• No results found

Does price deregulation in a competitive hospital market damage quality?

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Does price deregulation in a competitive hospital market damage quality?"

Copied!
16
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

ContentslistsavailableatScienceDirect

Journal

of

Health

Economics

jo u rn al h om ep age :w w w . e l s e vi e r . c o m / l o c a t e / e c o n b a s e

Does

price

deregulation

in

a

competitive

hospital

market

damage

quality?

Anne-Fleur

Roos

a,∗

,

Owen

O’Donnell

b

,

Frederik

T.

Schut

c

,

Eddy

Van

Doorslaer

d

,

Raf

Van

Gestel

e

,

Marco

Varkevisser

c

aNetherlandsBureauofEconomicPolicyAnalysis(CPB)&ErasmusSchoolofHealthPolicy&Management(ESHPM),Erasmus

UniversityRotterdam(EUR),Netherlands

bErasmusSchoolofEconomics(ESE)&ESHPM,EUR,TinbergenInstitute(TI),Netherlands cESHPM,EUR,Netherlands

dESHPM&ESE,EUR,TI,Netherlands eESHPM&ESE,EUR,Netherlands

a

r

t

i

c

l

e

i

n

f

o

Articlehistory: Received17April2018

Receivedinrevisedform14April2020 Accepted18April2020

Availableonline23May2020 JELclassification: I11 L14 L15 Keywords: Healthcare Hospital Competition Quality Contracting

a

b

s

t

r

a

c

t

Regulatorsmaybehesitanttopermitpricecompetitioninhealthcaremarketsbecauseof itspotentialtodamagequality.Weassesswhetherthisfeariswellfoundedbyexamining areformthatpermittedDutchhealthinsurerstofreelynegotiatepriceswithhospitals. Unlikepreviousresearchonhospitalcompetitionthathasreliedonqualityindicatorsfor urgenttreatments,wetakeadvantageofaplausibleabsenceofselectionbiastoidentifythe effectonthequalityofelectiveproceduresthatshouldbemorepriceresponsive.Usingdata onalladmissionsforhipreplacementstoDutchhospitalsandadifference-in-differences comparisonbetweenmoreandlessconcentratedmarkets,wefindnoevidencethatprice deregulationinacompetitiveenvironmentreducesqualitymeasuredbyhipreplacement readmissionrates.

©2020ElsevierB.V.Allrightsreserved.

1. Introduction

Competitionbetweenhealthcareprovidersis

increas-inglyencouragedwiththeaimofimprovingqualityofcare

whileslowingthegrowthofhealthspending.Whenprices

areregulated,providersareforcedtocompeteonquality

toattractpatientsorcontractswithinsurers.Whenprices

∗ Correspondingauthor.

E-mailaddresses:a.f.roos@cpb.nl(A.F.Roos),odonnell@ese.eur.nl (O.O’Donnell),schut@eshpm.eur.nl(F.T.Schut),vandoorslaer@ese.eur.nl (E.VanDoorslaer),vangestel@ese.eur.nl(R.VanGestel),

varkevisser@eshpm.eur.nl(M.Varkevisser).

areunregulated,theeffectofcompetitiononqualityisless

clear.Ifdemandismoreresponsivetopricethantoquality,

thentheoptimalcompetitivestrategywillinvolvedriving

downthepriceandsacrificingquality(Gaynor,2006).This

isaplausiblescenariowheninformationonqualityispoor.

Fearthatcompetitionwithunregulatedpriceswillbe

dam-agingtoqualitymaymakeregulatorswaryaboutallowing

healthcareproviderstocompeteonprice.However,itisnot

clearwhetherthisfeariswellfounded.Providersmaynot

adopttheprofitmaximizingcompetitivestrategies.

Not-for-profitgoals,asocialmissionandintrinsicmotivation

mayleadthemtomaintainqualityevenifthismeans

for-goingopportunitiestogain a competitiveadvantage by

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jhealeco.2020.102328 0167-6296/©2020ElsevierB.V.Allrightsreserved.

(2)

cuttingpricesattheexpenseofquality.Whetherquality

suffers in competitivehealthcare marketswith

unregu-latedpricesisanempiricalquestion.Evidencetoanswer

itissparse.

Thispaperexaminestheimpactofpricederegulation

on the quality of hospital care delivered in the Dutch

healthcare market in which insurers compete for

cus-tomersandhospitalscompeteforcontractswithinsurers.

Weestimatetheeffectofmovingfromfinancinghospitals

throughprospectiveglobalbudgetstoallowinginsurers

andhospitalstofreelynegotiateprocedure-specificprices

in contractsfor the deliveryof DRG-type products.We

identifytheeffectofthispricederegulationbyexploiting

variationinitsconsequences acrosshospitals

differenti-atedby theconcentration of themarket in which they

operate.Assumingthatfreeinsurer-hospitalnegotiationof

pricescreatesgreatercompetitivepressurewherethe

mar-ketislessconcentrated,thedifference-in-differences(DID)

betweenmoreandlessconcentratedmarketscanidentify

alowerboundontheeffectofderegulatingpricesinamore

competitiveenvironment.

Weestimatetheeffectofpermittingpricecompetition

onan elective procedurequality indicator– unplanned

readmissionafternon-acutehipreplacement.Higher

read-missionratesfollowinghipreplacementhavebeenshown

toberelated tosuboptimal quality(Rosen et al.,2013;

Mokhtaret al.,2012).Theinstitutional context and our

empiricalstrategyfacilitateidentificationwithoutrunning

muchriskoftheselectionbiasthatmostotherstudiesof

competitioninhealthcaremarketshaveavoidedonlyby

estimatingeffects onindicatorsof thequalityofurgent

treatments,suchasmortalityafteracutemyocardial

infarc-tion(AMI)(e.g.Kessler&Geppert, 2005; Propperetal.,

2008;Cooperetal.,2011;Mutteretal.,2011;Romano& Balan,2011;Gaynoretal.,2013).1Thisrestrictionof

atten-tiontourgenttreatmentsleavesadearthofevidenceonthe

effectofcompetitionontreatments,suchaselective

surg-eries,thathospitalsdirectlycompeteforandthedemand

forwhichpotentiallyexhibitsmuchgreaterresponsiveness

topriceandquality(BevanandSkellern, 2011;Gravelle

etal.,2014;Collaetal.,2016;Skellern,2019).Thereform

weexploit permittedprice competitionbut leftpatient

choiceof provider effectively unconstrained. There was

noavailableinformationonhipreplacementreadmission

rates,andsopatientscouldnotselecta hospitalonthe

basisofthisoutcome.Toidentifytheeffect,weseparate

hospitalsintotwobroad(treatment/comparison)groups

accordingtotheconcentrationofthemarketinwhichthey

operate.Iftherewere anyselectioncorrelated withthe

outcome,itwouldmostlikelyinvolveswitchingbetween

1 TheurgencyofAMItreatmentgreatlyreducestheriskofselectionbias

sincepatientsaresimplytakentothenearesthospital.Thereislittleorno opportunityfordifficult-to-treatpatientsselectinghospitalsthatdeviate fromtheaverageinbothqualityandexposuretocompetition.Andthere islittlescopeforthosehospitalstocherrypicktheeasiercases.However, thisempiricalstrategyidentifiestheimpactofcompetitiononquality onlyinsofarasthepressuretocompeteinthedeliveryoftreatments thatarepriceand/orqualityresponsiveaffectsthegeneralmanagement ofahospitalandthisfeedsthroughtotreatments,suchasAMI,thatare largelyshieldedfromcompetition.

neighboringhospitalsthatbelongtothesamegroup.This

wouldnotinduceselectionbias.Baselinepatient(casemix)

characteristicsaresimilaracrossthetreatmentand

com-parison groups, changes in these characteristicsdo not

differbetweenthegroupsandconditioningonthese

char-acteristicshaslittleimpactontheestimates.

Wefindnoeffectonqualitydespiteexamininga

situ-ationinwhichpricederegulationhadthegreatestscope

todamagequality–anelectiveprocedurewithlittle

infor-mationonitsquality,potentiallyleaving thedemandof

insurer-purchasersmoreresponsivetopricethanto

qual-ity. Overa five-yearperiodafterpricederegulation,the

changeinthe90-dayhipreplacementreadmissionrates

of hospitalsin less concentrated markets didnot differ

significantlyfromthatofhospitalsinmoreconcentrated

marketsthatwereexposedtolesscompetitivepressure.

Theinsignificantpointestimateissmallinmagnitude–less

than1percentofthepre-reformreadmissionrate–and

reasonablypreciselyestimated.Failuretorejectthenullof

noeffectisrobusttoalternativedefinitionsofthemarket,

tocomparinghospitalsattheextremesofmarket

concen-tration,tousingthe30-day(insteadof90-day)readmission

rate,todroppingthemostruralhospitalsandtousing

read-missionafterkneereplacementasthequalitymeasure.In

theyearimmediatelyafterpricederegulation,wefinda

marginallysignificantnegativeeffectonthereadmission

rate,whichisfollowedbyinsignificantpositivepoint

esti-matesin later years.This hintsata positive immediate

impactonqualitythatisnotsustainedwhenhospitals

con-tinuetobeexposedtocompetitivepressuresarisingfrom

pricederegulation.Overall,this studyfindsnoevidence

thatpricederegulationinamorecompetitivehealthcare

marketdamagesquality,evenwheninformationonquality

ispoor.

