• No results found

Governmental activism in the Argentine media realm : populist strategy to construct political

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Governmental activism in the Argentine media realm : populist strategy to construct political"

Copied!
100
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

   

 

 

 

 

Governmental activism in the

Argentine media realm:

Populist strategy to construct political

agency

Master thesis Conflict Resolution & Governance Date: 27-06-14 Author: Tobias de Graaf Student number: 6156967 Total words: 30712

(2)

 

 

 

 

 

   

The Clarín newspaper President Fernández de Kirchner holds, reads “The equity of [the city] Moreno grew 91,5% in one year”, while the Clarín newspapers in the background have headlines like “Gigantic protests against the government”, “The government appeals to the Court and continues to attack Justice”, “Kirchner already has the law of media control” and “They claim that the freedom of expression is in great danger”.

(3)

                     

“Many times [President Fernández de Kirchner] uses the Casa Rosada itself to broadcast, and many times she speaks from the Salon of Mujeres Argentinas, the Argentine Women, which is a salon that she made. And there's this little maquette of the building with [two images of] Evita on it in Buenos Aires. […] Whenever she announces good news, you see smiling Evita behind her, and she announces family support, more money for schools, a new hospital... always good news, happy news. But when she needs to make some tough decisions, or starts insulting people, the building is always turned the other way and it's the shouting Evita”

– Peter Scheffer on Fernández de Kirchner’s national broadcasts

(Interview Scheffer, 2014: 19:00)  

   

(4)

Table of contents

 

 

Introduction                     p  5  

 

Theory:  Rethinking  populism                 p  10  

 

Operationalization:  Populist  strategy  in  the  media  realm           p  21    

Methods:  Expert  interviews  and  participant  observation           p  27    

Case  study:  Institutionalization  of  power  in  Argentina           p  35    

Case  study:  Performance  of  power  in  Argentina             p  55    

Conclusion                     p  78  

 

References                     p  84  

 

Attachment  1:  Overview  of  experts               p  94  

 

Attachment  2:  Interview  guide                 p  96  

 

Attachment  3:  Selected  Cadenas  Nacionales             p  98  

 

Attachment  4:  Framework  performance  analysis             p  100    

(5)

Governmental activism in the

Argentine media realm:

Populist strategy to construct political agency

 

This   thesis   sets   out   to   answer   the   question   how   President   Fernández   de   Kirchner   constructs  political  agency  in  the  Argentine  media  realm.  Since  Fernández  de  Kirchner   took   office   in   2007,   the   confrontations   between   government   and   media   have   considerably   increased.   She   is   generally   characterized   as   a   populist,   which   has   been   argued  to  constitute  a  strategy  that  actively  confronts  the  large  media  and  furthermore   utilizes   media   like   television   and   radio   to   directly   reach   the   masses.   Therefore,   the   broader  aim  of  the  thesis  is  to  theoretically  connect  Kirchner’s  populist  strategy  to  her   governmental  activism  in  the  media  realm.  To  this  end,  the  concept  of  populist  political   agency  is  proposed:  the  strategic  aim  and  active  efforts  of  a  populist  to  create  populist   structures   of   support   amongst   mass   constituencies   in   a   manner   that   a)   contrasts   regular   party   institutionalization   and   b)   highlights   his/her   charisma.   It   presupposes   a   virtuous   cycle   of   populist   leaders’   presidential   power   being   used   to   enlarge   their   legitimacy,   thereby   constructing   political   agency.   The   concept   thus   provides   a   way   to   approach   Fernández   de   Kirchner’s   efforts   in   the   media.   More   specifically,   a   two-­‐part   case  study  on  Argentina  inquires  into  Kirchner’s  construction  of  political  agency  through   the   institutionalization   of   power   in   the   media   realm   as   well   as   the   performance   of   power  through  the  media.  I  find  that  the  former  is  achieved  by  strategically  rewarding   and  punishing  media  outlets  with  a  variety  of  instruments  that  ultimately  stimulate  self-­‐ censorship   amongst   the   media;   the   latter   concerns   the   performance   of   an   elaborate   discourse  that  unites  the  Argentine  people  in  Kirchner’s  support  base,  the  core  elements   of   which   are   an   emphasis   on   unity,   democratic   diversity   and   Kirchner’s   indispensable   leadership.  

   

Introduction

 

On  September  13,  2012,  a  protest  against  Argentine  President  Christina  Fernández  de  Kirchner   and  her  government  took  place  in  the  biggest  Argentine  cities.  Two  months  later,  on  November   8,  there  were  even  bigger  protests:  estimations  are  that  around  half  a  million  people  marched  

(6)

on   the   streets   of   Buenos   Aires   and   other   cities,   while   people   also   protested   at   Argentine   embassies  and  consulates  in  other  countries.  (Al  Jazeera,  2012;  Goni  &  Watts,  2012).  In  general,   many  of  the  middle  class  were  fed  up  with  Kirchner’s  ‘strong-­‐arm’  politics,  illustrated  by  the   popular   chant   ‘We   are   not   afraid’   amongst   the   protesters   (Ibidem).   The   protests   targeted   Kirchner’s  government  as  a  whole,  with  people  raising  attention  for  a  wide  variety  of  issues  like   corruption,   high   inflation   rates,   restrictions   on   buying   U.S.   dollars,   high   crime   rates   and   the   possible   extension   of   presidential   term   limits   (Al   Jazeera,   2012).   But   in   particular   one   issue   stood  out  in  these  protests:  the  new  controversial  anti-­‐monopoly  media  law.  

  Supporters   of   Kirchner   defend   this   law   as   ensuring   press   freedom   and   diversity   of   information   (Garton,   2012A)   and   the   UN   Special   Reporter   on   freedom   of   expression   even   called  it  an  example  for  the  entire  continent  (Woerden,  2012).  However,  critics  claim  that  the   law   constitutes   “underhanded   measures   to   censor   [the   government’s]   critics   in   the   media”   (Garton,   2012A)   with   the   purpose   to   dismantle   powerful   media   groups   like   Clarín   and   La   Nación   (Al   Jazeera,   2012;   Garton,   2012B).   Symbolizing   this   broadly   shared   concern   are   the   names  of  the  protests:  they  were  referred  to  as  ‘13S’  (September  13)  and  ‘8N’  (November  8),   because   the   government’s   campaign   for   the   media   law   had   been   called   ‘7D’,   after   the   day   (December  7)  that  the  new  media  law  would  go  into  effect.  

