• No results found

Are financial analysts inattentive : evidence from a natural experiment in context of FAS 123-R

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Are financial analysts inattentive : evidence from a natural experiment in context of FAS 123-R"

Copied!
61
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

   

   

 

Are  Financial  Analysts  Inattentive?

   

Evidence  from  a  Natural  Experiment  in  context  of  FAS  123-­‐R                  

Program:  MSc.  Business  Economics,  Finance  track   Subject:  Master  Thesis  First  Draft  

Name:  Tessa  Wanders  

Student  number:  6144667     Supervisor:  Dr.  T.  Ladika   Date:  July  6th  2015  

(2)

Statement  of  Originality  

This  document  is  written  by  Tessa  Wanders  who  declares  to  take  full  responsibility  for  the     contents  of  this  document.  

I   declare   that   the   text   and   the   work   presented   in   this   document   is   original   and   that   no   sources   other   than   those   mentioned   in   the   text   and   its   references   have   been   used   in   creating  it.  

The   Faculty   of   Economics   and   Business   is   responsible   solely   for   the   supervision   of   completion  of  the  work,  not  for  the  contents.  

                             

(3)

Abstract  

We   provide   evidence   that   financial   analysts   using   EBITDA   and   Net   Income   multiples   are   inattentive   and   incorrectly   adjust   their   earnings   forecasts   although   no   new   information   comes  to  light.    We  document  this  effect  by  exploiting  a  unique  event  in  2005,  FAS  123-­‐R.   Using  the  random  variation  in  the  timing  of  FAS  123-­‐R  -­‐  firms  with  fiscal  year  ending  June  or   later  had  to  comply  in  2005,  while  all  other  firms  could  postpone  compliance  until  2006  –   we   construct   a   treatment   and   a   control   group.   Our   two   stage   least   squares   estimates   suggest  that  analysts  unjustifiably  adjust  their  earnings  estimates  downwards  by  $0,06  for   the   (early   complier)   treatment   group,   although   nothing   actually   changes.   Results   are   especially   significant   for   commodity-­‐like   industry   analysts,   and   insignificant   for   the   tech   industry   analysts.   We   also   show   in   an   event   study   that   not   only   financial   analysts   react   inefficiently  to  FAS  123-­‐R,  but  the  market  as  a  whole  does  so  too.    

                   

*  I  would  like  to  thank  my  supervisor  dr.  Tomislav  Ladika  for  providing  me  with  a  large  part   of  the  data,  extensive  feedback  and  useful  comments.  I’m  also  grateful  for  moral  support   from  Roland  Wanders  and  Thomas  Plantenga.  All  errors  are  my  own.  

(4)

Table  of  Contents  

1.  Introduction  ...  5  

2.  Background  FAS  123-­‐R  ...  7  

3.  Literature  Review  ...  9  

4.  Hypotheses  and  Methodology  ...  16  

5.  Data  and  Descriptive  Statistics  ...  20  

6.  Results  ...  24  

6.1  First  Stage  Results  ...  24  

6.2  Second  Stage  Results  ...  26  

6.3  Event  Study  Results  ...  28  

7.  Robustness  Checks  ...  29   8.  Conclusion  ...  32   References  ...  35                            

(5)

1.  Introduction  

 

Do   financial   analysts   depend   on   detailed   company   research   when   constructing   earnings   forecasts,  or  are  they  inattentive  and  merely  focus  on  easily  observable  earnings  headlines?   This   paper’s   contribution   is   to   provide   an   answer   to   this   question.     A   vast   majority   of   literature  confirms  that  analysts  do  not  incorporate  all  available  information  in  an  efficient   way  and  that  it  matters  how  information  is  displayed.    A  number  of  studies  have  shown  that   financial   analysts   can   be   lazy,   inattentive   or   both.   Dellavigna   and   Pollet   (2009)   show   that   analysts  are  more  distracted  on  trading  days  before  the  weekend.  Similarly,  Hirshleifer,  Lim   and   Teoh   (2009)   find   evidence   that   shows   analysts   are   also   distracted   when   concurrent   earnings   are   announced.   Herrmann   and   Thomas   (2005)   distinguish   lazy   analysts   by   observing  forecast  rounding.  Lazy  analysts  tend  to  forecast  earnings  in  nickel  intervals  more   frequently   than   hard-­‐working   analysts.   Analysts   play   a   significant   role   in   the   process   of   impounding  information  into  US  stock  prices  (Potrioski  and  Roulstone,  2004).  They  have  a   large  group  of  clients  and  other  investors  that  follow  their  forecasts  and  recommendations   (Davies   and   Canes,   1978).   It   is   therefore   important   for   investors,   companies,   analysts,   managers,   shareholders,   academics   and   policymakers,   to   understand   how   analysts   use   information  and  that  their  forecasts  sometimes  might  be  flawed.    

