• No results found

Regional integration and the power of international parliamentary institutions: A comparative analysis of the EALA, Parlasur and UEMOA Parliament

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Regional integration and the power of international parliamentary institutions: A comparative analysis of the EALA, Parlasur and UEMOA Parliament"

Copied!
36
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

Regional Integration and the Power of International Parliamentary Institutions

A comparative analysis of the EALA, Parlasur and UEMOA Parliament.

Student Mattijn Kroos

Studentnumber 1390619

Supervisor Dr. T.P. Louwerse Word count 8.336 (text-only)

(2)
(3)

Abstract

This thesis explores explanations for the weak relation between regional integration and power of international parliamentary institutions. There is an assumed causal relationship between regional integration as an independent variable, and parliamentary power as a dependent variable. However, quantitative research has shown that this relation is weak. As there are clear expectations for such a relationship, why, then, is this relationship weak? A comparative case study is done for the UEMOA Parliament, EALA and the Parlasur. These cases are analyzed on the areas of linkage between national and international parliamentary assemblies; the mandate of the IPI; the involvement of grassroots support; and executive dominance. The relationship between regional integration and parliamentary powers is weak because of a dominating intergouvernmentalist attitude of the member states.

Introduction

Many scholars connect integration to parliamentary powers: political and economic integration led to the powerful European Parliament (Malamud & Sousa, 2007), integration increased when the European Economic Community was founded (Moravcsik, 2005) and integration and regional governance rise along the establishment of parliamentary organs (Bechle & Rüland, 2014). Integration leads towards supranational governance. Moreover, vertical accountability is an upcoming issue with regard to supranational governance. Parliaments are then the organs needed for representation and transparency (Habegger, 2006; Marschall, 2007). Democratic legitimacy is therefore considered as a reasonable explanation for the relationship between parliaments and integration (Habegger, 2010; Nzewi, 2014; Malamud & Sousa, 2007). However, quantitative research by Papenborg (2016) has shown that this relationship is weak. Some strongly integrated international governmental organizations do not have such strong parliamentary assemblies. Examples are the Parlandino, the Benelux Council and the OECS Assembly.

This thesis examines the East African Legislative Assembly (EALA), the West African Economic and Monetary Union (UEMOA in French) and Parlasur (Parliament of Mercosur). These parliaments have similar levels of parliamentary powers but different levels of integration, which makes them an excellent example when exploring the weak relationship between regional integration and parliamentary powers. The research question for this thesis will be:


(4)

Why does integration not impact parliamentary powers?

Explanations for this weak relationship can possibly be found in different paths towards parliamentary development or the level of executive dominance. To analyse the different paths towards parliamentary powers, the process of integration and the development of parliamentary powers over time is studied to recognize the working mechanisms in these parliaments (Malamud & Sousa, 2007).
 Next to path dependency, executive dominance is viewed as a possible explanation for the weak relationship. Executive dominance is based on the idea that international organizations that predominantly have members with parliamentary regimes are different from international organizations that predominantly have members with presidential regimes. It is considered to be unlikely that members with presidential regimes are very supportive to the parliaments of the international organization (Malamud, 2005).

This discrepancy between broadly shared expectations and actual results offers an interesting case for research. Also Cofelice and Stavridis (2014, p. 160) argue that “it would be particularly interesting to explore whether the conditions that led to the development of EP’s (European Parliament) powers are actually working in other contexts, or whether totally different processes are underway” and comparative studies in this field would “allow to test the accuracy and validity of theoretical approaches aiming to explain the puzzle of IPIs’ establishment and empowerment – approaches that so far have been mainly based on the analysis of the EP case’’ (Cofelice & Stavridis, 2014, p. 160). Thereafter, there is need for a better understanding of parliamentary power with regard to vertical accountability. Vertical accountability will decrease the democratic deficit (Habegger, 2006). Parliamentary assemblies are considered as an accepted way to legitimate authority of transnational governance (Marschall, 2007), which hint towards the importance of parliamentary powers.

The weak relationship between regional integration and the power of international parliamentary institutions can be explained by the intergouvernmentalist approach of the member states. The member states of the three studied IPIs are primarily concerned with their national interests. In all of the three cases, member states seem to be primarily concerned with their national 


(5)

interests, just as we observe a relative similar, but limited level of parliamentary power. 


Theory and concepts

Various scholars (Cutler, 2006; Sabic, 2008) have offered definitions for international parliamentary institutions (IPI). In Cutler’s words “may an IPI be defined as an international institution that is a regular forum for multilateral deliberations on an established basis of an either legislative or consultative nature, either attached to an international organization or itself constituting one, in which at least three states or transgovernmental actors are represented by parliamentarians, who are either selected by national legislatures in a self-determined manner or popularly elected by electorates of the member states’’ (Cutler, 2006, p. 83). Sabic (2008) makes a distinction between international parliamentary organs (IPO) and international parliamentary associations (IPA). The difference is that an IPO is a formal organ of an international governmental organization (IGO) and consists of parliamentarians. In contrast, IPAs are ‘’irrespective of how they are constituted and to what extent the appointment reflects the political spectrum in home parliaments’’ (Sabic, 2008, p. 258). An example of an IPO is the European Parliament, which is a formal, institutional part of the European Union. An example of an IPA is the NATO Parliamentary Assembly (NATO PA). The NATO PA is an IPA as it is “institutionally separate from the NATO structure” (Cofelice & Stavridis, 2014, p. 151). Both IPOs, and IPAs are relevant for the study to IPIs, therefore no distinctions are made between in these two forms (Cofelice & Stavridis, 2014).

The main explanatory variable in this thesis is the level of integration between the member states of an international organization (IO). A distinction between two main forms of integration can be made; political and economic integration (Nello, 2002). The first, political integration, has been defined by Haas as follows: “Political integration is the process whereby political actors in several distinct national settings are persuaded to shift their loyalties, expectations and political activities toward a new center, whose institutions possess or demand jurisdiction over the pre-existing national states. The end result of a process of political integration is a new political community, superimposed over the pre-existing ones’’ (Haas, 1958, p.16). The second form of integration, economic integration, is defined as "measures designed to abolish discrimination between economic units belonging to 


(6)

different national states" (Balassa, 2011, p.1). Balassa also identifies five different stages of integration; from a Free Trade Area to complete economic integration with a supra-national authority. These stages of integration are seen as an sequential process, but this does not necessarily have to be so (Sapir, 2011).

The main dependent variable in this thesis is the level of parliamentary power. In the work of Cofelice and Stavridis (2014), parliamentary power is built upon five different parliamentary functions which are consultative, oversight, appointment, budgetary, and legislative powers. The actual operationalization of these functions will be discussed later. Every IPI has consultative powers, while appointment and legislative powers are often lacking. Parliamentary powers can also be seen as institutional authority (Rocabert et al, 2014).

Now we will take a look at the dominant integration theories. An important theory on integration is developed by Haas. “Haas sought to develop a theory that explained why, once an initial commitment was made, forward momentum of integration was inevitable” (Moravcsik, 2005, p. 350). Therefore he developed the theory of functionalism (Moravcsik, 2005). According to neo-functionalism, integration takes place via spillover. Spillover is the ongoing process of cooperation, from one sector into another. This process is no coordinated process, but merely a result of unintended developments. Several different kind of spillover can be identified. First, we distinguish functional spillover. Functional spillover is based on enhancing cooperation to realize a certain objective. Political spillover is the furthering cooperation to related policy areas. Cultivated spillover is “upgrading the common interest’’ (Van der Vleuten, 2015, p. 231). Fourth, we can identify geographical spillover. Geographical spillover is expansion of cooperation by attracting new member states (Van der Vleuten, 2015).