The   law   constitutes   the   newest   confrontation   in   an   ongoing   conflict   between   Fernández  de  Kirchner’s  administration  and  the  Clarín  media  group:  both  the  government  and   Clarín  accuse  each  other  of  attempts  to  control  the  media  landscape  (Garton,  2012A,  2012B).   While  the  media  group  Clarín  owns  the  best-­‐selling  newspaper,  the  most  popular  TV  and  cable   channel  and  “a  whole  array  of  other  TV  channels,  local  newspapers  and  radio  stations”  (Martin,   2011),   they   claim   that   Kirchner   has   ‘colonized’   and   indirectly   controls   80%   of   the   media   landscape  (Gilbert,  2013;  Website  Clarín  A).    Either  way,  while  such  ambiguity  and  controversy   continues  to  characterize  the  implementation  of  the  new  media  law,  “the  rise  in  news  media-­‐ government  conflict  and  oppositional  polarization”  (Kitzberger,  2009:  2)  has  been  striking  since   the  election  of  Fernández  de  Kirchner  as  president  in  2007.  

Interestingly,  it  seems  that  this  conflict  between  Kirchner  and  the  media  is  also  fought   out  with  more  subtle  tactics:  government  expenditures  in  public  advertising  have  for  instance   increased   by   87%   in   the   first   quarter   of   2012   in   comparison   to   the   year   before   and   are   allegedly   used   to   fund   pro-­‐Kirchner   outlets   (Crettaz,   2012;   Website   CPJ).   Official   media   also   appear  to  be  employed  in  attempts  to  control  information  streams  for  political  benefit:  with   regard  to  the  8N  protests,  for  instance,  the  public  television  channel  barely  reported  on  them  

(7)

and   categorically   understated   the   number   of   protestors,   talking   about   100.000   rather   than   500.000  or  more  (Al  Jazeera,  2012).  

In  addition,  Kirchner  has  used  her  constitutional  right  to  broadcast  a  Cadena  Nacional   [National   Broadcast]   on   all   television   and   radio   stations   more   often   almost   every   year   (Pecoraro,  2009;  Website  Clarín  B),  thereby  bypassing  traditional  media  outlets  to  reach  the   Argentine   people   directly.   According   to   the   new   media   law,   a   Cadena   Nacional   may   be   arranged  in  ‘serious  and  exceptional  situations’  (Website  InfoLEG  Argentina).  As  these  criteria   are  kept  vague,  President  Kirchner  regularly  uses  her  right  for  a  Cadena  Nacional  more  than   fifteen   times   a   year   (Website   Clarín   B).   In   the   first   five   months   of   2014,   she   has   already   broadcasted   twelve   Cadenas   Nacionales   on,   amongst   others,   public   events,   new   bills,   governmental  policy  and  the  introduction  a  new  pesos  bill.  This  stands  in  stark  contrast  to  her   late   husband   Néstor   Kirchner,   who   only   used   it   twice   throughout   his   entire   four-­‐year   term   from  2003  until  2007.  

 

Previous  work  has  characterized  President  Fernández  de  Kirchner  of  Argentina  as  a  left-­‐wing   populist  (Etchemendy  &  Garay,  2013:  284,  303;  Kaufman,  2013:  94;  Levitsky  &  Roberts,  2013:   13-­‐14;  Roberts,  2013;  Weyland,  2013).  Weyland  for  example  compares  Kirchner’s  leadership   style  to  that  of  other  renowned  left-­‐wing  populist  presidents  –  like  Hugo  Chávez  of  Venezuela   and  the  leaders  of  Bolivia,  Ecuador  and  Nicaragua  (2014:  21)  –  and  argues  that  Kirchner  caused   the   ‘populist   pressures’   on   Argentine   democracy   to   increase   (2013).  Such   populist   pressures   are   often   related   to   pressures   on   the   media:   populists   would   actively   confront   influential   media   outlets   and   employ  policies  of  governmental  activism   in   the   media  realm  (Kitzberger,   2009,   2012;   Waisbord,   2003).   Furthermore,   the   politicization   of   the   media   and   subsequent   conflict  have  been  argued  to  be  caused  by  the  rise  of  left-­‐wing  populism  in  Latin  America,  not   the  least  in  Kirchner’s  Argentina  (Kitzberger,  2012:  135-­‐136).  In  addition  to  being  related  to  the   increase  in  media  conflict,  populists  are  argued  to  benefit  from  the  rise  of  media  platforms  like   radio   and   television.   As   Kirchner’s   use   of   the   Cadena   Nacional   exemplifies,   these   media   can   provide  ways  to  maintain  frequent  and  direct  contact  with  the  masses  and  to  employ  frames   (Weyland,   2001).   All   in   all,   left-­‐wing   populists   are   argued   to   actively   seek   the   confrontation   with  the  media.  

  According  to  O’Donnell,  these  Latin  American  populist  leaders  enjoy  eminent  political   agency  to  shape  society  –  for  instance  the  media  realm  –  without  too  much  constraint:  their   countries  have  ‘delegative  democracy’  systems,  in  which  a  great  amount  of  political  power  is   delegated  to  the  president  who  does  what  he/she  deems  best.  Therefore  “most  political,  social,  

(8)

and  economic  agents  can  disclaim  responsibility”  (1994:  67).  Furthermore,  a  president  can  use   this   power   to   create,   destroy   and   alter   societal   structures   in   a   very   personalized   search   for   stability  (Ibidem).  

Altogether,  the  16S  and  8N  protests  characterize  a  complex  conflict  between  political   authority   and   the   media   in   Argentina.   Herein,   Kirchner’s   populist   leadership   plays   a   central   role:  she  engages  with  and  confronts  the  media  in  several  ways  and,  as  O’Donnell  has  argued,   actually   employs   power   to   (re)shape   the   media   realm   in   a   personalized   search   for   stability.   Motivated  by  the  question  how  Kirchner  attempts  to  do  this,  in  this  thesis  I  aim  to  provide  a   rich   and   grounded   understanding   of   Kirchner’s   populist   efforts   in   the   media.   All   in   all,   this   leads  to  the  following  research  question:  

 

“How  does  President  Fernández  de  Kirchner  construct  political  agency   in  the  Argentine  media  realm?”  

