and  recessions  in  the  U.S.  (Campolieti,  2011).  Comparisons  between  U.S.  and   Canadian  business  cycles  and  labor  markets  therefore  generate  a  high  level  of  interest.    

 

Figure  1:  Relative  GDP  per  capita  and  labor  productivity  (U.S.  =  1)  

Source:  The  Conference  Board.  Figure  shows  the  relative  GDP  per  capita  and  labor  productivity  growth  of  Canada  and  the  U.S  using  GDP   in  2014  prices  and  labor  productivity  per  person  employed  in  2014  prices,  from  1950  up  until  2013.  

 

Figure   1   makes   a   first   comparison   by   outlining   the   relative   development   of   GDP   per   capita   and   labor   productivity.   It   displays   a   distinct   change   appearing   in   relative   labor  

(7)

productivity  during  the  mid  1980´s.  The  Canadian  relative  labor  productivity  embarks   on  a  significant  decline  showing  no  clear  sign  of  returning  to  pre-­‐1980s  levels.  

In   light   of   the   U.S.   decline   in   the   procyclicality   of   labor   productivity   (van   Zandweghe,  2010;  Gali  &  van  Rens,  2014;  Wang,  2014)  the  declining  volatility  of  output   (Galί  &  Gambetti,  2008;  Stiroh,  2009)  and  the  clear  decline  in  the  relative  Canadian  labor   productivity   that   all   appeared   since   the   mid   1980s,   this   paper   attempts   to   form   a   unifying   explanation   based   on   structural   flexibility   differences   in   U.S.   and   Canadian   labor   markets.   While   the   business   cycle   changes   in   the   U.S.   have   been   increasingly   recognized   and   analysed,   similar   research   in   a   closely   integrated   nation   has   been   lacking.  A  primary  motivation  for  this  research  therefore  is  to  explore  the  changes  in  U.S.   business  cycle  dynamics  and  to  compare  them  to  Canadian  business  cycles.  

This   paper   adds   to   the   debate   by   proposing   a   single   explanation   for   all   of   the   above   observations;   a   structural   change   in   labor   market   dynamics.   This   approach   hypothesises  that  structural  changes  have  led  to  greater  flexibility  in  the  American  labor   market.   These   changes   have   primarily   come   in   the   form   of   a   reduction   in   labor   adjustment   costs,   like   hiring   and   firing   costs.   The   adjustment   costs   act   as   frictions   limiting   the   ability   of   firms   to   fire   and   hire   employees   at   will.   A   reduction   therefore   allows  firms  to  more  easily  adjust  their  labor  force  in  response  to  changes  in  output.  In   times   of   recession,   this   could   lead   to   sharper   adjustments   in   employment   than   reductions  in  output  leading  to  higher  labor  productivity.  Moreover  increased  flexibility   allows   firms   to   more   easily   reallocate   productive   resources   in   response   to   different   shocks,  reducing  the  volatility  of  output  (Cuñat  &  Melitz,  2012).  

(8)

II.

Literature  Review  

Previous  empirical  work  has  already  recognized  the  influence  of  a  flexible  labor  market   on  the  volatility  of  output  and  the  cyclical  behaviour  of  productivity.  A  number  of  papers   have   investigated   the   facts   and   proposed   mechanisms   that   may   explain   the   observed   changes.   Stiroh   (2009)   investigates   the   declining   volatility   of   U.S.   output   growth   and   provides   an   internally   consistent   framework   dubbed   volatility   accounting.   His   framework   tracks   which   of   the   inputs;   hours,   productivity   and   covariates,   contribute   most  to  the  volatility  of  output.  His  evidence  points  to  a  volatility  decline  due  to  smaller   covariances  between  sectors  as  well  as  a  significant  decline  in  both  labor  productivity   growth   and   hours   growth.   These   results   speak   in   favour   of   the   presence   of   common   factors  across  sectors.  Among  this  explanations  are  underlying  changes  in  labor  market   flexibility  that  support  and  facilitate  increased  reallocations.  

Similarly,   Gali   &   Gambetti   (2008)   find   a   significant   decline   in   the   correlations   between   output,   hours   and   labor   productivity   in   their   time   series   from   the   1960s   up   until  the  2000s  using  1984  as  a  breaking  point.  They  argue  the  correlation  change  is  due   to   more   flexible   labor   markets,   which   made   firms   more   likely   instead   of   reluctant   to   change  employment  in  reaction  to  output  changes.  Gordon  (2010)  notices  the  last  three   recessions  (1990-­‐91,  2001  and  2007-­‐2009)  have  been  followed  by  ´jobless  recoveries´.   In   these   recoveries   output   growth   was   accompanied   by   a   burst   in   labor   productivity,   although   employment   declined.   A   leading   argument   in   his   analysis   links   the   shift   to   jobless  recoveries  to  the  greater  flexibility  in  American  labor  markets.  

(9)

productivity.  The  results  show  that  labor  productivity  is  strongly  procyclical  in  terms  of   its   correlation   with   output   in   the   model   with   a   frictional   labor   market   but   its   procyclicality  reduces  substantially  as  labor  market  frictions  are  reduced.  

Van  Zandweghe  (2010)  assesses  two  explanations  for  the  shift  in  the  behaviour   of   U.S.   labor   productivity;   structural   changes   and   supply   shocks.   Supply   shocks   are   shocks  that  drive  both  output  and  productivity  in  the  same  direction,  such  as  an  oil  price   increase.  His  findings  however  suggest  the  importance  of  these  shocks  has  been  stable   over  time,  and  so  the  shift  in  the  business  cycle  behaviour  of  labor  productivity  is  due  to   structural   changes   in   the   labor   market.   These   changes   include   a   decline   in   labor   adjustment   costs   as   a   result   of   a   decline   in   hiring   and   firing   costs,   and   an   intensified   reallocation  across  industries  to  more  effectively  absorb  the  existing  labor  costs.    