However neo-functionalism is considered to be an approach which deserves to be taken seriously, it is not free from criticism. Empirical results do not always fit neo-functionalist expectations. European cooperation has not always been the smooth process as neo-functionalist suppose, but a mere stop-and-go process. Functional spillover and geographical spillover are also less commonly observed than functionalists would expect (Van der Vleuten, 2015). The theory of neo-functionalism is strongly connected to the case of the European Union. However the theory is not

(7)

designed to specifically explain European integration, it is questionable whether it is applicable to other cases of regional integration (Cini & Borragán, 2013).

The realist counterpart of neofunctionalism is intergouvernmentalism. Just like supranationalism, intergouvernmentalism as described here is not used as a term to describe the distribution of powers between national governments but as an approach to integration. According to intergouvernmentalism, states are the central actors in decision-making and explains that agreements only take place by convergence of national interests. States will only cooperate on issues of low politics, as high politics impair national sovereignty too much. Low politics are less sensitive issues on which states are willing to cooperate and to shift decision-making to a higher, supranational level. High politics are concerned with vital interests to which states protect their sovereignty (Van der Vleuten, 2015). Critics of intergouvernmentalism argue that this approach does not acknowledge the possible movement of interests during negotiations. Thereafter, negotiations are often a showdown of force in which less powerful states cannot always defend their national interests (Van der Vleuten, 2015).

Integration needs institutionalization to facilitate further cooperation. Malamud and Sousa (2007) argue that the European Parliament has become such a powerful parliament because of the high extent of political and economic integration. Regional integration increased at the moment that the European Economic Community was founded (Moravcsik, 2005). Nzewi (2014) argues too that “integration implies community-building’’ (Nzewi, 2014, p. 492). Furthermore, Bechle and Rüland (2014) state that the establishment of parliamentary organs often goes along with developing levels of integration and regional governance. This reaction on integration might be the result of increasing national and international pressures (Bechle & Rüland, 2014). More often, explanations are found in a need for democratic legitimacy (Habegger, 2010; Nzewi, 2014; Malamud & Sousa, 2007). Higher levels of integration often go along decision-making at supranational levels. Then the question arises how such a vertical accountability can be guaranteed (Habegger, 2010). Parliamentarism is viewed “as a widespread accepted way to legitimize political constitutions“ (Marschall, 2007, p.5).

(8)

In defiance to this, research of Papenborg (2016) has shown that the assumed link between regional integration and parliamentary powers lacks empirical evidence. Powers of IPIs and levels of regional integration show a positive, but weak relationship. How could this possibly be?

Malamud and Sousa (2007) offer several explanations. The European integration process is widely seen as an example and the outcome of this process is admired by other regional organizations. But the process tend to be overlooked and phases are sometimes skipped. Path dependency, thus, might be a possible explanation. Path dependency is the notion that history matters and that history influences the path to the future (Mahoney, 2000). The idea of path dependency is based in the study of historical institutionalism. Hall and Taylor (1996) argue that path dependency rejects the view that the same operative forces will lead to the same results, due to different contexts. “Contextual features are often inherited from the past” (Hall & Taylor, 1996, p. 6). State capacities and policy legacies do influence policy choices in a nation’s response (Hall & Taylor, 1996).

Next, executive dominance can be viewed as a likely explanation. Executive dominance is the extent to which the executive power dominates the legislative power. International organizations that predominantly have members with parliamentary regimes are different from international organizations that predominantly have members with presidential regimes. Presidential regimes emphasize the executive power and will therefore prefer intergovernmental structures. Parliamentary regimes emphasize the legislative power and will therefore support international parliaments. If the level of executive dominance is high on a national level, it is likely that there is comparable level of executive dominance on an international level (Malamud, 2005). Parliamentary of presidential regimes do influence the integration process (Malamud & Sousa, 2007), knowledge on this issue therefore is very interesting for this study. However, it is important to know that this mechanism is not always the case. For example, the United States have a relative powerful parliament while being part of a presidential regime. Moreover, despite the parliamentary regime of the United Kingdom, the British parliament is still dominated by the executive power and therefore have a high level of executive dominance (Erk et al, 2013).

(9)

Another more intergouvernmentalist explanation is integration merely takes place by convergence of interests of national states and the importance and competences of parliamentary assemblies thus are of relative minor importance (Moravcsik, 2005).

Case selection

The case selection is based upon a quantitative data analysis. The method of case selection is provided by Gerring and Seawright (2008). This “diverse case selection strategy has as its primary objective the achievement of maximum variance along relevant dimensions (Gerring & Seawright, 2008, p. 300). The relevant dimension in this study is the explanatory variable of integration. This method is used to explore explanatory relationships. In this study, we work with three independent variables which all lead towards the same dependent variable, which is a comparable level of parliamentary power. As the three independent variables cover a major range of all possible values, the representativeness is considerably high (Gerring & Seawright, 2008).

This case selection based upon three data indexes. These indexes are economic integration, political integration, and parliamentary power, of which the latter is the dependent variable. The population of IPIs is determined by Cofelice and Stavridis (2014) and Cofelice (2015). These two sources are quite similar but complement each other (Papenborg, 2016).

The economic integration is defined by the Integration Achievement Score (IAS). This index is originally created by Huffbauer and Scott (1994), which Feng and Genna have further developed (2003). Feng and Genna have made this economic integration index for regional organizations. The index is composed by six different categories: “trade in goods and services; the degree of capital mobility; the degree of labour mobility; the level of supranational institutional importance in decision-making; the level of monetary policy coordination; and the level of fiscal policy coordination. Each category has a value of 0 to 5 along a Guttman scale with higher values translating to higher levels in each category” (Feng & Genna, 2003, p. 287). The final IAS is an average of the scores of these six categories.

(10)

The political integration is measured by three different indicators. These indicators are the degree of supranationality, the locus of activity and supranational institutional importance. The relative importance of these indicators is measured by a principal component analysis (Papenborg, 2016, p. 6). The used index for this case selection originates from Papenborg's study either (2016).

Cofelice and Stavridis (2014) have measured parliamentary powers over five different parliamentary functions. These functions are consultation, oversight, appointment, budgetary, and legislation. Each of these functions is given a score from zero to five powers, respectively indicating no power to very powerful. Via these scores is a weighted average calculated which indicate the Parliamentary Power Index (PPI). It is a weighted average because not all parliamentary functions have a common importance; consultative power cannot be, by definition, supranational or legislative, whereas the other parliamentary functions can. Appendix A shows on which parliamentary competencies the PPI is decided.

The PPI is based on scores of 2016, while scores on political and economic integration depend on statistics of 2012. This difference is theoretically explainable. According to Malamud and Sousa (2007 in Papenborg, 2016) change international structures gradually. There is a time lag between the increased level of integration and the level of parliamentary power. Additionally, taking consistency and reliability into account, there was a lot of data available for the year 2012 (Papenborg, 2012).

(11)

The case selection consists of the Parlasur, the EALA, and the UEMOA Parliament. The sample varies on the extent of integration, which is the explanatory variable, and is rather similar on the dependent variable, which is parliamentary power (See graph 1). The complete range on the cumulative integration varies from 0.87 to 7.8 of which the least integrated IO is the UMA Council and the most 1 integrated IO is the European Union. The sample varies between 3.20 and 5.67 and therefore represents a major part of the complete range.

