• No results found

“THE IMPACT OF TRUST, INTERDEPENDENCE AND POWER ON THE INTERACTION BETWEEN RELATIONAL AND CONTRACTUAL GOVERNANCE IN BUYER-SUPPLIER RELATIONSHIPS” 6 of July 2015

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "“THE IMPACT OF TRUST, INTERDEPENDENCE AND POWER ON THE INTERACTION BETWEEN RELATIONAL AND CONTRACTUAL GOVERNANCE IN BUYER-SUPPLIER RELATIONSHIPS” 6 of July 2015"

Copied!
43
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

“THE IMPACT OF TRUST, INTERDEPENDENCE AND

POWER ON THE INTERACTION BETWEEN

RELATIONAL AND CONTRACTUAL GOVERNANCE IN

BUYER-SUPPLIER RELATIONSHIPS”

6

th

of July 2015

Author: Hazar Turkmen

Studentnr: S1895273

Tel: +31(0)648245088

h.turkmen@student.rug.nl

Master thesis MSc. Supply Chain Management

First Supervisor: Prof. Dr. Ir. Kees Ahaus

Second assessor: Dr. J.T. van der Vaart

University of Groningen, Faculty of Economics and Business

P.O. Box 800, 9700 AZ Groningen

 

 

Acknowledgements:  My  gratitude  goes  to  everyone  who  were  part  of  this  thesis,   from  company  representatives  who  participated  to  fellow  group  students  Derk   and  Arjen,  who  made  this  period  more  fun  and  especially  my  family  who   provided  unconditional  support  during  good  and  bad  times.  I  would  like  to   specially  thank  my  supervisor  for  his  useful  comments  and  guidance  throughout   the  thesis,  giving  me  the  confidence  and  motivation  to  achieve  my  objectives.      

(2)

Abstract:  

 

Purpose-­‐  This  thesis  is  aimed  towards  enhancing  the  understanding  of  the  

interaction  between  relational  and  contractual  governance  with  trust,   interdependence  and  power  as  influencing  factors.  

Design/methodology/approach-­‐  An  explorative  multiple-­‐case  study  is  

conducted  and  four  cases  are  selected  from  the  metal  assembly  and  processing   industry  in  the  Netherlands.  

Findings-­‐   The   interaction   of   relational   and   contractual   governance   is  

complementary,   because   trust   overcomes   the   rigidness   of   contracts   and   contracts   reduce   ambiguity   created   through   informal   mechanisms.   Interdependence   positively   moderates   the   relationship   between   relational   and   contractual   governance   but   the   negative   understanding   of   interdependence   by   managers  limits  this  interaction.  Finally,  power  imbalances  undermine  trust  and   commitment  and  imbalanced  relationships  therefore  lack  the  appropriate  setting   for  relational  governance  to  complement  contracts.    

Practical  implications-­‐  Results  indicate  that  the  interaction  between  relational  

governance   and   contractual   governance   is   volatile   and   complex.   An   enhanced   understanding  can  help  managers  in  making  appropriate  governance  decisions,   saving  costs  and  creating  synergies.    

Originality/value-­‐  This  study  is  the  first  study  to  incorporate  interdependence  

and   power   into   the   discussion   of   relational   and   contractual   governance.   In   addition,  this  study  is  one  of  the  few  studies  that  provide  empirical  evidence  for   the  interaction  between  relational  and  contractual  governance.    

(3)

Contents  

1.  Introduction  ...  3  

2.  Theoretical  background  ...  5  

2.1  Inter-­‐organizational  relationships  ...  5  

2.2  Interdependence  and  power  ...  8  

3.      Methodology  ...  10  

3.1  Sample  selection  ...  11  

3.2  Data  collection  ...  12  

3.3  Development  interview  protocol  and  document  study

 ...  13  

3.4  Data  analysis  ...  14  

4.Results  ...  16  

4.1  Within-­‐case  analysis  ...  16  

4.2  Cross-­‐case  analysis  ...  Error!  Bookmark  not  defined.  

5.Discussion.  ...  27  

6.  Conclusion  ...  31  

References  ...  33  

Appendix  I:  Interview  protocol  ...  38  

Appendix  II:  Document  study  ...  39  

(4)

1.  Introduction  

 

(5)

contractual   governance.     We   have   chosen   interdependence   and   power   because   these   concepts   are   found   to   significantly   impact   the   management   of   a   buyer-­‐ supplier   relationship   and   therefore   have   the   potential   to   reveal   how   relational   and   contractual   governance   interact,   given   a   certain   dependency   or   power   position   in   a   relationship   (Anderson   and   Weitz,   1989;   Wagner   and   Johnson,   2004;   Caniels   and   Gelderman,   2007).   From   a   perspective   wherein   power   (im)   balances  and  mutual  dependencies  explain  the  causes  and  effects  on  governance   types,  we  contribute  to  the  body  of  literature  on  buyer-­‐supplier  relationships  by   adding   new   variables   to   the   framework   of   Cao   and   Lumineau   (2015)   to   better   understand  how  relational  and  contractual  governance  interact.    

 

Alongside  interdependence  and  power,  special  attention  is  paid  to  the  concept  of   trust  since  there  is  an  increased  ambiguity  of  how  trust  is  perceived  and  actually   adopted   in   practice   (Donney   and   Cannon,   1997;   Johnston   et   al.   2004).   More   importantly,  by  closely  examining  the  role  of  trust  in  a  relationship  we  hope  to   find   the   underlying   mechanisms   of   trust   that   lead   to   a   substitution   or   complementary  effect  on  contracts.  Contractual  governance  is  indicated  through   the  extensive  use  of  contracts  and  monitoring  efforts  (Sako,  1992).  In  the  end,  we   shed   light   on   the   discussion   of   relational   and   contractual   governance   as   substitutes  or  complements  by  incorporating  the  influence  of  interdependence,   power  and  trust  to  the  model.  We  do  this  by  answering  the  following  research   question:    

 

How  do  trust,  interdependence  and  power  influence  the  emergence  and  interaction   of  relational  and/or  contractual  governance  in  buyer-­‐supplier  relationships?    

After  having  answered  the  research  question  we  fill  the  gap  in  literature  by:     a)   Providing   empirical   evidence   for   the   interaction   between   relational   and   contractual   governance   from   an   interdependence   and   power   perspective   and   hence  react  to  the  lack  of  empirical  data  and  incompleteness  on  the  influence  of   external  factors  on  these  governance  mechanisms  in  literature.    

b)   Depicting   when   and   how   trust   substitutes   or   complements   contractual   governance  and  identify  the  conditions  for  this  effect  with  data  from  practice  and   therefore   eliminate   some   of   the   ambiguity   on   the   role   of   trust   as   being   a   substitute  or  complementary  to  contracts.    