 

In   order   to   be   able   to   answer   this   question,   the   thesis   turns   to   populism   for   its   theoretical   framework.  The  field  of  –  especially  Latin  American  –  populism  studies  provides  an  elaborate   context   for   why   Kirchner   engages   with   the   media   to   construct   political   agency   and   thereby   allows   me   to   theoretically   approach   the   ways   in   which   she   would   do   so.   This   theoretical   assessment   results   in   the   proposition   and   introduction   of   the   concept   of   populist   political   agency,  which  explains  how  populist  leaders  are  able  to  construct  political  agency.  It  presents   two   different   innovative   strategic   angles   in   which   this   is   presumably   done   –   the   institutionalization   of   power   and   the   performance   of   power   –   that   shine   a   new   light   on   populism   in   practice.   These   strategic   angles   will   subsequently   guide   the   case   study   on   Argentina.  

Furthermore,  this  new  concept  fills  a  gap  in  knowledge  on  how  populist  leaders  have   been   able   to   govern   with   electoral   success:   it   has   been   assumed   that   populist   executive   leadership   tends   to   be   a   transitional   period   and   cannot   be   combined   with   electoral   success   (Canovan,  1999:  12;  Weyland,  2001:  14).  But  theory  and  practice  do  not  add  up  here:  in  the   last  fifteen  years  populists  like  Kirchner  in  Argentina  –  but  also  Chávez  in  Venezuela,  Morales  in   Bolivia  and  Correa  in  Ecuador  –  have  been  reelected.  There  is  little  academic  knowledge  and   clarity   on   this   subject,   though   the   question   is   a   very   pressing   and   apparent   one.   Populist   political   agency   however   proposes   that   populist   leaders   maintain   power   by   strategically   creating   structures   of   support   in   society,   which   continuously   construct   political   agency   and   thereby   add   to   and   stabilize   a   populist   president’s   support.   Nevertheless,   in   this   thesis   the  

(9)

concept   of   populist   political   agency   is   only   used   to   research   populist   strategy   in   the   media   realm.   Still,   thereby   the   thesis   will   evaluate   the   concept’s   theoretical   usefulness   for   further   studies  on  populism  in  general  as  well  as  on  conflict  between  left-­‐wing  populist  leaders  and   media,   which   can   be   found   throughout   the   whole   of   Latin-­‐America.   Arguably,   this   is   also   important   because,   increasingly,   media   conflicts   “deeply   affect   the   future   shape   and   role   of   the  media  in  Latin  American  democratic  politics  in  unpredictable  ways”  (Kitzberger,  2012:  136)   and,  in  the  same  vein,  the  populist  left  has  been  argued  to  be  “more  dangerous  for  the  quality   of  democracy  than  the  neoliberal  populist  of  the  right”  in  Latin  America  (Weyland,  2014:  21-­‐ 22).  

 

First,  I  will  explore  and  subsequently  address  my  broader  theoretical  expectations:  that  Latin   American   populists   maintain   power   as   president   by   constructing   political   agency   in   varying   ways  and  that  the  media  realm  is  subject  to  these  efforts.  Second,  a  theoretical  framework  will   be  constructed  in  order  to  analyze  exactly  why  and  how  political  agency  is  constructed  in  the   media  realm  by  a  left-­‐wing  populist  such  as  Kirchner,  using  the  concept  of  populism  as  starting   point.   Third,   following   the   proposition   of   populist   political   agency,   the   concept   is   operationalized   with   regard   to  the   media   realm.   This   divides  the   case   study   in  two  parts:   1)   research  into  how  political  agency  is  constructed  through  the  institutionalization  of  power  in   the  media  realm  in  the  conflict  between  the  Kirchner  administration  and  the  Argentine  media   groups  (most  notably  Clarín);  2)  research  into  how  political  agency  is  constructed  through  the   performance   of   power   through   the   media   in   Kirchner’s   Cadena   Nacional   broadcasts.   Fourth,   the  methods  for  data  collection  are  detailed:  expert  interviews  and  participant  observation  are   utilized.   Finally,   the   two-­‐part   case   study   on   Argentina   will   show   the   multiplicity   in   which   Argentina’s   current   president   Fernández   de   Kirchner   uses   her   presidential   power   in   and   through  the  media  realm  to  construct  political  agency.  The  case  study  will  provide  a  rich  and   detailed   understanding   for   the   media   conflict   in   Argentina,   inform   us   about   what   populist   presidents  are  able  to  accomplish  in  the  media  realm  in  general  and  evaluate  the  theoretical   usefulness  of  the  concept  of  populist  political  agency.  

(10)

Theory: Rethinking populism

 

This   chapter   offers   a   context   to   answer   the   question  why  populists   would   construct   political   agency.   Thereby,   it   allows   me   to   more   specifically   theorize   and   explore  how  this   done.   First,   populism   is   argued   to   be   a   mobilization   strategy   based   on   theories   of   Weyland   (2001)   and   Roberts   (2007).   Second,   the   thesis   turns   to   what   this   definition   means   for   Latin   American   populists   in   power,   which   enables   the   thesis   to   answer  why  populist   presidents   such   as   Kirchner   construct   political   agency.   Third,   Giddens’s   approach   to   political   agency,   combined   with   a   practical   assessment   of   the   definition   of   populism,   presents   a   view   that   comprehends  how  populists  construct  political  agency.  Altogether,  this  brings  me  to  propose   and   define   the   concept   of   populist   political   agency,   which   embodies   an   overarching   understanding   to   both   the   questions   why   and   how   populists   construct   political   agency.   Consequently,   the   two   presented  strategic   angles  in   which   populists   can   construct   political   agency  are  further  detailed  by  an  exploration  of  the  legitimacy-­‐power  mechanism  behind  them.   With   the   offered   understanding,   the   next   chapter   can   then   operationalize   these   angles   of   populist  political  agency  in  the  context  of  a  populist’s  relation  with  the  media,  which  allows  me   to  research  Kirchner’s  construction  of  political  agency  in  the  Argentine  media  realm.  