The complete range on parliamentary power varies from 0.07 to 0.89 of which the European Parliament has the highest score. Six parliaments score 0.07 in the parliamentary power index. The sample varies slightly between 0.33 and 0.38 on parliamentary power. See Appendix B for more information. More parliaments had a parliamentary power score in the range of the sample but are not included in this study due to methodological considerations. Literature or data were missing in these cases; this would decline the reliability of this study.

The Treaty of Ascunsión established the Mercosur in 1991. The Mercosur was created as an entirely intergovernmental system. Current member states are the Argentine Republic, the Federative Republic of Brazil, the Republic of Paraguay, the Oriental Republic of Uruguay and the Bolivarian Republic of Venezuela. The Treaty of Ascunsión also established the Joint Parliamentary Committee of which the Parlasur became the successor. The Parlasur was the result of demands among the members for a formal organ to trigger integration. The Parlasur was inaugurated in 2006 and the working session started in 2007 (Parlasur, 2015).

The East African Legislative Assembly (EALA) is established by the Treaty for the Establishment of the East African Community (EAC) in 1999, which came into force in 2000. The first member states were the Republic of Uganda, the Republic of Kenya and the United Republic of Tanzania. In 2007, the Republic of Burundi and the Republic of Rwanda also also joined the EAC. According to Article 49 of the Treaty, the EALA is the legislative organ of the EAC. It is the mission of the Assembly to legislate, to oversight, to represent, and to foster integration (EALA, n.d.).

The cumulative integration score is the sum of the economic and political integration score. This 1

index is made to index both integration levels of IPOs on which the case selection is determined. Economic and political integration are checked on high differences, but were absent.

(12)

The UEMOA is the West African Economic and Monetarian Union (UEMOA in French) and is established in 1994. The UEMOA is based on its predecessor, the UMOA (Unité Monetaire Ouest Afrique). In 1994, seven states became member of the UEMOA (Worldbank, 2015). These countries were Benin, Burkina Faso, Mali, Niger, Senegal and Togo. Guineau-Bissau joined the UEMOA in 1997. The countries in the UEMOA use the same currency, which is the CFA Franc. The CFA France is at fixed-rate to the euro. The main objectives of the UEMOA are to intensify the competitiveness and financial activities of the region, to develop an open market, and to harmonize national legislation. In 2003, UEMOA Parliament succeeded the UEMOA Inter-Parliamentary Committee (UEMOA, 2003). The UEMOA Parliament is a formal part of the UEMOA structure and therefore considered to be an IPO.

Research methods

A comparative case study is done for the Parlasur, EALA, and the UEMOA. The research design is inspired on meta-ethnography. Meta-ethnography offers an excellent method to discover ‘what works’ and is considered to be highly replicable and transparent (Bryman, 2012; Tranfield et al, 2003). The actual meta-ethnography framework cannot be applied to this thesis because of the use of primary literature in this thesis. However, the process inspires the research method used in this study. An interpretive approach is a dominant feature of meta-ethnography (Noblit & Hare, 1988).

In the process of meta-ethnography, we can identify several phases. As this study is not an exact form of meta-ethnography, the phases have been adjusted modestly. This study is executed in four phases. The first phase concerns the research question and the theoretical framework. The second phase is about deciding which sources are credible and the intensive reading of these sources. The third phase is about determining the relevant fields in order to secure the structure of the research results. In the fourth phase, the various IPIs are compare. These phases are interconnected and do overlap (Bryman, 2012).

Used sources are a combination of primary and secondary literature. The primary literature consists of treaties and official documents of the different institutions and parliaments. The EALA and EAC are the only IPI and institution of which the documents and treaties were written in English. Documents and treaties of the UEMOA and its parliament were written in French, but could be well

(13)

translated to English with Google Translate. When doubts on translations occurred, language experts 2 were consulted. Documents and treaties of the Parlasur and Mercosur are written in Spanish, except for some official documents. These sources were also well translatable into English with Google Translate and when needed, language experts were consulted.

Secondary literature was found with Google Scholar and the Leiden Catalogue. Only one source came from the Africa Study Centre in Leiden (Adar, 2008). Literature on the EALA, UEMOA parliament and Parlasur is found by searching on the organization’s name the parliament belongs to (respectively EAC, UEMOA and Mercosur) or by searching on the names of the parliaments themselves. These names were searched in combination with the terms: institutional development, political development and (regional) integration. The resulting articles of which these searches led to, are subsequently used to find new connecting articles by using snowball sampling. For the EALA, Lumallas provides a comprehensive in-depth analysis of the EALA from which snowball sampling takes place for the case of EALA. Lumallas acquired his information from “academic papers, journals, books, annual reports of EALA and information from persons affiliated with the Assembly” (Lumallas, 2011, p. 5). Secondary literature is used to provide contexts for the treaties.

For each case, a literature analysis is done. First, the development over time will be described for each case. These developments will then be explained by four categories. These categories have come forward during the reading of the literature; the main arguments tend to fall in four categories. These categories are: the link between national and international PAs; the mandate of the IPI; the involvement of grassroots support; diverging national political systems. When these categories are discussed, a short conclusion per IPI will follow. In this conclusion, the understood relation between regional integration and parliamentary power is key. 


The first category of this analysis is the link between national and international PAs and describes the interconnectedness of the two levels of policy. Do members of the IPI also have a seat in the national parliament, or are they separated? The second category is the mandate of the IPI. This focuses merely on the shifting of sovereignty from the national level to the international level. Themes within this category are intergouvernmentalism; supranationalism; sovereignty; diverging/converging interests. The third category is the level of grassroots support affected with the IPI. This category

Native speakers.

(14)

covers elections; civil society movements; connectedness with citizens of the region. The fourth category is the level of executive dominance. This is the extent to which the parliament is dominated by the executive power. This dominance can manifest in various ways. First, national structures of decision-making will likely influence the international structures of decision-making. If presidential regimes are predominant on a national level, than it is unlikely that the parliament dominates the international level of decision-making in the IO. Second, executive dominance might also manifest itself in the IO itself when there are considerably low parliamentary powers.

Results

Parlasur

The purpose of the Parlasur is, according to the Protocolo Constitutivo del Parliamento Del Mercosur, to “ensure participation of civil society actors in the integration process” (Art. 1.4) and to “contribute to consolidating integration through deepening and expansion” (Art. 1.6). Parlasur shows the lowest score on integration of the sample in this study (Appendix B). Studied literature endorses this low level of integration. Integration did increase over time, especially due to the enactment of direct elections. Parliamentary powers have risen significantly with the establishment of the Parlasur, as the successor of the joint parliamentary committee of the Mercosur. Since then, no developments took place (Cofelice & Stavridis, 2014).

The first argument is based on the link between national and international parliamentary assemblies. Members of the Parlasur have no function in the national assembly, as this is considered to be incompatible (Parlasur, 2005). The Mercosur parliamentarians organize themselves in political parties “according to ideological affinity rather than nationality” (Malamud & Dri, 2013, p. 228). Members of the Parlasur are directly chosen by the Mercosur citizens (Parlasur, 2005). 