2. Competitionandhealthcarequalitywith unregulatedprices:theoryandevidence

Whenpricesareunregulated,theimpactofcompetition

onqualitydependsonhowitaffectstheresponsivenessof

demandtoqualityrelativetoitsresponsivenesstoprice.If

consumers,orinsurerspurchasingontheirbehalf,observe

pricesbuthaveonlyimperfectinformationonquality,then

competitionmightbeexpectedtoraisethepricesensitivity

relativetothequalitysensitivityofdemand,andsoreduce

quality(Kranton,2003).Gaynor(2006)makesthis

argu-mentusinganamended versionoftheDorfman-Steiner

condition(DorfmanandSteiner,1954):=p

d εz

εp,wherezis

quality,pisprice,disthemarginalcostofquality,εz is

theelasticityofdemandwithrespecttoqualityandεpis

theelasticitywithrespecttoprice.2Ifcompetitionexerts

downwardpressureonthepricerelativetothemarginal

costand/orraisesthemagnitudeofthepriceelasticity

rel-2Although Dorfman and Steiner (1954) model a monopolist’s

behaviour, Dranoveand Satterthwaite (2000) show thatthe model providesanapproximationtothebehaviourofanoligopolisticor monop-olisticallycompetitivefirmifwethinkofthedemandfunctionasareduced form.Hence,themodelhasrelevanceforimperfectlycompetitive health-caremarkets(Gaynor,2006;Gaynoretal.,2015).

(3)

ativetothequalityelasticity,thenitwillreducequality (Gaynoret al.,2015).3 However,ifqualityissufficiently

observable,thencompetitioncouldconceivablyraisethe

quality elasticity relative to theprice elasticity.Quality

wouldincrease,providedpricedoesnotfallrelativetothe

marginalcostofquality.Theeffectofcompetitionon

qual-itywithanunregulatedpriceisthereforeambiguous.It

dependsoncharacteristicsofthemarket,theobservability

ofqualityandtheobjectivefunctionsofthedemand-side

and supply-sideagents –insurersand hospitals

respec-tively(Gaynoretal.,2015).

Evidence on theeffect of competition on healthcare

quality when prices are unregulated is scarce.4 This is

mainlybecauseonlyafewcountriespermitfreeprice

nego-tiationinhealthcaremarketsanddataontheperformance

ofprivatehealthcareprovidersaretypicallynotaccessible.

UsingdatafromSouthernCalifornia,Gowrisankaranand

Town (2003)findthatincreasedcompetitionfor Health

Maintenance Organization (HMO) patientsis correlated

with reduced risk-adjusted hospital mortality for both

pneumonia and AMI. Consistent with this, Sari (2002)

findsthatlowerhospitalmarketconcentrationin16US

states is associated with fewer hospital complications.

However, the internal validity of these studies can be

doubted becauseof endogeneity problems (Gaynor and

Town,2012),andtheirexternalvalidityislimitedbecause

theHMOmarketsstudiedareveryparticulartotheUS

hos-pitalmarketinthe1990s.

Thefewstudiesthatexploitapolicychangeto

iden-tifythequalityeffectofsomeformofpricederegulation

arestrongerwithrespecttointernalvaliditybutalso

dif-ficulttogeneralizebecausethefindings areobtainedin

specificsettingswithaparticulardesignofprice

competi-tion.Subjecttothiscaveat,thesestudiesgenerallyfindthat

permittinggreaterpricecompetitiondoesdamage

hospi-talquality.Volppetal.(2003)compareAMImortalityrates

ofNewJerseyhospitalsbeforeandafterthederegulation

ofpricesin1992withthoseofNewYorkhospitalswhere

there wasno deregulation. The mortality rateof

unin-suredAMIpatientsincreasedinNewJerseyrelativetoNew

York.However,coincidenttothereforminNewJerseyand

potentiallyconfoundingitseffect,hospitalpriceswerealso

pressuredthroughrapidgrowthoflarge-volumebuyers,

suchasHMOs,andtherewerelargereductionsinsubsidies

forhospitalcareofuninsuredpatients.

Theswitchfromfixedbudgetsthathospitalsreceived

directlyfromthenationalgovernmenttocontracts

hospi-3Itisunlikelythathospitalsdeliberatelysetouttolowerqualityof

care.Studiesthatinvestigatethecompetition-qualityrelationshipoften arguethatinresponsetocompetitivepressurehospitalsmaycutservices thataffectqualityoutcomes(Propperetal.,2008;Bloometal.,2015). GaynorandTown(2012)showthat,forthepurposeofmodeling,itdoes notmatterwhetherhospitalsareassumedtochoosequalitydirectlyor indirectlythrougheffortexerted.

4Thereismoreevidenceontheimpactofcompetitiononhealthcare

qualitywhenpricesareregulated.Findingsaremixed.Somestudiesfind thatcompetitionimprovesqualityinthiscontext(KesslerandMcClellan, 2000;KesslerandGeppert,2005;Cooperetal.,2011;Gaynoretal.,2013; Gaynoretal.,2016;GobillonandMilcent,2017).Othersfindevidenceof thecontrary(Moscellietal.,2019;Skellern,2019),whileonestudyfinds noeffectatall(Bertaetal.,2016).

talsnegotiatedwithpurchasingorganizationsintheBritish

NationalHealthServicein1991hasbeenusedtoestimate

thequalityeffectofahighlyregulatedformofprice

compe-tition(Propperetal.,2004;Propperetal.,2008).Contracts

werewrittenforblocksofservices,includingaccidentand

emergencyproceduresandnotfordefinedproducts,such

asDRGs.Hospitalsweremandatedtosetpriceequal to

averagecost,hadtopublishthesepricesandwerenot

per-mittedtocarrysurplusesorlossesacrossfinancialyears.A

limiteddegreeofpricecompetitionwaspossibleatthe

spe-cialtylevelbecauseofthedifficultyofcheckingadherence

tothepricingruleatthatlevel(Propperetal.,2008).The

evidencesuggeststhateventhisregulatedformofprice

competitionhadanegativeimpactonquality(measured

byAMImortalityrates),whichisattributedtohospitals’

incentivestocompeteonpriceratherthanqualitywhen

theavailableinformation onthelatter ispoor(Propper

etal.,2004;Propperetal.,2008).

Ifthehighlyregulatedformofpricecompetition

per-mittedin theUKcoulddamagequality,thenonemight

anticipatethatallowinghospitalstofreelynegotiateprices

withpurchasers would be seriouslydetrimental to the

quality of care deliveredin more competitive markets.

The2005reform oftheDutchhospital marketprovides

anopportunitytotestthis conjecture. Sincethere were

nopublishedoutcome indicators of qualityavailable to

patientsandhealthinsurersbeforeandafterthereform,

theriskofanegativeimpactonqualitywassubstantial.

Particularlyin morecompetitivehospitalmarkets,price

deregulationmayhaveraisedthemagnitudeoftheprice

elasticityrelativetothequalityelasticityandsomayhave

reducedquality.

3. PricederegulationintheDutchhospitalcare market

Comprehensive health insurance in the Netherlands

withverylimitedcostsharingleavespatientsinsensitiveto

priceandplausiblymoreconcernedaboutquality.5

How-ever,asDutchhealthinsurerscompeteonthepricesofthe

packagestheyoffer,theyarelikelytobemoresensitive

tothepricesofhealthcareproductsthanpatients.6 After

pricederegulationin2005,insurershad anincentiveto

pushpriceslowerinnegotiationswithhospitalsandwere

possiblymoreconcernedaboutpricethanquality.Thiswas

strengthenedbythelackofoutcome-basedquality

indica-tors–onlyalimitedsetofstructure-andprocess-based

indicatorswasavailableatthetime.Ifbetterinformation

5 Inthespecificcontextofourstudy,pricesofhipreplacementsexceed

thedeductible,whichistheonlyformofcost-sharing.Forthis proce-dure,out-of-pocketcoststopatientsare,therefore,invarianttotheprices chargedbyhospitals.

6 Thescenarioweexamineissimilartothatcapturedbyatwo-stage

modelinwhichinsurers(ManagedCareOrganizations)andhospitals firstnegotiateprices,andthenpatients,whoareexposedtolittlecost sharing,selectahospital(Cappsetal.,2003;TownandVistnes,2001; Gowrisankaranetal.,2015).TheestimatesGowrisankaranetal.(2015) obtainfromsuchamodelimplythattheinsurersaremuchmoreprice sensitivethantheinsuredpatients,buttheinsurersarelesspricesensitive thanpatientswouldbeiftheywereuninsured.

(4)

onqualityhadbeenavailable,theninsurers,presumably,

wouldhavebeenmoreresponsivetoit.

AllDutchhospitalsareprivatenonprofitfoundations

facinga legallybindingnon-distributionconstraint

pro-hibitingthemfromdistributinganynetearnings.Before

2005,thehospitalswerefinancedbyaprospective

bud-getingsystemwithregulatedperdiemratesthatproduced

relativelystablerevenueflowsknownatthebeginningof

eachyear.From2005,hospitals’revenuesbecame

contin-gentoncontractssecuredwithindividualhealthinsurers.

