• No results found

Wage rigidity in Portugal : a DSGE approach

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Wage rigidity in Portugal : a DSGE approach"

Copied!
51
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

University  of  Amsterdam    

MSc  in  Economics  –  Monetary  Policy  and  Banking   Supervisor:  Dr.  Christian  A.  Stoltenberg  

Student  number:  10605169                

Francisco  Pais  de  Sousa  

                 

Wage  Rigidity  In  Portugal  –  A  DSGE  Approach  

                             

July  2014  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(2)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Abstract:  

 

 

In  this  thesis  I  study  the  impact  of  wage  rigidity  on  the  Portuguese  business  cycle   fluctuations.  I  do  so  by  building  on  a  small  open  economy  DSGE  model  and  data   on   public   sector   careers   and   minimum   wage   negotiations   in   Portugal.   My   findings  suggest  that  Portugal  has  a  high  level  of  wage  rigidity  in  the  European   context.   Especially,   the   public   sector   careers   and   minimum   wage   negotiations   denote   a   very   lengthy   process   of   wage   adjustment.   High   wage   rigidity   implies   less   responsive   wage   inflation.   In   the   event   of   a   monetary   contraction,   this   results  in  a  lesser  decrease  of  price  inflation  in  Portugal.  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(3)

 

Contents    

 

 

 

1-­‐  Introduction………  3   2-­‐  Literature  Review  ………...  5   3-­‐  Model  .………  7     3.1  –  Households    ……….…...7  

  3.2  -­‐  Terms  of  Trade  and  International  Risk  Sharing  ………11  

  3.3  –  Firms  ……….………..12  

  3.4  -­‐  Foreign  Country    ………...15  

  3.5  –  Equilibrium    ………...16  

  3.6  -­‐  Log-­‐linearized  Equations  and  Monetary  Policy  Rule  ……….18  

4-­‐  Portuguese  Labour  Market  ………...23  

5-­‐  Wage  Rigidity  Parameter  ……….26  

6-­‐  Impulse  Response  Analysis  and  Policy  Implications  ………...30  

6.1  –  Portuguese  level  of  wage  rigidity  compared  to  wage  flexibility  …...  31  

  6.2  –  Portuguese  economy  as  a  whole  compared  to  two  of  its  sectors…..  35  

7-­‐  Conclusion  ……….36   8-­‐  References  .………....38   9-­‐  Appendix  ……….41                                                      

(4)

1  -­‐  Introduction  

 

 

Nominal  wage  rigidity  is  a  structural  characteristic  of  the  Portuguese  economy.  It   is  historically  connected  to  the  period  that  followed  the  democratic  revolution  of   1974,   during   which   workers   generally   improved   their   contractual   conditions,   especially  those  with  permanent  contracts.  The  phenomenon  of  wage  rigidity  is  a   divisive  topic  in  Portuguese  politics,  as  left  wing  parties  see  the  conquered  rights   with  good  eyes  while  right  wing  parties  refer  to  it  as  one  of  the  main  weaknesses   of  the  Portuguese  economy.    

The   last   three   years   made   the   debate   on   labour   market   rigidity   become   a   hot   topic   in   the   Portuguese   society.   Since   the   17th   of   May   2011,   Portugal   has   been  

under   financial   assistance   from   the   so-­‐called   Troika   (European   Commission,   European  Central  Bank  and  International  Monetary  Fund).  During  this  period  of   influence,   all   these   institutions   have   repeatedly   stated   that   Portugal   should   increase   the   flexibility   of   its   labour   market.   Furthermore,   the   ruling   prime   minister  of  Portugal,  Pedro  Passos  Coelho,  has  been  publicly  in  favour  of  greater   labour  market  flexibility  since  he  started  to  run  for  office  in  2010.  Aligned  with   this,  the  push  for  reforms  in  the  labour  market  has  been  visible,  despite  the  well-­‐ established  power  of  the  trade  unions.    

In  2011  the  World  Economic  Forum  ranked  Portugal  111th  out  of  142  countries  

with  respect  to  ‘flexibility  of  wage  determination’.  In  2013,  Portugal  changed  its   position  to  105th  out  of  148  countries.  

 

Wage   rigidity   introduces   the   hypothesis   that   the   wage   setting   process   is   not   perfectly  flexible.  Assuming  a  flexible  wage  setting  process,  households  optimally   alter   the   price   of   the   labour   they   supply   whenever   the   state   of   the   economy   requires  it.  Therefore,  wage  rigidity  questions  the  ability  of  every  household  to   adapt  instantly  to  shocks  in  the  economy  via  changes  in  the  price  of  their  labour.   This   causes   nominal   wages   to   be   less   responsive   to   the   economy   fluctuations.   Assuming   sticky   prices,   the   bigger   the   degree   of   wage   rigidity,   the   less   responsive  to  the  economy  fluctuations  real  wages  are.  Moreover,  the  evolution   of  wages  and  prices  are  connected  to  each  other.  Wage  rigidity  might  cause  wage   and  price  inflation  to  be  persistently  far  away  from  their  long-­‐term  values.  This   generates   inefficient   allocations   of   resources   and   reduces   welfare.   That   being   said,  rigid  wages  increase  the  importance  of  inflation  stabilization.  

 

In   order   to   analyze   the   role   played   by   the   Portuguese   labour   market   nominal   wage   rigidity   in   the   Portuguese   business   cycle,   I   use   a   Dynamic   Stochastic   General   Equilibrium   small-­‐scale   small   open   economy   model.   The   model   combines  the  small  open  economy  model  by  Walsh  (2010)  with  the  Calvo-­‐type   staggered  wage  setting  as  in  Erceg,  Henderson  and  Levin  (2000)  and  Galí  (2008).   Also,  I  provide  a  short  description  of  the  Portuguese  labour  market  and  highlight   the  importance  of  the  minimum  wage  discussions  and  the  public  sector  careers   for   the   study   of   wage   rigidity   in   Portugal.   I   build   on   established   literature   and   data  on  the  public  sector  careers  and  minimum  wage  negotiations  to  construct   three  different  wage  rigidity  parameters.  One  denotes  the  labour  market  rigidity   of   the   Portuguese   economy   as   a   whole.   The   second   denotes   the   rigidity  

(5)

concerning  the  minimum  wage  negotiations  and  the  third  refers  to  the  nominal   wage   rigidity   of   the   Portuguese   public   sector   careers.   Finally,   using   the   DSGE   model,   I   discuss   the   impact   of   different   levels   of   wage   rigidity   on   the   transmission   of   shocks   in   an   economy.   I   do   so   by   comparing   the   three   constructed   wage   rigidity   parameters   with   the   scenarios   of   a   standard   level   of   labour  market  flexibility  and  of  total  flexibility.  From  these  comparisons,  I  draw   policy  implications  of  wage  rigidity  for  the  Portuguese  economy.    