 

(6)

the   findings   to   the   findings   in   literature   and   a   conclusion   is   drawn   at   the   very   end  with  managerial  implications  and  the  contribution  to  academic  literature.      

 

2.  Theoretical  background    

 

In  the  theoretical  background  we  dive  into  literature  and  establish  a  conceptual   structure  for  the  analysis  in  order  to  answer  our  research  question.  First  we   distinguish  two  types  of  inter-­‐organizational  relationships,  which  characterize   relational  governance  and  contractual  governance.  This  is  necessary  in  order  to   understand  how  these  two  mechanisms  differ  from  each  other  but  also  to   identify  conditions  where  they  can  substitute  or  complement  each  other.  The   concept  of  trust  is  included  in  the  theory  of  relational  governance,  because  trust   is  the  main  component  of  this  relationship  type.  Subsequently,  literature  on   interdependence  and  power  are  depicted  to  understand  why  these  concepts  are   interrelated  and  how  this  influences  the  buyer-­‐supplier  relationship.    

2.1  Inter-­‐organizational  relationships  

 

Many   different   types   of   inter-­‐organizational   relationships   exist   between   firms   that   exchange   resources   and   information.   These   relationships   are   also   recognized   as   buyer-­‐supplier,   customer-­‐distributor   or   customer-­‐supplier   relationships  but  for  the  sake  of  simplicity  this  paper  will  use  the  buyer-­‐supplier   concept.    Most  of  these  inter-­‐organizational  relationships  can  be  categorized  into   two   different   types:   Arm’s   Length   Contractual   Relation   (ACR)   and   Obligational   Contractual   Relation   (OCR)   (Sako,   1992).   A   typical   ACR   is   managed   by   explicit   contracts   that   contain   each   party’s   tasks   and   duties   in   every   conceivable   eventuality.   Unforeseen   contingencies   are   resolved   with   legal   actions   or   normative   rules.   The   high   level   of   contractual   governance   in   this   relationship   may   reduce   opportunism   and   safeguard   inter-­‐organizational   relationships   (Williamson,  1985).    ACRs  have  independence  as  a  guiding  principle,  which  often   requires   not   disclosing   much   information   to   existing   and   potential   buyers   and   suppliers.  This  strategy  enables  firms  to  obtain  competitive  prices  through  hard   negotiations   and   by   exploiting   a   position   of   power.   However,   contracts   are   subject   to   some   limitations   (Sako,   1992).   First,   a   contract   may   be   incomplete   because  of  human  being’s  bounded  rationality  and  can  therefore  leave  space  for   opportunistic  behaviour  on  unanticipated  events  or  clauses  (Lewis  and  Roehrich,   2009;  Luo,  2002).  Second,  people  may  perceive  contracts  as  a  lack  of  trust,  which   can  harm  a  cooperative  relationship  (Poppo  and  Zenger,  2002).  Third,  a  possible   mismatch   can   occur   in   contract   application   wherein   one   contracting   partner   uses  contract  terms  more  rigidly  and  the  other  uses  the  terms  more  flexibly.  The   mismatch  in  interpretation  and/or  application  is  likely  to  cause  conflicts.  These   limitations   constrain   the   effective   use   of   contractual   governance   in   inter-­‐ organizational  relationships  (Cao  and  Lumineau,  2015).    

   

(7)

process  that  stimulates  both  parties  to  deviate  from  the  contract  specifications   and   to   do   more   than   expected   by   the   trading   partner.   Trust   refers   to   the   partner’s  integrity,  credibility  and  benevolence  in  a  risky  exchange  environment.   (Zaheer  et  al.,  1998,  Cao  and  Lumineau,  2015).  In  an  environment  of  high  mutual   trust,   partners   are   less   likely   to   exploit   any   adverse   situation   because   they   consider   their   partner’s   interests   as   much   as   they   do   their   own.   Based   on   this   construct,  trust  acts  as  a  mechanism  on  its  own  to  reduce  opportunism  (Liu  et  al.,   2009).   Furthermore,   the   incentive   that   the   act   of   goodwill   is   likely   to   trigger   a   similar  response  from  the  trading  partner  can  result  in  major  cost  reductions  or   create   an   idiosyncratic   relationship   that   is   difficult   to   imitate   for   competitors   (Dyer  and  Singh,  1998;  Sako,1992).  However,  it  should  be  noted  that  OCRs  take   substantial   time   and   resources   to   develop.   They   are   also   more   exposed   to   opportunism  due  to  its  ambiguous  nature  (Cannon  et  al.,  2000;  Dyer  and  Singh,   1998).    Therefore,  one  should  choose  carefully  choose  with  whom  to  engage  in   an  OCR,  considering  both  the  opportunities  and  risks  that  come  along  in  this  type   of  governance.    

 

Another   discussion   is   raised   to   answer   whether   these   two   interorganizational   relationships  are  substitutes  or  if  they  can  complement  each  other  (Poppo  and   Zenger,  2002;  Cao  and  Lumineau,  2015).  More  specifically,  they  are  substitutes   when   the   use   of   one   governance   type   decreases   the   use   or   the   benefits   of   the   other.   The   governance   types   complement   each   other   when   the   use   of   one   increases  the  use  or  the  benefits  of  the  other  (Huber  et  al.,  2013;  Liu  et  al.,  2009).   Proponents   of   a   substitutive   relationship   between   contracts   and   relational   governance   have   implicitly   focused   on   the   control   function   of   contracts.   As   a   result,   the   main   assumption   that   contracts   are   solely   a   controlling   mechanism   enforcing  partners  to  behave  appropriately  evokes  the  question  of  the  partners’   good  intentions.  However,  the  coordination  function  of  contracts  may  not  signal   a   lack   of   trust   but   a   commitment   to   the   relationship.   A   coordinating   function   facilitates   mutual   understanding   and   trust,   allowing   contracts   to   support   relational   governance   (Cao   and   Lumineau,   2015;   Ryall   and   Sampson,   2009).   Poppo  and  Zenger  (2002)  initially  raised  the  discussion  of  relational  governance   being  a  substitute  or  complementary  to  contractual  governance.  They  provide  a   conceptual   framework   that   represents   the   interaction   of   the   two   mechanisms   (See  figure  1.)  According  to  their  findings,  contractual  governance  was  found  to   complement   relational   governance   as   contract   complexity   increases,   because   customized   contracts   specify   contingencies,   adaptive   processes   and   controls   likely   to   mitigate   opportunistic   behaviour   and   thereby   support   relational   governance.  In  addition,  relational  governance  complements  the  adaptive  limits   of  contracts  by  fostering  continuance  of  the  exchange  and  entrusting  both  parties   with  mutually  agreeable  outcomes  (Poppo  and  Zenger,  2002).    