Atthattime,therewerefivehealthinsurancecompanies,

plusajointpurchasingcooperativeofsmallerinsurers.7

Contractsarewrittenforproductsdefinedbyapurposively

developedproductclassificationsystem–Diagnosisand

TreatmentCombinations (DTCs)– akintoDRGs.8 These

productsbearnorelationtotheoutputparametersofthe

pre-reformhospitalbudgets(e.g.number ofadmissions

andhospitaldays)andtheproduct-specificpricesarenot

relatedtotheregulatedperdiemratesthatwereusedtoset

thesebudgets.Forallproducts,hospitalsandinsurersare

permittedtonegotiateovervolumewhiletakingaccountof

quality,althoughintheperiodwestudytheattentionthat

couldbepaidtoqualitywashamperedbythelackof

out-comeindicators.9Forsomeproducts,freeinsurer-hospital

negotiationofpriceswasallowed.In2005,thiswas

permit-tedforasubsetofproductsthataccountedforabout10%

ofhospitalrevenues.Thissubsetincludednon-acutehip

replacements–theprocedurewefocuson.Overtime,the

numberofproductsforwhichfreepricesettingis

permit-tedhasincreased.Anextensionin2008tooktheshareof

hospitalrevenuesobtainedfromproductswithnegotiated

pricesto20%.Thefractionwasfurtherincreasedto34%in

2009and70%in2012.

Afterpermittingpricecompetition,theprice

elastic-ityoftheinsurers’ demandisgreater(inmagnitude)in

lessconcentrated,morecompetitivemarkets,andprices

couldbepusheddownfurtherinthesemarkets.

Accord-ingtotheDorfman-Steinercondition,qualitywouldthen

suffer in more competitive markets unless there was

a sufficient countervailing increase in the quality

elas-ticity. This increase would occur only if quality was

sufficientlyobservablesuchthatinsurerscouldmonitorit

andthenewcontractingarrangementsgavethemgreater

motivation and scope to pressure hospitals for quality

improvements.10

7 Thefourlargestcompaniesaccountfor90percentofthemarket.

Mar-ketconcentrationbyregionisoftenevenhigher,whichisduetothe factthatthesecompaniestypicallyevolvedfromformerregionalsickness funds(Halbersmaetal.,2010).

8 TheDTCsystemismorecomprehensivethanDRGs.Itincludes

out-patientconsultationsandtheremunerationofmedicalspecialists.There wereabout29,000DTCsintheperiodweexamine.

9 Duringtheperiodcoveredbyouranalysis,almostallcontractual

agreementsthatincludedqualityimprovementinitiativeswereframedin termsofstructureandprocessindicatorsratherthanoutcomeindicators (SchutandVandeVen,2011).

10 Notethat,atthetimeofthecontractingreform,medical

special-istswerepaidfee-for-serviceatregulatedproduct-specificremuneration ratesdeterminedbythepredictedtimerequiredforeachprocedureand afixedpaymentperhour.Whilespecialists,likehospitals,hadafinancial interestinattractingmorepatients,theircompensationwas,therefore,

Becauseofthehighoverallnumberofproducts(DTCs),

insurersandhospitalsoftennegotiateoverclustersof

prod-ucts.Thiswasnotthecaseforhigh-volumeproductslike

non-emergencyhipreplacementsduringtheperiod

cov-ered by this study.11 At that time, contracts, including

those agreedafternegotiationoverprices,werewritten

foraperiodofoneyear.Thegoalofthecontractingreform

wastomakeinsurers,actingaspurchasingagentsfortheir

customers,moreresponsivetoprice,volumeandquality.

Insurerswereallowedtocontracthospitalsselectively,

giv-ingthemleveragetonegotiatelowerpricesand,possibly,

alsotoobtainbetterqualitytotheextentthatthiscouldbe

specifiedbythelimitedqualityindicatorsavailableatthe

time.

Inacompetitiveinsurancemarket,lowerpriceswould

feedthroughtolowerpremiums(Ho,2009).Inthisrespect,

an important complement tothe 2005 insurer-hospital

contractingreformwasa2006reformofthehealth

insur-ancemarketintendedtoincreasepricecompetitionamong

insurersbymandatingcitizenstopurchaseabasichealth

insurancepackagefromprivateinsurers(SchutandVande

Ven,2011).Thelogicofthesetwinreformsisthat–asin

thetwo-stagemodelofhospitalcompetition(Cappsetal.,

2003;TownandVistnes,2001;Gowrisankaranetal.,2015)

–insurerswouldcompeteforcustomersonpremiums,as

wellasthescopeandqualityoftheirprovidernetworks,

while hospitalswould competeonpriceand qualityfor

inclusion inthosenetworks.Infact,prior to2010–the

last yearcovered by ouranalysis – there was very

lit-tleimplementationofselectivecontracting.Bythatyear,

onlyoneinsurerhadenteredintoselectivecontractsand

thesedidnotcoverhipreplacements(SchutandVande

Ven,2011).Since2010,thenumberofinsurerscontracting

withrestrictedprovidernetworkshasincreased.12But

dur-ingthepost-reformperiodwestudy(2006–2010),insurers

reliedonthethreatofselectivecontracting,ratherthanits

implementation,togivethembargainingpowerin

negoti-ationswithhospitals.

Someinsurerstriedtosteertheircustomerstohospitals

identifiedontheirwebsites as‘preferredproviders’that

wereclaimedtooffergoodqualitycare,althoughchoice

wasnotrestrictedtothesehospitals.Oneinducementwas

towaivethedeductibleiftheinsuredsoughttreatment

at apreferredprovider. Theavailableevidencesuggests

thatthesesoftchannelingpolicieshadlittleinfluenceon

patientchoiceduringtheperiodwestudy(VanderGeest

andVarkevisser,2016,2019),andwearenotawareofany

attempttousethemtospecificallytargethipreplacement

notdirectlyaffectedbytheoutcomeofanypricenegotiation.The qual-ityoftreatmentdeliveredbythespecialistscouldbeaffectedindirectly throughthevolumeofprocedures–negotiatedsimultaneoustoprice– theywerecalledupontoperform.Quality–specifically,thereadmission ratesweexamine–couldalsohavebeenaffectedbypricenegotiation throughconsequentpressuresonnon-specialistmedicalstaff,attention paidtoaftercareandhospitalpurchasingofnon-manpowerinputs.

11Thishasbeenconfirmedbytheauthorsthroughinterviewswith

rep-resentativesofinsurersandhospitalswhowereinvolvedincontract negotiationsduringtheperiodcoveredbythisstudy.

12Thisisoftendonebystipulatingminimumvolumestandards,butonly

foralimitedsetoftreatments,suchascomplexcancersurgery,thatdoes notincludehipreplacements.

(5)

patients.Additionally,asurveyofpatientswhohad

non-emergencyhospitalcareintheperiod2008-10revealed

thatonly7percenthadsearchedforqualityinformation

(VanderGeestandVarkevisser,2012).Hence,thereform

leftpatients’choiceofhospital(forhipreplacementsand

otherprocedures)effectivelyunfetteredduringtheperiod

studied.

The complexityof healthcare andits stochastic

rela-tionshipwithhealthoutcomesmakesmeasurementofits

qualityinherentlydifficult.In2008,theDutchHealthCare

Inspectoratelaunchedaninitiativewiththeambitionof

developingacomprehensivesetofqualityindicatorsfor10

procedures,includinghipreplacement.Butthiswas

con-finedtoaminorityof33hospitalsandplanstoextendit

werenotimplementedbecauseoflackofcooperationfrom

hospitalsandfailuretoagreeonastandardizedsetof

qual-ityindicators(SchutandVandeVen,2011).Afterthisfailed

attemptatselfregulation,onlyin2013didthegovernment

establishaQualityInstitutetodisseminateuniform

qual-ityindicatorsanddefinelegallyenforcedstandards.Hence,

uptotheendofourperiodofanalysisin2010,no

mean-ingful, comparable information aboutthequality ofhip

replacements,suchashospital-specificreadmissionrates,

wasavailable.

Thelackofinformationwouldbeexpectedtoresultin

hospitalsexposedtogreatercompetitivepressureshifting

effortfrom maintainingpoorlyobserved quality to

cut-tingcostsinordertobecomemorepricecompetitiveonce

priceswerederegulated(Propperetal.,2008).Ontheother

hand,thenewcontractsinvolvedhospitalsandinsurers

negotiatingforthefirsttimeoverthedeliveryofspecific

proceduresakintoDRGs.Hospitalsexposedtomore

com-petitionmighthaveexpendedgreatereffortonensuring

thattheywerenotpenalizedforpoorperformanceonthe

availableproxiesforqualitytakenintoaccountinfuture

contract negotiations.Ifthis motivationwassufficiently

strong,thenexposuretogreatercompetitivepressureafter

thecontractingreformcouldevenhaveraisedquality.