A Parlasur member can be seen as a two-faced official. On the one hand, the official is tied to national linkages and its own government. On the other hand, officials are appointed by the political parties and they quickly adapt themselves to the regional parliament by creating connections with ideologically affiliated parliamentarians (Malamud & Dri, 2013). This policy offers both an advantage and a disadvantage. Beneficial is the likelihood for spillover. Detrimental, however, is that this double

(15)

function is considered to be a contributing factor for the low legislative output by members of Parlasur. Especially in a recently established parliament as the Parlasur, a high level of engagement is a necessary condition (Lucci, 2013). 


The double position seems to hold down the level of engagement towards the international assembly and therefore restraints the actual parliamentary powers, considering the low legislative production.

Secondly, we focus on the mandate of the Parlasur. The parliamentary powers increased significantly after the constitution of the Parlasur in 2005 (Cofelice & Stavridis, 2014). The preceding joint parliamentary committee existed and only had some consultative powers (Cofelice & Stavridis, 2014; Parlasur, 2005). 


Since 2005, there have been no increases in parliamentary powers. Dri (2010) tries to explain this by pointing out a different aim. He argues that the objective of the Parlasur was not directly related to a democratic concern, but to include national parliaments formally in negotiations to facilitate later ratification of treaties (Dri, 2010 in Medeiros et al, 2016). The actual Parlasur activities are also considered as not being very influential. Although the consultative powers are relatively high (Cofelice & Stavridis, 2014), the Parlasur has not given any opinions, has proposed almost no bills and has not produced any human rights reports which the Parlasur ought to do (Malamud & Dri, 2013; Lucci, 2013; Parlasur, 2005). 


This low level of parliamentary activity is possibly an outcome of a region-wide intergovernmental preference. The Parlasur member states are characterized by a deeply rooted intergovernmental nature (Ledo, 2015; Malamud & Dri, 2013). Mercosur states fear supranationalism, according to a Brazilian Ministry of Foreign Affairs official (Malamud & Dri, 2013). Mercosur elites advocate for regionalism, except when it costs them sovereignty. Another important factor impairing integration is more structural and a result of demographic asymmetry. Brazil covers around eighty percent of the Mercosur population, accordingly more than half of seats in the Parlasur should be distributed to Brazil. Obviously, this is a triggering situation but assigning less than fifty percent of the seats would be undemocratic (Malamud & Dri, 2013). Criticism on the Mercosur and Parlasur is frequently heard, for example in Uruguay. Former President Lacalle argued that Parlasur disadvantaged Uruguay on the aspect of economic integration and therefore called for a withdrawal

(16)

from the Parlasur. President Lacalle also stated that the Parlasur was also responsible for high costs for the member states (Lucci, 2013). 


Considering the critiques of President Lacalle, regional economic integration has declined since 2005. The Parlasur member states are not willing to transfer sovereignty to higher levels of decision-making which impairs development on integration and on parliamentary powers. This unwillingness might be strengthened due to the asymmetries among the Parlasur member states.

Thirdly, we observe the involvement of grassroots support. Mercosur is willing to “increasingly close the ties between their peoples” (Mercosur, 1991, p. 1), and the Parlasur, as well as the Mercosur, wants to harmonize legislation and ensure participation of civil society in the integration process (Mercosur, 1991; Parlasur, 2005). 


With the establishment of the Parlasur, no grassroots movements were involved. Only national officials and policy experts were associated with the creation of Parlasur (Grugel, 2007 in Malamud & Dri, 2013). When the Parlasur was eventually established, civil society and social movements had no interests in Mercosur decision-making as it was of such little relevance that it discouraged participation (Hochstetler, 2007 in Malamud & Dri, 2013). 


To establish a sustainable organ, the development is divided into two transition periods (Parlasur, 2005; Parlasur 2015). In 2011 was the start of the second transition period of the Parlasur. This period is characterized by the direct elections which are being implemented since 2015. This election takes place on Mercosur Citizen Day via universal suffrage. In this way, the Mercosur citizens are represented in the Parlasur (Mercosur, 2009; Parlasur, 2015). Actual progress on the implementation of these direct elections differs (Lucci, 2013). 


Engagement among the Mercosur population has risen over time. In the beginning, citizens were not involved in their actual representation. But with the second transition period, direct elections were held on the Mercosur Citizen Day. Unfortunately, social movements have had no role in this process.

Fourthly, we consider the level of executive dominance. All of the Mercosur member states are led by presidential regimes (CIA, 2013). This creates a high level of national executive dominance. On the international level, the executive dominance can also be considered as quite high. Because the Parlasur has no actual making powers, the Council is the only organ responsible for

(17)

decision-making. Therefore, the Parlasur has very limited capabilities to influence decision-making in the Mercosur (Gorenman, 2007). The Parlasur “comprises an entirely intergovernmental system (Parlasur, 2005).

Although integration is considered to be relative low among the Mercosur member states, we do observe a slight increase of integration over time through the implementation of direct elections on Mercosur Citizen Day. Since the establishment, no social movements were involved in the Parlasur’s creation nor in its consultation. 


Parliamentary powers have risen strongly since the establishment of the Parlasur, as the successor of the Mercosur Joint Parliamentary Committee. However, the parliament still lacks any decision-making powers which results in high executive dominance. Since the creation of the Parlasur, the parliament have neither used, nor increased its powers. According to Dri (2010), this is because the parliament is merely used as an instrument to facilitate later treaty negotiations. As the dominant feature is of no democratic concern, there is no incentive to increase the parliamentary powers. 
 Overall, parliamentary development is limited because the member states mainly concerned with their national interests. The focus on national interests also limits integration.

EALA

The EALA is the middle case of the sample considering its level of integration. The EALA scores 3.87 on the integration index, which is the independent variable. The level of integration has risen over time. This is foremost a result of the East African Community Legislative Assembly Elections Act of 2011 which unified the elections dates for representatives for the EALA (EALA, 2011; Lumallas, 2013). The parliamentary powers, being the dependent variable, stayed the same over time (Cofelice & Stavridis, 2014).

The first argument is based on the link between the national and international assemblies. The Members of the Regional Assembly (MRA) are elected by the national assembly. Members of the EALA cannot be members of their national parliaments, according to Art. 51 of the EAC Treaty. This consequently means that MRA are not bound to national elections and can, therefore, fulfill their function in the EALA for the complete term of five years, regardless of the result of national elections

(18)

(EAC, 2002). 


This policy can be viewed in two perspectives. On the one hand, this policy enhances the continuity of the EALA policies. Changing domestic policies and preferences do not directly change preferences of the EALA, as well as changes in the composition of the national parliament, due to national elections, do not directly change the MRA. It is also argued that as a result, MRA focus more on the regional mandate if these parliamentarians are not bound to national parties (Lumallas, 2013). However, this disconnection might also be seen as counterproductive to EALA’s interests. Such a disconnection limits the available instruments to translate regional policy into national policy (Terlinden, 2004; Lumallas, 2013). Integration might have risen over time due to the intense cooperation in the EALA. But this intense cooperation is a result of a disconnection between the national and international parliament. The integration has thus only taken place on the international level. The disconnection does not constrain the formal parliamentary powers but does constrain the actual parliamentary power.

Secondly, we focus on the mandate of the EALA. Considering that the EALA is by definition the legislative organ of the EAC, it is remarkable that the EALA has a very small legislative mandate. According to Cofelice and Stavridis (2014), the Assembly scores two out of five on legislative powers. However, these power of the EALA can easily be overruled by the Summit and the Council (Adar, 2008; Cofelice & Stavridis, 2014). According to Art. 63 of the EAC Treaty, if a head of state withholds assent, the bill will lapse (EAC, 2002). This makes the autonomy and exclusiveness practically useless (Adar, 2008; Lumallas, 2013). “It therefore is not very surprising that the five pieces of legislation enacted by the EALA do not seem terribly influential in the overall regional integration process” (Terlinden, 2004, p. 8). 