(8)

 

Figure  1:  Conceptual  model  of  Poppo  and  Zenger  (2002)  on  the  interaction  of  relational  governance   and  contractual  governance  

Cao  and  Lumineau  (2005)  have  revisited  this  discussion  and  focused  on  external   factors  to  better  explain  the  dynamics  of  the  interaction  between  relational  and   contractual  governance.  The  mutual  relationship  between  the  two  is  negatively   moderated  by  the  legal  system  and  power  distance  but  positively  moderated  by   collectivism.  Informal  mechanisms  are  encouraged  and  more  widely  accepted  in   collectivist   countries   as   China,   fostering   more   relational   governance   (Zhou   and   Poppo,   2010;   Wuyts   and   Geyskens,   2005)   Vertical   inter-­‐organizational   relationships   advance   the   complementarity   of   relational   and   contractual   governance,  because  the  higher  interdependence  in  these  relationships  requires   more   information   sharing   and   mutual   adjustments   (Burkert   et   al.,   2012;   Rindfleisch,   2000;   Krishnan   et   al.,   2006).   Finally,   relationship   length   positively   moderates   the   relationships   between   contractual   and   relational   governance,   because   short-­‐term   partners   rely   more   heavily   on   calculative   logic   and   use   contracts   to   control   opportunism.   Long-­‐term   partners   give   each   party   enough   time  to  get  to  know  each  other  and  develop  trust,  which  complements  contracts   through  its  coordinating  and  adaptation  functions  (Talay  and  Akdeniz,  2014;  Cao   and   Lumineau,   2015).   The   conceptual   model   of   Cao   and   Lumineau   (2015)   is   shown  in  figure  2.    

 

712 L. Poppo and T. Zenger

Relational Governance Customized Contracts Exchange Performance + or − + or − Notes:

+ = Positive relationship, support for Complements (H4a, H4b) − = Negative relationship, support for Substitutes (H3a, H3b)

Exchange Hazards IT Size Managerial Experience Previous Business Relations

Figure 1. Empirical Model effect on performance exists if both relational

gov-ernance and contract complexity positively influ-ence performance, but negatively influinflu-ence one another.

Following from the above arguments, we hypo-thesize (see Figure 1):

Hypothesis 3a: Increases in contractual com-plexity discourage the formation of relational governance.

Hypothesis 3b: Increases in relational gover-nance discourage the use of complex contracts. Hypothesis 3c: Contractual complexity and rela-tional governance will function as substitutes in explaining exchange performance.

RELATIONAL GOVERNANCE AND FORMAL CONTRACTS AS

COMPLEMENTS

Despite compelling arguments for viewing rela-tional governance and contractual complexity as substitutes, the logic for viewing them as com-plements appears equally compelling. In settings where hazards are severe, the combination of for-mal and inforfor-mal safeguards may deliver greater exchange performance than either governance

choice in isolation. The presence of clearly artic-ulated contractual terms, remedies, and processes of dispute resolution as well as relational norms of flexibility, solidarity, bilateralism, and continuance may inspire confidence to cooperate in interorga-nizational exchanges.

We noted earlier that economic models of rela-tional governance (Klein, 1996; Baker et al., 2002) highlight the role of simple repeated ex-change in motivating long-term cooperation. In such models the expected pay-offs from a pattern of future exchange deters the pursuit of short-run gains that undermine the longevity of the relationship. Contracts not only have this source of advantage because of their formal specifica-tion of a long-term commitment to exchange, but through clearly articulated clauses that specify punishments they also limit the gains from oppor-tunistic behavior. This reduction in short-run gains heightens comparatively the gains from cooper-ating in the exchange relationship. By contrast, failing to contractually specify elements of the exchange that are easily specified merely height-ens incentives for short-run cheating and low-ers expectations of cooperation (Baker, Gibbons and Murphy, 1994). Thus, the specification of contractual safeguards promotes expectations that the other party will behave cooperatively and thus complements the informal limits of relational

(9)

  8  

 

Figure  2:  Conceptual  model  of  Cao  and  Lumineau  (2015)  with  external  factors  moderating  the   relationship  between  relational  and  contractual  governance  

2.2  Interdependence  and  power  

 

Mutual   dependence   and   power   are   closely   related   concepts.   The   supplier’s   dependence   on   the   buyer   is   a   source   of   power   for   the   buyer,   and   vice   versa   (Caniels   and   Gelderman,   2007).   In   asymmetric   relationships,   the   most   independent   partner   dominates   the   relationship,   whereas   in   balanced   relationships   neither   party   is   dominated   (Buchanan,   1992).   Asymmetry   in   this   respect  refers  to  the  difference  between  the  two  partner’s  levels  of  dependence.   Buyer-­‐supplier  relationships  that  are  characterized  by  power  imbalances  tend  to   be  deficient,  because  the  independent  party  experiences  high  power  and  might   be  attempted  to  exploit  it  (McDonald,  1999).  However,  unbalanced  relationships   do  not  automatically  lead  to  misuses  in  power.  Besides  relative  interdependence   dyadic   relationships   also   include   total   interdependence   (Geyskens   et   al.,1996;   Kumar   et   al.,   1995).   Total   interdependence   refers   to   the   intensity   of   a   relationship.   Such   interdependence   indicates   a   strong,   cooperative   long-­‐term   relationship,  in  which  both  parties  have  invested  (Caniels  and  Gelderman,  2007).   Mutual   trust   and   mutual   commitment   are   the   drivers   that   enhance   these   relationships   (Geyskens   et   al.,   1996).   Consequently,   the   probability   that   either   party  acts  opportunistically  due  to  its  high  power  is  quite  low,  because  the  risk  of   retaliation   is   considered   to   be   high   (Ramsay,   1996).   Additionally,   a   high   total   interdependence   in   the   relationship   leaves   partners   with   high   exit   barriers,   making   them   reluctant   in   taking   advantage   from   each   other   (Geyskens   et   al.,   1996).   After   having   identified   the   two   dimensions   in   interdependence,   relative   and   total,   the   next   step   is   to   describe   concepts   that   determine   dependence.   According   to   Caniels   and   Gelderman   (2007),   all   empirical   studies   highlight   ‘importance’   and   ‘substitutability’   as   concepts   that   determine   dependence.   Empirics   have   shown   that   importance   is   found   to   have   a   positive   relationship   with   dependence   and   substitutability   constitutes   a   negative   relationship.   Importance  can  refer  to  the  financial  magnitude  or  the  criticality  of  the  specific   item  on  firm  performance.  If  one  of  these  attributes  is  high,  the  company  will  act   on  a  strategic  level,  knowing  that  a  small  change  can  have  a  big  impact  on  results.  