 

The  setting  in  which  the  research  question  will  be  tested  is  a  2005  change  in  US  accounting   rules;   statement   FAS   123-­‐R.   With   this   new   standard   The   Financial   Accounting   Standards   Board  (FASB)  required  firms  to  expense  their  employee  stock  options.  A  key  element  of  FAS   123-­‐R  that  we  will  exploit  to  answer  the  research  question  is  the  fact  that  the  compliance   date  across  firms  differs  almost  randomly  (Ladika  and  Sautner,  2014).  Firms  with  fiscal  year   ending  in  June  or  later  had  to  comply  with  FAS  123-­‐R  in  2005  (treatment)  the  rest  comply  in   2006  (control).  According  to  Damodaran  (2005)  FAS  123-­‐R  would  have  a  big  impact  on  the   profit  and  loss  (P&L)  headlines  of  the  treated  firms.  Using  a  Two-­‐Stage  Least  Squares  model   for   identification   and   data   from   the   Compustat   and   IBES   databases,   we   will   test   Damodaran’s  statement  in  the  first  stage  of  the  research.  Then  in  the  second  stage,  we  will   test  whether  this  exogenous  change  in  P&L  headlines  results  in  significantly  lower  analyst   forecasts   for   the   treatment   group.   It   is   important   to   note   that   for   both   treatment   and  

(6)

control  groups,  the  same  amount  of  information  is  available.  The  only  difference  is  that  the   treatment  group  has  to  recognize  the  ESO’s  as  an  expense,  whereas  the  control  group  only   has   to   disclose   the   ESO’s   in   a   footnote.   If   we   find   significant   results   in   our   second   stage   regression   we   may   conclude   that   analysts   only   use   ESO   information   when   it   is   easy   to   observe.  But  when  the  expense  is  hidden  in  a  footnote  they  don’t  worry  about  it.      

 

This   paper   contributes   to   two   streams   of   empirical   literature.   The   first   stream   links   accounting  or  tax  changes  to  real  firm  outcomes  or  investor  attitude,  more  specifically  on   the  impact  of  FAS  123-­‐R  on  real  firms  outcomes  and  investor  behavior.  The  other  stream   engages   in   explaining   how   analysts   construct   forecasts.   The   unique   contribution   of   my   paper  is  that  it  combines  both  research  streams  and  analyzes  the  way  analysts  react  to  the   introduction  of  the  specific  US  Accounting  Rule  FAS  123-­‐R.  

 

Our  results  confirm  our  hypothesis  that  financial  analysts  incorrectly  adjust  their  earnings   forecasts  for  the  treatment  group  as  a  reaction  to  FAS  123-­‐R  although  no  new  information   came   to   light.   In   the   first   stage   results   we   show   that   FAS   123-­‐R   significantly   impacts   the   treatment  group’s  earnings.  The  second  stage  results  show  that  as  a  result  financial  analysts   incorrectly  adjust  their  forecast  estimates.  We  find  these  results  to  be  different  for  the  tech   firm   subsample.   Tech   firm   results   are   stronger   in   the   first   stage   but   insignificant   in   the   second   stage.   For   the   majority   of   the   remaining   tests,   the   tech   firm   subsample   shows   different  results.  We  believe  this  is  the  case  because  as  ESO’s  play  a  large  role  in  the  tech   industry,  tech  industry  analysts  already  efficiently  incorporated  ESO  information  before  FAS   123-­‐R.   Using   consensus   estimate   standard   deviation   as   a   proxy   for   confusion   among   analysts,   we   show   that   confusion   increased   around   firms   that   had   to   comply   with   the   accounting  rule.  The  forecast  error,  used  as  a  proxy  for  analyst  accuracy,  shows  that  after   FAS   123-­‐R   analysts   become   more   accurate.   Our   event   study   results   show   that   also   the   security  markets  as  a  whole  respond  inefficiently  to  FAS  123-­‐R.  The  average  buy  and  hold   abnormal   returns   are   lower   for   the   treatment   group   than   for   the   control   group.   We   also   show   that   results   are   stronger   for   widely   followed   firms   than   for   less   followed   firms.   In   addition  we  show  that  commodity-­‐like  industries  (e.g.  Chemicals,  Food,  Smoke)  appear  to   be  particularly  affected  by  FAS  123-­‐R  and  inefficient  markets.    

(7)

The  rest  of  this  paper  is  structured  as  follows.  The  second  chapter  provides  a  brief  summary   of   FAS   123-­‐R’s   history.   The   following   chapter   elaborates   on   the   two   aforementioned   streams   of   literature   that   blend   together   in   this   research.   Chapter   4   and   5   explain   our   methodology  and  data,  respectively.  Chapter  6  presents  the  results  for  the  first  and  second   stage  and  our  event  study.  Chapter  7  presents  the  results  from  our  robustness  checks  and   several  extensions.  Finally  the  last  chapter  concludes  our  results  and  hypotheses.    