Next, when a bill does make it to the national assemblies, there is no actual follow-up mechanism which leads to the implementation of decisions and policies in the member states. When a member state does not implement decisions from the EAC or EALA, there are no sanctions to impose on the neglecting member state (interview Gervase Akhaabi in Lumallas, 2013). 


This limited mandate might be the result of economic and political tensions between member states. There is an ongoing dispute between Kenya and Uganda. Also, Rwanda and Burundi are in different phases of economic development (Adar, 2008; Lumallas, 2013). Diverging economic

(19)

progress and strifes between nation-states complicate regional integration. 


In the 2010 - 2012 strategic plan, the EALA declared the need to review its mandate to ensure meaningful integration (EALA, 2010). According to the 2013 - 2018 strategic plan “It [the Assembly] developed and implemented EALA’s first Strategic Plan (2010 - 2012)” (EALA, 2013). Unfortunately, no evidence or support for this claim can be found.

Thirdly, we observe the involvement of grassroots support. The EAC and EALA argue to be people-centered (EAC, 2002; EALA, 2010; EALA, 2013) as grassroots support is “crucial for the success of the regional integration process” (Lumallas, 2013, p. 70). However, “the EAC integration process is largely political elite-driven and the people of East African are not directly linked to the integration process” as there are no elections which would legitimize the parliamentarians in their function (Adar, 2008, p. 91). The absence of direct elections is explained by logistic and financial issues, according to former Kenyan Assembly Speaker Kenneth Marende (Lumallas, 2013). To improve this minor link with the EAC citizens, bus tours with EALA representatives have been organized to bring the assembly to the people (Adar, 2008; EALA, 2010). According to Lumallas (2013), these tours provide no replacement for direct elections, as elections are one of the core principles of liberal democracy. Furthermore, the assembly is often criticized on the conduct of its mandate as it stays away from providing advice in matters concerning the dispute between Uganda and Kenya or other matters concerning the EAC citizens’ interests (Lumallas, 2013). 


However, the EALA has been working on harmonization of the national election procedures. These procedures varied per nation but the East African Community Legislative Assembly Elections Act has united these procedures. This bill passed in 2011 and is considered to be a big step on the issue of integration (EALA, 2011; Lumallas, 2013). The election date of the EALA representatives has been harmonized among the member states. Still, the national assemblies continue to make the rules for the election procedure of EALA members and direct elections remain to be absent (EALA, 2011).

Fourthly, we consider the level of executive dominance. The EAC member states are all led by presidential regimes (CIA, 2013). This results in a high executive dominance on the national level. On the international level, the extent of this executive dominance is also considerably high. The few legislative powers of the Assembly are easily overruled by a single head of state (Adar, 2008: Cofelice & Stavridis, 2014; Lumallas, 2013).

(20)

The EALA shows no clear relationship between regional integration and parliamentary powers. As already mentioned in the introduction of this case, integration has risen due to the Elections Act of 2011. Parliamentary powers did not change (Cofelice & Stavridis, 2014) 
 This absent relationship can be explained by the disconnection of the EALA elite with the citizens of the EAC and by the high level of executive dominance. The members of the EALA cooperate closely which might intensify integration through spillover. But through disconnection between the national assembly and the EALA and the missing mechanism to implement EAC policy, possible integration does not gain a foothold as there is no strong top-down policy process. EAC integration remains to be an EALA project, while the member states need to be become involved.
 Next, the EAC is characterized by a very high level of executive dominance. The national assemblies, as well as the EALA, are dominated by the executive powers which likely causes a preference for intergovernmental structures.

UEMOA Parliament

The UEMOA has the highest score on the integration index of the sample. The UEMOA scores 5.67 on the level of integration; the independent variable (Appendix B). Based on the literature on the UEMOA, integration has risen over time. Before the UEMOA Parliament, the UEMOA IPC existed and only had consultative and appointment powers. Parliamentary powers increased strongly with the establishment of the UEMOA Parliament. Since then, no developments concerning parliamentary powers took place (Cofelice & Stavridis, 2014).

The first argument is, again, settled on the link between national and international parliamentary assemblies. The precursor of the UEMOA Parliament was the ‘international parliamentary committee’ (IPC). The members of the IPC were representatives of their national interests and did not directly serve the common interests of the UEMOA (Grimm, 1999). Also, according to Claeys and Sindzingre (2003), national governments focus foremost on national interests in the UEMOA. This focus on the parliamentarian’s member state changed with the Treaty of the UEMOA Parliament. Art. 6 states that “the members of the UEMOA Parliament do exercise their

(21)

mandate independently and cannot be bound by instructions from any member state (UEMOA, 2003). This shift of dominant focus can be observed as an increase of integration.

Secondly, we focus on the mandate of the UEMOA Parliament. Before the Treaty of the UEMOA parliament, the Interparliamentary Committee was only “advisory and animating - it was thus a body without power” (Grimm, 1999, p. 17; Cofelice & Stavridis, 2014). 


The current UEMOA parliament is held responsible for the democratic control and participates in the decision-making, according to Article 14 of the Treaty of the UEMOA parliament (UEMOA, 2003: 1). However, this participation in the decision-making is of minor extent. The parliament is permitted to pronounce its views on discussed issues, according to Article 26 (UEMOA, 2003: 1). 


Change after the Treaty Modifying the UEMOA can be summarized as the increase of mandatory consults to the parliament by the Commission (UEMOA, 2003: 2). Interesting is the parliamentary competence to submit a motion of censure against the Commission, after which the Commission can be discharged from its function (UEMOA, 2003: 1). 


The small mandate might be the consequence of diverging economic performances. The economies are not complementary and only Ivory Coast seems to benefit from the external tariff. This strengthens the different development of UEMOA member states even more (Kireyev, 2016). Also Nigeria and the ECOWAS influence the UEMOA negatively on politics and economy. These regional imbalances are furthermore bolstered by the landlockedness of certain states which hampers trade (Claeys & Sindzingre, 2003).

Thirdly, we observe the involvement of grassroots support. In the Traite Portant Creation du Parliament de l’UEMOA is “reaffirmed that the parliament will give new impetus to the process of integration by greater participation” (UEMOA, 2003: 1, p. 1). But according to Article 31, each national legislative assembly appoints five members of the UEMOA parliament and citizen participation is neglected (UEMOA, 2003: 1). Next to this, no literature on the participation or inclusion of civil society is found. The level of integration is considered to be very low and development over time did not take place.

The fourth and last argument is on the level of executive dominance. In the UEMOA are four out of seven member states run by presidential regimes. Guinea-Bissau, Mali, and Niger are run by

(22)

semi-presidential regimes (CIA, 2013). The level of executive dominance is therefore considered to be relatively high for most of the member states. The UEMOA Parliament does not have a significant amount of supranational powers (Cofelice & Stavridis, 2014). Therefore, the executive dominance can be considered as high. But this executive dominance is limited due to the parliament’s right to submit a motion of censure against the Commission. When such a motion is submitted, the Commission can be discharged (UEMOA, 2003: 1). With this competence, the UEMOA Parliament has a strong control function.

Integration as well as parliamentary powers has risen over time in the UEMOA. During the UEMOA IPC, the member states focused foremost on their national interests and the IPC did not have a strong mandate. 