22 Z.Cao,F.Lumineau/JournalofOperationsManagement33–34(2015)15–42

Fig.2. Factorsmoderatingtheinterplayofcontractualandrelationalgovernance.

numberof empiricalstudiesoncontractualandrelational gover-nancesurges,seeFig.1)(Changet al.,2009).7 Wefound another

setof170articlesoncontractualorrelationalgovernance.Fourth, wemanuallysearchedthereferencelistsofhighly-citedandnewly published studies such as Huber et al. (2013), Jayaraman et al. (2013), Liuet al.(2009), Yanget al.(2012), andZhouandPoppo (2010)tocheckifanystudycouldhavebeen lostintheprevious searchprocess.Wefound27additionalarticlesthatwerenot iden-tifiedintheprevioussteps. Finally,weemailed theauthorswho didnotreportacorrelationmatrixandaskedthemtoprovidethe matrixandtheirunpublishedstudies,ifany,onthistopicforus. Anotherfivearticleswereprovided.Insum,afterthesefivesteps, weretrievedatotalof3894articles.

We set up threeinclusion criteria to selectstudies (Heugens andLander,2009;Jiang et al.,2012).8 Theselected studies must

havemettherequirementsofallcriteria.Ifonestudyviolatedany ofthesecriteria,itwasexcluded fromfurtheranalysis.Ourthree criteriawereasfollows:first,theunitofanalysisofselected stud-iesmust havebeen aninterorganizational dyad. 3349articlesat theorganization(e.g.,Cruzetal.,2010;Gomez-Mejiaetal.,2001; RedikerandSeth,1995;Tosietal.,1997),team(e.g.,Chatmanand Flynn,2001;DeJongandElfring,2010),andindividuallevel(e.g.,

MalhotraandMurnighan,2002;McAllister,1995;Rajaetal.,2004) wereexcluded and 545 articles remained. Second, the selected studies must have been empirical and report at least one cor-relationbetweencontractual governance, relational governance, performance,andopportunism.Non-empiricalstudiessuchascase studies(e.g.,Faemsetal.,2008;Huberetal.,2013;Mahapatraetal., 2010;Vlaaretal., 2007;Zhengetal.,2008)andconceptual stud-ies(e.g.,InkpenandCurrall, 1998, 2004;Luo,2006)orempirical studiesthatdid notreport anyofthecorrelations weredropped fromoursampleforthemeta-analysis(e.g.,Saparitoetal.,2004; WastiandWasti,2008; Zhouet al., 2008).9 From theremaining

545articles,wefurtherexcluded402articles,and143articleswere selected.Third,selectedstudiesmusthavehadindependent sam-ples(Geyskens et al.,2006).Wechecked thesamplingprocesses

7 Wedidnotsetuptheconstraintsof2002fortheotherpartsofthesearch

pro-cess.ThesejournalsweretheAcademyofManagementJournal,JournalofInternational BusinessStudies,JournalofManagement,JournalofManagementStudies,Journalof Marketing,JournalofMarketingResearch,JournalofOperationsManagement, Organi-zationScience,andStrategicManagementJournal.

8 Wehadafourthinclusioncriterionaboutthelanguageandpublicationoutlet

descriptionofeachstudy.Studiessharingthesamesamplewere alldroppedexceptonethatwaspublishedinthejournalwiththe highestimpactfactor.10Fourstudieswereexcluded,andourfinal

databasethusincluded139articles.Theprocessofstudiessearch andselectionisillustratedinFig.3.

Followingpriorresearch(LipseyandWilson,2001),wedesigned a coding protocol to record information about the study (e.g., author,publicationdate,researchquestion,andabstract),sample (e.g., sample size, country, industry, unit of analysis, and

rela-tionship length mean), measurement (measurement items and

reliability),andeffectsize(correlation).Forstudiesonlyreporting correlations betweenmeasures(e.g.,Cavusgilet al.,2004;Poppo andZenger,2002)orbetweendifferentdimensions(e.g.,Luiand Ngo,2004;MalhotraandLumineau,2011)ofcontractualand rela-tionalgovernance, wecalculated thecompositecorrelationsand reliabilities according to the formulas provided by Hunter and Schmidt(2004:433–442)toapproachthecorrelationbetween con-tractual and relational governance. We averaged the inter-item correlations orinter-dimension correlationsonly when informa-tionfortheformulaswasnotavailable(Geyskensetal.,2006,2009). Wecheckedallrecordedinformationthreemonthslater,andfew discrepancies (less than 1%)were identified andsolved through discussions(Geyskensetal.,2006).

We calculated the sample-adjusted meta-analytic deviancy (SAMD) statistics to detect outliers (Huffcutt and Arthur, 1995; Geyskensetal.,2006).Oneoutlierwasdetectedandcheckedbefore being finally dropped.11 After dropping the outlier, wehad 149

studies across 138 articles reporting correlations of contractual andrelational governance.12 All studiesexcept twounpublished

studiesandonebookchapterwerepublishedinacademicjournals.

10 Liuetal.(2008,2009),andLuoetal.(2011)sharedthesamedataset,andweonly

keptLiuetal.(2009).Similarly,wedroppedCannonetal.(2000)andBianchiand Saleh(2010)butkeptCannonandPerreault(1999)andBianchiandSaleh(2011).

11 JapandGanesan(2000)wastheoutlierforthecontracts–relationalnorms

rela-tionship.Wedroppeditforthreereasons(Geyskensetal.,2009):(1)ithasextremely highnegativeSAMDstatistics(−30.41)whilethevaluesofSAMDofotherstudies rangefrom−1.36to7.93;(2)theunitofanalysisofthisstudyisdifferentfromall otherstudies;and(3)thefinalresultsarequitesensitivetoeffectsizeofthisstudy.

12 Theremaybemorethanonestudyinonearticle.Thereisnoconsistent

(10)

Substitutability  refers  to  the  availability  of  alternate  sources  of  supply.  Switching   costs  are  an  important  element  in  this  decision  process.  Dedicated  investments   in   resources   or   relation   specific   investments   exclusively   in   one   customer/supplier   result   in   higher   switching   costs,   thereby   limiting   options   when  the  relationship  deteriorates  (Caniels  and  Gelderman,  2007).    