Existingevidenceonthemarketresponsetothe2005

contracting reform is limited. Qualitative analyses

con-cludethatpriceratherthanqualityhasbeentheprimary

focusofcontractnegotiations(Meijeretal.,2010;Ruwaard

etal.,2014;SchutandVandeVen,2011).Thisis

unsurpris-inggiventhedearthofinformationavailableonquality.The

DutchHealthcareAuthorityreportsthatpricesofproducts

(DTCs)thatwereinthefree-pricingsegmentfrom2005

declinedinrealtermsandrelativetotheregulatedpricesof

otherproductsupto2008(NZa,2009).Between2006and

2009,nominalpricesincreasedby2.7%,onaverage,inthe

regulatedsegmentofproductscomparedwithanincrease

ofonly1.2%inthefree-pricingsegment(SchutandVande

Ven,2011).Thereisnoevidencethathospitalsoffsetlower

priceincreasesbyincreasingservicevolumeinthe

free-pricingsegment(Krabbe-Alkemadeetal.,2017;Schutand

VandeVen,2011).Krabbe-Alkemadeetal.(2017)found

thatpermittingpricecompetitionledtolowertotal

hospi-talcosts.

Theeffectofthepricederegulationbroughtaboutbythe

2005reformonhospitalqualityhasnotpreviouslybeen

estimated.Afewstudieslookattherelationshipbetween

priceand qualityvariation orbetweenhospital

concen-trationand qualityafterprices wereliberalized.Heijink

etal.(2013)findonlylimitedvariationinhospitalquality

andnorelationshipbetweencontractpricesandqualityfor

cataracttreatment.Croesetal.(2017)findanegative

rela-tionshipbetweenhospitalmarketshareandqualityscores

fortwoofthethreediagnosticgroupsstudied.Bijlsmaetal.

(2013)findthathospitalconcentrationisassociatedwith

variousprocessindicatorsofquality,butbothpositiveand

negativerelationshipsarefoundandthereisno

relation-shipbetweenhospitalconcentrationandanyofanumber

of outcome indicators examined.None of these studies

haveadesigncapableofidentifyingthecausaleffecton

qualityofpricederegulation.

4. Dataandmeasures

4.1. Sources

We usecomprehensive, hospital-level datafrom the

NationalMedicalRegistryonpatientdischargesfromall

Dutchhospitalsfor the years 2001–2010.For each

dis-charge, we observe the patient’s gender, age,zip code,

primary/secondary/tertiarydiagnoses(ICD-9CM),

admis-sion period, the admission hospital code (but not its

name)andprocedurescarriedout.Proceduresare

classi-fiedaccordingtoamethodthatisbasedon,andforthe

proceduresexaminedequivalentto,theInternational

Clas-sificationofProceduresinMedicine(WHO-FIC,2017).For

mostoftheanalyses,werestrictattentiontopatients

dis-chargedafteranon-acutehipreplacement(seebelowfor

detailsoftheselectioncriteria).13Asarobustnesstest,we

examinepatientsdischargedafternon-acuteknee

replace-ment.Weconstructahospital-levelpanelwhichincludes

informationonqualityofcareandpatientcasemix,and

supplementthiswithanindexofsocioeconomicstatusthat

isaveragedoverallthenon-acutehipreplacementpatients

ofahospitalinagivenyear.Thisindexisconstructedby

theNetherlandsInstituteforSocialResearchfromthe

edu-cation,incomeandlabormarketstatusofresidentsofazip

codearea(SCP,2017).

4.2. Qualitymeasures

We use theunplanned 90-day readmission rate

fol-lowing non-acute hipreplacement as our main quality

indicator. Thisis preferred totheposthip replacement

mortality rate because the latter was very low in the

periodstudied.14 Werestrict attentiontoallunplanned

readmissions,includingemergencyreadmissions,because

plannedreadmissions(e.g.forascheduledprocedure)are

notgenerallyasignalofqualityofcare.Higherunplanned

readmissionrateshavebeenshowntoberelatedto

sub-optimalqualityoftreatmentgenerally(e.g.Mokhtaretal.,

13 Alsosometimesreferredtoasplannedhipreplacementsorelective

hipreplacements.Hence,thesedonotincludehipfracturesoracutehip replacements.

14 UsingtheCausesofDeathRegisterprovidedbyDutchHospitalData

andStatisticsNetherlands,wecalculateawithinhospitalmortalityrate of0.25percentanda30-daymortalityrateof0.30percentfollowing non-acutehipreplacementintheperiod2001–2010.

(6)

2012;Rosenetal.,2013)andspecificallyforhip

replace-ments(e.g.Clementetal.,2013;Avrametal.,2014;Saucedo

etal.,2014;Kurtzetal.,2016).Allunplannedreadmissions

areattributedtotheoriginaltreatmenthospitalusingthe

anonymizedhospitalcodes.

Unplannedreadmissionsfollowing jointreplacement

aredetermined,inpart,bythequalityandsafetyofthe

initialhospitalstay,transitionalcareservicesandpost

dis-charge support(Friebel et al., 2017). Widespread belief

thatreadmissionsareindicativeofpoorqualitytreatment

isreflectedinthefactthatfinancialpenaltiesforexcess

readmissions(includingforhipreplacements)havebeen

imposedonhospitalsinboththeUSandtheUKsince2012

(JoyntandJha,2012).Consistentwiththis,inourdata,four

ofthetopfivereasons(identifiedfromdiagnosticcodes)for

hipreplacementpatientstobereadmittedwithin90-days

arerelated tocomplications, infections orinflammatory

reactionsduetoprostheticimplants.15Thereisno

consen-susonwhethera90-dayor30-dayfollow-upwindowto

defineorthopedicreadmissionsprovidesthebetter

indica-torofquality(Ramkumaretal.,2015).Sincethetwoare

highlycorrelatedforhipreplacementsinourdata(r=0.85,

p<0.01atthestartofourstudyperiodin2001),itshould

make little differencewhich is used. Complicationsare

alsothemainreasontobereadmittedwithin30-days.We

examinerobustnesstousing30-dayreadmissions.

Infor-mationonhipreplacementreadmissionrateswasnotin

thepublicdomainoravailabletohealthinsurersduring

theperiodofanalysis,andsothisindicatorisunlikelyto

havebeensubjecttomanipulationbyhospitals.

4.3. Sampleselection

Wehave abalanced panelof 103hospitalsobserved

from2001to2010,yielding1,030hospital-year

observa-tions.Patientlevelsampleinclusionandexclusioncriteria

arebasedonthosedefinedinthetechnicalspecifications

of the US Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality

(AHRQ)InpatientQualityIndicator#14(AHRQQIVersion

5.0;IQI#14),whichmeasuresthehipreplacement

mor-tality rate.The total populationincludes all discharged

patients aged 18 or older in any year between 2001

and 2010 with any procedure code that indicates

par-tialor fullhip replacementand anyprincipal diagnosis

codethatindicatesosteoarthrosisofthepelvicregionor

thigh,andforwhichallnecessaryinformationwaspresent

(n=153,208).16Forouranalysis,wedropthosewithany

listeddiagnosiscodes indicating hipfracture and those

withcodesindicatingpregnancy,childbirthorpuerperium

(n=793).Wealsoexcludethosewhotransfertoanother

hospital(n=264) because it is impossibleto determine

whetherreadmissioninsuchcasesindicatessub-optimal

qualityofthetreatmentreceivedinthefirstorthe

sec-15 Consequently,itisunlikelythatrestrictingattentiontounplanned

readmissionsjudged(bysomecriteria)toberelatedtotheindexhip replacementadmissionwouldhavemuchaffectonourestimates.

16 SeeAppendix1fortherelevantprocedurecodesandICD-9CM

diag-nosiscodes.

ondhospital.17Patientswhodiedinthehospital(n=85)

are also dropped.18 After imposing all these exclusion

restrictions,weareleftwith152,066(99.3%of)discharges

followingnon-acutehipreplacementduringourperiodof

analysis.Ofthese,8.0percentwerereadmittedtoahospital

within90daysforanyreasonthatwasnotplanned.19

4.4. Measuresofhospitalmarketstructure

Wemeasureconcentrationatthehospitallevelusing

theHerfindahl-HirschmanIndex(HHI)basedonthe

num-berofhospitalbeds:HHIh=

Nh



i=1

m2

i,wheremiisthepercent

marketshareofhospitalithatlieswithinafixedradius

of hospitalhand Nh isthetotal numberof hospitalsin

thatmarket.Somehospitalshavemultiplelocationsthat

donotallliewithinthesamemarketdefinedbydistance.20

Appendix2 explainshow wecalculatetheHHIinthese

cases.For ourbaselineanalysis,weusea30 kilometers

(by road)fixedradiusbecause patientstravel, on

aver-age,for20minutestogettothehospitaloftheirchoice

(Varkevisseretal.,2010;Varkevisseretal.,2012;Beukers

etal.,2014)andallDutchhospitalsdohipreplacements

(Roosetal.,2019).Butsincevariationaroundthemean

traveltime ishigh(Varkevisseret al.,2010; Varkevisser

etal.,2012;Beukersetal.,2014),weexaminesensitivityto

fixingtheradiusat20,40and50kilometerstodefinethe

market.