Although   populist   political   agency   is   meant   to   constitute   a   universally   applicable   concept,   it   should   be   noted   that   its   theoretical   value   is   based   on   studies   to   Latin   American   populism.   As   such,   the   thesis’s   theoretical   conclusions   and   empirical   findings   must   not   be   compared  to  European  populism  too  easily.  

   

Defining  Latin  American  populism  

If  we  are  to  understand  how  Latin  American  populists  construct  political  agency,  it  first  needs   to  be  established  what  it  is  that  populism  means  and  how  it  differentiates  the  politicians  that   are  characterized  by  this  term.  

Since  the  introduction  of  mass  suffrage  and  thereby  mass  politics  in  the  first  half  of  the   20th  century,   Latin   American   waves   of   populist   mobilization   have   been   a   fact   throughout  

history  (Roberts,  2007:  3).  It  is  inescapably  linked  to  historical  period  of  the  Import  Substitution   Industrialization   (ISI)   era,   in   which   interventionist   states   extended   “material   benefits   to   organized   working   and   lower   class   constituencies”   (Ibidem).   In   many   cases   this   system   operated   through   strong   personalistic   leadership   and   the   political   tactics   of   union   leaders,   which   ultimately   impeded   stable   party   building   and   consequently   a   more   thorough   consolidation   of   democracy   (McGuire,   1997;   González,   1999:   214-­‐215).   Such   a   political  

(11)

environment   again   favours   personalistic   leadership:   without   much   democratic   checks   and   balances,   a   charismatic   leader   can   more   successfully   address   the   masses   directly   and   claim   that   it   is   his   personal   mission   to   fight   for   their   cause.   Thereby,   these   shakily   organized   but   comprehensive  political  movements  –  lead  by  populists  –  have  ensured  their  survival.  

Going  back  to  the  notion  of  extending  material  benefits  to  mass  constituencies,  these   populist   movements   are   often   characterized   by   scholars   as   entailing   a   form   of  political  

clientelism:  “the  distribution  of  recourses  (or  promise  of)  by  political  office  holders  or  political  

candidates  in  exchange  for  political  support,  primarily  –  although  not  exclusively  –  in  the  form   of  the  vote”  (Gay,  1990:  648).  Take  for  instance  Argentina’s  Peronism,  which  is  a  broad  social   and  political  movement  (and  according  to  some  an  ideology)  that  “has  been  in  and  out  of  state   power  for  the  last  50  years,  has  been  a  major  political  actor  in  Argentina,  and  has  generated   resilient  socio-­‐political  identities  amongst  popular  groups”  (Auyero,  2000:  58).  This  approach   to   Peronism   unites   the   movement   with   the   concept   of   political   clientelism,   as   it   reproduces   “domination  and  inequality  [and  guarantees]  a  somewhat  stable  number  of  hard-­‐core  voters”   (Auyero,   2000:   74)   and   thereby   also   stimulates   the   frail   political   environment   in   which   populism  flourishes.      

So  if  Peronism  and  other  political  clientelist  party  projects  are  historically  linked  to  the   Latin  American  populist  tradition  (Auyero,  2000,  2001;  de  la  Torre,  1992;  Roberts,  1995),  how   should   modern   populism   be   approached?   Despite   the   fact   that   it   does   –   in   the   case   of   left-­‐ wing  populism  –often  entail  gaining  support  of  lower  classes  by  extending  material  benefits  to   them,   the   ways   in   which   this   is   reached   vary   greatly.   Latin   American   populism   survived   the   demise   of   the   ISI   era   and   “coexisted   with   —   or   even   implemented   —   neoliberal   structural   adjustment   policies”   (Roberts,   2007:   4).   During   and   after   the   1980s,   strikingly   different   examples   of   populist   leadership   have   been   identified   in   Latin   America,   from   the   neoliberal   variants  of  Menem  to  more  statist  leftist  ones  of  Chávez.  Therefore,  populism  should  not  be   understood   as   a   primarily   economic   phenomenon.   Roberts   offers   a   useful   example   of   the   different   economic   policies   that   have   been   proposed   by   Peronist   populist   leaders:   when   Néstor   Kirchner   “outmanoeuvred   his   rivals   to   consolidate   a   high   degree   of   personal   control   over   Peronism’s   vast   but   fractious   party   machine”   he   pulled   the   party   back   towards   its   nationalist   and   statist   roots   after   the   failed   neoliberal   experiment   by   “Kirchner’s   Peronist   predecessor  Carlos  Menem  in  the  1990s”  (2007:  12).  

   

In   summary:   by   placing   populism   in   such   a   comparative   historical   perspective   as   Robert’s   account  above  (2007),  one  can  more  adequately  explore  its  meaning.  Although  an  economic-­‐

(12)

focused  definition  is  tempting  at  first  glance,  it  does  not  cover  the  historical  manifestations  of   populist  leadership  in  Latin  America:  economic  policies  have  been  the  result  of  very  different   experiences,  which  would  then  all  qualify  as  populism  (Weyland,  2001:  11).  Rather,  this  thesis   turns   towards   a   political   definition   of   populism,   as  a   “specific   way   of   competing   for   and   exercising  political  power”  (Weyland,  2001:  11).  In  this  political  competition,  socio-­‐economic   measures   and   policies   make   up   instruments   rather   than   the   core   of   populists.   As   such,   populism  constitutes  a  more  universal  definition  that  can  be  used  throughout  history  on  for   instance  the  “classical  populist  Perón,  neopopulist  Alan  García,  conservative  José  Sarney,  and   Marxist  Salvador  Allende”  (Weyland,  2001:  11;  Sachs,  1989:  17-­‐23).  

More  specifically,  the  thesis  utilizes  Roberts’s  definition  of  populism  as  “the  top-­‐down   political   mobilization   of   mass   constituencies   by   personalistic   leaders   who   challenge   elite   groups  on  behalf  of  an  ill-­‐defined  pueblo,  or  ‘the  people’“  (2007:  5).  This  definition  is  in  line   with  Weyland’s  view  of  populism,  which  focuses  on  “the  basic  goal  of  populist  leaders,  to  win   and  exercise  power,  while  using  economic  and  social  policy  as  an  instrument  for  this  purpose”   (2001:  11).  Both  scholars  thus  approach  a  minimal  definition  of  populism  with  a  focus  on  the   intent  and  goals  of  populists  themselves,  namely  the  mobilization  of  the  masses.  