 

Two   results   from   the   construction   of   the   three   wage   rigidity   parameters   are   worth   accentuating.   Firstly,   the   Portuguese   economy   degree   of   nominal   wage   rigidity   is   very   high   in   the   European   context.   In   practical   terms,   it   takes   significantly  more  than  one  year,  on  average,  until  a  household  gets  the  chance  to   reset  wages.  This  is  in  line  with  the  established  literature  on  this  topic  and  with   the   EPL   Index   by   OECD.   Secondly,   the   level   of   rigidity   regarding   the   minimum   wage  negotiations  and  the  public  sector  careers  is  even  higher  than  that  of  the   Portuguese   economy   as   a   whole.   This   is   also   aligned   with   the   established   literature  on  this  topic  because  these  two  particular  negotiations  are  associated   with  more  pronounced  influence  of  collecting  bargaining  and  trade  unions.      

I  highlight  one  main  result  from  analyzing  the  impact  of  different  wage  rigidity   levels   on   the   transmission   of   shocks   in   a   small   open   economy.   It   results   from   comparing   the   Portuguese   level   of   wage   rigidity   with   a   flexible   wage   setting   economy.  The  Portuguese  economy  denotes  substantial  wage  rigidity  compared   to   other   countries.   Consequently,   wage   inflation   becomes   less   responsive.   This   implies  that  the  decrease  of  price  inflation  is  less  pronounced  after  a  monetary   contraction   in   Portugal.   Furthermore,   I   emphasize   one   main   policy   implication   for  the  Portuguese  economy.  Wage  rigidity  increases  the  importance  of  inflation   stabilization  for  an  economy.  As  the  Portuguese  denotes  a  higher  level  of  wage   rigidity   than   many   other   economies,   this   implies   that   inflation   stabilization   becomes   more   important   for   the   Portuguese   economy   compared   to   economies   with  more  flexible  wages.  

 

In   the   next   section   I   provide   a   brief   overview   of   the   related   literature.   Then   I   explain  the  small  open  economy  DSGE  model.  In  the  following  sections  I  analyze   the   Portuguese   labour   market   and   explore   the   theoretical   concept   of   wage   rigidity.  In  the  end,  I  analyze  the  impact  of  wage  rigidity  in  the  transmission  of   shocks  and  draw  policy  implications  from  it.    

       

 

 

 

 

 

 

(6)

2  -­‐  Literature  Review  

 

 

In  this  section  I  provide  a  brief  reference  to  the  evolution  of  the  studies  on  the   topics   covered   by   this   thesis.   In   order   to   do   so,   I   highlight   relevant   events   and   literature  on  the  topics  of  macroeconomic  modeling  and  wage  rigidity.  

 

Macroeconomic   analysis   relied   on   large-­‐scale   models   during   the   1960’s   and   1970’s.   These   models   incorporated   economic   theory   in   their   equations.   However,  their  coefficients  were  determined  using  time  series  analysis  and  were   assumed  to  remain  constant  over  time,  which  has  raised  much  criticism.  Robert   Lucas   (1976),   in   his   famous   “Lucas   critique”,   claimed   that   the   economic   parameters  estimated  by  these  models  were  not  structural,  but  rather  time  and   policy  varying.    

Rational  decision-­‐making  and  microeconomic  foundations  were  brought  by  the   seminal   work   of   Kydland   and   Prescott   (1982),   which   featured   formation   of   expectations  in  a  general  equilibrium  model.  Firms  and  households  were  optimal   and   faced   intertemporal   maximization   problems   while   a   perfectly   competitive   economy   with   no   kind   of   rigidities   was   assumed.   Also,   fluctuations   were   both   endogenous   and   optimal   for   a   given   equilibrium   of   the   variables   of   the   model   and,   thus,   policymaking   was   fruitless.   Moreover,   the   main   drivers   of   these   aggregate   fluctuations   were  technology   shocks  and   money  was  not  included  in   the   model,   as   it   was   assumed   to   have   no   influence   in   the   real   economy.   This   model  was  adopted  by  many  economists  and  was  on  the  basis  of  the  RBC  (Real   Business  Cycle)  Theory.    

What  followed  was  the  New  Keynesian  model.  It  captured  the  microeconomics   foundations   of   the   RBC   models   and   kept   the   DSGE   framework   but   also   introduced   specific   theoretical   contributions   that   contrasted   with   the   RBC   models.  According  to  Galí  (2008),  these  contributions  were  three:  Firstly,  it  was   consistent   with   the   Keynesian   thinking,   as   it   justified   the   existence   of   policymaking.  This  was  done  by  modeling  constraints  in  price  and  wage  setting   for   the   re-­‐optimization   of   agents,   such   as   Calvo   pricing.   Moreover,   these   same   constraints   to   the   re-­‐optimization   of   each   agent   allowed   money   to   interfere   in   the   real   interest   rate.   This   was   due   to   the   fact   that   inflation   did   not   react   instantly  to  the  changes  in  interest  rate,  making  money  become  non-­‐neutral  in   the  real  economy.  Thirdly,  markets  were  assumed  to  have  imperfections,  which   were  typically  modeled  by  the  Dixit-­‐Stiglitz  form  of  monopolistic  competition.      

As  previously  stated,  the  inclusion  of  rigidities  in  the  DSGE  models  proved  to  be   of   irrefutable   importance   for   justifying   the   business   cycle   fluctuations.   Firstly,   Calvo   pricing   was   introduced   to   the   goods   market.   Subsequently,   Erceg,   Henderson   and   Levin   (2000)   extended   nominal   Calvo-­‐type   rigidity   to   wages.   This   marked   the   inclusion   of   wage   rigidity   in   macroeconomic   modeling.   Additionally,   this   work   showed   an   important   result   for   monetary   policy   in   the   context  of  nominal  wage  and  price  rigidities.  It  stated  that  monetary  policy  could   not  achieve  the  Pareto-­‐optimal  equilibrium  that  would  occur  under  completely   flexible  wages  and  prices.  This  represents  that  monetary  policy  faced  a  trade-­‐off   in  stabilizing  the  output  gap,  price  inflation  and  wage  inflation.  For  this  reason  

(7)

monetary  policy  rule  should  aim  at  maximizing  welfare,  given  that  it  could  not   stabilize  the  output  gap,  wage  inflation  and  price  inflation  at  the  same  time.      