To protect privacy, hospitals are anonymized in the

patient-level data and we are not allowed to attach a

continuousmeasureofHHItoapatientrecordsincethis

couldrevealthehospitalused.TheHHI ofeachhospital

was thereforeconstructed in a databasenot containing

patient-leveldata.Next,anindicatorofwhethertheHHI

of each hospital is under2500was derived –to

deter-mine location in a less concentrated market – and this

was then linked to the patient-level dataset using the

hospital identifier code byStatistics Netherlands.There

is no objective HHI threshold for defining a

competi-tivemarket.Ourchoiceof2500,whichcorrespondstoa

marketcomprising fourequallysizedhospitals,isbased

on theUS FederalTrade Commission(2010) horizontal

mergerguidelines.21Giventhegreatercompetitive

pres-17Whiletransfertoanotherhospitalcoulditselfbeanindicatoroflow

quality,theextremelysmallnumberoftransfersrulesoutanalysisofsuch anindicator.Italsomeansthatdroppingthesecaseswillhaveanegligible impactonourestimates.

18Giventheverylowwithinhospitalmortalityratefollowingnon-acute

hipreplacement,anyselectionbiasarisingfromexcludingthosewhodie islikelytohaveanegligibleimpactontheestimates(Laudicellaetal., 2013;Fischeretal.,2014).

19AsshownbyFigureA2intheAppendix,totalvolumesaggregated

overthetwogroupsdroppedin2006andthenslightlyincreasedagain. Thedifferenceinvolumesbetweenthetreatmentandcomparisongroups isrelativelystableovertime.

20Ofthe103hospitals,4hadmorethanonelocationwithintheperiod

thatwestudy.

21TheEuropeanCommission(2004)guidelinesontheassessementof

horizontalmergersdonotincludeanHHI-basedmarketclassification. Theymentionaslightlylowerthreshold(HHI>2000)asaninitialindicator ofalackofcompetition.

(7)

sureonhospitalsoperatinginlessconcentratedmarkets

approximatedbyHHI<2500,itishypothesizedthatthey

wouldbeaffectedmorebythe2005reformthatpermitted

competitionthroughfreenegotiationofpricesthanwere

hospitalsoperatinginmoreconcentratedmarkets(i.e.with

HHI≥2500).22Overtheperiod2001–2010,thereisanearly

evensplitbetweenhospitalswithHHI≥2500(n=52)and

hospitalswithHHI<2500(n=51).

5. Empiricalstrategy

Identificationofthequalityeffectofpermitting

compe-titionthroughfreenegotiationofpriceisdifficultgiventhat

allhospitalsareexposedtopricederegulationafter2005.

Intherelatedliterature,identificationfroman

across-the-boardpolicychangeistypicallydonethroughcomparison

ofthebefore-and-afterchangeintheoutcomeinless

con-centrated markets with the respective change in more

concentrated markets(e.g. Propperet al., 2008; Cooper

etal.,2011;Gaynoretal.,2013).Whilethis

difference-in-differences(DID)strategydoesnotidentifytheeffectofthe

policyperse,itmaybethoughtcapableofidentifyingthe

differentialeffectofthegreatercompetitiongeneratedby

thepolicyinlessconcentratedmarketscomparedwiththe

weakercompetitioninducedinmoreconcentrated

mar-kets,providedtheoutcomesofhospitalsoperatinginmore

and in less concentrated markets would have followed

commontrendsifthepolicyhadnotbeenimplemented.

Fricke(2017)pointsoutthatthestatedcommontrends

assumptionisinsufficienttoidentifythedifferentialeffect

oftreatmentintensities.Iftheassumptiondoeshold,then

the differential effect is identified only under the

fur-therassumptionofhomogeneityintheeffectofmarginal

changes in treatmentacross, in this context, more and

lessconcentratedmarkets.Thishomogeneityassumption

islikelytobeimplausiblegiventhathospitalsarenot

ran-domlyassignedtomarkets.ApplyingFricke’slogictothe

situationstudiedhere,whatcanplausiblybeidentifiedis

alowerbound(inmagnitude)ontheeffectofprice

dereg-ulationinlessconcentratedmarketscomparedwiththe

continuationofpriceregulationinthosemarkets.23Two

assumptionsarenecessarytoobtainthispartial

identifi-cation.First,there mustbecommontrendsacrossmore

andlessconcentratedmarketsunderthecounterfactualof

nopolicychange.Second,thepolicyeffect(relativetono

change) inlessconcentrated marketsmustbethesame

signbutofgreatermagnitudethantheeffectinmore

con-centratedmarkets.24Intuitively,ifpricederegulationhas

anyeffectinmoreconcentratedmarkets,thentakingthe

22Asacheckforfurtherheterogeneityinhospitals’responsestoprice

deregulation,afinercategorizationofhospitalsbyHHIisalsoused.

23Fricke(2017)considersidentificationoftheeffectsoftwo(ormore)

distincttreatmentsusingaDIDstrategy.Thetreatmentscanbe distin-guishedbydegreeofintensity.Toapplythesetuptothisstudy,onemust thinkofthetreatmentsnotaspricederegulation,butratherasthe inten-sityofcompetitionarisingfromthispolicy.Weareinterestedinthe qualityeffectofmoreintensecompetitionandidentifythisby (effec-tively)interactingasinglepolicychange(pricederegulation)withmarket concentrationtoobtainvariationincompetition(treatment)intensity.

24Thatis,monotonicityintreatmentintensity,wheretreatmentisthe

competitivepressureinducedbythepricederegulation.

DIDbetweenmoreandlessconcentratedmarketscannot

pointidentifytheeffectinthelatter.Butitwillgivealower

boundontheeffectinthelessconcentratedmarkets

pro-videdthattheeffectisgreaterinmagnitudebuthasthe

samesignastheeffectinmoreconcentratedmarkets(and

commontrendshold).

Hospitals with an HHI below 2500 form our

treat-ment group, while those with an HHI of at least 2500

belongtothecomparisongroup.Onlyhospitalswithan

HHIeitheralwaysbelow2500oralwaysabove2500during

the2001–2010periodareusedintheanalysis.Hence,no

hospitalcanswitchfromthetreatmentgrouptothe

com-parisongrouporviceversa,andthecompositionofeach

groupisheldconstantbyconstruction.Twenty-one

hospi-talsoutofatotalof103areexcludedbecausetheyfailto

meetthiscriterion.Thisismainlybecauseofmerger

activ-itybetween2001and2010.Oftheremaining82hospitals,

43haveHHI<2500andareinthetreatmentgroup.

Inourmainanalysis,weusedatafrom2001to2004to

capturetheperiodbeforepricederegulationanddatafrom

2006to2010forthepost-reformperiod.Weexcludedata

from2005,asthepolicywasimplementedonFebruary1

ofthatyear.

Weestimatethefollowingfixedeffectsmodelbyleast

squares:

RRht=˛+ı1 (HHIh<2500)×POSTt+Xht

+uh+t+εht (1)

whereRRhtistheunplanned90-dayreadmissionrate

(per-cent)fornon-acutehipreplacementsathospitalhinyear

t,1()istheindicatorfunction,POSTt isabinaryindicator

equalto1forthepost-reformperiod(2006-2010),Xhtisa

vectorofhospitalcharacteristicsthatvaryovertimebutare

plausiblynotaffectedbypricederegulation,uhisahospital

fixedeffect,␭tisayeareffectandεhtisarandomerrorterm.

ThecovariatesconsistoftheCharlsonindexofcomorbidity

(Quanetal.,2011;Quanetal.,2005)averagedovera

hos-pital’snon-acutehipreplacementpatientsinayear,the

percentageofthesepatientsaged65+,40–60and18–39

years,thepercentagefemale,thepercentagedischargedto

askillednursingfacility,25andthemeanzipcode-specific

socioeconomicscoreofthepatients. Theseindicatorsof

casemixareincludedtoincreaseefficiencyandtoallowfor

anychangeinthecompositionofhipreplacementpatients

thatdiffersbetweenhospitalsin lessand more

concen-tratedmarketswithoutbeingcaused bythedifferential

effectofpricederegulation.Wehavearguedthatthereis

littleornoreasontoexpectthereformtohavecausedhip

replacementpatientstoselectdifferenthospitalsor

hos-pitalstohaveselecteddifferentpatients,andwereturnto

thispointattheendofthissection.

Table1 presentsmeansofthe covariatesbeforeand

afterthereformforthetreatmentandcomparisongroups.

Priortothereform,therearesomesignificantdifferences

inthecharacteristicsofthepatientsacrossthetwogroups.

25 Weassignedpatientsreportedtobedischargedto‘otherhealthcare

organization’toanursinghomedischargesincearecent(unpublished) StatisticsNetherlandsstudyreportsthataround70%ofthesepatientsare transferredtoanursinghomefacility.

(8)

Table1

Meansofcovariatesbyperiodandtreatmentgroup.