Wang  (2014)  differs  in  relation  to  the  aforementioned  papers  by  using  a  cross-­‐ industry  dimension  as  an  alternative  method  to  the  much-­‐used  aggregate  time  series,  to   gain   a   better   understanding   of   the   forces   underlying   the   diminished   procyclicality   of   aggregate   productivity.   The   main   findings   are   in   line   with   the   hypothesis   that   both   internal   and   external   labor   markets   have   become   more   flexible,   reducing   the   cost   of   adjusting  and  reallocating  existing  employment.      

The  above-­‐mentioned  literature  all  share  a  common  finding:  a  reduction  in  labor   market  frictions  that  enhanced  U.S.  labor  market  flexibility.  With  the  integrated  nature   of   both   countries   it   would   be   interesting   to   investigate   how   Canadian   labor   markets   have   developed.   Given   the   declining   relative   labor   productivity,   the   vanishing   procyclicality  of  U.S.  labor  productivity  and  the  decline  in  U.S.  output  volatility,  it  seems   the  two  countries  are  diverging.  This  leads  to  the  formulation  of  the  hypothesis  that  the   United  States  and  Canada  have  diverged  in  their  structural  labor  market  flexibility  since   the  mid-­‐1980s.  

(10)

III. Assessing  how  the  business  cycle  in  the  U.S.  and  Canada  have  

evolved  

This  section  presents  the  evidence  for  the  key  changes  in  the  U.S.  and  Canadian  business   cycles   that   the   paper   seeks   to   explore.   The   goal   of   the   paper   is   to   understand   these   changes   as   related   phenomena   that   explain   the   structural   change   in   labor   market   flexibilities.   While   most   of   these   changes   have   been   previously   documented,   a   joint   explanation  is  still  lacking.    

III.1  Source  data  

Unless  otherwise  noted  the  primary  source  of  data  for  both  the  U.S.  and  Canada  is  the   WORLD  KLEMS  dataset  for  the  period  1961  up  until  2007.  A  major  advantage  is  that  it   supplies   a   rich   panel   dataset   covering   27   sectors   for   both   the   U.S.   economy   and   its   Canadian  counterpart.  The  database  has  been  set  up  to  promote  the  analysis  of  growth   and  productivity  patterns  based  on  a  growth  accounting  framework,  within  which  the   interaction  between  variables  can  be  analysed.  Specifically,  it  looks  at  the  relationships   between  productivity  and  output,  and  productivity  and  labor  inputs  measured  as  hours.   In   these   comparisons   output   is   defined   as   total   value   added   within   a   country,   hours   worked   is   total   hours   worked   by   persons   employed   and   productivity   is   measured   as   output  per  hour.  These  indicators  fluctuate  over  time  due  to  business  cycle  fluctuations   and  long-­‐term  trends.  These  long-­‐term  trends  include  gradual  increases  in  capital  stock,   technology   and   populations.   Therefore,   in   several   of   the   calculations,   these   influences   are  removed  by  using  the  statistical  Hodrick  and  Prescott  filter  (HP  filter),  which  allows   for  the  gradual  movement  in  trend  growth  rates  over  time.    

(11)

III.2  The  great  moderation    

The   first   well-­‐documented   fact   is   the   declining   volatility   of   U.S.   output.   This   decline   is   often  termed  the  Great  Moderation  (van  Zandweghe,  2010;  Garin,  Pries  &  Sims,  2013;   Gali   &   van   Rens;   2014)   and   simply   means   that   on   average,   yearly   output   growth   has   become  more  stable;  growth  has  shown  less  steep  peaks  and  troughs  opposed  to  earlier   periods.    

Macro  evidence    

Figure  2  plots  the  10-­‐year  forward  rolling  standard  deviation  of  output  for  both  the  U.S.   and  Canada.  The  figure  displays  very  well  the  U.S.  drop  in  volatility  that  occurred  in  the   mid   1980s.   Also   when   comparing   the   two   periods   on   average,   the   volatility   of   output   post-­‐1984  remains  well  below  the  heightened  levels  of  the  1970s.  This  is  not  necessarily   true   for   Canada,   where   output   volatility   shows   only   a   mild   decline   beginning   in   the   1980s,  and  even  increases  until  the  recession  in  the  beginning  of  the  1990s.    

 

Figure  2:  10-­‐year  forward  rolling  standard  deviation  of  output  

  Source:  WORLD  KLEMS  database.  Figure  shows  standard  deviations  of  output  for  both  the  US  and  Canada,  from  1961  –  2007.  

 

A  complementary  method  to  analyse  the  declining  volatility  of  output  growth  in   both   countries,   is   to   compose   a   growth   and   variance   decomposition   comparing   the   differences   in   pre-­‐   and   post-­‐1984   periods   (Stiroh,   2009).   This   method   allows   a   straightforward  quantification  of  the  different  sources  of  volatility.  Firms  can  increase   output   either   by   producing   more   output   per   hour   worked,   which   is   by   increasing  

0.00   0.50   1.00   1.50   2.00   2.50   3.00   1972   1974   1976   1978   1980   1982   1984   1986   1988   1990   1992   1994   1996   1998   2000   2002   2004   2006  

Rolling  output  volatility  

(12)

productivity,  or  by  increasing  total  hours  worked.  As  an  identity,  aggregate  output  (Y)   equals  the  product  of  hours  (H)  and  average  labor  productivity  (ALP),  defined  as  output   per  hour  worked  (y  =  ALP  =  Y/H).  The  growth  decomposition  is  the  following:  

 

𝑌 =   𝐻 +  𝑦               (1)    

where  dots  over  the  individual  letters  signify  growth  rates.    