2.  Background  FAS  123-­‐R  

 

FAS  123-­‐R  is  the  outcome  of  a  heated  debate,  on  how  firms  should  treat  their  stock-­‐based   compensation  when  reporting  their  income,  which  had  been  going  on  for  multiple  decades.   This  section  presents  a  summary  of  the  legal  history  and  a  brief  description  of  this  debate.   In  1972  the  U.S.  Accounting  Principles  Board  issued  Opinion  25  (APB  25).  APB  25  ruled  that   the   intrinsic   value   based   method   should   be   used   to   account   for   stock   option   based   remuneration.  This  entailed  that  the  expense  concerned  with  option-­‐based  payments  is  the   difference,  if  any,  between  the  firm’s  stock  price  on  the  date  the  option  is  granted  minus  the   option   strike   price.   As   firms   usually   granted   their   employees   at-­‐the-­‐money   stock   options,   this  difference  was  null,  and  thus  so  was  the  accounting  expense.    

For  the  first  time,  in  1984,  the  Financial  Accounting  Standards  Board  (FASB)  put  an  Exposure   Draft  on  the  agenda  that  mandated  firms  to  use  the  fair-­‐value  approach  to  recognize  share-­‐ based  payments  on  their  income  statement,  rather  than  the  previously  mentioned  intrinsic-­‐ value   based   method.   The   proposal   was   released   in   June   1993,   and   was   met   with   strong   resistance.   The   FASB   received   over   1,700   letters   of   comment,   almost   all   of   them   in   opposition  of  the  Exposure  Draft.    

The   central   arguments   against   the   fair-­‐value   based   approach   could   be   divided   into   two   categories,  public  policy  issues  and  reliability  of  measuring  the  fair  value  of  employee  stock   options   (ESOs)   (Rees   and   Stott,   1998).   Firstly,   opponents   reasoned   that   fair   value   recognition  of  ESOs  as  an  expense  would  harm  stock  prices.  This  would  result  in  companies   having   to   cut   stock   plans   (Khalaf   1993,   Beese   1994,   Harlan   1994).   It   would   1)   stifle   new   businesses  and  high-­‐tech  companies,  2)  companies  would  go  out  of  business  so  jobs  would  

(8)

be  lost  and  3)  it  would  harm  overall  US  competitiveness  with  foreign  markets  that  do  not   follow   the   fair   value   method.   The   other   central   argument   concerned   accuracy   of   measurement   methods   (Rodgers   1994,   Beese   1994).   Coopers   and   Lybrand   (1993)   found   evidence  that  the  expense  calculated  using  the  FASB  guideline  option  pricing  model  would   vary  widely  depending  on  the  assumptions  made.  Even  the  Accounting  Standards  Executive   Committee,   which   was   initially   in   favor   of   the   FASB   Exposure   Draft,   disagreed   on   the   reliability  of  the  measurement  method  (AcSEC,  1994).    

The   lobby   urging   abandonment   of   the   proposal   grew   so   strong,   even   President   Clinton   warned   that   it   would   possibly   undermine   the   competitiveness   of   the   U.S.   tech   industry   (Harlan  1994).  In  May  1994,  the  U.S.  Senate  passed  a  resolution  that  urged  withdrawal  and   Congress   gave   the   FASB   an   ultimatum.   Allow   the   alternative   of   disclosure   (rather   than   expensing)  or  the  FASB  will  seize  to  exist  as  an  accounting  rule  making  body  (Brown  and  Lee,   2003).  In  October  1995,  the  FASB  chose  the  former,  and  accepted  a  pro  forma  disclosure  in   a  footnote  of  earnings  that  reveal  what  earnings  would  be  if  the  fair  value  of  the  ESOs  would   be   recognized.   This   proposal,   FAS   123,   recommended   fair-­‐value   accounting,   but   not   surprisingly  the  lion’s  share  of  firms  stuck  to  APB  25  (Ladika  and  Sautner,  2014).      

The  discussion  on  ESO  expensing  resurged  in  the  early  2000s,  after  the  Enron  scandal  and   other  major  corporate  failures.  Murphy  (2003)  and  Murphy  and  Hall  (2003),  argued  that  the   absence   of   ESO   expensing   fueled   the   surge   in   stock   option-­‐based   pay.   Greenspan   (2002)   concluded  that  this  surge  incentivized  managers  to  “artificially  inflate  reported  earnings  in   order  to  keep  stock  prices  high  and  rising”.    From  July  through  December  of  2002,  150  firms   started   expensing   ESOs   voluntarily   using   the   fair   value   approach   (Aboody,   Barth   and   Kasznik,   2004a).   Recognizing   or   disclosing   ESOs   has   a   different   effect   on   corporate   investment.   Bernard   and   Schipper   (1994),   Libby,   Nelson   and   Hunton   (2006)   explain   that   managers  and  auditors  take  more  care  measuring  recognized  items,  as  opposed  to  disclosed   items.  It  follows  from  Bushman  and  Smith  (2001),  Bens  and  Monahan  (2004),  McNichols  and   Stubben  (2008),  Biddle  et  al.  (2009)  Balakrishnan  et  al.  (2014),  that  this  increased  financial   reporting  quality  is  associated  with  enhanced  investment  efficiency.  Hirschleifer  and  Teoh   (2003)   find   evidence   that   inattentive   investors   focus   on   recognized   items   and   ignore   important  footnotes.  As  a  consequence  firms  can  issue  overpriced  stocks  to  fund  additional   investment.    