Patients’characteristics Pre-reform Post-Reform Change(Post-Pre)

Proportiondischargedto skillednursingfacility

ComparisonGroup 0.048 0.059 0.011 {0.061} {0.084} (0.009) TreatmentGroup 0.075 0.087 0.012 {0.096} {0.133} (0.013) Difference(T-C) 0.03*** 0.001 (0.009) (0.016) Proportionfemale ComparisonGroup 0.69 0.68 −0.01* {0.05} {0.06} (0.01) TreatmentGroup 0.72 0.69 −0.03*** {0.06} {0.07} (0.01) Difference(T-C) 0.03*** −0.02* (0.01) (0.01) Meanage ComparisonGroup 69.85 70.36 0.51* {19.23} {22.53} (0.24) TreatmentGroup 70.60 70.50 −0.11 {25.09} {33.50} (0.34) Difference(T-C) 0.75*** −0.61 (0.25) (0.42)

MeanCharlsonScore (comorbidity) ComparisonGroup 0.0018 0.0009 −0.0009* {0.01} {0.00} (0.0005) TreatmentGroup 0.0039 0.0017 −0.0022 {0.02} {0.00} (0.0016) Difference(T-C) 0.0021 −0.0014 (0.0016) (0.0016)

Meansocioeconomicscore

ComparisonGroup 6.81{0.53} 6.88{0.55} 0.06 (0.06) TreatmentGroup 7.46 7.49 0.03 {0.48} {0.48} (0.06) Difference(T-C) 0.65*** −0.04 (0.06) (0.08)

Numberofhospitals ComparisonGroup 39 39 39

TreatmentGroup 43 43 43

Numberofpatients ComparisonGroup 28613 33096 61709

TreatmentGroup 25528 26851 52379

Notes:Pre-/post-reformcellentriesareobtainedbyfirstcomputingthemeanacrossallnon-acutehipreplacementpatientsdischargedfromeachhospital andthentakingthesimpleaverageofthesemeansacrossallhospitalswithinagroupandperiod.Figuresincurlybracketsarestandarddeviationsacross hospitals.Figuresinparenthesesarestandarderrorsoftheestimatedchangeinthemean.Hospitalsandpatientsareselectedusingthecriteriadescribed intheData,sampleselectionsection.Thesocioeconomicscoreisincreasinginsocioeconomicstatusandrangesfrom0to10.TheCharlsonscore(Quan etal.,2011)rangesfrom0to9,withhigherbeingmoresevere.***Significantatthe1percentlevel.**Significantatthe5percentlevel.

Butthedifferencesarerathersmall.Significancereflects

thelargesamplesize.Thetreatmentgrouphasaslightly

higherproportionoffemales,itspatientsareabout1year

older and they have a higher socioeconomic status as

wellasagreater propensitytobeadmittedtoa skilled

nursingfacilityafterdischarge,onaverage.Thereareno

pre-reformdifferences in comorbidity measuredby the

Charlsonindex.Thecharacteristicsofthepatientschange

relativelylittlebetweenthetwoperiodsforbothgroups.

Noneofthedifference-in-differencesofthese

character-isticsaresignificantlydifferentfromzero,indicatingthat

therewasnodifferentialchangeinthecompositionofthe

groupswithrespecttotheseobservables.

Conditionalonthecovariates(Xht),ifintheabsenceof

pricederegulationin2005theaveragereadmissionrateof

hospitalsinlessconcentratedmarketswouldhavechanged

in2006-10 by asmuch as thechangethat would have

occurredinhospitalsoperatinginmoreconcentrated

mar-ketsandifpermittingpricecompetitionhadalargereffect

inlessconcentratedmarkets,thentheparameterıin(1)is

alowerbound(inmagnitude)ontheaverageeffectofthe

pricederegulationinamorecompetitivemarket

environ-mentonthereadmissionrateamongthehospitalsinthe

lessconcentratedmarkets.

Fig.1supportstheplausibilityofthecommontrends

assumption. Between 2001 and 2005, the trend in the

readmissionrate,andindeeditslevel,isverysimilarfor

hospitalsoperatinginmoreandlessconcentratedmarkets.

Estimationofamodelsimilarto(1)usingdatafrom2001to

2004onlyandallowingtheyeareffectstodifferbetween

hospitalslocatedinmore(HHI2500) andless

concen-tratedmarketsrevealsnoevidenceofdifferentialtrendsin

theperiodimmediatelyprecedingthereform(Appendix3,

TableA1column(i)).

Agapopensupinthereadmissionratesin2006

imme-diatelyafterthecontractingreform.Thereadmissionrate

fallsinthelessconcentratedmarkets,whileitcontinuesto

riseinthemoreconcentratedmarkets.Takenatfacevalue,

this wouldsuggestthathospitalsthatexperiencedprice

deregulationinamorecompetitiveenvironmentraisedthe

qualityofthecaretheydelivered.However,thedivergence

(9)

sim-Fig.1.90-dayreadmissionrateafternon-acutehipreplacement.

Notes:HospitalsandpatientsselectedbycriteriadescribedintheData,sampleselectionsection.HHI(Herfindahl-HirschmanIndex)calculatedwitha radiusof30kmdefiningtheboundaryofamarket.

ilarinmoreandinlessconcentratedmarkets.Overthefull

five-yearpost-reformperiod,thefiguresuggeststhatprice

deregulationinamorecompetitiveenvironmentdidnot

consistentlylowerorraisethequalityofhipreplacements.

MotivatedbyFig.1,andbecausehospitalsandinsurers

maynothavefullyadjustedtothenewcontracting

condi-tionsimmediatelyafterpricesbecamefreelynegotiable,

we estimatea secondmodel that allows thetreatment

effecttovaryinthepost-reformperiod:

RRht=˛+



k=06,10

ık1(HHIh<2500)×YEARkt

+Xht+uh+t+εht (2)

whereYEAR06t=1(YEARkt=1)iftheyearis2006(20k).

Underthesameassumptionsaboutcommontrendsand

differentialeffectsinmoreandlessconcentratedmarkets,

␦06givesalowerboundontheaverageeffectofprice

dereg-ulationinamorecompetitivemarketenvironmentin2006,

etc.

Market concentration is generally considered to be

potentially endogenous because performance may feed

backintostructureandunobservableattributesmay

influ-enceboth quality and patientchoice ofhospital (Evans

etal.,1993).Theempiricalstrategyadoptedandthe

insti-tutionalcontextinwhichthisstudyisconductedminimize

the threats to identification from these two potential

sourcesofendogeneity.Hospitalfixedeffectsdealwithany

timeinvariantcorrelatedunobservables.Weavoidusing

timevaryinginformationonmarketconcentrationby

cat-egorizingeachhospitalintooneoftwogroupsaccording

towhetheritsHHIisalwaysbelow2500oralwaysabove

2500.Hospitalsthatcrossthisthresholdovertheperiod

ofanalysisaredropped.26TheHHIarecalculatedfrombed

numbers,ratherthanpatientflows,andsoendogeneityof

26Asnotedearlier,horizontalmergersamonghospitals aremainly

responsibleforthresholdcrossings.

thismeasureofmarketstructuretoperformanceisnota

majorconcern.

Wedeliberatelychooseanelectiveprocedureto

mea-surequalityinorder toobtainevidenceontheeffectof

competitiononatreatmentthatislikelytoexhibitmuch

greaterdemandelasticitywithrespecttopriceand

qual-itythanisthecasewithacutetreatments (e.g.forAMI)

thathavebeenthefocusofpreviousreseach(e.g.Cooper

etal., 2011; Gaynoretal., 2013).Ifgreater competition

doespotentiallyreducequalitybecausedemandismore

responsivetopricethantoquality,thenwewouldexpect

toobservethisforanelectiveprocedure.Therearethree

reasonswhythis studyisnot particularlyvulnerableto

selectionbiasarisingfrompatientchoicedespiteitsfocus

onan electiveprocedure. First,we eliminate correlated

timeinvariantunobservabledifferencesinpatient

compo-sitionacrosshospitalswithfixedeffects.Onlyifthereform

weretochangeunobservablepatientcharacteristics

dif-ferentiallyacrossthetreatment andcomparison groups

wouldtherebeanypotentialbias.Thelackofany

substan-tialorsignificantdifference-in-differencesinobservable

covariates(Table1)suggeststhattheremaybelittlereason

toworryaboutpotentiallycorrelatedtimevarying

unob-servables.Second,aspreviouslymentioned,patientsand

insurerslackedinformationonhospitalquality,including

readmissionratesforhipreplacements,beforeandafter

thereform.Therewaslimitedscopeforselectionon

qual-ity.Third,incontrasttotheUKhealthcaremarketreforms

that have beenthesubject of many previousstudies,27

thereformweexaminedidnotchangeopportunitiesfor

27 Thesestudieseitheruserichdataorintrumentstodealwithtime

vary-ingpatientselection.Skellern(2019)controlsforrisk-adjustedPatient ReportedOutcomeMeasures(PROMs),whileGaynoretal.(2013),Cooper etal.(2011)andMoscellietal.(2016)instrumenthospitalchoiceusing GP/patient-hospitaldistances.Cooperetal.(2011)donotreject exogene-ityofmarketstructureandMoscellietal.(2016)findthatinstrumenting hasverylittleimpactontheestimates,relativetocontrollingforarichset ofpatientcovariates.

(10)

Table2

Unplanned90-dayand30-dayhipreplacementreadmissionratesbyperiodandtreatmentgroup.