Next  the  variance  decomposition  shows  the  breakdown  of  the  variance  of  output   growth   in   the   sum   of   the   variance   of   hours   (H),   the   variance   of   average   labor   productivity  (y)  and  twice  the  covariance.  It  indicates  to  what  extent  output  in  between   the  periods  is  influenced  by  productivity  and  hours  worked.      

 

𝑉(𝑌) = 𝑉 𝐻 + 𝑉 𝑦 +  2𝐶(𝐻, 𝑦),         (2)  

 

Where  V(⋅)  is  the  variance  and  C(⋅,⋅)  is  the  covariance  of  the  variables.      

Table  1:  Business  sector  growth  U.S.  and  Canada  

  Growth  Decomposition     Variance  Decomposition  

  Pre-­‐1984   Post-­‐1984   Change     Pre-­‐1984   Post-­‐1984   Change  

  U.S.   Output   3.23   3.04   -­‐0.19     6.01   1.92   -­‐4.09***   Hours   1.27   1.36   -­‐0.09     3.92   2.11   -­‐1.81   ALP   1.96   1.68   -­‐0.28     2.14   0.96   -­‐1.18*   2xCov(Hours,  ALP)           -­‐0.05   -­‐1.15   -­‐1.10   Corr(Hours,  ALP)           -­‐0.01   -­‐0.42   -­‐0.41     Canada   Output   4.06   2.99   -­‐1.07*     4.25   3.02   -­‐1.23   Hours   1.78   1.65   -­‐0.14     4.09   2.26   -­‐1.83   ALP   2.28   1.34   -­‐0.94**     2.25   1.05   -­‐1.20*   2xCov(Hours,  ALP)           -­‐2.09   -­‐0.30   1.79   Corr(Hours,  ALP)           -­‐0.36   -­‐0.10   0.26  

(13)

Table   1   compares   these   growth   and   variance   decompositions   for   both   the   U.S.   and   Canada,  before  and  after  the  1984  breaking  point.  The  first  thing  to  note  for  the  U.S.  is   that  there  is  no  clear  evidence  of  changes  in  mean  growth  rates  of  output,  hours  or  labor   productivity  after  1984.  The  results  show  that  U.S.  output  growth  diminished  by  -­‐0.19   between  the  years  prior  to  1984  and  the  years  after.  Canadian  output  growth  does  show   a  sharper  decline,  by  -­‐1.07,  in  which  a  decline  in  labor  productivity  by  -­‐0.94  contributes   the  most.  The  second  part  of  the  table  shows  the  variance  decompositions  of  output.  In   each   column,   the   sum   of   the   individual   variances   and   covariance   is   the   variance   of   output   given   in   the   top   row.   For   the   U.S.   the   variance   of   output   has   steeply   declined   since  1984.  It  describes  the  ‘Great  Moderation  ’and  simply  means  that  on  average,  yearly   output  growth  has  become  more  stable.  It  reflects  roughly  equal  drops  in  the  volatility  of   hours,  from  3.92  to  2.11,  the  volatility  of  labor  productivity,  from  2.14  to  0.96,  and  the   covariance  between  them,  from  -­‐0.05  to  -­‐1.15.    

The  results  for  Canada  show  that  output  volatility  has  decreased.  Both  hours  and   labor  productivity  contribute  similar  declines  as  in  the  U.S.,  -­‐1.83  and  -­‐1.20  respectively.   Judging   from   these   components   Canada   has   turned   into   a   much   more   stable   economy   with   less   fluctuations   in   the   post-­‐1984   period.   Counterbalancing   these   developments   however  is  the  covariance  between  productivity  and  hours,  which  increases  by  1.79.  It   proves  that  compared  to  the  pre-­‐1984  period,  productivity  and  hours  increasingly  show   co-­‐movements,  and  means  productivity  will  fall  with  hours  during  recessions.  It  stands   in  sharp  contrast  with  U.S.  results  in  which  the  covariance  went  in  the  opposite  direction   and  has  turned  more  negative  in  the  post-­‐1984  period.    

Lastly,   the   tables   also   display   the   correlations   between   hours   and   labor   productivity.  The  Canadian  correlation  positively  changed  by  0.26  when  comparing  the   pre-­‐1984   and   post-­‐1984   periods.   The   U.S.   correlation   on   the   other   hand   went   from   essential  zero  at  -­‐0.01  in  the  first  period  to  -­‐0.42  in  the  second.  This  indicates  the  U.S.   and  Canada  differ  in  the  linear  association  between  hours  and  productivity  over  time.  In   the  U.S.,  with  a  decrease  in  hours,  labor  productivity  will  move  in  the  opposite  direction,   positively  contributing  to  a  drop  in  output  volatility.    

Sectoral  variation  

(14)

sources  in  the  decline  of  aggregate  volatility  (Stiroh,  2009).  It  allows  an  identification  of   the  importance  of  the  variance  declines  within  industries,  so  due  to  specific  changes  in   one   industry,   and   the   importance   of   variance   declines   between   industries,   so   general   changes  that  lead  to  smaller  volatilities  among  sets  of  industries.    