Two  works  were  important  for  the  study  of  wage  rigidity.  Stiglitz  (1984)  called   for  the  need  of  explaining  wage  rigidity.    He  stated  that  in  order  to  explain  the   cyclical   movements   in   wages,   one   must   take   into   account   the   presence   of   asymmetric  information,  the  limitations  of  enforcement  mechanisms,  the  nature   of   insurance   and   restrictions   on   the   degree   of   complexity   of   feasible   contracts.   Robert   Solow   (1998)   enumerated   the   symptoms   that   define   nominal   wage   rigidity.  Some  examples  are  high  level  and  duration  of  unemployment  benefits,   high  number  of  restrictions  on  hiring  and  firing  and  excessive  influence  of  over-­‐ protective  trade  unions.    

Many   other   studies   were   done   on   the   topic   of   nominal   wage   rigidity.   Dickens,   Gotte,  Groshen,  Holden,  Messina,  Schweitzer,  Turunen  and  Ward  (2006)  provide   a  microeconomic  approach  to  how  wages  change  by  analyzing  the  distribution  of   wage  alterations.  This  study  showed  that  the  trade  unions  level  of  influence  on   wage   bargaining   is   a   significant   factor   for   explaining   the   level   of   rigidity   of   a   labour  market.  Haefke,  Sonntag  and  Rens  (2013)  restricted  the  scope  of  study  of   nominal   wage   rigidity   to   new   hires.   The   results   demonstrated   that   for   this   particular   group   of   workers   there   was   little   evidence   for   wage   stickiness,   as   wages   responded   almost   one-­‐to-­‐one   to   changes   in   productivity.   This   draws   attention  to  the  importance  of  the  length  of  the  relationship  between  employer   and  employee  for  the  study  of  nominal  wage  rigidity.    

Furthermore,  many  are  the  studies  regarding  the  consequences  of  nominal  wage   rigidity.  Nickell  (1997)  discussed  how  higher  levels  of  wage  stickiness  in  Europe   might  contribute  for  higher  levels  of  unemployment  compared  to  North  America.   Doing   so,   this   work   contributed   for   demonstrating   important   impacts   of   wage   rigidity:   lower   labour   mobility   and   higher   unemployment.   Moreover,   Messina,   Caju,   Duarte,   Izquierdo   and   Hansen   (2010)   showed   again   that   nominal   wage   rigidity   has   a   negative   impact   on   employment.   Also,   this   study   introduced   the   possibility   that   that   nominal   wage   rigidity   might   affect   labour   productivity   positively.    

Finally,  labour  market  dynamics  and  levels  of  wage  rigidity  are  also  studied  on  a   national   scale.   In   the   specific   case   of   Portugal,   nominal   wage   rigidity   is   a   structural  characteristic  of  the  economy,  as  Alexandre,  Bação,  Silva  and  Portela   (2010)  pointed  out.  Cardoso  and  Portugal  (2005)  argued  that  firms  respond  to   the  Portuguese  labour  market  rigidity  by  creating    ‘wage  cushions’.  Firms  do  so   by   hiring   employees   with   wages   above   those   set   in   the   sectorial   bargaining,   which   gives   room   to   decrease   wages   when   needed.   Nonetheless,   Portugal   features   low   job   creation   and   destruction,   which   according   to   Portugal   and   Blanchard  (2001)  is  mainly  caused  by  high  employment  protection.    

               

(8)

3  -­‐  Model    

 

 

In  this  section  I  present  the  model  that  I  use  in  the  next  stages  of  this  thesis.  As   stated   in   the   introduction,   it   is   based   on   the   small   open   economy   model   as   in   Walsh  (2010)  and  Galí  (2008),  featuring  sticky  prices.  I  augment  the  model  with   wage  stickiness  following  the  works  of  Erceg,  Henderson  and  Levin  (2000)  and   Galí  (2008).    

The   structure   of   the   model   economy   consists   of   three   different   sectors,   households,   intermediate   goods   firms   and   final   goods   firms,   each   of   them   optimizing   their   respective   objective   function.   Also,   both   labour   and   intermediate  goods  markets  face  monopolistic  competition  and  sticky  prices  and   wages.  I  close  the  model  with  a  Taylor-­‐type  monetary  policy  rule.    

 

The   ‘Appendix’   section   contains   the   full   list   of   variables   and   parameters   mentioned  in  the  model.    

 

I  follow  Walsh  (2010)  for  the  approach  and  order  of  description  of  the  model.  In   order  to  do  so,  I  focus  mainly  on  chapter  nine  of  his  2010  book.  For  the  ‘Firms’   section  I  also  follow  its  chapter  eight.  

   

3.1  -­‐  Households  

 

The  economy  contains  a  continuum  of  infinitely  lived  households,  indexed  by  𝑘.   Each   household   aims   at   achieving   an   optimal   bundle,  𝐶!,!,   of   home   produced   goods,  𝐶!!,   and   foreign   produced   goods,  𝐶

!!.   Given   that   every   household   has   constant   elasticity   of   substitution   (CES)   over   foreign   and   home   goods,   each   of   them  faces  the  following  minimization  problem:  

    (1)   𝑚𝑖𝑛!!!!  𝑃!!𝐶 !!  +  𝑃!!𝐶!!           subject  to     (2)   𝐶!,! =     (1 −  𝛾)!!    𝐶!,!! !!! ! + (𝛾)!!  𝐶 !,!! ! !!! ! !!! .      

In  words,  households  minimize  total  expenditures  given  the  price  of  each  type  of   goods,  𝑃!!  for   home   goods   and  𝑃

!!  for   foreign   goods,   taking   into   account   the   restriction  on  the  composition  of  consumption.  This  restriction  depends  on  the   degree   of   openness   of   the   economy,  𝛾,   and   the   price   elasticity   of   substitution   between  home  and  foreign  goods,  𝑎.  

(9)

 

This   optimization   problem   leads   us   to   the   following   first   order   condition:     (3)   𝐶!! 𝐶!! =   (1 −  𝛾) 𝛾     𝑃!! 𝑃!! !! ,      

which   gives   the   intuitive   result   that   the   home   country’s   relative   demand   for   home   and   foreign   produced   goods,   𝐶!! 𝐶

!! ,   depends   on   their   relative   price   (𝑃!! 𝑃

!!).   Also,   the   bigger   the   degree   of   openness   is,   the   greater   the   weight   of   consumption  of  foreign  goods  in  the  total  consumption.    

 

Combining  the  first  order  conditions  with  respect  to  𝐶!!  and  𝐶

!!and  applying  the   restriction   on   the   composition   of   consumption   described   in   (2),   I   reach   the   following  expression:     (4)   𝑃!=   1 − 𝛾 𝑃!!!!! +  𝛾  𝑃 !!!!! ! !!! .      

The  above  equation  provides  the  Consumer  Price  Index  (CPI).    