The establishment of the UEMOA Parliament in 2003 led to a significant rise of parliamentary powers. The level of executive dominance also decreased by the parliament’s power to submit a motion of censure against the UEMOA Commission after which the Commission can be discharged. Next to the executive dominance, the members of the UEMOA Parliament were not bound to instructions of the member states which increased loyalties to the collective interest. 


Since the establishment of the UEMOA Parliament, no increases of parliamentary powers have been observed. This might be the consequence of differences between the member states in economic strength and economic development. These differences result from landlockedness of some member states in the Sahelian zone (World Bank), which limits trade opportunities. Next to the argument on landlockedness, does the common external tariff only benefit the further developed states such as Ivory Coast and Senegal. This even enlarges the gap between the lowest and highest developed member states. As a result, member states focus more on their national interests, which hinder integration (Lumallas, 2011). 


As a reaction to this, the UEMOA has set up convergence criteria for monetary integration for debts, deficits and price stability (Claeys & Sindzingre, 2003). This convergence is supported by flexible adhesion. Member states can operate in the field of their own interest while still be deepening integration with the other member states (Gnassou, 1997 in Claeys & Sindzingre, 2003).

(23)

Discussion

The link between national and international assemblies has been discussed in detail. UEMOA parliamentarians, as well as EALA parliamentarians exercise their regional mandate considerably independent of the national assemblies. Even though this might enhance continuity of the regional policies, the disconnection between the national and regional assembly might also be counterproductive for the implementation of regional integration policies (Terlinden, 2004; Lumallas, 2013). As a result, actual parliamentary power of the international assembly decreases although this is not observable in formal parliamentary powers. 


Accordingly, Ruffing (2015) has written about the differences between formal and de facto autonomy within the framework of the principal-agent theory. He argues that “the correlation between formal and de facto autonomy is often disputed (Ruffing, 2015, p. 1114). 


A high level of national autonomy can have various consequences. First, the IPI is less able to observe changing national political context and its influence on the national assembly. Second, the IPI does not retrieve knowledge from its member states. These two arguments might result in information asymmetry. According to the principal-agent theory, a risk is connected to information asymmetry, which is called ‘bureaucratic drift’. In the case of a bureaucratic drift, the agent takes a different path than proposed by the principal (Bach & Ruffing, 2013; Ruffing, 2015). The agent in this scenario is the member state, while the IPI is the principal. The disconnectedness of the regional parliament to the member states might rise over time, which complicates integration and the transfer from regional policy to national policy. Therefore, I recommend limiting the disconnectedness between the national and international assemblies.

The EP is considered to be one of the largest examples of international parliaments. It is one of the oldest IPIs and currently has the highest level of parliamentary powers (Cofelice & Stavridis, 2014). Considering the development of the EP, the rise of parliamentary powers is an incremental process. The EP slowly accumulated various powers, but still does not have the powers like a national legislative assembly, as the Council and Commission remain to be the most powerful organs in the EU (Terlinden, 2004). 


This incremental process of development however, is hardly observable in the sample of this study. The Parlasur, EALA, and the UEMOA Parliament are all successors of parliaments with less

(24)

parliamentary powers. Possibly, their predecessors might have laid a foundation for a significant rise in powers of the newly-established parliaments. Since the establishment of the current IPIs however, no increases have taken place. There, one can question wether the establishment of a parliamentary organ is solely a formality for an IO in the international system.

One of the main tasks of parliaments is to represent the citizens’ preferences and to translate these into legislation (Hänggi, 2004). Representation increases democratic legitimacy (Habegger, 2010; Nzewi, 2014; Malamud & Sousa, 2007). Despite this, actual representation is hard to discover in the sample of this study. The Parlasur introduced direct elections with the second transition period and is therewith the only parliament which directly represents its citizens. Next to a lack of representation, the legislative powers of parliaments are also weak (Cofelice & Stavridis, 2014). This is remarkable, as all three parliaments discussed have considerably low legislative powers, even though legislation is one of their main tasks (Hänggi, 2004). Especially the ‘East African Legislative Assembly’ , which is called after its main task, does not live up to its name. This strengthens the previous remark whether a parliamentary organ is considered to be only formality for an IO.

Limitations in this research lie in its reliability and generalizability. The reliability of this thesis is limited by the available literature on this sample. International parliamentary assemblies have been regularly discussed in academic literature, but literature on specific IPIs is limited. If more literature would be available, further substantiated claims could be made. 


Furthermore, generalizability is limited due to the sample size. Generalizability however, is considered less relevant in qualitative research (Bryman, 2012). As a result of time limitations and available literature on specific IPIs, I was limited in my choice of data.

Conclusion

Referring to the introduction, the assumed relationship between regional integration and parliamentary powers is argued to be weak (Papenborg, 2016). This originally assumed relationship is based on the idea that “integration implies community-building’’, as summarized by Nzewi (2014, p. 492). Mercosur member states show a low level of integration; the East African Community shows a medium level of integration and the UEMOA member states show a high level of integration. Despite

(25)

this, the parliamentary powers of these respective IOs are quite similar. This case selection, therefore shows that IPIs can increase their powers indifferent of the level of integration. 


Answering the main question of this thesis ‘why regional integration does not impact parliamentary powers’, member states are dominantly concerned with their national interests. This intergouvernmentalist approach is observable in all three cases. The Mercosur member states can be characterized by their strong nationalist approach to regionalism, as they do not want to shift their sovereignty to supranational levels of bureaucracy. This might be the result of high asymmetries among the member states (Lucci, 2013). The intergouvernmentalist approach of the Mercosur member states is also noticeable among the EAC member states. This dominant concern with national interest is a result of tensions between EAC member states. Kenya and Uganda are in an ongoing conflict and Rwanda and Burundi experience different stages of economic development (Adar, 2008; Lumallas, 2011). The UEMOA development of parliamentary powers is also constrained by varying economic performances of members statees. These differences are caused by the common external tariff and landlocked states in the Sahelian region. Only Ivory Coast is profiting from the common external tariff, as the Ivory Coast is the most economically developed member state (Kireyev, 2016; Claeys & Sindzingre, 2003). 


Next to intergouvernmentalism, the level of executive dominance is also likely to influence the level of parliamentary powers. Most of the member states are governed by presidential regimes. Presidential regimes emphasize the executive power the national government and will consequentially focus on intergouvernmentalist structures. It is considered to be unlikely that the institutional design of an IGO would differ heavily from the architecture of the domestic regime (Malamud, 2005; Malamud & De Sousa, 2007). This domestic situation offers an interesting opportunity for future research.
 As deliberated in the discussion, one can argue that IPIs are formalities within the IO structure. After the establishment of the studied IPIs, no increases in parliamentary powers have taken place. Moreover, these IPIs have a very low levels of democratic legitimacy. The Parlasur is the only parliament that is directly elected by the Mercosur citizens. Considering these arguments, it is hard to compare the European Parliament with other IPIs. The European Parliament is, in contrast, directly elected and has experienced incremental increase of its powers. Perhaps, the European Parliament is sui generis. Addressing the democratic deficit seems to solely concern the European Union. Possibly,

(26)

international parliamentary institutions are only formalities for IOs, in order to become accepted in the international system.