According   this   composition,   aggregate   output  𝑌  can   be   defined   as   a   growth   function   of   industry   value   added  𝑉𝑖.   Growth   in   aggregate   value-­‐added   is   the   weighted   sum  of  industry  value  added  growth:  

 

𝑌 =   !𝑣!,!𝑉!             (3)    

where  𝑣!,!,   is   the   two   period   average   nominal   share   of   industry   value-­‐added   in   aggregate   value-­‐added.   Each   factor   in   the   summation   is   the   industry’s   contribution   to   aggregate  value-­‐added  growth.  The  output  factor  can  be  decomposed  into  a  contribution   from   hours   and   labor   productivity,   but   now   for   each   industry.   Labor   productivity   can   then  be  defined  as  υi  =  Vi/Hi.  The  industry  aggregate  output  growth  becomes:    

 

𝑌 =   (𝑣! !,!𝐻!) +   !𝑣!,!𝑣!           (4)    

Similar   to   table   1,   each   decomposition   of   aggregate   output   and   labor   productivity   growth   comes   with   a   variance   decomposition.   It   is   the   sum   of   the   direct   variance   contributions   from   individual   industries   and   the   sum   of   the   covariances   between   industries  and  is  defined  as:  

 

𝑉(𝑌) =   !𝑉(𝑣!,!𝑉!) +   ! !!!!!2𝐶(𝑣!,!𝑉!, 𝑣!,!𝑉!)     (5)    

The  industry  labor  productivity  decomposition  is  defined  similarly  as:    

𝑉(𝑌) =   !𝑉(𝑣!,!𝐻!) +   !𝑉(𝑣!,!𝑣!)    

     +   ! !!!!!2𝐶 𝑣!,!𝐻!,𝑣!,!𝐻! ,+ ! !!!!!2𝐶 𝑣!,!𝐻!,𝑣!,!𝑣! ,   (6)        +   ! !!!!!2𝐶 𝑣!,!𝑣!,𝑣!,!𝑣! ,    

 

(15)

all  industry  pairs.  In  this  decomposition,  the  hours/hours  and  productivity/productivity   relationships   are   strictly   between   industry   effects.   To   make   a   further   distinction,   the   hours/productivity   covariance   can   be   split   into   a   within   component   that   reflects   covariances   of   hours   and   productivity   for   a   given   industry   and   a   between   component   that  reflects  the  covariances  across  different  pairs  of  industries  as:  

 

  ! !!!2𝐶 𝑣!,!𝐻!,𝑣!,!𝑣! ,=   !2𝐶(𝑣!,!𝐻!, 𝑣!,!𝑣!)    

     +   ! !!!!!2𝐶 𝑣!,!𝐻!,𝑣!,!𝑣! ,       (7)                      =  Within  +  Between  

 

Table   2   displays   the   results.   The   top   parts   report   the   growth   decomposition   columns.   The   variance   decomposition   columns,   which   consist   of   the   sum   of   the   variances   and   covariances,  are  shown  in  the  bottom  parts  of  the  table.  For  the  variance  decomposition,   the  first  line  shows  the  total  within  effect  for  each  period,  and  the  second  the  between   effect.    

(16)

Table  2:  Growth  and  Variance  decomposition  from  industry  data  U.S.  and  Canada  

  Growth  Decomposition     Variance  Decomposition  

  Pre-­‐1984   Post-­‐1984   Change     Pre-­‐1984   Post-­‐1984   Change  

  U.S.  

Output     3.23   2.63   -­‐0.59     10.37   4.16   -­‐6.21  

Industry  output  decomposition                  

𝑉 𝑣!,!𝑉!,  =  Within           1.86   0.81   -­‐1.05  

2𝐶 𝑣!,!𝑉!,𝑣!,!𝑉! =  Between           8.51   3.35   -­‐5.16  

Industry  labor  productivity  decomposition                

𝑉 𝑣!,!𝐻!,     1.64   0.84   -­‐0.79     0.81   0.33   -­‐0.48   𝑉 𝑣!,!𝐴𝐿𝑃!,     1.59   1.79   0.20     1.73   0.83   -­‐0.91   2𝐶 𝑣!,!𝐻!,𝑣!,!𝐻!             4.93   2.47   -­‐2.46   2𝐶 𝑣!,!𝐻!,𝑣!,!𝐴𝐿𝑃! =  Within           -­‐0.68   -­‐0.35   0.33   2𝐶 𝑣!,!𝐻!,𝑣!,!𝐴𝐿𝑃!  =  Between           -­‐0.47   -­‐0.94   -­‐0.48   2𝐶 𝑣!,!𝐴𝐿𝑃!,𝑣!,!𝐴𝐿𝑃!             4.05   1.82   -­‐2.23     Canada   Output   4.05   2.77   -­‐1.28     7.02   6.54   -­‐0.48  

Industry  output  decomposition                  

𝑉 𝑣!,!𝑉!,  =  Within           0.82   0.54   -­‐0.27  

2𝐶 𝑣!,!𝑉!,𝑣!,!𝑉! =  Between           6.20   6.00   -­‐0.20  

Industry  labor  productivity  decomposition                

𝑉 𝑣!,!𝐻!,     2.02   1.22   -­‐0.80     0.71   1.19   0.48   𝑉 𝑣!,!𝐴𝐿𝑃!,     2.04   1.55   -­‐0.48     1.05   1.26   0.21   2𝐶 𝑣!,!𝐻!,𝑣!,!𝐻!             5.07   4.35   -­‐0.72   2𝐶 𝑣!,!𝐻!,𝑣!,!𝐴𝐿𝑃! =  Within           -­‐0.94   -­‐1.91   -­‐0.97   2𝐶 𝑣!,!𝐻!,𝑣!,!𝐴𝐿𝑃!  =  Between           -­‐2.39   -­‐1.78   0.61   2𝐶 𝑣!,!𝐴𝐿𝑃!,𝑣!,!𝐴𝐿𝑃!             3.52   3.42   -­‐0.09  

Note:   Decomposition   of   aggregate   output   growth   for   27   industries.   Growth   Decomposition   shows   alternative   decompositions   of   aggregate   output.   Variance   decomposition   shows   alternative   decompositions   of   aggregate   output   variance.   For   industry   sums,   V(-­‐)   indicates  the  variance  of  weighted  growth  rates,  while  C(-­‐)  indicates  the  covariance  of  the  weighted  growth  rate.  All  growth  rates  are   log  differences  of  annual  data  multiplied  by  100,  from  1961  –  1983  and  1984  –  2007.    