Outcome Pre-reform Post-Reform Change(Post-Pre)

90-dayreadmissionrate

ComparisonGroup 0.0768 0.0827 0.0059* {0.0316} {0.0290} (0.0036) TreatmentGroup 0.0766 0.0813 0.0047 {0.0321} {0.0326} (0.0037) Difference(T-C) −0.0003 −0.0012 (0.0036) (0.0051)

30-dayreadmissionrate

ComparisonGroup 0.0419 0.0482 0.0062** {0.0227} {0.0200} (0.0025) TreatmentGroup 0.0439 0.0493 0.0054* {0.0237} {0.0239} (0.0027) Difference(T-C) 0.0019 −0.0008 (0.0026) (0.0037)

Numberofhospitals ComparisonGroup 39 39 39

TreatmentGroup 43 43 43

Numberofpatients ComparisonGroup 28613 33096 61709

TreatmentGroup 25528 26851 52379

Notes:Tablegivesthesimplemeanreadmissionrateaveragedoverallhospitalsinthetreatment(HHI<2500)groupandthecomparison(HHI≥>2500) group.Figuresincurlybracketsarestandarddeviationsacrosshospitals.Robuststandarderrorsinparentheses.Hospitalsandpatientsselectedbycriteria describedintheData,sampleselectionsection.*Significantatthe10percentlevel.

patientchoice.Asexplainedabove,patientshaddefacto

freechoiceofproviderbeforeandafterthereform.

Hospital-initiatedselectionofpatientsispotentiallyof

greaterconcern.Afterpriceswerederegulated,hospitals

operatinginmorecompetitivemarketscouldpossiblyhave

hadtheincentivetodrivedowncosts;e.g.bycherrypicking

morestraightforwardcasessothattighterbudgetswould

notimpingeonquality.However,becauseweidentifyfrom

comparisonacrosshospitalscategorizedbybroadranges

ofHHI,anycherrypickingwouldonlybiasourestimates

inthehighlyunlikelysituationthatpatientswereshunted

longdistances.Morelikelyisthatahospitalwouldrefer

apatientwhoisatgreaterriskofreadmissiontoa

neigh-boringhospital,whichwillmostprobablybeinthesame

treatmentorcomparisongroup.So,whilethecasemixof

individualhospitalsmaychangeduetopatientselectionin

responsetothereform,itisratherunlikelythatthiswould

changethecompositionofthegroups,andthecomparisons

inTable1againsupportthis.

6. Results

6.1. Mainestimates

Prior to the reform, there was no difference in the

90-dayreadmissionratebetweenthetreatment(low

mar-ketconcentration,HHI<2500)groupandthecomparison

(highmarket concentration) group(Table2, toppanel).

Thegroupsarebalancedontheoutcomeatbaseline.Post

reform,thereadmissionrateincreased(10%significance)

by0.59 percentage points (pp) or7.8% in the

compari-songroupandbyonlyslightlyless(andnotsignificantly)

inthetreatmentgroup.Consequently, thesimple

(non-parametric)DIDestimateisnegative,whichwouldindicate

thatpricederegulationinacompetitivemarket

environ-mentledtolowerreadmissionrates(i.e.higherquality).

Buttheestimateisverysmallinmagnitude–1.6%ofthe

treatmentgrouppre-reformrate–andnotatallcloseto

beingsignificantlydifferentfromzero.

TheconditionalDIDestimateobtainedfrommodel(1)

andgiveninthefirstcolumnofthetoppanelofTable3is

positive,butitisevensmallerinmagnitudethanthesimple

DIDestimate,anditalsolacksanysignificance.Thefactthat

conditioningonobservablesdoesnotmarkedlychangethe

estimatefurtherindicatesthatthereislikelytobelittlebias

fromcorrelatedtimevaryingunobservables.The

insignif-icant conditionalDIDpoint estimateis only0.7% ofthe

readmissionrateinthetreatmentgrouphospitalspriorto

thereform.Wecanruleoutaneffectgreaterthan11%ofthe

pre-reformreadmissionratewith95%confidence.Subject

totheusualcaveatthatfailuretorejectthenull

hypoth-esisdoesnotnecessarilyimplythatthereisnoeffect,the

magnitudeandprecisionoftheestimatedonotgivecause

tobelievethatpricederegulationinacompetitivemarket

ledtosubstantial,orevenany,deteriorationinthequality

oftreatment.Thisinferenceissubjecttothefurthercaveat

thatourempiricalstrategydeliversonlyalowerbound(in

magnitude)estimateoftheeffectofpricederegulationin

acompetivesetting.

ConsistentwithwhatisobservedinFig.1,the

condi-tionalDIDestimatesinthefirstcolumnofthebottompanel

ofTable3suggestthatpricederegulationinless

concen-tratedmarketsmayhavereducedthe90-dayreadmission

rate byat least1.5 percentage points (19%) in thefirst

year(2006)afterthereformbuthadnoeffectintheyears

thereafter(2007-2010).Asisapparentfromthefigure,the

negativeeffectin2006,whichissignificantonlyatthe10%

level,isdrivenbyafallinthereadmissionrateofthe

hos-pitalsoperatingin lessconcentrated marketsanda rise

inthereadmissionrateofhospitalsinmoreconcentrated

markets.Itwouldbedifficulttoattributethesedivergent

movementstoapositive effectofpricederegulationon

quality.

For all post-reform years after2006, the point

esti-matesarepositive.Overlookingthefactsthatnoneofthe

estimatesareremotelysignificantandtheyaresmallin

magnitude,onemightventuretoexplainthispatternas

arising froman initialpost-reform shock (in 2006)

(11)

Table3

Estimatedeffectsofpricederegulationonreadmissionratesafterhip(knee)replacement.

Hipreplacement KneeReplacement

Specification (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

90-dayreadmission 90-dayreadmission 90-dayreadmission 30-dayreadmission 90-dayreadmission radius30 radius20 radius40 radius30 radius30 Model(1) ␦ 0.0005 0.0063 0.0016 0.0003 0.0007 (0.0048) (0.0055) (0.0057) (0.0037) (0.0153) R2 0.49 0.461 0.458 0.437 0.375 Model(2) ␦6 −0.0147* 0.0007 −0.0056 −0.0059 −0.0315 (0.0076) (0.0097) (0.0093) (0.0054) (0.0199) ␦7 0.0077 0.0089 0.0062 0.0072 0.0080 (0.0086) (0.0099) (0.0098) (0.0064) (0.0249) ␦8 0.0039 0.0085 0.0012 0.0028 0.0260 (0.0085) (0.0101) (0.0097) (0.0066) (0.0215) ␦9 0.0003 0.0018 0.0026 −0.0011 −0.0147 (0.0068) (0.0074) (0.0077) (0.0058) (0.0195) ␦10 0.0081 0.0122 0.0038 −0.0015 0.0220 (0.0074) (0.0087) (0.0088) (0.0058) (0.020) R2 0.4990 0.4630 0.4600 0.4410 0.3880 NTreatmentHospitals 43 13 29 43 34 NComparisonHospitals 39 32 15 39 32 Nhospitalsxyears 738 495 396 738 5974 Npatients 114408 80077 74888 114408 18231 Nreadmittedpatients 9064 6489 6043 5241 1183

Notes:ToppanelgivesOLSestimatesof␦fromregression(1).SecondpanelgivesOLSestimatesof␦6until␦10fromregression(2).Allestimatesobtained fromregressionscontaininghospitalandyearfixedeffectsandcovariatesidentifiedinTable1.FullestimatesinAppendix3;Tables2and3.Robuststandard errorsinparentheses.HospitalsandpatientsselectedbycriteriadescribedintheData,sampleselectionsection.RadiusXindicatesthattheestimatesare basedontreatment/comparisongroupsformedonthebasisofaHHIcalculatedwitharadiusofXkmdefiningtheboundaryofamarket.Thesamplesize fallsastheradiusisreducedbecausemorehospitalscrosstheHHIthresholdof2500usedtodefinethetreatment/comparisongroupsduringtheestimation period.**Significantatthe5percentlevel.*Significantatthe10percentlevel.

hospitalsthatareexposedtomorecompetitivemarkets

areoperatingwithunregulatedprices.Inconsistentwith

thishypothesis,thepointestimatesdonotmonotonically

increaseinmagnitudeastimesincethereformlengthens.

Still,thelargest(buthighlyinsignificant)pointestimate

isinthelastofthepost-reformyearsanditis10%ofthe

pre-reformreadmissionrateofthetreatmentgroup.This

placesafinalcaveatontheconclusionthattherewasno

negativeimpactonquality.

6.2. Robustness

6.2.1. Marketdefinition

ThemainestimatesaregeneratedonthebasisofHHIs

calculatedwitharadiusof30kmusedtodefinethe

bound-aryofthemarketaroundahospital.Tocheckrobustness,

we recalculatetheHHI using a radiusof 20 and 40km

todefineamarket,recategorizehospitalsintothe

treat-mentandcomparisonsgroupsonthebasisoftherevised

indexandthenre-estimatemodels(1)and(2)ineachcase.

Estimatesaregivenintheappropriatelylabelledcolumns

of Table3.Witha radiusof30km, hospitalsareevenly

splitbetweenthetreatmentandcomparisongroups.Asthe

radiusiswidened,morehospitalsgetputintothe

treat-ment groupbecausetheHHI decreasesastheareathat

definesthemarketincreases.