(27)

Bibliography

Primary literature

East African Community (1999). The Treaty for the Establishment of the East African Community.
 Arusha: East African Community. Retrieved from http://www.eala.org/uploads/


The_Treaty_for_the_Establishment_of_the_East_Africa_Community_2006_1999.pdf East African Community (2001). Rules of procedure of the East African Legislative Assembly.
 Retrieved from http://www.eala.org/uploads/EALA_Rules_Final_document_


_26.02.2015_1.pdf

Mercosur (1991). The Treaty for the Establishment of the Mercosur. Retrieved from
 https://idatd.cepal.org/Normativas/MERCOSUR/Ingles/Treaty_of_Asuncion.pdf Mercosur (2004). Protocolo Constitutivo del Parlamento del Mercosur. Retrieved from
 https://archivos.juridicas.unam.mx/www/bjv/libros/5/2236/5.pdf

Mercosur (2009). Acuerdo Político Para la Consolidación del Mercosur y Proposiciones 
 Correspondientes. Retrieved from https://www.parlamentomercosur.org/innovaportal
 /file/7309/1/acuerdo_politico.pdf

Parlasur (2015). Factsheet. Requested from https://ghum.kuleuven.be/ggs/projects/paco/vipco-1/ 
 vipco-factsheet-southamerica.pdf

UEMOA (1994). Traité de l’Union Économique Et Monétaire Ouest Africaine. Requested from: 
 http://www.bceao.int/IMG/pdf/TraiteUMOA2010.pdf

UEMOA (2003). Traité portant création du Parlement de l’Union Économique Et Monétaire Ouest 
 Africaine. Requested from: http://www.uemoa.int/sites/default/files/bibliotheque/


traitparlement.pdf

UEMOA (2003). Traite modifie de l’Union Économique Et Monétaire Ouest Africaine. Requested 
 from: http://www.uemoa.int/fr/system/files/fichier_article/traitreviseuemoa.pdf

(28)

Secondary literature

Adar, K. G. (2008). Fast tracking East African political federation: the role and limitations of the East African legislative assembly. Africa Insight, 37(4), 76-97. (Not online available,
 retrieved from Africa Study Center in Leiden, the Netherlands).

Bach, T., & Ruffing, E. (2013). Networking for autonomy? National agencies in European networks.
 Public Administration, 91(3), 712-726. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9299.2012.02093.x

Balassa, B. (2011). Towards a theory of economic integration. Kyklos, 14(1), 1-17.
 doi:10.1111/j.1467-6435.1961.tb02365.x

Bechle, K. & Rüland, J. (2014). Defending state-centric Regionalism through Mimicry and 


Localisation: Regional Parliamentary Bodies in the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) and Mercosur. Journal of International Relations and Development, 17(1), 61-88. 
 doi: 10.1057/jird.2013.3

Bryman, A. (2012). Social research methods. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Cini, M. & Borragán, N.P.S. (2013). European union politics. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Claeys, A. S. & Sindzingre, A. (2003). Regional integration as a transfer of rules: the case of the


relationship between the European Union and the West African Economic and Monetary
 Union (WAEMU). Requested from http://www.business.mmu.ac.uk/edpsg/docs/dp26.pdf

Cofelice, A. & Stavridis, S. (2014). The European Parliament as an International Parliamentary
 Institution (IPI). European Foreign Affairs Review, 19(2), 145-178. Retrieved from


http://www.kluwerlawonline.com/document.php?id=EERR2014008&PHPSESSID=npj5ho9
 vo7bqifa14hjn6mcg2

Central Intelligence Agency (2013). The World Factbook 2013-2014. Washington, DC. Retrieved from https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/index.html

Cutler, R. M. (2006). The OSCE's Parliamentary Diplomacy in Central Asia and the South Caucasus in Comparative Perspective. Studia Diplomatica, 59(2), 79. Retrieved from 


http://s3.amazonaws.com/academia.edu.documents/35335259/ar06sdip.pdf?AWSAccessKey 
 d=AKIAIWOWYYGZ2Y53UL3A&Expires=1497186226&Signature=a9pVXfh%2FbfCZV
 2F1tv0JGL3pYI08%3D&response-content 


(29)

Dri, C.F. (2010). Limits of the institutional mimesis of the EU: the case of the Mercosur parliament.
 Latin American Policy. 1(1), pp. 52-74. Doi:10.1111/j.2041-7373.2010.00004.x

Erk, J., Heijstek-Zieman, K. and Louwerse, T. (2013). Politiek in een veranderende wereld: 
 Nederland en België in vergelijkend perspectief. Leuven: Acco.

Gnassou, L. (1997), La coordination des politiques macro-économiques en UEMOA : les e
 jeux budgétaires de l’Union. De Pecunia, 8(1), 119-157.

Grimm, S. (1999). Institutional change in the West African Economic and Monetary Union


(WAEMU) since 1994: A fresh start after the devaluation shock? Africa Spectrum 34(1), 5-32.
 Retrieved from http://www.jstor.org/stable/40174785?seq=1#page_scan_tab_contents

Gorenman, C. (2007). Institutions and Politics of Mercosur. Retrieved from: http://international
 trade.blogspot.nl/

Grugel, J. (2007). Democratization and Ideational Diffusion: Europe, Mercosur and Social 
 Citizenship. Journal of Common Market Studies, 45(1), pp. 43–68. doi:10.1111/j.1468
 5965.2007.00702.x

Haas, E.B. (1958). The Uniting for Europe: Political, Social and Economic Forces, 1950-1957.
 Stanford, California: Stanford University Press.

Habegger, B. (2006). Democratic control of the OSCE: the role of the Parliamentary
 Assembly. Helsinki Monitor, 17(2), 133-143. doi:10.1163/157181406777813635 .Habegger, B. (2010). Democratic Accountability of International Organizations: Parliamentary 


Control within the Council of Europe and the OSCE and the Prospects for the United 
 Nations. Cooperation and Conflict, 45(2), 186-204. doi:10.1177/0010836709347218 Hall, P.A. & Taylor, R.C. (1996). Political science and the three new institutionalisms. Political 


studies, 44(5), 936-957. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9248.1996.tb00343.x

Hänggi, H. (2004). The ‘Double Democratic Deficit’: Parliamentary accountability and the use of 
 force under international auspices. Aldershot: Ashgate.

Hochstetler, K. (2007). Multi-Level Governance and Social Movements in Mercosur, Paper


delivered at the Annual Convention of the American Political Science Association, Chicago,
 30 August - 2 September 2007.

(30)

Kireyev, M. A. P. (2016). Building Integrated Economies in West Africa: Lessons in Managing Growth, Inclusivemess, and Volatility. Retrieved from http://www.elibrary.imf.org 
 /page/building-integrated-economies-west-africa-excerpt?redirect=true

Ledo, G. (2015). Parlasur Direct Elections: A Step towards Integration. The Federalist Debate, (2), 
 30-32. Retrieved from http://www.internationaldemocracywatch.org/attachments/ 


529_Gretel%20Ledo%20-%20Parlasur-RevLC3.pdf

Lumallas, E. (2011). Carving The Nation Of East Africa: An In-depth Survey Of The Role Of The 
 East African Legislative Assembly (Doctoral dissertation University of Nairobi). Retrieved
 from http://erepository.uonbi.ac.ke/bitstream/handle/11295/59774/Lumallas_Carving%20The 
 %20Nation%20Of%20East%20Africa%3A%20An%20Indepth%20Survey%20Of%20
 The%20Role%20Of%20The%20East%20African%20Legislative%20Assembly%20 
 ?sequence=4

Lucci, J. J. (2013). MERCOSUR Parliament: Institutional weakness and political stalemate. 
 Analysis six years after its formation. Journal of Arts and Humanities, 2(3), 61-66.
 Retrieved from http://search.proquest.com/openview/9e13e447a1afd803dd234b


12f158c8b1/1?pq-origsite=gscholar&cbl=2035643

Malamud, A. (2005). Presidential diplomacy and the institutional underpinnings of Mercosur: an
 empirical examination. Latin American Research Review, 40(1), 138-164. doi:


10.1353/lar.2005.0004

Malamud, A. & Dri, C. (2013). Spillover effects and supranational parliaments: The case of 
 Mercosur. Journal of Iberian and Latin American Research, 19(2), 224-238. doi:

10.1080/13260219.2013.853354.