Altogether,   populism   constitutes   a  mobilization   strategy.   Still,   Roberts   does   incorporate   the   two   classical   characteristics   that   are   ascribed   to   populists   in   almost   every   political   definition,   whether   considered   a   political   communication   style   (Jagers   &   Walgrave,   2007),   an   ideology   (Mudde,   2004;   Rooduijn   &   Pauwels,   2011)   or   as   a   specific   set   of   ideas   (Hawkins   et   al.,   2012).   These   characteristics   are   that   populists   a)   target   the   masses   by   spreading  an  anti-­‐establishment  sentiment  and  b)  appeal  to  the  ‘virtuous’  and  true  people  of  a   country   (Roberts,   2007:   5).   Populists   should   thus   be   seen   as   politicians   who   employ   wide   varieties  of  strategies  and  instruments  to  gain  the  support  of  mass  constituencies.  Now  let  us   turn  to  what  this  means  for  populists  in  power  like  Kirchner.  

   

Populists  in  power  

With  the  ‘anti-­‐establishment’  characterization  of  populist  strategy,  Robert’s  definition  already   hints  at  the  shared  academic  assumption  on  populists  in  power:  that  they  cannot  govern  as   they  make  up  the  establishment  that  they  normally  criticize.  Weyland  has  for  instance  argued   that  populist  executive  leadership  tends  to  be  a  transitory  period,  because  it  “either  fails  or,  if   successful,   transcends   itself”   in   a   democratic   system   (2001:   14).   He   further   claims   that,   in   recent  history,  at  least  three  Latin  American  presidents  were  removed  from  office  due  to  this   reason   (2001:   16).   Canovan   further   details   why   populists   would   fail   by   explaining   that   they  

(13)

cannot  live  up  to  their  broad  promises  when  chosen  as  chief  executive  (1999:  12).  This  view   coincides  with  the  general  contention  that  populists  and  authoritarian  rulers  gain  support  in   settings  of  institutional  frailty  by  making  promises  without  much  cost  to  anyone,  while,  once  in   power,  government  policies  will  hit  many  parts  of  the  country’s  population  (O’Donnell,  1994:   66).  

Nevertheless,  in  the  last  decade,  several  populist  leaders  have  governed  with  electoral   success:  Chávez  (Venezuela),  Morales  (Bolivia),  Correa  (Ecuador)  and  Kirchner  (Argentina)  have   all  been  re-­‐elected.  This  poses  an  issue  in  the  academic  field  on  populism.  But  when  populism   is  defined  as  a  mobilization  strategy,  as  it  is  here,  it  actually  does  not  seem  so  strange  that  a   populist  in  power  manages  to  maintain  power.  After  all,  the  winning  and  exercising  of  power   are  put  central  as  the  main  goal  of  populists  (Weyland,  2001:  11).  It  suggests  that  populists  can   utilize  certain  instruments  to  maintain  power  –  like  for  instance  extending  material  benefits  to   the  poor  –  that  counter  the  likelihood  of  a  “shift  from  wide  popularity  to  general  vilification   [that]  can  be  as  rapid  as  it  is  dramatic”  (O’Donnell,  1994:  66).  In  short:  most  scholars  in  the   field   on   Latin   American   populism   never   accounted   for   other   instruments   –   besides   socio-­‐ economic  measures  –  that,  in  theory,  prevent  such  rapid  ‘vilification’.  Thus,  it  seems  likely  that   successfully  governing  populists  have  employed  other  instruments  with  which  they  maintain   support  and  power.  More  recently,  Weyland  hinted  at  the  practices  of  Chávez,  which  further   supports  this  view:  he  has  provided  a  sort  of  successful  populist  script  to  govern  with  electoral   success,   which   regards   strategic   measures   like   reinvigorating   the   constitution,   special   tax   audits  to  critics  and,  indeed,  ceaselessly  opposing  critical  media  outlets  (2013).  

All  in  all,  I  propose  that,  instead  of  failing  or  transcending  their  populist  characteristics,   these   presidents   aim   to   create   and   have   created  populist   structures   of   support  in   society:   structural  factors  that  strengthen  the  bond  of  the  populist  and  his/her  constituency  in  order  to   maintain   a   high   and   stable   level   of   support.   This   view   presents   an   understanding   for   the   question  why  populists  would  construct  political  agency:  when  they  are  in  power,  they  need  to   rely  on  structural  factors  instead  of  broad  promises  to  maintain  their  support.  In  the  following   paragraph,   I   address   how   this   view   relates   to   the   broader   academic   discussion   on   structure   and  agency.  Afterwards,  I  set  out  to  also  answer  the  question  how  populists  construct  political   agency.  The  answers  to  both  the  questions  why  and  how  populists  construct  political  agency,  is   ultimately  incorporated  in  the  proposition  of  the  concept  of  populist  political  agency.  

       

(14)

Structure/agency  –  the  construction  of  political  agency  

The   argument   that   populist   presidents   utilize   certain   populist   structures   of   support   logically   brings  up  the  question:  are  they  indeed  able  to  do  so?  This  question  inquires  into  the  larger   academic   debate   in   the   social   sciences   about   the   importance   of   agency   and/or   structure   in   society.  I  follow  Giddens’s  philosophical  academic  perspective,  which  presupposes  a  complex   dynamic   between   the   two:   structure   and   agency   are   constantly   influencing   each   other.   He   defines   political   agency   as   “the   stream   of   actual   or   contemplated   causal   interventions   of   corporeal  beings  in  the  ongoing  process  of  events-­‐in-­‐the-­‐world”  (1976:  75).  Within  the  field  of   politics,   agency   then   represents   deliberate   actions   that   intervene   in   political   and   social   structures.  Structures  are  understood  as  practices  that  are  built  up  from  “rules  and  resources,   recursively   implicated   in   the   reproduction   of   social   systems”   (1984:   377).  These   rules   are   “generalizable   procedures   applied   in   the   enactment/reproduction   of   social   life"   (1984:   21),   whereas   resources   form   the   sources   of   power   that   are   activated   by   rules   and   guide   social   interaction.  A  good  metaphor  that  is  often  used  to  put  this  into  context  is  that  of  language:   there   are   certain  rules  to   language   that   people   use   to   communicate;   however,   there   is   also   room  for  interpretation  and  language  keeps  changing  (e.g.  new  rules  are  formed)  due  to  the   lively  social  practices  of  interaction,  which  are  the  resources  of  language.  