Simultaneously,  each  household  k  aims  at  maximizing  its  lifetime  utility  function   taking  into  account  a  sequence  of  budgets  constraints:  

      (5)   𝑈 =   𝐸! 𝛽!𝜃!! 𝐶!,!!!!!! 1 − 𝜎−   𝑁!,!!!!!! 1 + 𝜂 ! !!!     subject  to   (6)   𝐸! 𝛽!𝜃!! 𝑊!,!𝑁!,!!! +  𝑅!!!𝐵!,!!!!!−  𝑃!!!𝐶!,!!!−  𝐵!,!!! = 0 ! !!! .      

As   in   Walsh   (2010),   each   period’s   utility   depends   positively   on   the   total   consumption   of   foreign   or   home   produced   goods,  𝐶!,!,   and   negatively   on   the   amount  of  labour  supply  by  each  household  𝑘,  𝑁!.  

To  compare  the  utility  of  different  combinations  of  labour  and  consumption  over   time,   households   discount   the   future   by   the   factor  𝛽.   Also,   I   follow   Erceg,   Henderson  and  Levin  (2000)  by  applying  the  Calvo  price  setting  mechanism  to   the   labour   market.   I   then   assume   that   wage   contracts   are   not   revised   until  

(10)

households   are   given   the   chance   to   adjust   them.   Merely   1 − 𝜃! ∈ 0,1  of   the   total  number  of  households  is  allowed  to  reset  their  wage.  Being  so,  the  utility   function   is   augmented   by   the   probability   of   the   household   not   being   able   to   adjust  its  wage,  𝜃!,  which  influences  not  only  wage  setting  but  also  consumption   and  investment  decisions.1  

𝜎  represents   the   elasticity   of   intertemporal   substitution   while  𝜂  denotes   the   inverse  of  wage  elasticity  of  labour  supply.  

The  optimization  must  fulfill  the  restriction  imposed  by  (6):  the  discounted  sum   of   the   subtraction   of   one   period’s   expenditure   (via   consumption,  𝑃!!!𝐶!,!!!,   or   investment   in   bonds,  𝐵!,!!!)   from   one   period’s   earnings   (via   labour,  𝑊!,!𝑁!,!!!,   or  internationally  traded  bonds  from  the  period  before,  𝑅!!!𝐵!,!!!!!)  must  equal   zero.  𝑊!,!  denotes   the   nominal   wage   earned   for   each   unit   of   labour.   This   restriction  introduces  a  ‘no-­‐Ponzi  game’  condition  for  households.  

 

The   labour   market   is   defined   by   the   rules   of   monopolistic   competition.   Each   household  𝑘  faces   demand   for   its   specific   differentiated   type   of   labour.   This   demand   function,   which   is   obtained   from   the   intermediate   goods   producing   firms’  cost  minimization  problem,  is  as  follows:  

  (7)   𝑁!,! =   𝑊!,! 𝑊! !!! 𝑁!.    

Since  𝜀!,  the  inverse  of  wage  elasticity  of  substitution  between  different  types  of   labour,  is  greater  than  zero,  the  above  equation  presents  demand  as  negatively   dependent  on  the  relative  wage  demanded  by  the  household,  (𝑊!,! 𝑊!).  Also,  it   depends  positively  on  the  amount  of  aggregated  labour  supplied  in  period  𝑡,  𝑁!.    

I  introduce  the  restriction  of  fulfilling  the  labor  demand,  (7),  to  the  maximization   problem  of  (5)  subject  to  (6).  Doing  so  and  combining  the  optimality  conditions   for  the  nominal  wages  of  household  𝑘  in  period  𝑡,  𝑊!,!,  and  the  respective  level  of   consumption,  𝐶!,!,  yields:     (8)   𝐸!   𝛽!𝜃 !! 𝑁!,!!!!  𝑁!!!   𝜀! 𝜀! − 1 =   𝐸!   𝛽!𝜃!! ! !!! ! !!! 𝐶!,!!!!!  𝑊!,! 𝑃!!!  𝑁!,!!! .    

This  equation  presents  the  first  order  wage  setting  condition  for  each  period  𝑡.   On  the  left  hand  side,  it  gives  the  expected  value  at  period  𝑡  of  the  infinite  sum  of   the   discounted   present   and   future   period’s   utility   obtained   from   an   additional   unit  of  labour  supplied.  In  order  to  verify  optimality,  it  shall  match  the  right  hand   side   of   the   equation,   which   represents   the   expected   value   at   period  𝑡  of   the   infinite  sum  of  discounted  present  and  future  marginal  disutilities  obtained  from   an  additional  unit  of  labour  supplied.  

                                                                                                               

1  I  will  further  explore  this  fact  in  the  next  sections.  

(11)

When  this  condition  is  verified,  the  wage  setting  function  meets  a  specific  value.   Since   the   marginal   benefit   subtracted   by   the   marginal   loss   of   supplying   labour   equals   zero,   setting   the   wage   at   period  𝑡  above   or   below   the   level   set   by   (8),   given  the  assumed  restrictions,  would  be  non-­‐optimal.    

 

I  re-­‐arrange  (8)  to  have  only  one  expectations  operator  and  to  get  labour,  𝑁!!!,   and  the  marginal  utility  of  consumption,  𝐶!,!!!!! ,  as  common  factors.  This  yields:     (9)   𝐸!   𝛽!𝜃 !!𝑁!!!𝐶!,!!!!! 𝑊!,! 𝑃!!! − 𝜀! 𝜀!− 1𝑀𝑅𝑆!,!!! ! !!! = 0,    

where  𝑀𝑅𝑆!,!!!stands   for   marginal   rate   of   substitution   between   consumption   and  labour  at  period  for  household  𝑘  at  period  (𝑡 + 𝑖).  

Since  this  thesis  focuses  on  the  role  played  by  wage  rigidity  in  the  fluctuations  of   the  business  cycle,  it  is  worth  further  exploring  (9)  focusing  on  the  value  of  𝜃!.  If   it   equals   zero,   the   labour   market   is   defined   by   perfect   wage   flexibility.   Mathematically,   that   implies   that  𝜃!!  is   equal   to   zero   for   every  𝑖  from   one   to   infinity   and   equal   to   one   in   the   current   period  𝑡.   In   this   case,   the   equation   simplifies  to:     (10)   𝛽𝑁!𝐶!,!!! 𝑊!,! 𝑃! − 𝜀! 𝜀!− 1𝑀𝑅𝑆!,! = 0.    

Assuming   the   scenario   where  𝛽 > 0, 𝑁! > 0  and  𝐶!,!!! > 0,   the   household  𝑘  sets   the   real   wage,  (𝑊!,! 𝑃!),   as   a   mark-­‐up,  (𝜀! (𝜀!− 1)),   over   the   current   period   marginal   rate   of   substitution   between   labour   and   consumption,  𝑀𝑅𝑆!,!.   This   way,   the   wage   setting   decision   of   household  𝑘  in   period  𝑡  is   no   longer   forward   looking,  as  (10)  documents.  