 

When   further   examining   the   concept   of   power   we   distinguish   the   sources   of   power  and  the  use  of  power  within  a  relationship.  Complementary  to  the  already   discussed   linkage   between   power   and   interdependence,   resource   dependence   theory   explains   a   source   of   power.   Firms   are   embedded   in   a   web   of   exchange   relationships  within  an  uncertain  environment  (Salancik  and  Pfeffer,  1978)  and   a  firm’s  power  within  the  web  resides  in  others’  dependence  on  it  for  resources   (Emerson,  1962).  Firms  have  power  to  the  degree  that  others  depend  on  them   for   resources   (Crook   and   Combs,   2007).   Dependence   is   elevated   through   the   importance   and   concentration   of   resources.   We   already   discussed   how   importance   increases   dependence   through   high   financial   magnitude   and   the   criticality   of   resources.   Benton   and   Maloni   (2005)   argue   that   concentrated   industries  where  a  few  competitors  generate  most  sales,  have  bargaining  power   due   to   their   large   volumes   and   the   small   number   of   alternatives.   Thus,   highly   concentrated   supply   chains   such   as   aircraft   assembly   and   oil   refining,   cannot   easily   replace   these   important   members,   which   enhances   dependency.   Supply   chain   members   offering   high   magnitude   or   critical   resources   in   highly   concentrated  industries  are  stronger  as  opposed  to  weaker  members  who  lack   such   resources   (Crook   and   Combs,   2007).   In   order   for   suppliers   to   be   in   a   position  of  power,  Bensao  (1999)  argues  that  offered  products  must  be  complex   as  in  not  easily  imitable,  have  a  proprietary  technology,  have  a  few  suppliers  of   large   size   and   have   a   concentrated   market.   The   high   competitive   barriers   between  suppliers  are  then  high,  making  them  not  easily  interchangeable.  At  the   same   time,   suppliers   can   sustain   the   levers   of   power   if   they   successfully   block   competitors  from  market  entry  (Cox,  2001).  The  following  question  is  how  firms   use   this   kind   of   bargaining   power   in   the   relationship.   In   Maloni   and   Benton’s   (2000)  paper,  five  bases  of  power  are  depicted:  expert,  referent  and  legitimate   power  belong  to  non-­‐  mediated  types  of  power  and  reward  and  coercive  power   are   mediated   types   of   power.   Mediated   power   is   controlled   by   the   customer,   which   can   reward   a   supplier   by   placing   more   orders   or   coerce   it   through   negative   consequences   such   as   fines   and   cancelling   orders   for   its   non-­‐ performance.  In  contrast,  non-­‐mediated  power  as  expert,  referent  or  legitimate   power  depends  upon  the  decision  of  the  supplier,  whether  and  to  what  extent  is   influenced   by   the   customer.   Since   we   focus   on   the   power   perspective   of   the   buyer,   coercive   and   rewarding   forms   of   mediated   power   are   more   relevant   in   this  context.    

 

(11)

proportion   of   informal   mechanisms   are   included   in   the   two   concepts.   Contractual  governance  is  indicated  by  the  adoption  of  formal  contracts.    

     

 

                     

Figure  3:  Conceptual  model  of  the  relationship  between  relational  governance  and   contractual  governance  with  the  influence  of  interdependence  and  power  as  moderators   on  this  relationship.  

 

3.Methodology  

 

(12)

3.1  Sample  selection  

In  order  to  collect  the  data,  we  have  selected  four  firms  from  the  metal  assembly   and  processing  industry  that  are  part  of  the  NEVAT  network.  NEVAT  is  a  Dutch   business   platform   that   connects   suppliers   with   potential   customers   by   organizing  international  networking  activities.  NEVAT  stimulates  innovation  and   cooperation  between  buyers  and  suppliers  and  this  initiative  may  result  in  more   complex  contracts,  which  we  can  hopefully  benefit  from  in  the  form  of  rich  data.     For  the  selection  of  cases  we  wanted  to  have  some  variety  in  sub-­‐category,  firm   size   and   resources   and   possibly   relate   the   findings   to   one   of   these   attributes.   Table  1.  gives  an  overview  of  the  selected  cases  and  their  attributes.  Replication   logic   is   applied   by   selecting   contrasting   characteristics   e.g.   small   vs   large   firm,   component   subcategory   vs   system   subcategory.   This   way   differences   between   the  cases  are  highlighted  (Eisenhart,  1989;  Yin,  1994).  To  get  an  evenly  spread   selection  of  cases,  we  targeted  two  firms  from  GPI  with  a  firm  size  of  50-­‐100,  two   firms  from  SYS  with  a  firm  size  of  >500  and  two  firms  from  GVE  with  a  firm  size   of  <50.  Unfortunately,  two  of  these  firms,  one  from  SYS  and  another  from  GVN,   have  not  responded  to  our  request  in  participating  in  our  research.  Nevertheless,   with  4  cases,  we  still  meet  the  recommendations  by  Eisenhardt  (1989)  to  select  a   minimum  of  4  cases  in  order  to  have  reliable  data.    

 

The  abbreviations  GPI,  SYS  and  GVN  are  Dutch  and  each  stands  for  a  specific  sub-­‐ category  of  firms  in  the  NEVAT  network.  We  will  briefly  depict  each  category  to   provide   a   better   understanding   of   the   different   contexts.   GPI   refers   to   Groep   Plaatverwerkende   Industrie   and   means   Sheet   Metalworking   Industry   sector   group.  This  group  of  firms  generate  revenue  through  processing  sheets  of  metal   with   advanced   processing   machines   and   tools.   Market   conditions   are   rapidly   changing  and  customers  have  customized  wishes  from  the  metalworking  firms.   Therefore,  it  is  key  that  the  metalworking  firms  respond  swiftly  and  effectively   to   changing   market   demand   or   to   new   requirements.   This   guarantees   a   very   short  ‘time  to  market’  and  is  essential  to  stay  ahead  of  international  competition.   Next  are  the  group  System  Suppliers  within  the  NEVAT  network  referred  to  as   SYS.  This  group  of  suppliers  are  service-­‐oriented  relational  leaders  with  a  highly   adaptable   capacity,   focused   on   customer   intimacy.   They   are   proactive   lifecycle   managers   with   relevant   knowledge   of   various   markets   such   as   semiconductor,   medical,  multimedia,  analysis,  energy  and  industrial  automation  markets.  System   suppliers   are   different   from   other   suppliers   in   the   sense   that   they   take   responsibility   in   the   field   of   product   development,   process   development,   serial   production   and   end-­‐of-­‐life-­‐   management.   In   addition,   they   contribute   unique   knowledge   in   the   field   of   sheet   metalwork,   electronics,   precision   components   and/or  mechatronics.  Lastly,  GVN  is  Dutch  for  Groot  Verspaners  Nederland  and   means   Dutch   Heavy   Machining   Industry.   Members   of   this   group   supply   heavy   machine  processes  or  alternatively  manufacture  products  using  heavy  machine   process   techniques.   They   have   made   significant   investments   in   recent   years   to   be   able   to   process   large   complex   pieces   with   a   high   degree   of   precision   for   various   industry   sectors   including,   energy,   petrochemicals,   heavy   machine   construction,   the   maritime   sector   (ship   newbuilds   and   repairs)   and   offshore  