 

(17)

individual   contribution   of   the   hours   covariance   (-­‐0.72)   and   the   labor   productivity   covariance  (-­‐0.09),  the  between  effect  only  decreases  by  -­‐0.20.  This  is  due  to  the  fact  that   the   covariance   between   hours   and   labor   productivity   actually   increased   in   the   same   period   (0.61).   These   results   strengthen   earlier   obtained   findings   in   the   aggregate   Canadian   decomposition;   the   Canadian   drop   in   volatility   has   been   less   severe   and   the   covariance  between  hours  and  labor  productivity  display  opposing  behaviours.    

III.3  The  shift  away  from  the  procyclical  behaviour  of  productivity  

The  second  changing  factor  in  U.S.  business  cycle  fluctuations  that  points  to  structural   changes  in  the  individual  labor  markets  is  the  cyclical  behaviour  of  labor  productivity.   Until  the  mid-­‐1980s  productivity  growth  rose  and  fell  with  output  growth  and  is  said  to   have   moved   procyclical.   Since   then   however,   average   labor   productivity   has   moved   countercyclical.    

Macro  evidence  

Figure   3   plots   the   cyclical   behaviour   of   output   and   labor   productivity   for   the   U.S.   Observation   shows   that   labor   productivity   has   indeed   behaved   different   in   recent   recessions  from  the  1980s  onwards  when  compared  to  earlier  decades.    

 

Figure  3:  U.S.  cyclical  output  and  productivity  

  Source:  WORLD  KLEMS  database.  Trends  are  removed  with  the  Hodrick  and  Prescott  filter,  from  1961  –  2007.  

 

(18)

productivity  fell  as  output  dropped  and  during  recoveries  both  output  and  productivity   rose.   In   sharp   contrast   stands   the   period   after   the   mid   1980s,   in   which   cyclical   productivity   and   output   increasingly   began   to   move   in   opposite   directions.   Things   appear  different  however  in  Canada.  Figure  4   does  not  display  the  same  switch  in  the   cyclicality   of   labor   productivity.   Despite   two   exceptions   in   the   1980s   and   the   1990s   where   productivity   did   not   fall   with   output,   the   two   keep   tracking   each   other   in   their   movements.    

 

Figure  4:  Canada  cyclical  output  and  productivity  

                 

Source:  WORLD  KLEMS  database.  Trends  are  removed  with  the  Hodrick  and  Prescott  filter,  from  1961  –  2007.    

In   addition,   to   show   the   distinct   difference   in   correlation   movements,   both   U.S.   and  Canadian  developments  can  be  tracked  in  a  single  correlations  panel.  Figure  5  plots   the   10-­‐year   rolling   correlations   between   output   and   productivity.   It   distinctively   visualises   the   difference   in   the   changing   behaviour   of   productivity   between   the   two   countries.   For   the   U.S.   the   two   series   are   positively   correlated   until   the   mid   1980s.   Afterwards   this   correlation   drops   significantly   before   turning   slightly   negative   during   the   1990s.   This   pattern   is   contrastingly   different   for   Canada   where   the   correlation   increases  during  the  same  time  period.  This  marks  the  fact  that  productivity    has  began   to  move  countercyclical  in  the  U.S.  while  moving  more  procyclical  for  Canada.    

(19)

Figure  5:  Rolling  correlation  output  and  productivity  

  Source:  WORLD  KLEMS  database.  The  panel  plots  the  10-­‐year  forward  rolling  correlation  between  output  and  productivity,  

 

The  relationship  between  productivity,  output  as  well  as  hours  can  be  examined   in   more   detail.   Table   3   displays   the   correlations   between   these   variables   for   both   Canada  and  the  U.S.,  both  pre-­‐  and  post-­‐1984.  The  results  confirm  earlier  findings  that   the  correlation  between  productivity  and  output  has  improved  for  Canada  in  the  period   after  1984.  The  correlation  rose  from  0.38  in  the  former  period  to  0.50  in  the  latter.  The   rise  in  the  output-­‐productivity  correlation  reflects  a  rise  in  the  procyclical  behaviour  of   productivity.  In  addition,  the  correlations  between  productivity  and  hours,  and  output   and  hours,  showed  similar  patterns.    

 

Table  3:  Correlations  U.S.  and  Canada  

  Correlations  

  Pre-­‐1984   Post-­‐1984   Change  

  U.S.   Productivity-­‐Output   0.59***   0.27   -­‐0.32   Productivity-­‐Hours   -­‐0.01   -­‐0.42**   -­‐0.41   Output-­‐hours   0.80***   0.76***   -­‐0.04     Canada   Productivity-­‐Output   0.38*   0.50**   0.13   Productivity-­‐Hours   -­‐0.36*   -­‐0.10   0.26   Output-­‐Hours   0.73***   0.81***   0.08  

Note:  The  variables  are  expressed  in  log  growth  rates  and  approximated  by  first  difference.  The  correlation  between  two  variables  is   based  on  a  Pearson’s  correlations  test.  Significance  is  denoted  by  *  at  the  10%  level,  **  at  5%  and  ***  at  the  1%  level.    