However,  under  a  circumstance  where  there  is  any  rigidity  in  wage  setting,  𝜃!  is   a   positive   number.   In   general   terms,   the   bigger  𝜃!  is,   the   less   likely   it   is   that   a   household  gets  the  chance  to  reset  its  wage  in  future  periods.  As  households  are   perfectly   rational,   a   higher  𝜃!  implies   that   the   future   has   a   greater   weight   in   current  period  wage  setting.  

 

The   combination   of   the   optimality   conditions   with   respect   to   bonds   holdings,   𝐵!,!,  and  consumption  𝐶!,!,  yields:  

   (11)   𝐶!,!!! =   𝐸 !  𝛽𝜃! 𝑃! 𝑃!!! 𝑅!!!𝐶!,!!!!! .    

The   above   equality   is   the   so-­‐called   Euler   equation.   It   relates   present   consumption   to   future   consumption   through   the   discount   factor,   𝛽 ,   the   probability   of   the   household   not   being   able   to   reset   its   wage,  𝜃!,   and   the   real   interest  rate,   𝑃! 𝑃!!!  𝑅!!!.  

(12)

This   equation   provides   the   channel   through   which   monetary   policy   affects   inflation,  as  it  contains  the  interest  rate,  𝑅!!!,  and  the  inverse  of  the  inflation  rate  

𝑃! 𝑃!!!  linked  by  the  equality.    

 

3.2  -­‐  Terms  of  Trade  and  International  Risk  Sharing  

 

I  assume  that  the  law  of  the  one  price  holds.  This  implies  the  following:    

(12)   𝑃!! =   𝑆!𝑃!,  

 

where  𝑃!!denotes   the   price   of   foreign   produced   goods   in   terms   of   domestic   currency,  𝑃!∗  the   price   of   the   same   foreign   produced   goods   but   expressed   in   foreign  currency  and  𝑆!  the  nominal  exchange  rate.  

 

Also,  I  assume  complete  exchange  rate  pass  through:    

(13)   𝑃! =   𝑆!𝑃!.  

 

This   implies   that   import   prices   have   a   one-­‐for-­‐one   response   to   changes   in   the   exchange  rate.  𝑃!  is  the  CPI  as  derived  in  (4).  

 

Following  Walsh  (2010),  I  treat  the  rest  of  the  world  as  a  large  closed  economy.   For  that  reason,  I  do  not  distinguish  between  the  price  level  of  home  and  foreign   produced  goods.  

 

Terms   of   trade,  ∆!,   and   the   real   effective   exchange   rate,  𝑄!,   are   defined   as   follows:     (14)   ∆!=   𝑃!! 𝑃!! =   𝑆!𝑃!∗ 𝑃!!     and   (15)   𝑄! =   𝑃!! 𝑃! =   𝑆!𝑃!∗ 𝑃! =   𝑃!! 𝑃!  ∆!.    

Foreign   households   face   the   same   constrained   optimization   problem   that   domestic  households  do.2  Assuming  foreign  households  have  access  to  the  same  

internationally  traded  bonds,  this  yields  the  foreign  households  Euler  equation:    

   

                                                                                                               

(13)

(16)   𝐶!∗ !! 𝑆!𝑃!∗ =   𝐸!  𝛽 𝑅!!! 𝑆!𝑃!∗ 𝐶!!!∗ !!    

The  left  hand  side  represents  the  foreign  household  disutility  from  obtaining  an   extra  unit  of  domestic  currency  to  buy  a  bond  that  pays  𝑅!!!  in  the  next  period.   In   order   to   verify   the   optimality   condition   this   must   match   the   expected   discounted   marginal   utility   obtained   from   buying   that   same   extra   unit   of   currency   for   investing   in   the   bond.   The   earnings   are   then   converted   to   foreign   currency  again.3  

(16)   provides   a   twofold   channel.   Firstly,   it   relates   domestic   consumption   to   foreign   consumption.   Secondly,   since   I   assume   the   rest   of   the   world   to   be   a   closed  economy,  foreign  consumption  equals  foreign  output,  which  implies  a  link   between  domestic  consumption  and  foreign  output.  

   

3.3  -­‐  Firms  

 

There   are   two   categories   of   firms   operating   in   this   model  economy:   composite   final   consumption   goods   producing   firms   and   intermediate   goods   producing   firms.   The   latter   hires   differentiated   labour   to   produce   differentiated   goods,   while   the   former   buys   these   intermediate   goods   as   the   only   input   to   produce   homogeneous  composite  final  consumption  goods.    

These   final   goods   are   then   consumed   by   households   as   home   produced   goods,   (𝐶!,!! )4.   Because   I   assume   the   rest   of   the   world   to   be   a   closed   economy,   these  

goods  can  only  have  the  domestic  market  as  destination.    

The  final  consumption  goods  market  is  defined  by  perfect  competition  because   the  many  firms  that  are  part  of  it  sell  the  same  completely  homogenous  product.    

The  production  function  of  a  representative  final  composite  consumption  goods   producing  firm  is  as  follows:  

  (17)   𝑌!=   𝑌!,! !!.!!! !!,! ! !  𝑑𝑗 !!,! !!,!!! .    

As  the  integral  suggests,  the  final  goods  firms  assemble  inputs  from  a  continuum   of   intermediate   goods   firms   indexed   by  𝑗   ∈ (0,1).   With   them,   each   final   goods   firm  creates  its  share  of  the  total  final  good  production,  𝑌!.  

𝑌!,!  denotes  the  production  of  intermediate  goods  by  firm  j  at  period  t,  whereas   𝜀!,!  signifies   the   inverse   of   price   elasticity   of   substitution   between   the   differentiated   intermediate   goods.   It   is   valuable   to   stress   the   presence   of   the   index  𝑡  in  𝜀!,!.  This  comes  from  the  fact  that,  contrarily  to  the  case  of  the  inverse                                                                                                                  

3  As  in  Wash  (2010),  I  assume  homogeneous  foreign  households  and  do  not  introduce  an  index  

for  them.  

(14)

of   wage   elasticity   of   substitution   between   different   types   of   labour,  𝜀!5,  this  

elasticity  varies  over  time  (indexed  by  𝑡).  According  to  Galí  (2008),  this  implies  a   time   varying   price   mark-­‐up   and   serves   as   a   source   of   a   cost-­‐push   shock   in   the   linearized  model.  

 

In  line  with  Galí  (2008),  I  follow  two  simplifying  assumptions:  final  consumption   goods   firms   only   use   home   produced   intermediate   goods   as   inputs   and   home   intermediate   goods   are   not   exported.   This   limits   trade   to   final   consumption   goods.  

 

Each  firm  𝑗  solves  its  cost  minimization  problem,  which  yields:       (18)   𝑌!,! =   𝑃!,! ! 𝑃!! !!!,! 𝑌!.    