Irrespective of the radius used, thetreatment effect

averagedoverthefiveyearsofthepost-reformperiodis

insignificant.Whentheradiusisincreased,thepoint

esti-mateoftheeffectin2006(frommodel(2))continuesto

benegativebutsignificanceislost.28Whentheradiusis

reduced,thispointestimateturnspositiveandagainitloses

significance.Themarginallysignificantnegativepoint

esti-mateobtainedfor2006usingthebaselineradiusof30km

isclearlynotrobust.Thereisnosignificanteffectafter2007

irrespectiveofthegeographic radiususedtodefinethe

market.Overall,irrespectiveoftheradiususedtodefine

a hospital market,there is noclearevidence that price

deregulationinamorecompetitivemarketenvironment

consistentlyimpactedonthereadmissionrate.

One might be concerned that exposure to different

degreesofmarketconcentrationisconfoundedby

differ-ences(inresponsetothereform)betweenurbanandrural

locations.Thisis unlikelytobea well-founded concern

in thecontext of the Netherlands, which is the second

mostdenselypopulatedcountryintheOECDandoneof

themost urbanized.29 Highlydeveloped and integrated

transportnetworksfurtherlimitthescopeforanymarked

and consequential urban-rural division in the country.

Onlythreehospitalsinoursamplearenotwithina30km

radiusofacitywithatleast50,000inhabitants,andonly

28 Extendingtheradiusfurtherto50kmproducesthesamegeneral

pat-tern:nosignificanteffectaverageoverallpost-reformyearsandanegative butnotatallsignificantpointestimatefor2006.SeeAppendix3TableA2 andA3,column(iv).

29 DutchpopulationdensityisalmosttwicethatoftheUKandmore

than14timesgreaterthanthatoftheUS(IndexMundi,2020).Morethan 75percentofthepopulationlivesinpredominantlyurbanregions(OECD, 2018).

(12)

oneofthesethreehospitalsremainsinoursampleafter

selectinghospitalsthatarepersistentlyinthesamegroup

definedbyHHIaboveorbelow2500.30Theestimatesare

robusttoexcludingthis hospital(seeAppendix3, Table

A2andA3,column(v)).

6.2.2. Curtailedpost-reformperiod

In 2008, there were a number of policy changes in

the Dutch hospital industry. As mentioned above, the

HealthCareInspectoratemadeanunsuccessfulattemptto

developandimplementacomprehensivesetofuniform

quality indicators across hospitals. Free price

negotia-tionwasextendedtomoreproceduresthatbroughtthe

share of hospital revenues derived from products with

unregulatedpricesto20%.Themethodofpaying

special-istsalsochangedin2008,suchthattheirannualincome

becamecompletelyactivity-based,whichgeneratedstrong

incentivestoincreaseproduction(SchutandVarkevisser,

2013).Theirremunerationrates,however,werestill

reg-ulatedand,therefore,notaffectedbytheoutcomeofthe

insurer-hospitalpricenegotiations.Entrytothehospital

marketbecameeasierfromthatyearbecausegovernment

approval forthe construction ofnew hospitalbuildings

(oradditionalcapacity)wasnolongerrequired.Thiswas

accompaniedbyagradualincreaseinthefinancialriskfor

hospitalsbecausereimbursementofcapitalcostswasno

longer(fully)assured.

Although the year-specific estimates in the bottom

panelofTable3givenoindicationofanysubstantialchange

from2008thatmaybeduetoconfounding,weexamine

therobustnessofourfindingstocurtailingthepost-reform

periodto2006–2007.Doingsogivesaninsignificant

neg-ativepointestimateoftheeffectaveragedoverthesetwo

yearsthatissmallinmagnitude.31 Thisgives noreason

tosuspectthataneffectofpricederegulationonthehip

replacementreadmissionrateisbeingconfoundedbyother

policychangesthatoccurredwithinourperiodofanalysis.

6.2.3. 30-dayreadmissionrate

Sincetheoreticalandempiricalgroundsfor

unambigu-ouslypreferringthe90-daytothe30-dayreadmissionrate

asanindicatorofthequalityofcarearelacking,wecheck

robustnesstousingtheshorterperiod.Pre-reformtrendsin

30-dayreadmissionratesarereasonablyparallelbetween

thetreatmentandcomparisongroups,althoughthereis

somedivergencein2004(seeFig.2).Thehypothesisthat

yeareffectsinthe30-dayreadmissionrateareequalfor

thetreatmentandcomparisongrouphospitalsinthe

pre-treatmentperiod isnot rejected(Appendix3, TableA1;

column(ii)),whichlendsplausibilitytothecommontrends

identificationassumptionforthisoutcomealso.32

Theestimatedeffect onthe30-dayreadmission rate

overthefullpost-reformperiodgiveninthetoppanelof

column(4)ofTable3isabouthalfthemagnitudeofthe

30 AllthreehospitalsareinthehighHHIgroup.

31 Theseresultsareavailablefromtheauthorsuponrequest. 32 Forbothgroups,thetrendsinthe30-dayratedisplaygreatervolatility

thanthoseforthe90-dayrate,whichisduetothesubstantiallylowerrate ofreadmissionsovertheshorterperiod.Thisgreaternoiseinthe30-day rateisonegoodreasonforrelyingmoreonthe90-dayrate.

baselineestimatedeffectonthe90-dayrateincolumn(1),

whichisduetothelowermeanrateofreadmissionsover

theshorterperiod.Theestimatedeffectonthe30-dayrate

isalsonotatallsignificant,andsotherecontinuestobeno

evidencethatpricederegulationinmorecompetitive

mar-ketsaffectedthequalityofcare.Theyear-specificestimates

arenegativein3ofthe5post-reformyears,buttheyare

alwayssmallinmagnitudeandneverclosetosignificance.

6.2.4. Kneereplacements

Tofurtherassessthecredibilityofourfindingofanull

effect,wereplicatetheanalysisforanindicatorofthe

qual-ityofasecondelectiveprocedure–readmissionafterknee

replacement.Withinthesubsetofproductsforwhichfree

pricenegotiationwasallowedfrom2005,knee

replace-ment is theonlyotherprocedurewithsufficientlyhigh

volumeandforwhichareliablequalityindicatorcanbe

constructed.Kneereplacementsandhipreplacementsare

commonlyperformedbythesamespecialty,whichmakes

thisalocaltestofrobustness.Theupsideisthatconsistency

acrossthetwoprocedureswouldlendalotofcredibilityto

theevaluationoftheeffectonthequalityofthetreatment

performedbyaparticularspeciality.We usethe90-day

readmissionrateasthequalityindicator.

Thereadmissionrateafterkneereplacementdisplays

greatervariationfromyeartoyearthantherateforhip

replacements(see AppendixFig.A1),which reflectsthe

muchsmallernumberofpatientsundergoingknee

replace-ment.Wecannotrejectthatthetimeeffectsarecommon

betweenthetreatmentandcomparisongroupsinthe

pre-reformperiod(seeAppendixTableA1,column(iii)).The

estimatesoftheeffectonthekneereplacement

readmis-sionratearehighlyconsistentwiththosefortheeffecton

readmissionafterhipreplacement(Table3.Column(5)).

Theestimatedeffectoverthefullpost-reformperiod(top

panel) isveryclosein (small)magnitudetothe

respec-tiveestimateforhipreplacements,onlyitislessprecise

reflectingthesmallersample.Aswithhipreplacements,

theestimatedeffectisnegativein2006.Thereafter, itis

positive,exceptfor2009.Overalltheyearsandforeach

year,theestimatedeffectisneverclosetosignificance.

Irre-spectiveofwhetherreadmissionrateafterhipreplacement

orafterkneereplacementisusedtoindicatequality,there

isnoevidencethatpricederegulationinamore

competi-tivemarketaffectedthequalityofcare.

6.3. Heterogeneity

WhiletheHHIthresholdof2500isbasedonUSantitrust

guidelines,itissomewhatarbitrary,andevenmoresoin

a European context. Further,a binaryclassification will

miss any variation in the response to the intensity of

competitivepressureinducedbypricederegulationacross

finerdegreesofmarketconcentration.Thenulleffectwe

findcouldpossiblyarisefromdifferentialresponsesatthe

extremesofthemarketconcentrationdistributionbeing

diluted by similar responses either side, but closer to,

the2500threshold.Totestforthis,wecategorize

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

In addition, we conducted four control treatments. First, we checked whether the strategy method used in the afore-mentioned treatment S EQ R AND induces different behavior than

The empirical analysis of Dutch quoted companies for the time period from 1979 to 1997 reveals that market-to-book values relate to future (abnormal) returns on equity over

Furthermore, the higher consumers perceive the Aldi as hedonic (high quality products, high prices, high service level, large assortment) the less a consumer wants to pay a

and 2005, and estimate the effect of banking market concentration on financial stability by using consolidated Z-scores as a measure of financial soundness at the country level..

Twente scoort in 2010 boven het Nederlands gemiddelde, maar heeft een lager innovatievermogen dan de regio’s Zuidoost-Noord-Brabant en

Cumulative abnormal returns show a very small significant reversal (significant at the 10 per cent level) for the AMS Total Share sample of 0.6 per cent for the post event

In the vast majority of patient groups there is an additional rise in turnover after the merger compared to the development of turnover in the control group of non-merged

Notes: BRENT(-1): One month lagged change in Brent oil price, WORLD: Excess return on MSCI world index, INFL: Change in IMF world Consumer Price Index, EXR: Monthly change in