This   two-­‐sided   interpretation   has   been   coined   the   ‘duality   of   structure’   by   Giddens:   agents   are   guided   by   this   social   interaction   in   their   actions,   but   at   the   same   time   structure   results   from   these   social   practices,   be   it   by   the   employment   of   political   agency   or   the   consequences   of   past   actions.   Therefore,   as   Giddens   states:   “structure   is  both  medium   and   outcome  of  reproduction  of  practices”  (1979:  5).  

Let  us  now  adjust  Giddens’s  approach  to  this  thesis’s  subject:  politicians  aim  to  shape   society   by   governing   and   implementing   policies   that   are   translated   into   laws.  In   this   perspective,   democratic   politics   lets   the   few   exercise   agency   in   name   of   the   many,   thereby   placing  a  significant  amount  of  agency  at  the  top  of  the  societal  hierarchy.  As  was  argued  by   O’Donnell,  Latin  American  presidents  even  wield  more  political  agency,  which  is  delegated  to   them  in  a  setting  of  institutional  weakness  and  which  they  often  use  in  a  personalized  search   for  stability  (1994).  They  are  thereby  better  enabled   to  establish  structures:  they  can  create   certain  structures  that  form  rules  for  the  societal  practices.  

In  summary:  a  Latin  American  president  is  presumed  able  to  destroy,  alter  or  create   societal   structures   with   deliberate   actions   that   intervene   in   society.   In   other   words:   with   political   agency.   The   twist   of   this   thesis   of   course   being   that   populist   actively   strategize   to   use  their   power   to   create  more  space   for   their   own   political   agency,   by   altering   the   societal  

(15)

system  that  gives  them  power.  The  notion  of  populist  strategy  in  exerting  agency  also  fits  with   Giddens’s  argument  that  an  agent  is  self-­‐aware  of  the  potential  of  his  actions  as  well  as  of  the   context   that   sets   limits   for   these   actions.  Think   of   (left-­‐wing   as   well   as   neoliberal)   populist   presidents   Fujimori   from   Peru,   Chávez   from   Venezuela,   Uribe   from   Colombia   and   also  Fernández  de  Kirchner  from  Argentina,  who  all  aimed  to  formally  extend  their  term  limits,   successful  or  not.  

Considering  all  the  above,  I  aim  to  have  clarified  that  active  populist  strategies  have   the   potential   to   construct   political   agency   by   creating   and/or   altering   populist   structures   of   support.  These  structures  presuppose  the  employment  of  strategic  instruments  with  which  a   populist   stabilizes   his/her   support;   this   thesis   specifically   focuses   on   the   strategic   efforts   of   Kirchner  to  utilize  populist  structures  of  support  in  the  media.    

   

Defining  populist  political  agency  

It  has  thus  far  been  argued  that  populism  should  be  understood  as  a  mobilization  strategy  and   that   Latin   American   populists   strategize   to   construct   political   agency   by   placing   populist   structures   of   support   in   society.   A   second   step   is   to   look   what   these   populist   structures   of   support   look   like,   in   order   to   provide   an   understanding   that   also   answers   the   question  how  populists  construct  political  agency.  

Weyland  argues  that  a  focus  on  uninstitutionalized  mass  support  is  useful  to  explore   populism   in   a   practical   way   (Weyland,   2001:   16).   This   thesis   has   claimed   that   populist   presidents   aim   to   prevent   a   rapid   fall   in   popularity   with   populist   structures   of   support.   The   assumption   behind   this   was   that   they   initially   have   a   strong   but   easily   breakable   bond   with   their  electorate,  based  on  broad  promises  they  had  made  as  candidates.  With  help  of  Weyland,   the  thesis  now  offers  an  in-­‐depth  look  at  this  assumption:  

Populists’  “lack  of  firm  organized  support”  (Ibidem)  makes  them  politically  vulnerable.   Therefore,   to   compensate   for   “the   fragility   of   their   mass   support,   populist   leaders   seek   to   create  a  particularly  intense  connection  to  their  followers”  (Weyland,  2001:  13).  Indeed,  they   tend   to   rely   on   a   direct   and   fluid   relationship   with   the   masses,   which   is   intensified   with   a   personal   appeal   of   charisma   (Ibidem).   Weyland   describes   a   populist’s   charisma   as   “a   supernatural  capacity  to  represent  and  lead  the  people,  rescue  them  from  adversity  and  usher   in   progress”   (Weyland,   2001:   13-­‐14).   This   is   also   what   Roberts   refers   to   with   the   use   of   the   word  ‘personalistic’  in  his  definition  of  populism.  Virtually  every  successful  populist  (elections-­‐ wise)  is  synonymous  with  the  concept  of  charismatic  rule:  it  signifies  his/her  capacity  to  truly  

(16)

speak  to  the  hearts  of  people,  convince  them  and  win  them  for  his/her  cause,  whatever  that   may  be.  

It  follows  that  this  central  feature  of  populism  plays  an  important  role  in  a  populist’s   structures   of   support:   in   some   way   he/she   maintains   the   support   from   the   masses   by   employing  charisma.  Weyland  for  instance  stresses  the  importance  of  the  spread  of  television   for  populists,  as  it  allows  them  to  reach  the  masses  directly  and  create  a  personal  relationship   with  them  (2001:  16).  So  a  populist’s  charismatic  appeal  forms  the  basis  for  the  bond  with  the   masses  and  the  stronger  this  bond  is,  the  less  it  matters  for  his/her  support  if  economic  issues   come  up  or  if  promises  are  not  kept.  After  all,  his/her  followers  will  be  convinced  that  it  is  not   the  populist’s  fault.  With  the  populist’s  ability  to  speak  to  the  hearts,  people’s  ability  to  judge   objectively   is   blurred   and   hearts   are   actually   won.   All   in   all,   populists   seem   to   construct   political  agency  through  populist  structures  of  support  that  assess  their  charisma.  