This   equation   determines   the   demand   schedule   for   each   firm  𝑗.   It   depends   negatively  on  the  relative  price  of  the  relative  price  of  the  firm’s  goods,   𝑃!,!! 𝑃

!! ,   and  positively  on  the  production  of  the  final  good,  𝑌!.  

 

Intermediate   goods   firms   supply   differentiated   goods   in   the   context   of   monopolistic   competition.   Accordingly,   they   hire   all   available   differentiated   types   of   labour.   That   said,   the   production   function   of   the   representative   intermediate  goods  firm  𝑗  is  as  follows:  

 

(19)   𝑌!,!!! =   𝑒!!𝑁!,!!!,  

 

where  𝜀!  denotes   the   common   technology   parameter   for   every   intermediate   goods  firm  𝑗.  It  depends  positively  on  that  same  parameter  and,  logically,  on  the   number  of  labour  units  hired.  

 

Cost   minimization   by   a   representative   firm  𝑗,   shows   that   real   marginal   costs   𝑀𝐶!,!  are   equal   for   every   intermediate   goods   firm.   For   that   reason,   I   drop   the   index  𝑗  and  define  𝑀𝐶!  as:  

  (20)   𝑀𝐶! =   𝑊! 𝑃!! 𝑒!! .      

As   stated   in   the   literature   review,   following   the   works   of   Calvo   (1983),   price   rigidity   was   established   as   a   common   practice   in   New   Keynesian   models.   Accordingly,  the  works  of  Walsh  (2010),  Galí  (2008)  and  Erceg,  Henderson  and   Levin  (2000),  on  which  this  models  builds,  feature  price  rigidity.  

                                                                                                               

(15)

I   assume   that   intermediate   goods   firms   adjusting   prices   each   period   is   not   a   certain  event.  It  is  associated  with  a  constant  probability  over  time  (1 − 𝜃!).  This   implies   that,   on   average,  𝜃!  of   the   intermediate   firms   do   not   get   the   change   to   reset  their  prices.  

Intermediate   goods   firms   are   profit-­‐maximizers   as   in   many   other   models.   However,  the  introduction  of  price  rigidity  changes  the  dynamics  of  the  optimal   decision-­‐making  for  firms.  When  these  firms  set  prices  they  take  into  account  the   fact  that  might  not  be  able  to  do  so  in  the  next  period.  This  forces  firms  to  take   into   account   future   periods.     More   rigid   prices   (larger  𝜃!)   imply   that   future   periods   have   greater   importance   for   firms   while   setting   prices   for   the   current   period.  

 

A  representative  intermediate  goods  firm  𝑗,  when  given  the  opportunity,  sets  its   price,  𝑃!,!!,  by  solving  the  following  problem:  

  (21)   𝜛!,! =   𝐸!   𝜃!!χ!,!!! 𝑃!,!! 𝑃!!!!  𝑌!,!!!−  𝑌!,!!!𝑀𝐶!!! ! !!!     subject  to   (22)   𝑌!,! =   𝑃!,! ! 𝑃!! !!!,! 𝑌!.    

In   words,   the   firm   maximizes   its   profits,  𝜛!,!,   constrained   by   the   demand   schedule  for  its  good,  (22)  and  (18),  with  respect  to  its  price.  𝜒!,!!!  denotes  the   real  stochastic  discount  factor.6  

 

The  solution  for  this  problem  yields:     (23)   𝑃!,!! 𝑃!!!! =   𝜀!,! 1 − 𝜀!,!   𝐸!   𝛽!𝜃 !! 𝑌!!!!!!   𝑃!!! ! 𝑃!! !!,!!! 𝑀𝐶!!! ! !!! 𝐸!   𝛽!𝜃 !! 𝑌!!!!!! 𝑃!!!! 𝑃!! !!!!,!!! ! !!! .      

This  equation  gives  the  first  order  condition  price-­‐setting  rule.  

Because  firms  face  the  same  problem  and  the  same  price  rigidity  level,  every  firm   that  can  adjust  its  price  will  do  so  the  same  way,  as  long  as  they  have  the  same  

                                                                                                               

6  The  stochastic  discount  factor,  𝜒

!,!!!,  is  equal  to  𝛽!   !!!!! !

!!

(16)

real  marginal  costs7.  As  (20)  shows,  that  is  always  the  case,  which  implies  that  

when  given  the  chance,  every  firm  resets  their  prices  to  same  level.    

Final  goods  firms  maximize  their  profit  with  respect  to  their  output,  which  gives   the  following  price-­‐setting  rule:  

  (24)   𝑃!! !!!! =   (𝑃 !,!!)!!!!𝑑𝑗. ! !    

As  stated  above,  when  firms  are  given  the  chance  to  reset  their  price  they  all  do  it   the  same  way  because  they  face  the  same  marginal  costs.    

I  combine  this  fact  with  the  premise  that  each  period,  on  average,  only  (1 − 𝜃!) ∈ (0,1)  of  the  firms  is  able  to  adjust  their  prices,  while  the  other  𝜃! ∈ (0,1)  is  not.   This  allows  me  to  derive  the  price  of  home  produced  goods  in  period  𝑡,  𝑃!!:     (25)   𝑃!! !!!!,! = 1 − 𝜃 ! 𝑃!,!! !!!!,!+ 𝜃! 𝑃!!!! !!!!,!,    

where  𝑃!,!!  denotes  the  price  set  by  the  firm  𝑗,  the  same  as  any  other  price  set  in   period  𝑡.  

   

3.4  -­‐  Foreign  Country  

 

Because  I  assume  that  the  rest  of  the  world  is  a  large  closed  economy  and  that   the  model  economy  can  only  import  final  goods  from  it,  I  only  need  to  define  the   level  of  domestic  consumption  of  foreign  goods,𝐶!!∗.    

 

In  order  to  do  it,  I  assume  homogenous  preferences  across  the  world.  This  yields:    

(26)   𝐶!!∗ =  𝛾Δ

!𝑌!∗,    

where  𝑌!  denotes  the  level  of  foreign  output.    

Finally,   the   assumption   that   the   rest   of   the   world   is   a   large   closed   economy,   allows  me  to  conclude  that  the  foreign  trade  is  irrelevant  to  the  level  of  foreign   output   and   income.   As   there   is   no   capital   or   investment,   the   level   of   foreign   income  or  output  is,  approximately,  the  same  as  foreign  consumption,  𝐶!∗.  

Mathematically,  I  assume  equality  instead  of  approximation:  

  (27)   𝐶!=   𝑌

!∗                                                                                                                  

7  Following  the  logic  of  (10)  in  the  section  ‘Households’,  (21)  implies  that  when  prices  are  

perfectly  flexible,   𝜃!= 0 ,  the  price  set  by  firms  is  a  mark-­‐up  over  the  current  period  marginal   cost.  