(NEVAT   website,   2015.   Retrieved   from   http://.nevat.nl/en-­‐GB/sectors-­‐

(13)

Table  1:  An  overview  of  the  selected  cases  and  their  characteristics  

  Case  A   Case  B   Case  C   Case  D  

Sub-­‐category     GPI   GPI   SYS   GVN  

Firm  size   (#Employees)  

50-­‐100   50-­‐100   >500   <50  

Interviewed  

positionee(s)   -­‐General  manager  

-­‐Purchasing   manager  

-­‐General  

manager   -­‐General  manager  (also  

involved  in   purchasing)   -­‐General   manager  (also   involved  in   purchasing)  

Strategic  item   Pre-­‐painted  

tire   3D  cutted  metal  

parts  

Lathed  and  

milling  parts   Processed  steel    

Supplier  

reference  code   Supplier  W   Supplier  X   Supplier  Y   Supplier  Z  

   

3.2  Data  collection    

 

(14)

 

We  planned  to  perform  all  our  data  collecting  activities  within  one  month,  which   forced  us  to  conduct  the  interviews  and  document  study  during  the  2  hours  we   spent  at  each  company.  The  secretaries  of  the  companies  reserved  a  closed  office   space,  in  which  we  could  take  the  interviews.  We  provided  the  managers  with  a   printed  version  of  the  interview  before  we  started  the  interview  protocol.  This   way   we   enabled   them   to   follow   the   red   line   of   our   protocol.   Next   to   that,   the   interviews  were  recorded  and  transcribed  within  24  hours  of  the  company  visit.   In  order  to  fill  in  our  document  study  template,  we  asked  the  managers  directly   after   the   interview   if   they   could   show   us   a   contract   that   is   used   in   the   trading   agreement   between   them   and   the   strategic   supplier.   Fortunately,   all   managers   cooperated  and  granted  our  request.  The  semi-­‐structured  interviews  averagely   took  one  hour  and  the  document  study  approximately  15  to  20  minutes.    

3.3  Development  interview  protocol  and  document  study  

 

In   order   to   measure   constructs   such   as   trust,   interdependence   and   power,   we   derived   from   literature   on   some   measurement   instruments   that   classify   the   interorganizational   relationship   as   ACR   or   OCR.   Based   on   the   frameworks   of   Zaheer  et  al.  (1998)  and  Corsten  and  Felde  (2005)  items  for  the  interview  were   developed  in  the  form  of  open  questions.  The  complete  interview  can  be  found  in   Appendix  I.  

 

(15)

 

Document   study   or   document   analysis   is   often   referred   to   content   analysis   in   literature.  Content  analysis  is  used  to  gain  data  from  text  content  and  compare  it   with   data   or   theories   gathered   beforehand.   Three   approaches   can   be   distinguished;   conventional,   directed   or   summative.   Conventional   and   directed   approaches   use   categorization   from   the   text   or   used   theories,   whereas   for   this   research   the   summative   approach   is   most   desirable.   With   the   summative   approach   the   content   from   the   documents   is   compared   to   the   context   the   documents  are  used  in  (Hsieh  &  Shannon,  2005).    The  template  in  Appendix  II  is   used   to   review   contracts   on   their   degree   of   explicitness.   The   contract   that   involves  the  trading  agreement  about  the  procured  item  is  scanned  and  analyzed   with  this  template.  The  items  1  to  13    in  the  template  determine  if  a  contract  is   more  ACR  or  OCR  related.  The  questions  are  based  on  elements  used  in  sample   supply  chain  contracts  found  on  the  Internet  and  which  are  commonly  used  in   different   types   of   settings   where   financial   incentives   play   a   role   (Lawinsider,   2014).   The   questions   are   sorted   in   different   groups:   determined   terms,   information  and  privacy,  clarity  of  roles  (Stone,  2015).    

 

3.4  Data  analysis  

 

After  having  completed  the  data  collection,  the  next  step  was  to  make  sense  of   the  obtained  data  in  a  structured  and  plausible  way.  The  used  tactic  is  similar  to   Eisenhardt’s  (1989)  cross-­‐case  pattern  analysis,  where  within  group  similarities   are  coupled  with  intergroup  differences  across  several  dimensions.  Prior  to  the   cross-­‐case  analysis,  we  performed  a  within-­‐case  analysis  to  get  familiar  with  the   results  per  case.  After  having  established  an  overview  of  the  variables  for  every   case,   pattern-­‐coding   was   applied   to   identify   patterns   across   cases.   The   most   important   patterns   were   discussed   and   put   into   perspective   in   regard   to   our   research  question.  A  chain  of  evidence  (Yin,  2013)  was  established  by  linking  the   constructs   developed   in   the   interview   protocol   to   the   cross-­‐case   analysis,   supported   by   the   circumstances   in   which   the   data   are   collected   e.g.   time   and   venue   (data   collection).   In   order   to   get   more   transparency   into   the   data   and   categorize   the   identified   concepts   and   elements   from   the   interviews,   a   coding   tree   was   developed   (see   table   2).   With   the   help   of   table   2,   we   were   able   to   highlight   patterns   across   cases   by   examining   differences   and   similarities   of   interpretive   codes.   Before   attaching   interpretive   codes,   descriptive   codes   were   established  from  our  theoretical  background  and  interview  protocol.    After  each   descriptive   code,   the   strongest   and   most   influential   quotes   about   the   specific   concept  was  picked  from  all  interviewees  and  translated  into  interpretive  codes.      

(16)

of   formal   contracting   efforts,   typical   for   an   ACR   (Sako,1992).   Interdependence   was   broken   down   into   three   descriptive   codes:   availability   of   substitutes,   switching  costs  and  supplier’s  dependence.  With  the  help  of  these  constructs,  we   get  better  insight  into  relative  power  of  the  buyer  in  the  relationship,  which  is   closely  related  to  interdependence  (Caniels  and  Gelderman,  2007;  Geyskens  et  al.   1996).   At   first   sight,   Case   A   shows   very   high   dependence   on   his   supplier   as   opposed  to  other  cases  occupying  a  low  dependency  position.  The  implications   of   this   finding   are   discussed   during   the   within-­‐case   and   cross-­‐case   analysis.   Power,  as  in  the  adoption  of  power  throughout  the  buyer-­‐supplier  relationship,   was   subdivided   into   coercive   power   or   non-­‐coercive   power.   These   forms   of   power  were  found  to  be  mediated  by  the  buyer  (Maloni  and  Benton,  2000)  and   hence  are  relevant  for  this  context.  We  notice  that  Case  C  was  the  only  case  to   use  coercive  power  and  relate  to  this  during  the  analysis.    