(9)

The  FASB  released  a  new  proposal  in  March  2004,  again  proposing  to  expense  stock  options   using  fair-­‐value  method.  The  final  standard  was  adopted  in  December  2004,  called  FAS  123-­‐ R.  Public  firms  were  mandated  to  apply  the  fair  value  method  to  1)  all  ESO  awards  granted   after  June  15,  2005  and  2)  unvested  ESO  awards  granted  after  1994,  in  their  first  financial   statement  (either  quarterly  or  annual)  released  after  June  15,  2005.  However,  on  April  14   2005,  in  response  to  worries  from  accountants  about  altering  fiscal  standards  in  the  middle   of   the   fiscal   year,   the   Securities   and   Exchange   Commission   (SEC)   decided   to   delay   the   effective  date.  Now  firms  were  allowed  to  implement  FAS  123-­‐R  with  the  start  of  their  first   fiscal  year,  rather  than  the  first  reporting  period,  after  June  2005.  To  clarify,  this  meant  that   firms   with   their   fiscal   year   ending   on   June   30,   2005   had   to   comply   starting   in   July   2005.   Whereas  firms  with  a  fiscal  year  ending  on  May  31,  2005  were  exempt  from  FAS  123-­‐R  until   June  2006.  (Ladika  and  Sautner,  2014).  Appendix  A-­‐3  clarifies  which  firms  comply  when.  

3.  Literature  Review  

 

This  study  adds  to  several  streams  of  empirical  literature,  the  most  important  two  will  be   discussed   in   this   section.   The   first   stream   links   accounting   or   tax   changes   to   real   firm   outcomes  or  investor  attitude,  and  specifically  we  will  focus  on  the  effect  of  accounting  rule   FAS   123-­‐R.   The   other   stream   we   will   discuss,   tries   to   understand   the   process   of   financial   analyst  forecasting.  This  section  will  present  the  most  relevant  publications  and  theories  in   these  different  fields,  and  explain  how  the  current  paper  aims  to  contribute.    

Firstly,   this   study   relates   to   papers   that   study   the   effects   of   accounting   changes   and   corporate   governance   measures   on   real   firm   outcomes   or   investor   attitude.   The   term   “perception”  reappears  often  in  this  field  of  research.  Accounting  rules  seldom  change  an   actual  economic  cost,  yet  they  do  change  the  perception  of  certain  costs.  The  way  managers   react  to  altered  accounting  regulation  often  seems  irrational  to  economists.  For  example,   when  the  FASB  introduced  a  new  current  accounting  charge  for  anticipated  post-­‐retirement   benefits  (PRB)  (SFAS  106),  managers  predicted  that  share  prices  would  come  down  with  the   reported   income   (Hall   and   Murphy,   2003).   So   companies   started   making   considerable   cutbacks  in  their  medical  benefits  for  pensioners  (Mittelstaedt,  Nichols  and  Regier,  1995).   Firms   also   attempted   to   correct   the   markets   perception   of   the   magnitude   of   the   PRB  

(10)

obligation  by  choosing  early  adoption  of  SFAS  106  (Amir  and  Livnat,  1996).  However,  stock   prices  did  not  fall  because  markets  are  fairly  efficient  and  the  economic  costs  were  already   incorporated  in  the  stock  price  (Amir  1993,  Espahbodi,  Strock  and  Tehranian,  1991).  These   results  are  inconsistent  with  our  expectations  for  the  current  research,  because  we  do  not   expect  markets  to  be  fully  efficient.  As  opposed  to  SFAS  106,  with  FAS  123-­‐R  not  all  firms   comply  at  the  same  time.  We  expect  that  exactly  due  to  this  difference,  the  incorporation  of   information   into   the   price   will   be   more   complex,   and   therefore   the   market   might   be   inefficient.    