Furthermore,   we   can   recognize   another   way   in   which   populist   structures   of   support   help   a   populist   chief   executive   maintain   support.   The   establishment   of   the   direct   and   fluid   relationship   with   the   masses   implies   that   other   more   indirect   forms   of   a   bond   between   a   populist   and   his/her   electorate   are   shunned   (Weyland,   2001:   16).   Indeed,   Weyland   also   concludes  modern  media  “further  diminished  populists’  interest  in  organized  intermediation”   (2001:  16);  something  political  parties  normally  pursue.  Low  levels  of  institutionalization  leave   room  for  a  populist  to  shape  and  dominate  his/her  organization.  But  party  organization  is  not   avoided   altogether.   Rather,   “to   stabilize   their   rule   many   populist   leaders   eventually   seek   to   ‘routinize   their   charisma’   and   solidify   their   mass   following   by   introducing   elements   of   party   organization   or   clientelism”   (Weyland,   2001:   14).   The   difference   being   that   these   populist   organizations  –  such  as  the  highly  disciplined  party  machine  from  Haya  de  la  Torre  (Peru)  or   the  government  supported  grass-­‐roots  Bolivarian  Circles  (Venezuela)  –  offer  almost  no  ways  to   influence  policy  on  higher  levels.  Rather,  their  main  function  is  to  cultivate  populists’  support   and  ‘stabilize  their  rule’,  as  Weyland  coined  it  well  (Ibidem).  Furthermore,  Roberts  adds  that   these   populist   organizations   also   serve   to   counteract   elite   threats   and   “crowd   out   new   or   competing  populist  projects”  (2007:  7-­‐8).  

Everything   considered,   these   political   institutions   thus   form   populist   structures   of   support:  they  represent  structural  factors  that  maintain  a  stable  level  of  support.  So  a  second   way   in   which   populists   construct   political   agency   is   through   manners   of   institutionalization  

that   contrast   regular   party   institutionalization.   Together   with   the   earlier   mentioned   way   of  

constructing   political   agency   –   through   structures   that   assess   a   populist’s   charisma   –,   the   established  view  also  answers  the  question  how  populists  construct  political  agency.  

(17)

Now   I   am   able   to   propose   and   define   the   concept   of  populist   political   agency:   the   strategic  aim  and  active  efforts  of  a  populist  to  create  populist  structures  of  support  amongst   mass   constituencies   in   a   manner   that   a)   contrasts   regular   party   institutionalization   and   b)   highlights  his/her  charisma.  Populist  political  agency  thus  symbolizes  a  sort  of  virtuous  circle:  a   populist   uses   political   agency   to   construct   more   political   agency.   Theoretically,   this   concept   enriches   the   field   of   populism   studies   by   comprehending   both   why   and   how   populists   construct  political  agency  and  thereby  are  able  to  maintain  power  without  abandoning  their   populist  ways.  Below,  I  further  explore  the  theoretical  mechanism  behind  the  two  manners  in   which  populists  construct  agency,  after  which  these  can  be  operationalized  in  the  next  chapter   so   that   they   can   guide   the   thesis’s   case   study   to   Kirchner’s   populist   political   agency  in   the   media  realm.  

   

The  legitimacy-­‐power  mechanism  of  the  two  strategic  angles  

Populist   political   agency   is   thus   taken   with   exerting   political   agency   to   construct   political   agency,  which  again  creates  space  for  the  enactment  of  presidential  actions  and  decisions  that   intervene   in   societal   structures.   This   cycle   can   also   be   understood   in   terms   of  power  and  legitimacy:  power  is  exerted  to  construct  legitimacy,  which  provides  the  populist   with  more  stable  support  and  therefore  with  more  potential  for  the  exertion  of  power.  After   all,  since  populists  in  opposition  have  been  argued  to  have  the  main  goal  to  mobilize  support   (becoming  legitimate  as  a  leader),  populists  in  power  seemingly  have  the  goal  to  maintain  their   support   and   position   (staying   legitimate   as   a   leader).   This   mechanism   of   populist   political   agency   thus   concerns   a   cycle,   which   –   with   effective   populist   structures   of   support   –   is   potentially  ever  continuing:  Chávez  for  instance  reigned  as  the  Venezuelan  president  until  his   death,  just  after  his  reelection  for  the  fourth  time  in  a  row.  Such  maintaining  of  power  asks  for   the  construction  of  enough  political  agency,  which  thus  can  be  understood  as  having  the  aim   to  enlarge  a  populist’s  legitimacy  as  a  leader.  

Weber’s  view  of  the  sorts  of  legitimate  rule  provides  a  way  to  distinguish  between  the   kinds  of  legitimacies  that  can  be  enlarged  by  populist  political  agency  (1978).  He  analyzes  three   ideal  types  of  legitimate  rule  as  having  three  different  reasons  for  legitimacy  at  their  core:      

1. Traditional   legitimate   rule,   as   derived   from   “an   established   belief   in   the   sanctity   of   immemorial   traditions   and   the   legitimacy   of   those   exercising   authority   under   them”   (Weber,  1978:  215).  This  would  concern  a  person  that  is  chosen  to  lead  people  out  of  

(18)

tradition  or  belief,  or  gets  such  a  position  due  to  its  heritage,  for  instance  a  king,  the   pope  or  a  priest;  

 

2. Legal-­‐rational   legitimate   rule,   as   derived   from   the   “belief   in   the   legality   of   enacted   rules  and  the  right  of  those  elevated  to  authority  under  such  rules  to  issue  commands”   (Ibidem).   This   would   concern   a   person   that   is   appointed   to   lead   people   through   commonly  accepted  rules  like  an  association’s  statutes  or  the  constitution,  for  instance   a  teacher,  a  member  of  congress  or  for  that  matter  the  chairman  of  a  bank;  

 

3. Charismatic  legitimate  rule,  as  derived  from  the  “devotion  to  the  exceptional  sanctity,   heroism  or  exemplary  character  of  an  individual  person,  and  of  the  normative  patterns   or  order  revealed  or  ordained  by  him”  (Ibidem).  This  would  concern  a  person  that  has   enacted  or  shown  exceptional  qualities  and  virtues  like  prudence,  courage  or  modesty.      