Malamud, A. & Sousa, L. de (2007). Regional Parliaments in Europe and Latin America: Between Empowerment and Irrelevance. In Hoffmann, R. & Vleuten, A. van der (eds.), Closing or Widening the Gap? Legitimacy and Democracy in Regional International Organizations (pp.85-102). Retrieved from http://repository.ubn.ru.nl/bitstream/handle/2066/45982/
 45982.pdf

Medeiros, M. D. A., Mota, M. H. R., & Meunier, I. (2016). Modernization Without Change: Decision-
 Making Process in the Mercosur Parliament. Brazilian Political Science Review, 10(1). Doi:
 10.1590/1981-38212016000100001

Mahoney, J. (2000). Path dependence in historical sociology. Theory and society, 29(4), 507-548.doi:
 10.1023/A:1007113830879

(31)

Moravcsik, A. (2005). The European constitutional compromise and the neofunctionalist legacy.
 Journal of European Public Policy, 12(2), 349-386. doi:10.1080=13501760500044215

Nello, S. S. (2002). Preparing for enlargement in the European Union: The tensions between economic
 and political integration. International Political Science Review, 23(3), 291-317. doi:


10.1177/0192512102023003005

Noblit, G. W. & Hare, R. D. (1988). Meta-ethnography: Synthesizing qualitative studies. Retrieved
 from https://books.google.nl/books?hl=nl&lr=&id=fQQb4FP4NSgC&oi=fnd&pg


=PA10&dq=Noblit,+G.+W.,+%26+Hare,+R.+D.+(1988).+Metaethnography:+
 Synthesizing+qualitative+studies+(Vol.+11).+%09sage.&ots=MU8Iqwb2Rg&sig
 =ozmVPQBvteGozWmA8XfOWKhHYpw#v=onepage&q&f=false

Nzewi, O. (2014). Influence and Legitimacy in African Regional Parliamentary Assemblies: The Case of the Pan-African Parliament’s Search for Legislative Powers. Journal of Asian
 and African Studies, 49(4), 488-507. doi:10.1177/0021909613490138

Papenborg, S. (2016). Powerful integration? The effect of integration on International Parliamentary 
 Institutions (Bachelor's thesis Leiden University). Retrieved from


https://openaccess.leidenuniv.nl/bitstream/handle/1887/41181/Papenborg,%20Sietse
 s1389327-IBO%2002-POWE-2016.pdf?sequence=1

Rocabert, J., Schimmelfennig, F. & Winzen, T. (2014). The Rise of International Parliamentary
 Institutions? Conceptualization and First Empirical Illustrations. ECPR Joint Sessions,
 Salamanca (10-15 April 2014). Retrieved from


https://ecpr.eu/filestore/paperproposal/e0ac9c40-599d-48fa-bf35-4f77d10c21c8.pdf

Ruffing, E. (2015). Agencies between two worlds: information asymmetry in multilevel policymaking.
 Journal of European Public Policy, 22(8), 1109-1126. doi: 10.1080/13501763.2015.1011198

Šabič, Z. (2008). Building democratic and responsible global governance: the role of international
 parliamentary institutions. Parliamentary Affairs, 61(2), 255-271. doi:

 https://doi.org/10.1093/pa/gsm062

Sapir, A. (2011). European Integration at the Crossroads: A Review Essay on the 50th Anniversary of
 Bela Balassa’s "Theory of Economic Integration" Journal of Economic Literature, 49(4),
 1200-1229. Retrieved from http://www.jstor.org/stable/23071666

(32)

Seawright, J., & Gerring, J. (2008). Case Selection Techniques in Case Study Research: A Menu of 
 Qualitative and Quantitative Options. Political Research Quarterly, 61(2), 294-308. Retrieved
 from http://www.jstor.org/stable/20299733

Sandholtz, W. & Sweet A.S. (1998). European Integration and Supranational Governance. Oxford: 
 Oxford University Press. Retrieved from https://books.google.nl/books?hl=nl&lr=&id=
 qddCCXEFDDcC&oi=fnd&pg=PR7&dq=Sandholtz,+W.+%26+Stone+Sweet+A.+(red.)+
 (1998).+European+Integration+and+Supranational+++%09Governance.+Oxford:


+Oxford+University+Press.&ots=Uohu660jiq&sig=NVs9pTjbQCxZEEDNim9blFEJOAY
 #v=onepage&q&f=false

Terlinden, U. (2004). African Regional Parliaments: Engines of Integration and Democratisation?
 Retrieved from http://www.conflict-advocacy.org/docs/Terlinden2004Reg_Parl.pdf

Worldbank (2015). ECOWAS, UEMOA and the World Bank Group Conclude 2nd Tripartite Meeting 
 Requested from http://web.worldbank.org/WEBSITE/EXTERNAL/COUNTRIES/


AFRICA/EXTREGINI/EXTAF/PREICOO/0,,CONTENTmdk:20626471~menuPK:1592403~ 
 pagePK:64168445~piPK:64168309~theSitePK:1587585,00.html

Tranfield, D., Denyer, D. & Smart, P. (2003). Towards a methodology for developing evidence-
 informed management knowledge by means of systematic review. British journal of 
 management, 14(3), 207-222. doi10.1111/1467-8551.00375

Van der Vleuten, A. (2015). De bestuurlijke kaart van de Europese Unie: Instellingen,
 besluitvormingen beleid. Bussum: Coutinho.

Weisglas, F. W. & De Boer, G. (2007). Parliamentary diplomacy. The Hague Journal of


Diplomacy, 2(1), 93-99. Retrieved from http://booksandjournals.brillonline.com/content/
 journals/10.1163/187119007x180494

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

The socio-economic and cultural dimension both showed two significant results making them the most influential dimensions regarding the integration process of international

Furthermore, we could estimate the number of spiropyran molecules per one encapsulin particle that is ~ (1.16 mM/0.01 mM) = 116.. Characterization of encapsulin. b)

'n deur oop in die agterkant van die boegkajuit. As die loods die vliegtuig skiet. be· reik maar deskundiges is dit cens dat hierdie manier van uitspring nie

Bij vergelijking van de resultaten van Bildstar in de tabellen 5 en 6 blijken de verschillen weliswaar niet groot te zijn maar uit de statistische verwerking van

An in-depth study on the reasons why countries have not made use of the “optional clause” yet, followed by a global campaign to address these rea- sons and increase the number

The British and French parliaments were the leading examples for the rest of Europe during the nineteenth century, and the comparison and the connections between parliament

We consider the importance of different financial institutions – including low-end financial institutions, specialized lenders and banks – by calculating their asset share relative

From the perspective of the agency theory, agency costs are expected to increase with the appointment of international board members and an international CEO, thus imposing