(17)

3.5  -­‐  Equilibrium  

 

In  this  section  I  assemble  the  equations  that  define  the  model.  Below,  I  list  these   equations  and  verify  the  equilibrium  condition.  

 

The  market  clearing  condition  assures  that  the  total  output  of  a  period  is  totally   consumed,  by  domestic  or  foreign  households  in  that  same  period.  Therefore,  it   is  defined  as  follows:  

 

(28)   𝑌!=   𝐶!!∗+  𝐶

!!.    

This  is  added  to  the  core  of  what  was  presented  in  the  four  sections  before:   The   first   section   is   ‘Households’.   They   have   constant   elasticity   of   substitution   (CES)   over   foreign   and   home   goods   and   choose   between   domestic   and   foreign   final  goods,  (2)  and  (29).  Also,  they  solve  a  constrained  problem  of  minimization   of   expenditure,   which   yields   an   optimal   relationship   between   foreign   and   domestic  goods,  (3)  and  (30).  This  allows  me  to  determine  the  Consumer  Price   Index,  (4)  and  (31).    

Furthermore,   I   obtain   the   wage   setting   rule,   (9)   and   (32),   the   Euler   equation,   (11)   and   (33),   by   solving   the   utility   maximization   problem.   To   this,   I   add   the   definition   of   general   wage   level,   (34),   and   the   marginal   rate   of   substitution   between  labour  and  consumption,  (35).  

  (29)   𝐶! =     (1 −  𝛾)!!    𝐶!! !!! ! + (𝛾)!!  𝐶 !! ! !!! ! !!!   (30)   𝐶!! 𝐶!! =   (1 −  𝛾) 𝛾     𝑃!! 𝑃!! !!   (31)   𝑃!=   1 − 𝛾 𝑃!!!!!+  𝛾  𝑃 !!!!! ! !!!   (32)   𝐸!   𝛽!𝜃!!𝑁!!!𝐶!,!!!!! 𝑊!,! 𝑃!!! − 𝜀! 𝜀! − 1𝑀𝑅𝑆!,!!! ! !!! = 0   (33)   𝐶!,!!! =   𝐸 !  𝛽𝜃! 𝑃! 𝑃!!! 𝑅!!!𝐶!,!!!!!   (34)   𝑊!!!!! = 1 − 𝜃 ! 𝑊!,!!!!!+ 𝜃!𝑊!!!!!!!   (35)   𝑀𝑅𝑆!   =  𝑁!!! ! 𝐶!!!!!.    

(18)

Secondly,  I  model  the  ‘Terms  of  Trade  and  International  Risk  Sharing’.  I  define   the  terms  of  trade,  (14)  and  (36),  and  the  real  effective  exchange  rate,  (15)  and   (37).   I   add   to   this   the   relationship   between   total   consumption   and   foreign   consumption,  (38).      (36)   ∆!=  𝑃! ! 𝑃!! =   𝑆!𝑃!∗ 𝑃!!   (37)   𝑄!=  𝑃! ! 𝑃! =   𝑆!𝑃!∗ 𝑃! =   𝑃!! 𝑃!  ∆!   (38)   𝐶! =  𝜁𝑄!!!𝐶!∗.    

Thirdly,  I  highlight  the  equilibrium  conditions  for  the  sector  ‘Firms’.  I  define  the   production   function,   (17)   and   (39).   From   the   maximization   problem   faced   by   firms  I  derive  the  marginal  cost,  (20)  and  (40),  and  the  wage  setting  rule,  (23)   and  (41).  Given  this,  I  can  then  conclude  on  the  general  price  level,  (25)  and  (42).     (39)   𝑌!=   𝑌!,! !!.!!! !!,! ! !  𝑑𝑗 !!,! !!,!!!   (40)   𝑀𝐶!=  𝑊! 𝑃!! 𝑒!!   (41)   𝑃!,!! 𝑃!!!! =   𝜀!,! 1 − 𝜀!,!   𝐸!   𝛽!𝜃 !! 𝑌!!!!!!   𝑃!!! ! 𝑃!! !!,!!! 𝑀𝐶!!! ! !!! 𝐸!   𝛽!𝜃 !! 𝑌!!!!!! 𝑃!!!! 𝑃!! !!!!,!!! ! !!!   (42)   𝑃!! !!!!,! = 1 − 𝜃 ! 𝑃!,!! !!!!,!+ 𝜃! 𝑃!!!! !!!!,!.    

Finally,   I   select   the   equilibrium   conditions   from   the   section   ‘Foreign   Country’.   These  are  the  relationship  between  foreign  consumption  of  goods  produced  by   domestic   firms   and   foreign   output,   (26)   and   (43),   and   the   principle   that   approximates  foreign  total  consumption  to  foreign  output,  (27)  and  (44).  I  add  to   this   the   market   clearing   condition   mentioned   in   the   beginning   of   this   section,   (28)  and  (45).     (43)   𝐶!!∗ =  𝛾∆ !𝑌!∗   (44)   𝐶!∗ =   𝑌!∗   (45)   𝑌!=   𝐶!!∗ +  𝐶 !!  

(19)

Summing  up,  I  have  selected  a  set  of  equilibrium  conditions  to  form  a  system  of   seventeen,  (29)  to  (45),  nonlinear  difference  equations.    

The  number  of  selected  equations  is  the  minimum  enough  to  guarantee  that  the   economic   principles   discussed   in   the   last   four   sections   are   included   in   the   system.  

Nineteen   variables   are   used:  𝐶!, 𝐶!!, 𝐶

!!, 𝑃!, 𝑃!,!, 𝑅!, 𝑊!,!, 𝑊!, 𝑃!!,  𝑃!!, 𝑁!, 𝑀𝑅𝑆!,  ∆!,   𝑄!,  𝐶!,  𝑀𝐶

!,  𝑌!,  𝑌!∗,  𝐶!!∗.  Also,  a  technology  parameter,  𝜀!,  is  used.    

The  mathematical  equilibrium  of  a  system  of  equations  requires  the  number  of   equations   to   be   equal   to   the   number   of   variables.   However,   the   system   of   nonlinear  equations  has  twenty  variables,  but  only  seventeen  equations.    

For   that   reason,   I   introduce   three   different   equations.   The   first   two   are   the   equations  that  define  foreign  output  and  the  log  of  the  technology  parameter  as   AR(1)  processes.  The  third  is  a  monetary  policy  rule  that  targets  price  inflation   through  interest  rate  changes.  

 

I  will  present  these  three  equations  as  well  as  the  log-­‐linearized  equations  that   allow  me  to  solve  the  model  in  the  next  section.    