(20)

The  U.S.  contradicts  in  its  results  as  these  correlations  have  all  weakened  over  the   same   time   period.   The   largest   decline   is   obtained   for   the   relationship   between   productivity   and   hours.   It   dropped   from   -­‐0.01   to   -­‐0.41.   Similarly,   the   correlation   between   productivity   and   output   has   decreased   from   0.59   to   0.27.   This   indicates   that   there   is   evidence   that   the   cyclical   behaviour   of   U.S.   productivity   is   changing   in   the   opposite   direction   and   highlights   another   stark   difference   between   the   two   countries.   To   support   these   findings,   the   productivity-­‐output   correlations   from   table   5   can   be   extended  to  include  a  productivity-­‐output  correlation  at  industry  levels.    

Sectoral  evidence    

Table  4  shows  the  five  largest  industries  in  terms  of  value  added  for  both  the  U.S.  and   Canada   based   on   value   added   in   the   post-­‐1984   period.   Four   out   of   five   of   the   biggest   industries  in  terms  of  value  added  in  both  countries,  all  contribute  to  the  cyclical  trend   of  labor  productivity,  countercyclical  in  the  U.S.  and  procyclical  in  Canada.  In  total  these   industries  add  up  to  48%  of  value  added  in  the  U.S.  and  41%  in  Canada.  This  proves  that   the   cyclical   behaviour   of   labor   productivity   in   each   country   is   not   due   to   one   or   two   industries,  rather  a  movement  found  across  industries.  Table  2  in  the  appendix  provides   an  extensive  overview  of  the  productivity-­‐output  correlations  per  industry.  

 

Table  4:  Productivity-­‐output  correlation  largest  industries  

  U.S.   Canada  

  Pre-­‐1984   Post-­‐1984     Pre-­‐1984   Post1-­‐984    

Industry   Corr  (1)   VA   Corr  (2)   VA   Change   (2)–(1)  

(21)

IV. Labor  market  flexibility    

So  far  this  paper  has  provided  evidence  on  two  business  cycle  indicators  that  changed   around  the  mid  1980s.  Output  volatility  has  dropped  for  the  U.S.  while  it  only  slightly   decreased   for   Canada.   Additionally,   labor   productivity   in   both   countries   has   shown   opposing  results,  moving  countercyclical  in  the  U.S.  while  moving  procyclical  in  Canada.   The   main   purpose   in   what   follows   is   to   investigate   the   relation   between   these   developments   and   structural   changes   in   labor   market   flexibility.   Although   there   are   many   factors   having   an   influence   on   the   business   cycle   developments,   such   as   an   increase   in   the   use   of   capital   (Pessoa   &   van   Reenen,   2014)   and   technology   (Gali   &   Gambetti,   2008),   the   average   share   of   labor   in   output   throughout   the   entire   period   considered   in   this   paper   is   well   above   60%.1  Therefore   it   remains   interesting   to   investigate  the  role  of  labor  in  output  and  productivity  fluctuations.    

Flexibility  in  the  context  of  labor  markets  can  have  multiple  interpretations.  This   paper   makes   a   distinction   between   macro   and   micro   flexibility   as   in   Eamets   &   Paas   (2007).   In   the   macroeconomic   context,   flexibility   concerns   institutional   flexibility   to   show   to   what   extent   state   institutions   are   involved   in   the   regulation   of   labor   markets   (Eamets   &   Paas,   2007).   It   covers   labor   market   regulations   and   trade   union   activity.   Micro   flexibility   is   the   labor   market’s   ability   to   carry   out   the   reallocation   of   workers   needed  for  productivity  growth.  It  involves  labor  flows  indicating  worker  flows  between   different  labor  market  states  in  terms  of  employment,  and  job  flows  characterised  by  job   creation   and   job   destruction   (Eamets   &   Paas,   2007).   This   section   outlines   the   main   structural  differences  that  caused  the  diverging  gap  in  U.S.  and  Canadian  labor  markets.    

IV.1  Institutional  environment  

The   first   explanation   relates   to   the   institutional   framework   that   creates   labor   market   regulations  and  policies.  Legal  restrictions  exist  on  adjusting  the  level  and  composition   of  the  workforce  to  adapt  to  changing  demand.  It  prohibits  firms  from  sudden  hiring  and   firing  of  employees  during  cyclical  downturns,  with  the  aim  of  preserving  individual  job   security.   The   legislative   protection   therefore   has   important   consequences   for   the   flexibility   and   freedom   with   which   it   allows   employers   to   adjust   employment   for   changes   in   demand.   (Lammam   &   Macintyre,   2014).   According   OECD   statistics   the                                                                                                                  

(22)

Canadian  and  U.S.  institutional  framework  can  be  described  as  flexible  and  very  similar,   especially   when   compared   to   other   OECD   nations   (Gordon,   2011;   OECD   Employment   Outlook,   2013).   A   separation   can   be   made   however   between   flexibility   concerning   employment  protection  legislation  and  the  involvement  of  trade  unions.  

Employment  protection  legislation  

Employment  protections  legislations  (EPL)  govern  the  rules  concerning  the  hiring  and   firing  of  workers  (OECD  Employment  Outlook,  2013).  These  rules  have  been  designed  to   protect   jobs   and   increase   job   stability   for   employees.   Hence,   EPL’s   raise   the   costs   of   workforce   adjustments   by   distorting   the   optimal   composition   of   employment   and   pushes   firms   to   use   resources   less   efficiently.   Recent   research   on   the   labor   market   impact  of  employment  protection  has  found  that  overly  strict  regulations  can  reduce  job   flows  and  hinder  productivity  and  economic  growth  (Bassanini,  Nunziata  &  Venn,  2009;   Martin  &  Scarpetta,  2012).    