As   stated   by   Weber,   this   distinction   serves   to   enable   systematic   analysis,   while   these   ideal   types  are  usually  not  found  in  their  ‘pure’  form  (1978:  216).  Rather,  legitimate  rule  rests  on  a   mix   of   these   sorts   of   legitimacy   and   not   only   on   one   or   the   other.   Nevertheless,   the   thesis   discards   the   kind   of   legitimacy   that   comes   from   traditional   sources;   in   Latin   America   today   there  are  no  leaders  with  political/executive  power  who  got  their  power  from  such  religious  or   monarchic  traditions:  politicians  are  democratically  chosen  as  presidents,  as  executive  leaders.   Religion  and  sanctity  nowadays  only  play  a  role  in  the  church,  of  which  the  Latin-­‐American  top   might  have  informal  networking  power  due  to  its  role  of  facilitator  of  mobilization  of  rural  and   indigenous  communities  (Trejo,  2009).  But  this  kind  of  legitimacy  thus  cannot  be  attributed  to   democratically   chosen   political   leaders.   That   leaves   two   ideal   types   of   sources   of   legitimacy   that   are   applicable   to   Latin   American   democracies:   legal-­‐rational   and   charismatic.   In   the   current  Latin  American  democracies,  these  two  are  logically  intertwined.  The  president  derives   its   power   of   making   political   decisions   from   the   fact   that   he/she   occupies   the   position   of   president  as  the  constitution  prescribes  it  in  a  society  of  law.  Let  us  characterize  this  as  a  short-­‐

term  kind  of  legitimacy  for  a  chief  executive’s  political  agency,  due  to  its  immediate  reference  

to  the  backbone  of  a  constitutional  democracy.  The  charismatic  legitimacy  then  is  a  more  long-­‐

term  kind  of  legitimacy:  politicians  and  particularly  populists  use  their  charisma  over  time  to  

build   up   character   and   gain   support,   to   ultimately   be   elected   and  stay  elected   as   president,   which  consequently  results  in  legal-­‐rational  legitimacy  as  well.  Vice  versa,  with  legal-­‐rational   legitimacy,   the   president   also   occupies   a   position   in   which   he   or   she   can   potentially   gain   in  

(19)

charismatic  legitimacy  due  to  the  publicity  and  power  that  come  with  the  position.  Each  form   of  legitimacy  thus  creates  potential  for  the  politician  to  increase  the  other.  

   

Now  let  us  focus  on  the  conceptual  sorts  of  power  with  which  these  two  kinds  of  legitimacies   can   be   enlarged.   Combining   the   twofold   approach   to   the   power-­‐legitimacy   mechanism   with   the  definition  of  populist  political  agency  below,  leads  me  to  connect  the  two  strategic  angles   with   which   populist   political   agency   is   constructed   to   these   kinds   of   legitimacy   and   thereby   further  detail  them.  

Firstly,  legal-­‐rational  legitimacy  corresponds  well  to  Dahl’s  classical  view  of  the  use  of   power,  that  states  that  “A  has  power  over  B  to  the  extent  that  he  can  get  B  to  do  something   that  B  would  not  otherwise  do”  (1957:  203).  This  behavioral  view  of  power  is  concerned  with   the  manifest,  visible  and  observable  use  of  power:  legal-­‐rational  legitimacy  can  come  forth  out   of   manifest   actions   that   change   the   rules/laws   of   society.   Everything   considered,   the   thesis   proposes   that   populists   actively   institutionalize   power   to   maximize   their   legal-­‐rational   legitimacy:  the   way   society   works   is   altered   by   using   formal   tools   such   as   laws   but   also   by   informal  tools  such  as  exerting  pressure  on  other  actors.  A  constitutional  change  that  allows   the  president  to  serve  an  extra  term  falls  under  this  category  for  instance,  as  well  as  silencing   critics  by  for  instance  prohibiting  certain  associations  or  burdening  them  with  additional  taxes.   To  summarize,  these  kinds  of  populist  structures  of  support  are  used  to  get  a  grip  on  political   life  (influencing  what  is  legal)  as  well  as  civic  life  (influencing  the  discussion).  

Secondly,  this  thesis  argues  that  charismatic  legitimacy  can  also  be  forthcoming  out  of   an  exertion  of  power.  However,  this  constitutes  a  rather  unorthodox  and  new  view  of  power   that   draws   on   and   combines   elements   of   the   views   of   Lukes   (1957),   Bachrach   and   Baratz   (1962),   Goffman   (2003)   and   Hajer   (2009):   a   populist   can  perform   power  through   agenda-­‐ setting  and  framing,  which  has  to  potential  to  enlarge  a  populist’s  charismatic  legitimacy.  Let   me  illustrate  this  with  a  remark  of  ‘The  New  Yorker’  reporter  Anderson,  who  noticed  that  Hugo   Chávez   performs   government   live   on   television   (Anderson   2008;   Kitzberger,   2009:   9):   on   television   Chávez   was   portrayed   as   the   listening   leader   who   helped   Venezuela   where   and   when   it   was   necessary,   with   which   he   spoke   to   his   charismatic   legitimacy.   Charisma   in   this   sense  thus  has  everything  to  do  with  creating  a  frame  about  the  populist’s  virtuous  leadership.   All   in   all,   the   notion   of   performing   power   is   relatively   new   and   not   yet   understood   in   its   complexity   –   especially   with   regard   to   populist   tendencies   –,   but   Hajer   has   done   groundbreaking   research   on   the   performance   of   authoritative   governance.   However,   Hajer   states  that  authority  should  not  be  confused  with  power  (Hajer,  2009:  20;  Friedrich,  1958),  as  

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

Contextual cues of information online, such as source expertise, comment sentiment, and advertisement are thought to influence the perceived credibility of

By performing both functions at the same time, the role of information provider and of arena for promotion, the news media form a formidable resource for politicians affecting the

The introduction contains a clear and interesting research question that follows logically from the rationale of the study. The introduction contains a very clear,

[r]

Moreover, the activation of dendritic cells (DCs) by tumor-derived DNA induced the expression of cofactors that are crucial for T cell activation. Additionally,

(III) Considering the history of Utopia, however, little justice is done to Jesus’ life and works, his death and resurrection, as especially the latter gives actual and

In the second example the first instance of the pronoun uses the switching version ( \heshe ) (here assuming it has been already used once), but subsequent anaphoric references to

The cylindrical magnet, which has a more than 50 times higher magnetic volume than the cubes, shows roughly the same variation in magnetisation. From this, we can conclude