Although  certain  accounting  rules  have  no  effect  on  the  company  cash  flows,  companies  still   respond  because  of  the  changed  perceived  costs.  There  are  three  theories  that  attempt  to   explain   why   managers   undertake   actions   to   affect   income   but   that   have   no   cash   flow   effects.   Firstly,   Graham,   Hanlon   and   Rajgopal   (Bartov   E.   2007)   (2005)   interview   several   CFO’s.   The   interviewees   say   that   they   do   believe   stock   markets   are   efficient,   on   average,   however   when   reporting   their   firm’s   income,   they’d   rather   not   take   the   chance   that   the   market   inefficiently   prices   it.     Secondly,   Sloan   (1996)   and   Xie   (2001)   question   market   efficiency  with  respect  to  the  pricing  of  earnings  components.    Hirschleifer  and  Teoh  (2003)   state  that  partially  attentive  investors  pay  more  attention  to  recognized  than  to  disclosed   charges  to  income,  therefore  managers  have  an  incentive  to  avoid  recognizing  costs.  Finally   Graham  et  al.  (2005)  state  that  managers  manage  reported  income  to  signal  their  capability   to   the   executive   labor   market   or,   according   to   Bowen,   Ducharme   and   Shores   (1995),   to   other  stakeholders  such  as  creditors,  suppliers  and  employees.    A  study  by  Carter  and  Lynch   finds  evidence  that  suggests  firms  trade  off  financial  reporting  benefits  against  reputational   costs  in  determining  the  timing  of  repricings  to  get  beneficial  accounting  treatment.  Imhoff   and  Thomas  (1988)  scrutinized  capital  structure  changes  to  study  the  effect  of  SFAS  No.13   (capital  lease  disclosures  went  from  footnotes  to  balance  sheet)  on  lessees.  The  study  shows   that,  following  the  adoption  of  the  standard,  firms  systematically  substituted  capital  leases   with  operating  leases  and  non-­‐lease  sources  of  financing.  Furthermore,  lessees  appeared  to   reduce  book  leverage  by  increasing  equity  and  reducing  conventional  debt.    Graham,  Hanlon   and   Shevlin   (2011)   provide   evidence   that   whether   being   able   to   designate   earnings   as   permanently  reinvested  under  APB-­‐23  (accounting  for  income  taxes  -­‐  special  areas)  affects   real   corporate   decisions   about   operation   location   and   profit   reinvestment   versus  

(11)

repatriation.   Bens   and   Monahan   (2005)   show   that   banks   in   the   U.S.   avoid   consolidation   under  FASB  Interpretation  No.  46  by  restructuring  asset-­‐backed  commercial  paper  conduits.     The  term  perception  resurfaces  in  studies  on  employee  stock  options,  where  managers  act   as   if   ESOs   are   free   because   of   their   zero   accounting   cost   (before   FAS   123-­‐R).   Hall   and   Murphy  (2003)  argue  that,  because  of  the  favorable  accounting  treatment  of  ESOs  and  the   absence  of  a  cash  outlay  at  the  time  of  the  grant,  firms  act  as  if  the  ESO  perceived  cost  is   lower   than   the   true   economic   costs.   Using   the   perceived   rather   than   the   true   cost,   firms   tend  to  grant  more  options  than  they  would  otherwise.  Oyer  and  Schaefer  (2006)  confirm   that  the  median  firm  is  willing  to  incur  costs  of  up  to  $0,50  to  $1  to  issue  options  and  save   $1   in   compensation   expense.   Another   reason   for   the   decadent   use   of   ESOs   is   the   risk-­‐ averseness   of   managers.   They   value   ESOs   beneath   their   economic   value,   because   they   cannot   perfectly   hedge   the   risks   imposed   by   ESOs   (Lambert   et   al.   1991,   Hall   and   Murphy   2002).   To   compensate   for   this   risk,   firms   give   out   more   ESOs,   resulting   in   an   increased   executive  pay.  Numerous  studies  found  connections  between  the  magnitude  of  share-­‐based   compensation   and   real   firm   outcomes.   Cheng   and   Warfield   (2005),   Erickson   et   al.   (2006),   Bergstresser   and   Philippon   (2006),   all   established   a   link   between   ESO   compensation   and   earnings  management.  Dechow  and  Sloan  (1991)  show  the  more  stocks  or  options  in  their   firm  an  executive  owns,  the  less  likely  they  are  to  reduce  discretionary  expenditures  prior  to   their   departure.   Bens,   Nagar   and   Wong   (2002)   find   that   firms   experiencing   significant   employee   stock   option   exercises   shift   resources   away   from   real   investments   toward   the   repurchase  of  their  own  stock.  Weak  evidence  shows  that  the  performance  of  these  firms   tends   to   decline   in   subsequent   years,   possibly   implying   a   real   cost   in   terms   of   foregone   investment   opportunities.   These   studies   are   relevant   because   FAS   123-­‐R,   the   accounting   standard   that   will   be   studied   in   this   paper,   addresses   the   perception   and   accounting   treatment  of  ESOs.    

More   specifically   this   research   contributes   to   literature   on   the   real   firm   outcomes   that   followed   the   introduction   of   accounting   statement   FAS   123-­‐R.   Brown   and   Lee   (2007)   investigate   the   determinants   and   consequences   of   FAS   123-­‐R   on   the   option   based   components   of   the   compensation   for   the   top   five   executives   of   firms.   They   find   that   the   decrease  in  the  proportion  of  total  compensation  paid  in  ESOs  is  significantly  increasing  in   two   circumstances.   Firstly,   in   the   firm’s   tendency   to   use   ESO’s   favorable   accounting  