 

Table  2:  Coding  tree  across  all  cases  

Descriptive  codes   Quotes   Interpretive  codes  

Relational  governance      

Interpersonal  trust   Case  A:    “We  have  good  relations  with  the  people  

that  frequently  visit  our  company”   Relational  trust  

  Case  B:  “We  have  direct  contact  with  the  

management  and  strive  to  grow  together  as   strategic  partners”  

Relational  trust     Case  C:  “Our  relationship  is  very  open  in  the  sense  

that  I  can  express  my  price  expectations  and  he  can   respond  to  that”  

Price-­‐driven  trust     Case  D:  “My  contact  person  is  very  decent,  honest  

and  customer-­‐oriented”  

Relational  trust   Inter-­‐organizational  trust   Case  A:  “The  supplier  has  a  well-­‐established  

company  but  is  also  very  rigid”   Performance-­‐driven  trust  

  Case  B:  “The  supplier  is  a  healthy  firm  where  odd  

things  are  not  likely  to  happen”   Resource-­‐based  trust  

  Case  C:  “I  trust  the  supplier  because  I  know  their  

financial  structure  and  we  are  the  most  important   customer  they  have”  

Resource-­‐based  trust     Case  D:  “Suppliers  in  this  market  maintain  stable  

prices  and  can  provide  supply  for  the  long-­‐term   because  there  is  consistency”  

Market-­‐based  trust   Negotiations   Case  A:  “We  generally  negotiate  about  the  

conditions  of  the  strategic  item  in  terms  of  delivery   speed  and  quantities”.  

Performance-­‐driven   negotiations     Case  B:  ”During  negotiations  prices  are  determined  

and  secondly  strategic  elements  are  discussed”     Price-­‐driven  negotiations  

  Case  C:  “We  explore  opportunities  to  get  

competitive  prices  and  make  our  suppliers  aware   of  the  relative  prices  in  the  market”  

Price-­‐  driven  negotiations     Case  D:  “Our  suppliers  are  involved  in  project  

design  talks  with  our  customer  and  therefore  make   early  preparations  in  production  and  delivery”  

Supplier  integration  in  project   design  

Contractual  governance      

Contracting  efforts   Case  A:”  Consensus  is  reached  through  dialogue  

and  by  keeping  each  other  up-­‐to-­‐date  about   processes”  

Dialogue  and  information   sharing    

  Case  B:  “Supplier  X  fulfills  our  demand  through  

contracts  and  performance  is  therefore  higher  than   non-­‐contracted  items”  

Contracts  guarantee   performance  

  Case  C:  “Contracts  offer  little  meaning  when  

spontaneous  decisions  have  to  be  made”   Rigidness  of  contracts  

  Case  D:  ”Contracts  lack  problem  solving  capacity  

(17)

Interdependence      

Availability  of  substitutes   Case  A:  “We  have  a  big  problem  if  this  supplier  cuts  

the  supply”   Locked-­‐in  

  Case  B:  “The  supplier  does  face  some  competition  

on  the  strategic  item  on  a  European  level”   Low  dependence  

  Case  C:  “There  are  100  other  parties  in  the  

Netherlands  that  can  provide  this  product”   Not  dependent    

  Case  D:  “There  are  approximately  10  suppliers  

worldwide  but  we  buy  in  Europe”   Low  dependence  

Switching  costs   Case  A:  “It  is  almost  impossible  to  switch  suppliers  

on  the  strategic  item  because  it  is  too  specific  and   customized  for  our  customer”  

High  costs  of  switching     Case  B:  “It  is  possible  to  purchase  from  another  

supplier  although  you  have  to  start  over  in   achieving  the  same  quality  and  delivery  reliability,   which  is  not  desirable”  

Reluctant  to  switch     Case  C:  “I  can  assign  projects  to  other  suppliers  if  

they  offer  better  prices  than  my  supplier  but  I  have   to  take  into  account  that  longer  delivery  times  may   occur”  

Price-­‐focused       Case  D:  “Other  parties  are  able  to  provide  the  

product  the  way  we  want  it  to  be  but  we  need  to   invest  some  time  in  that”  

Reluctant  to  switch   Suppliers’  dependence   Case  A:  “  We  are  among  the  top  50  customers  of  

supplier  W”     Routine  customer  

  Case  B:  “  The  suppliers’  dependence  on  us  is  not  

really  high,  about  15-­‐20%”  

Moderately  important  customer     Case  C:  “If  we  drop  out  as  a  customer,  the  supplier  

has  a  big  problem  because  we  generate  30%  of   their  revenue”    

Important  customer     Case  D:  “The  supplier  is  for  about  10-­‐15%  

dependent  on  us”  

Moderately  important  customer  

Power  

     

Coercive  power   Case  C:    “By  showing  my  supplier  the  price  offers  of  

other  suppliers,  I  can  get  more  competitive  prices”  

Exploitation  

     

Non-­‐coercive  power   Case  A:  “We  try  to  push  the  supplier’s  performance  

back  to  the  accepted  norms,  if  they  deviate  from  it”   Joint  problem  solving  

  Case  B:  “I  actually  do  have  some  leverage  on  my  

supplier  but  I  prefer  to  be  honest  and  fair  because   the  tide  can  always  turn  

Balanced  interaction     Case  C:  “I  am  not  a  proponent  of  fines,  but  I  do  

reward  a  supplier  with  more  volume  if  he  can   decrease  his  price  for  example”  

Competitive  rewarding     Case  D:  “We  allocate  more  volume  to  suppliers  that  

we  are  content  with”   Performance  rewards  

 

4.Results      

 

4.1  Within-­‐case  analysis  

  Case  A     Relational  governance  

The   managers   of   Case   A   expressed   that   they   were   content   with   the   contact   persons  from  supplier  Y.  One  factor  contributing  to  this  is  that  the  relationship   stems  back  from  1970.  “We  exist  for  53  years  and  the  relationship  with  supplier  W  

(18)

them”   stated   the   general   manager.   Furthermore,   the   frequent   company   visits  

provided   by   both   parties   also   indicate   a   positive   atmosphere   between   the   partners.   The   purchasing   manager   revealed   that   the   people   from   supplier   W   were  regularly  visiting  the  company  and  that  he  knows  them  very  well.  “We  do  

not  want  to  buy  at  supplier  W  today  and  tomorrow  from  another.  We  have  good   relations   with   the   people   that   come   here”   says   the   purchaser;   referring   to   the  

amount   of   trust   they   have   in   this   supplier.     Despite   the   positive   relations,   the   managers  did  express  some  concerns  about  the  potential  and  consistency  of  this   supplier.  “Supplier  W  is  a  well-­‐established  company  but  also  very  rigid”.  Sometimes  

they  drop  a  few  stiches  and  are  not  able  to  compensate  for  it,  which  is  very  odd”,  

the   manager   declared.  Both   managers   referred   to   a   conflict   in   the   past,   which   damaged  the  relationship.  Some  other  minor  examples  were  given  that  indicated   the   inconsistency   and   their   inability   to   quickly   respond   to   that.   The   managers   find  it  very  odd  of  such  a  well-­‐known  company  to  perform  like  this.    This  means   that   although   organizational   trust   is   high,   it   is   tempered   by   the   drops   in   performance.    