Measured  on  a  scale  from  1  to  6,  both  the  U.S.  and  Canada  are  characterized  by  a   system  that  combines  little  protection  for  individual  workers  in  comparison  with  OECD   averages.   For   the   protection   of   permanent   workers,   0.26   for   the   U.S.   and   0.92   for   Canada,   as   well   as   the   protection   of   temporary   workers,   0.25   in   both   countries,   the   strictness   is   well   below   OECD   averages   of   2.04   and   2.29   respectively   (OECD   stat   extracts,   2013a;   OECD   stat   extracts,   2013b).   Further   EPL   indicators   as   notification   procedures   and   severance   pay   are   similar   to   the   dismissal   indicators   in   that   they   are   well  below  OECD  averages  for  both  the  U.S.  and  Canada,  but  also  in  that  they  have  not   changed  since  the  mid-­‐1980s.  Hence,  this  might  indicate  the  U.S.  and  Canada  are  more   flexible   in   comparison   with   other   developed   nations,   but   a   relative   lack   of   change   between  the  U.S.  and  Canada  can  therefore  hardly  be  presented  as  evidence  in  favour  of   structural  flexibility  divergence.    

Trade  unions  

(23)

labor  market  and  stronger  reductions  in  the  procyclicality  of  productivity.  A  decline  in   union   membership   would   therefore   signify   a   loss   of   union   power,   which   had   to   allow   employment   layoffs   more   readily   in   recent   times.   The   increase   in   layoffs   explains   the   countercyclical  behaviour  of  U.S.  labor  productivity.    

As   can   be   seen   from   figure   6,   trade   union   density   has   dropped   in   the   U.S.   in   comparison   with   Canada.   Trade   union   density   is   measured   as   the   percentage   of   wage   and   salary   workers   who   are   union   members,   divided   by   the   total   number   of   salary   earners.  While  trade  union  density  for  both  countries  was  almost  equal  in  the  beginning   of  the  1970s,  the  rates  in  2007  were  just  over  10%  for  the  U.S  and  almost  three  times  as   high   for   Canada.   Additionally,   in   a   direct   comparison   between   the   U.S.   and   Canada,   Lammam   &   Macintyre   (2014)   show   that   Canadian   labor   relation   laws   are   much   less   balanced   and   flexible   than   their   U.S.   counterparts.   These   laws   are   included   in   union   contracts  to  balance  the  needs  of  employers,  employees  and  unions  but  thereby  hinder   the  proper  functioning  of  a  labor  market  and  its  performance  in  terms  of  productivity.    

 

Figure  6:  Trade  union  density  (in  %  of  total  employees)  

  Source:  OECD  stat  extracts  2013c,  from  1960–  2007.  

 

IV.2  Labor  market  reallocation  

The   second   explanation   for   the   diverging   flexibility   gap   relates   to   the   reallocation   of   workers   and   jobs   across   industries.   The   functioning   of   labor   markets   involves   a   continuous  shifting  of  labor  across  firms  and  sectors.  It  however  involves  costs  for  firms,   as  it  is  a  resource-­‐intensive  and  costly  process  to  open  and  fill  new  vacancies.  Similarly,  

(24)

switching   from   and   searching   for   new   jobs   is   costly   and   time   consuming   for   workers   (Martin  &  Scarpetta,  2012).  Therefore,  rates  of  worker-­‐  and  job  flows  indicate  the  ease   with   which   workers   are   able   to   reallocate,   and   the   ease   with   which   firms   are   able   to   adjust   their   labor   force.   If   workers   are   more   easily   reallocated   from   declining   to   expanding   firms   and   industries   it   is   an   important   factor   influencing   productivity   and   output  growth  (Eamets  &  Paas,  2007;  Martin  &  Scarpetta,  2012;  Garin  et  al,  2013).  

Worker  flows  

Worker   flows   relate   to   all   transitions   between   the   various   states   of   the   labor   market:   employment,   unemployment   and   the   total   labor   force   (Eamets   &   Paas,   2007).   The   transitions   are   measured   through   the   unemployment,   employment   and   labor   force   participation  rates  as  given  by  the  U.S.  and  Canadian  household  surveys.  An  overview  of   these   rates   indicates   to   what   extent   the   labor   market   is   capable   of   employing   all   workers,   especially   during   downturns.   A   key   feature   of   downturns   is   an   increased   mismatch  between  workers  and  jobs.  Reallocation  helps  to  solve  this  mismatch  and  so   plays  a  key  role  in  the  recovery  from  a  recession  and  in  understanding  the  flexibility  of  a   labor  market  (Garin  et  al.,  2013).    

  The   development   of   these   three   rates   over   the   post-­‐1984   period   points   to   two   important   findings   (Appendix;   figures   1,   2   and   3).   The   first   is   that   the   higher   U.S.   employment  and  participation  rates  signify  more  labor  market  flexibility.  The  traditional   explanation  comes  from  Lazear  (1990)  who  argues  that  countries  with  less  flexible  labor   markets   simply   have   less   suitable   employment   for   workers   who   become   unemployed.   As   a   consequence   workers   drop   out   of   the   labor   force,   leading   to   lower   participation   rates.  Di  Tella  &  MacCulloch  (2005)  support  this  theory  by  arguing  higher  participation   rates   are   reached   through   a   lack   of   an   insurance   effect.   If   less   regulation   means   more   layoffs,   the   risk   of   losing   income   becomes   greater.   The   lack   of   such   wage   insurance   makes  workers  in  flexible  labor  markets  more  inclined  to  participate.    