   

3.6   -­‐   Log-­‐linearized   Equations   Around   The   Steady   State   and  

Monetary  Policy  Rule  

 

I   proceed   with   log   linearizing   the   above   selected   equilibrium   equations.   As   in   Walsh   (2010),   I   explain   the   most   important   economic   dynamics   of   the   model   through   obtaining   the   three   basic   equations   that   define   this   model:   the   small   open   economy   forward-­‐looking   New   Keynesian   IS   curve,   the   small   open   economy   New   Keynesian   Phillips   curve   and   the   small   open   economy   wage   Phillips   curve.   Moreover,   I   present   the   simplified   version   of   the   model   with   which  I  will  work  in  the  following  sections.  Finally,  I  close  the  model  by  defining   the  monetary  policy  rule  and  I  comment  the  choice  of  this  rule.  

I   log   linearize   the   equilibrium   conditions   presented   in   the   previous   section   around   the   zero   wage   and   price   inflation   steady   states.   This   turns   the   below   variables  into  percentage  deviations  from  the  steady  state.  

After  this,  I  assume  the  existence  of  four  different  shocks:  a  cost-­‐push  shock,  a   monetary  policy  shock,  a  technology  shock  and  a  foreign  output  shock.    

With   this   combination   of   log   linearized   equations   and   shocks,   I   build   the   following  three  basic  equations  and  a  simplified  version  of  the  model.  

 

I   combine   the   log-­‐linearized   equations   of   the   goods   market   clearing   condition,   (24)  and  (45),  the  definition  of  terms  of  trade,  (14)  and  (36),  the  real  effective   rate   definition,   (15)   and   (37),   the   optimal   international   risk   sharing   condition,   (38),  the  approximation  of  foreign  total  consumption  to  foreign  output,  (27)  and   (44),   and   the   Euler   equation,   (11)   and   (33),   to   obtain   the   small   open   economy   forward-­‐looking  New  Keynesian  IS  curve:  

 

   

(20)

(46)   𝑦! =   𝐸!𝑦!!!−   1 𝜎!   𝑟!− 𝐸!𝜋!!!! +  𝛾 1 − 𝜉 𝜎! 𝐸!𝑦!!!∗ − 𝑦!∗ ,   𝑔𝑖𝑣𝑒𝑛  𝑡ℎ𝑎𝑡:     𝜎! =   𝜎 1 − 𝛾(1 − 𝜉);      𝜉 = 𝑎𝜎 + 𝑎𝜎 − 1 1 − 𝛾 .    

Like  other  IS  curves,  this  equation  depicts  the  behavior  of  the  aggregated  supply   sector.   Accordingly,   it   shows   the   typical   negative   relationship   between   one   period’s  output  and  the  respective  interest  rate  that  bonds  yield.  The  higher  the   latter   is,   the   more   the   former   shrinks,   as   households   start   to   invest   more   and   delay  consumption  for  the  future.  

However,   this   IS   curve   includes   some   particular   features.   It   is   forward-­‐looking   because  it  takes  into  account  the  expectations  for  the  future  of  certain  variables,   such  as  the  growth  of  foreign  income.  

The   open   economy   feature   can   be   seen   by   the   presence   of   the   degree   of   openness   of   the   economy, 𝛾.   Put   simply,   this   is   due   to   the   fact   that   domestic   goods  face  the  competition  of  foreign  goods  even  though  the  rest  of  the  world  is   assumed  to  be  a  closed  economy,  which  has  further  implications  in  the  domestic   economy.  

 

I   combine   the   log-­‐linearized   equations   of   the   general   price   level   of   home   produced  goods,  (25)  and  (42),  and  the  pricing  rule  condition,  (23)  and  (41),  to   obtain  the  small  open  economy  New  Keynesian  Phillips  curve.  

                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                           (47)   𝜋!! = 𝛽𝐸 !𝜋!!!! + 𝜅!𝑚𝑐!+ 𝑧!     𝑔𝑖𝑣𝑒𝑛  𝑡ℎ𝑎𝑡:     𝜅! =(1 − 𝛽𝜃!)(1 − 𝜃!) 𝜃! ;      𝑚𝑐! = 𝑤!− 𝑝!!− 𝜀!;      𝜔!! = 𝑤!− 𝑝!!;      𝑧!~  𝑁 0, 𝜎!! .        

𝑧!  follows  a  normal  distribution  with  mean  zero  and  a  given  variance.    It  is  a  cost-­‐ push   shock   that   results   from   the   mark-­‐up   over   the   real   marginal   cost,    (𝜀!,!) (1 − 𝜀!,!),  that  determines  relative  pricing  in  (23)  and  (41).    

Home  price  inflation,  𝜋!!,  depends  positively  on  future  home  price  inflation.  Also,   it   depends   on   the   difference   between   real   production   wage8,  𝜔

!!,  and   the   representative   of   the   marginal   product   of   labour,  𝜀!.   The   intuition   behind   it   is   that   firms   manage   their   profit   margins.   If,   ceteris   paribus,   the   real   production   wage   increases,   firms   adapt   their   margin   by   increasing   prices.   In   case   the   marginal   product   of   labour   increases   firms   can   decrease   their   prices   because   they   can   now   use   less   labour   units   per   production   unit.   This   way,   they   can   maintain  the  profit  margin  and  increase  sales.9  

                                                                                                               

8  I  define  real  production  wage  as   𝑊

! 𝑃!! .    

9  Iterating  (47)  forward  yields:  𝜋

! ! = 𝜅

! !!!!𝛽!𝑚𝑐!!!.  Inflation  is  equal  to  the  discounted  sum  of  

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

This PhD study will therefore assess the breast milk FA composition of lactating mothers and LCPUFA nutrition of South African infants during breastfeeding

Om de tweede hypothese te toetsen, of volwassenen die hoog betrokken zijn bij gezondheid en/of gewicht, een sterkere intentie hebben om gezond te eten en het gezonde gedrag zal

This analysis leads us to propose the following defi- nition: The precautionary principle for deperimeterized software design states that lack of certainty about the use of

De werkzame beroepsbevolking omvat alle personen van 15 tot 75 jaar die in Nederland wonen en betaald werk hebben, ongeacht in welk land gewerkt wordt?. Bij de werkzame

Already quite a number of Upper Palaeolithic female representations were known at that time, almost none, however, being so complete, explicit and suggestive as the Laussel specimen

[6,7,8,9] This study aimed to determine the range and prevalence of reasons for encounter and diagnoses found among ambulatory patients attending public sector primary care

bepaald. Via deze data kan het fenomeen ttdrukberg" worden onderzocht en de invloed van de parameterstblankdikte,smering en de dikte van het aanliggend

Copyright and moral rights for the publications made accessible in the public portal are retained by the authors and/or other copyright owners and it is a condition of