(12)

treatment  to  report  higher  earnings  in  the  period  before  mandated  expensing.  Secondly,  in   the  amount  of  ESO  expense  to  be  recognized  upon  adoption  of  FAS  123-­‐R.  The  paper  also   shows   that   firms   are   likely   to   replace   the   ESO   compensation   with   restricted   stock,   rather   than   other   forms   of   compensation.   Choudhary   (2008)   also   finds   evidence   for   this   substitution.   Because   this   substitution   is   less   than   dollar   for   dollar,   the   conclusion   states   that   FAS   123-­‐R   resulted   in   reduced   abnormal   compensation   for   the   top   five   executives.   Hayes,  Lemmon  and  Qiu  (2012)  also  provide  evidence  that  is  consistent  with  Brown  and  Lee.   They  only  look  at  the  CEO’s  compensation  and  find  that  the  option-­‐based  pay  component,   pre-­‐  and  post-­‐  mandatory  expensing,  decreased  by  17  percentage  points.  Carter,  Lynch  and   Tuna   (2007)   also   provide   evidence   that   the   introduction   of   FAS   123-­‐R   decreased   option-­‐ based  pay.  Skantz  (2012)  documents  that  these  changes  in  CEO  compensation  composition   are   beneficial   for   shareholders,   because   FAS   123-­‐R   has   contributed   to   a   reduction   of   inefficient  CEO  compensation.    

The  most  important  related  research  is  Ladika  and  Sautner  (2014).  They  find  evidence  that   some   firms   accelerated   their   option   vesting   and   reduced   investment.   They   conclude   that   executives   with   more   short-­‐term   incentives   engage   in   myopic   behavior   by   reducing   investment.   Ladika   and   Sautner’s   paper   is   useful   as   this   paper’s   identification   strategy   is   similar  to  theirs.  They  also  use  the  different  FAS  123-­‐R  compliance  dates  as  an  exogenous   instrument  to  identify  causality.  Golden  and  Kohlbeck  (2014)  find  that  FAS  123-­‐R  increased   stock   repurchases   overall,   and   that   this   effect   is   stronger   with   increased   levels   of   management  stock  options.    The  last  research  that  fits  into  this  stream  of  literature  but  also   touches  upon  the  final  stream  is  performed  by  Barth,  Gow  and  Taylor  (2012).  They  examine   how   key   market   participants   responded   to   FAS   123-­‐R.   They   find   that   some   companies   exclude   stock-­‐based   compensation   expense   from   non-­‐GAAP   earnings,   despite   the   regulation,  and  that  some  analysts  exclude  it  from  street  earnings.  Barth,  Gow  and  Taylor   reason  that  the  former  is  explained  by  opportunism  and  the  latter  by  predictive  ability.  The   findings  suggest  that  the  decades-­‐old  controversy  around  the  expensing  of  ESOs  is  possibly   explained  by  cross-­‐sectional  variation  in  the  relevance  of  the  expense  for  equity  valuation,   as  well  as  to  varying  incentives  of  market  participants.    

The  other  stream  of  literature  that  the  current  paper  relates  to  is  the  literature  that  helps  to   enhance  our  understanding  on  analysts’  use  of  public  information.  Two  papers  in  the  early  

(13)

1990’s,   Schipper   (1991)   and   Brown   (1993),   already   call   for   more   research   into   what   accounting  inputs  analysts  actually  use  in  their  decision  process.  Since  then  a  vast  amount   on  research  is  done,  using  all  sorts  of  research  methodologies.  From  simply  asking  analysts   how  they  process  information  (Block,  1999),  recording  analysts  thinking  out  loud  (Bouwman   et  al.,  1995),  to  examining  errors  in  forecasts  as  a  consequence  to  a  tax  reform  act  (Plumlee,   2003)   and   laboratory   experiments   to   study   how   analysts   use   information   (Maines   et   al.   1997).  Brown  (1993)  and  Schipper  (1991)  also  indicate  that  behavioral  research  can  play  a   more   prominent   role   when   trying   to   grasp   the   way   analysts   use   accounting   and   other   information  to  make  stock  recommendations.    

Financial   statement   data   are   an   important   source   of   information   for   analysts   (Barker   and   Imam   2008,   Barron   et   al.   2002,   Schipper   1991).   Although   Liu,   Nissim   and   Thomas   (2007)   state  that  operating  cash  flows  are  better  at  explaining  valuations  than  accounting  earnings,   Barker   and   Imam   (2008)   find   that   the   earnings   stated   by   the   company   is   often   the   most   important   item   used   by   analysts.   Hirshleifer   and   Teoh   (2003)   state   that   analysts   are   boundedly   rational   and   that   they   do   not   have   the   cognitive   capabilities   nor   the   time   to   incorporate   all   available   information   in   their   stock   forecasts.   This   phenomenon,   called   information  overload,  can  actually  cause  people  to  make  worse  decisions  than  they  would   have  done  without  the  information  (Casey  1980,  Simnet  1996).  With  the  huge  amount  of   information  available,  it  is  difficult  to  separate  the  important  valuable  information  from  the   side-­‐issues.  This  information  overload,  we  believe,  could  be  an  explanation  for  the  fact  that   in  the  current  paper  analysts  do  not  make  a  distinction  between  the  treatment  and  control   group.   Not   only   do   we   believe   that   analysts   are   overloaded   with   information,   we   also   believe   that   they   sometimes   are   a   bit   inattentive,   maybe   even   lazy.   A   nice   example   that   confirms  inattentiveness  is  Dellavigna  and  Pollet  (2009.  They  show,  using  earnings  surprises,   that   Friday   earnings   announcements   have   a   15%   lower   immediate   response   compared   to   the  other  days  of  the  week.  Inattentive  analysts  are  also  found  in  a  study  by  Herrmann  and   Thomas   (2005).   They   show   that   analyst   forecasts   of   earnings   per   share   occur   in   nickel   intervals  more  often  than  the  actual  earnings  per  share  do.  These  analysts  that  round  their   forecasts  tend  to  be  less  informed,  exert  less  effort  and  have  fewer  resources.  Hirshleifer,   Lim   and   Teoh   (2009)   show   that   concurrent   earnings   announcements   distract   analysts.    