(25)

Additional  evidence  on  the  flexibility  of  worker  flows  is  based  on  the  share  of  long-­‐term   unemployment   in   total   unemployment.   As   stricter   labor   markets   are   associated   with   lower  job  flows  in  and  out  of  employment  (Eamets  &  Paas,  2007)  unemployed  periods   tend   to   last   longer   (OECD   employment   outlook,   1996).   This   has   an   impact   on   worker   reallocation,   as   long-­‐term   unemployed   are   different   from   the   rest   of   the   unemployed   labor   force.   First,   they   have   a   lower   chance   of   exiting   unemployment,   and   second   the   chance   of   exiting   unemployment   declines   with   the   duration   of   being   unemployed   (Hornstein,   2012).   A   larger   share   of   long-­‐term   unemployed   workers   therefore   negatively  impacts  the  ease  of  reallocation  from  declining  to  growing  industries.  If  U.S.   workers   circulate   through   existing   jobs   faster,   the   share   of   long   term   unemployed   in   total  unemployment  should  be  lower.  

  Figure  7  displays  the  share  of  long-­‐term  unemployment  in  total  unemployment   for   the   period   1984   up   until   2007.   Long-­‐term   unemployment   is   defined   as   being   unemployed  for  6  months  or  more.  It  displays  the  U.S.  long-­‐term  unemployment  share  is   consistently   lower   than   its   Canadian   equivalent   for   a   majority   of   the   post-­‐1984   time   period.  This  indicates  larger  shares  of  the  Canadian  unemployed  have  more  difficulty  in   finding  new  jobs  and  suggests  less  flexibility.    

 

Figure  7:  Long-­‐term  unemployment  (in  %  of  total)  

  Source:  U.S.  (BLS)  and  Canadian  (LFS)  household  survey,  from  1984  –  2007  

(26)

Job  flows  

Another  way  of  accounting  for  reallocation  flexibility  is  by  looking  at  job  flows.  Greater   job  flows  are  associated  with  more  flexibility,  as  it  indicates  firms  are  more  easily  firing   workers,   and   workers   are   more   easily   finding   jobs   (Eamets   &   Paas,   2007).   Following   research  by  Shimer  (2012),  two  indicators  can  be  identified  to  support  this  argument;   the  rate  of  job  creation  and  the  rate  of  job  destruction.  Job  creation  and  job  destruction   can  be  measured  as  the  job  finding  and  job  separation  probabilities.    

 

Figure  8:  Job  finding  probability  

Source:  U.S.  (BLS)  and  Canadian  (LFS)  household  survey,  from  1976  –  2007.    

Figure  9:  Job  separation  probability  

(27)

Figure  8  and  9  display  both  probabilities  for  the  U.S.  and  Canada.  It  reveals  the  U.S.  job   finding  probability  has  been  much  higher  throughout  the  period.  Although  the  Canadian   job  finding  probability  is  on  a  clear  upward  trend,  it  only  converges  with  the  U.S.  rate   during  the  early  2000s.  A  contrasting  result  from  the  separation  probability  is  that  it  is   actually  higher  for  Canada  in  a  majority  of  the  time  period.  Shimer  (2012)  however  finds   that  up  to  90%  of  employment  fluctuations  were  a  consequence  of  movements  in  the  job   finding  probability.  

Further  evidence  on  job  flows  derives  from  the  nature  of  layoffs.  Layoffs  can  be   temporary   and   permanent.   Temporary   layoffs   account   for   furloughed   employees   who   stay   at   home   because   an   employer   does   not   have   enough   work   (Groshen   &   Potter,   2003).   Permanent   layoffs   however   measure   the   amount   of   employees   who   have   lost   their  jobs  and  are  not  returning  to  the  same  firm.  An  increase  in  the  relative  importance   of  permanent  layoffs  is  consistent  with  the  idea  that  it  became  easier  to  fire  workers.      

Figure  10:  U.S.  and  Canada  permanent  and  temporary  unemployment  rates  (in  %)  

  Source:  U.S.  (BLS)  and  Canadian  (LFS)  household  survey,  from  1976  –  2007.  

 

Figure   10   displays   the   contribution   of   both   types   of   layoffs   to   each   of   the   total   unemployment  rates.  A  distinctive  characteristic  for  the  U.S.  is  the  disappearing  share  of   temporary   layoffs   in   the   post-­‐1984   period.   Before   1984   both   the   temporary   and   permanent   unemployment   rates   rose   during   recessions.   After   1984   temporary   layoffs   barely  increased,  while  the  burst  of  permanent  layoffs  remained  large.  This  may  suggest   U.S.  firms  have  increasingly  started  to  rely  on  permanent  layoffs.  In  Canada  on  the  other  

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

Tables 5 and 6 show the coefficient estimates and t-values of the equally weighted WLS regression for the different portfolios. First of all, the acquisitive portfolio in

In line 7 grande locuturi refers directly to the high genres of epic and tragedy (Conington 1874:84; Némethy 1903:237) although grandis seems to have been poetic jargon at Rome in

experiments it could be concluded that two types of acid sites are present in H-ZSM-5: Weak acid sites corresponding with desorption at low temperature and small

We aim to contribute to an (i) understanding on how in-network processing can accelerate real-time data analytics and (ii) assess what models of in-network computing can

The knowledge on the dynamics of the NGS disease between cultivated and wild grasses and its host range will contribute to the development of management approaches for

Hypothesis 2: implicit CSR (Personal values and norms of leaders) and the corresponding emergent authentic leadership style exists in the organization and is necessary for

Een veldexperiment (studie 2) toonde aan dat priming met de Schijf van Vijf niet leidde tot minder ongezonde of meer gezonde voedingsaankopen door consumenten in de

Effect of follicle size on bovine oocyte quality and development competence following maturation, fertilization and culture in vitro. Commercial aspects of oocyte