 

Contractual  governance    

Table  3:  Document  study  results  of  Case  A  

Item  category   Outcome  

Determined  terms   Very  determined  

Information  sharing   Less   determined   with  

frequent  result  exchange  

Clarity  of  roles   Monitoring   and   planning  

governed   by   the   buying   firm  

 

The   template   indicates   that   terms   and   conditions   are   very   determined   in   the   contract.   Quantitative   data   such   as   price,   quantities   and   timing   of   payments/deliveries   are   mentioned   and   are   also   fixed.   However,   information   sharing   is   less   determined,   not   stating   what   and   when   information   exchange   occurs  and  by  whom.  Unlike  the  monitoring  of  results,  which  is  governed  by  Case   A.  Results  are  thereby  frequently  exchanged  in  a  timespan  of  every  two  months.   In  addition,  the  buying  firm  was  solely  in  control  of  monitoring  and  planning.      

The   conflict   that   had   risen   between   the   buyer   and   supplier   did   not   end   in   a   termination  of  the  relationship,  although  the  problems  were  severe.  The  conflict   could   have   easily   been   prevented   if   the   supplier   communicated   the   planned   change   to   its   customer   but   instead   they   decided   to   hide   information.   Despite   very   determined   contracts   and   agreements,   the   buyer   was   not   able   to   force   compensation   or   take   legal   action   but   came   to   a   resolution   in   revising   agreements   and   tightening   control   through   monitoring.     The   role   of   contracts   was  not  of  significance,  because  they  could  not  prevent  the  problem  nor  provide   a   solution   for   the   problem.   Instead,   the   manager   indicated   that   in   general   consensus   is   reached   through   dialogue   and   by   joint   problem   solving   efforts,   especially  when  you  have  a  long-­‐lasting  partnership  with  a  supplier.    

(19)

 

Interdependence  

Case   A   occupies   a   supplier   dependent   position,   because   they   do   not   have   substitutes   for   the   strategic   item.   The   purchasing   manager   admitted   that   they   would  have  a  big  problem  if  supplier  W  cuts  the  supply.  According  to  him  there   are  two  main  reasons  why  this  item  has  become  very  critical  and  strategic:  “the  

item  is  very  specific  and  customized  for  our  customer  and  unfortunately  there  are   no  other  parties  at  the  moment  that  can  provide  it  with  the  same  or  better  quality”.  

As  a  result,  the  switching  costs  are  rather  high.  However,  the  manager  sees  the   strategic  item  as  a  part  of  the  overall  relationship  with  supplier  W.  “We  purchase  

non-­‐strategic  items  from  supplier  W  as  well  and  we  can  re-­‐allocate  these  volumes   to  other  suppliers  if  we  want  to.  This  way  we  somehow  have  a  balance  in  power  in   our   relationship”,   the   general   manager   declared.   Furthermore,   the   company   is  

among  the  top  50  customers  of  supplier  W,  making  them  a  routine  customer.      

Power  

In  general,  Case  A  uses  non-­‐coercive  power  to  manage  the  supplier.  This  became   apparent  during  conflict  management.  “We  try  to  push  the  supplier’s  performance  

back  to  the  accepted  norms,  sounded  the  purchasing  manager  after  being  asked  

for   measures   against   failures.   This   was   mainly   done   in   a   jointly   fashion.   In   addition,   the   absence   of   fines   and   actions   against   supplier   W   after   the   conflict   shows   that   Case   A   lacked   the   power   and   hence   the   determination   in   taking   measures.   The   purchasing   manager   responded   that   after   the   conflict   new   agreements  were  made  and  ever  since  no  major  problems  were  detected.    

  Case  B    

Relational  governance  

The   general   manager   of   Case   B   emphasized   the   mutual   interests   between   the   company   and   its   strategic   supplier.   He   pointed   to   the   strategic   relevance   of   moving   forward   together,   as   they   are   part   of   the   same   supply   chain.   “We  have  

direct   contact   with   the   management   and   strive   to   grow   together   as   strategic   partners”   he   says.   To   further   illustrate   his   point   he   went   on   about   mutual  

interests.   “You   have   to   see   the   whole   chain   where   products   are   sold   to   the   same  

customer  and  it  is  important  that  the  interests  within  the  chain  are  aligned.  If  we   cannot   sell   to   a   customer,   our   supplier   cannot   sell   to   us,   which   is   bad   for   both   parties.   Our   contact   person   is   aware   of   this   and   therefore   acts   accordingly”.   We  

can   say   that   the   relational   trust   among   the   partners   is   playing   a   role   in   this   setting.   The   manager   was   confident   about   the   continuity   and   reliability   of   his   supplier.  He  acknowledged:  “The  supplier  has  a  healthy  firm  where  odd  things  are  

not  likely  to  happen”.  Hereby  he  specifically  aimed  at  the  supply  of  the  strategic  

item,  because  the  supply  of  non-­‐strategic  items  went  less  smooth.  “Non-­‐strategic  

products   purchased   at   this   supplier   are   less   consistent   in   quality   and   delivery   because  we  do  not  have  contracts  for  these  items”,  he  added.    

 

 

Contractual  governance  

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

Effectiveness of sustainability risk management = constant + β1 * level of usage of formal governance mechanisms + β2 * level of usage of relational governance

Mediator relationship: To test if relational trust mediates the relationship between the significant relational norms continuity expectation and information exchange

When buying firms implement competitive incentives to motivate suppliers for social sustainability performance improvement, these firms usually promise suppliers future business

Thus, the given thesis aimed at contributing to research through the analysis of joint venture contracts from high-tech industries in order to evaluate if knowledge proximity

Four relational dimensions (trust, commitment, communication quality and knowledge sharing) and two contractual dimensions (contractual complexity and contractual

First and foremost, this study builds on the findings of Poppo and Zenger (2002) and explores the avenue of future research as pointed out by these scholars to

We find that, for the short and long term relationship of the buyer there are significant differences in the effect of contracting on RACAP, the effect of

Thus, in addition to the positive effect of legitimate power (because of high brand awareness) on SSC, buyers are mostly reliant on mediated power to influence SSC,