(14)

These  studies  conclude  that  analysts  can  be  inattentive,  lazy  and  time  constrained,  and  are   consistent  with  what  we  expect  to  find.    

The   timing   and   the   style   of   announcements   and   disclosures   matter   for   the   efficiency/accuracy  analysts  incorporate  information.  Information  that  is  difficult  to  extract   from  public  data  is  less  completely  incorporated  in  the  market  prices  (Grossman  and  Stiglitz,   1980)   and   Bloomfield   (2002).   This   is   consistent   with   the   notion   that   hard-­‐to-­‐process   disclosure  is  costlier  to  process  and  delays  the  incorporation  of  the  information  into  stock   prices   or   forecasts.   Andersson   and   Hellman   (2007)   show   that   analysts   who   receive   pro   forma   and   GAAP   information   make   significantly   higher   EPS   forecasts   than   analysts   who   merely  received  GAAP  information.  Fredrickson  and  Miller  (2004)  however  say  that  analysts   are   less   likely   to   be   distracted   by   pro   forma   disclosures   than   non-­‐professionals.   In   1996,   Lang   and   Lundholm   published   a   paper   that   examines   the   relations   between   disclosure   practices  of  firms,  the  number  of  analysts  following  each  firm  and  properties  of  the  analysts’   earnings  forecasts.  The  findings  suggest  that  firms  with  more  informative  disclosure  policies   have   a   larger   analyst   following,   more   precise   analyst   earnings   forecasts,   less   dispersion   among  individual  analyst  forecasts  and  less  volatility  in  forecast  revisions.  The  way  Lang  and   Lundholm   measure   forecast   accuracy   could   be   helpful   for   our   research.   Hope   (2003)   also   finds  that  firm-­‐level  disclosures  and  the  enforcement  of  accounting  standards  is  associated   with   higher   analyst   forecast   accuracy.   Lehavy,   Feng,   Li   and   Merkley   (2011)   find,   not   surprisingly,   that   less   readable   10-­‐Ks   are   associated   with   lower   analyst   forecast   accuracy   and   greater   dispersion   among   analyst   forecasts.   Another   study   that   could   contribute   to   mine   is   Plumlee   (2003).   She   finds   evidence   that   indicates   that   a   higher   information   complexity  reduces  analysts’  use  of  the  information.  She  interprets  that  this  is  due  either  to   analyst  limited  processing  capacity  or  time  constraints.  Similar  to  our  research,  Plumlee  uses   a   federal   regulatory   change   as   an   event   to   examine   and   makes   inferences   on   analyst   behavior.  Demirakos  et  al.  (2004)  and  Bradshaw  (2002)  find  that  analysts  refer  to  simple  P/E   multiples   to   support   their   stock   recommendations   rather   than   extensive   present   value   techniques.  They  do  not  conclude  that  this  is  because  of  a  time  constraint.  If  our  research   indeed  finds  that  after  FAS  123-­‐R,  the  treatment  firms  are  punished  with  adjusted  analyst   forecasts,  while  the  control  group  does  not  experience  such  an  adjustment,  this  would  be   consistent  with  Demirakos’  and  Bradshaw’s  findings.  

(15)

According   to   the   (semi-­‐strong)   efficient   market   hypothesis   (EMH)   (Fama,   1970)   capital   markets  should  incorporate  all  publicly  available  information  into  stock  prices  and  forecasts   in   a   quick   and   efficient   manner.   It   should   not   matter   how   the   information   is   displayed,   whether  it’s  disclosed  in  a  footnote  or  recognized  in  the  income  statement.  However,  prior   research   shows   investors   or   analysts   find   recognized   items   more   pertinent   than   disclosed   items.  Davis-­‐Friday  et  al.  (1999  find  that  the  market  treats  disclosed  PRB  liabilities  as  less   reliable   than   recognized   PRB   liabilities   and   pension   liabilities.   Barth,   Clinch   and   Shibano   (2003)  find  evidence  that  “recognition  of  a  highly  unreliable  accounting  amount,  rather  than   simply   disclosing   it,   can   result   in   greater   price   informativeness.   Likewise,   recognition   of   a   highly   reliable   amount   can   result   in   lower   price   informativeness”.   They   also   find   that   the   coefficients  in  a  regression  of  price  on  accounting  numbers  is  affected  by  recognition  and   disclosure.   Choudhary   (2008)   finds   that   mandatory   recognition   of   ESOs   reflects   increased   dividend   and   interest   input   accuracy.     Hence   financial   statements   reflect   differences   in   behavior   between   recognition   and   disclosure   reporting   regimes.   Choudhary   (2011)   investigates  reliability  differences  across  recognition  and  disclosure  regimes.  The  evidence   shows  that  opportunism  increases  with  recognition  as  compared  with  disclosure,  but  that   accuracy  does  not  decline  for  the  recognizers.  Bratten,  Choudhary  and  Schipper  (2013)  find   that   disclosed   items   are   not   handled   differently   from   recognized   items   when   the   “disclosures   are   salient,   not   based   on   management   estimates,   and   amenable   to   simple   techniques  for  imputing  as-­‐if  recognized  amounts”.  Finally,  Balsam,  Bartov  and  Yin  (2006)   show  that  the  market  valuation  of  the  ESO  expense  does  not  differ  whether  the  amount  is   disclosed  or  recognized.  They  claim  that  firms  need  not  worry  about  the  first  order  effect  of   mandated  recognition  of  ESO’s  on  their  share  prices.  This  outcome  is  inconsistent  with  what   we  expect  to  find,  as  it  shows  markets  are  efficient  and  that  prices  already  incorporate  all   available  information.  It  also  assumes  that  firms  voluntarily  expensing  have  exactly  the  same   characteristics  as  the  rest  of  the  US  firms.    

These  papers  are  relevant  to  ours,  because  most  of  them  show  that  investors  and  analysts   sometimes   treat   disclosed   information   differently   from   recognized   information,   and   thus   that  markets  might  be  inefficient.  In  this  paper  we  aim  to  prove  the  same,  using  a  treatment   group  that  has  to  recognize  their  ESO  expenses  and  the  control  group  that  merely  discloses   them   in   a   footnote.   According   to   the   EMH   there   should   not   be   a   difference   in   analyst  

(16)

forecasts  in  response  to  FAS  123-­‐R,  yet  we  expect  analysts  to  lower  their  earnings  forecasts   for  the  treatment  group.            

4.  Hypotheses  and  Methodology  

 

The   aim   of   the   current   paper   is   to   show   that   when   constructing   forecasts   and   recommendations,   analysts   look   at   headlines   of   the   Profit   &   Loss   Statement,   rather   than   researching   the   company   in   close   detail.   Due   to   globalization,   technology   and   high   frequency  trading  a.o.,  the  amount  of  information  to  be  processed  has  risen  substantially,   but  the  timespan  for  analysis  has  not.  In  other  words,  suspected  is  that  in  light  of  this  time   constraint,  analysts  prefer  using  the  easy  observable  P&L  headlines  over  extensive  research.   Hence  my  main  hypothesis:  

H1:   When   constructing   earnings   forecasts,   financial   analysts   depend   on   P&L   headlines  

rather  than  in-­‐depth  company  analysis.      

To  find  proof  for  H1,  an  event  is  needed  that  plausibly  led  to  an  exogenous  change  in  the   P&L  headlines,  but  did  not  actually  change  anything  in  the  company.  Thus  the  analyst  doing   an  in-­‐depth  company  analysis  would  not  find  anything  to  have  changed  and  not  adjust  his   forecasts,  but  the  analyst  who  solely  studies  the  P&L  will  observe  a  company  change  and   adjust  his  estimates.  To  further  explain  the  importance  of  an  exogenous  event,  consider  the   following  linear  regression  model  that  does  not  use  such  an  event.  

1      ∆𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑐𝑎𝑠𝑡!,!!!,! = 𝜃 ∗ ∆𝐸𝐵𝐼𝑇𝐷𝐴!,!+ 𝛽 ∗ 𝑥!,!!!+ 𝜇!+ 𝜀!,!   2      ∆𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑐𝑎𝑠𝑡!,!!!,! = 𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑐𝑎𝑠𝑡!,!!!,!− 𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑐𝑎𝑠𝑡!,!!!,!!!   3      ∆𝐸𝐵𝐼𝑇𝐷𝐴!,! = 𝐸𝐵𝐼𝑇𝐷𝐴!,! − 𝐸𝐵𝐼𝑇𝐷𝐴!,!!!  

In  this  model  the  dependent  variable  is  a  change  in  the  financial  analysts’  forecast  for  future   time   period   t+1   for   firm   f   at   current   time   period   t.  ∆𝐸𝐵𝐼𝑇𝐷𝐴!,!  is   the   change   in   EBITDA  

between  time  period  t  and  t-­‐1.    𝑥!,!!!  is  a  vector  of  variables  to  control  for  observable  firm  

characteristics  and  𝜇!  is  a  variable  that  controls  for  time  fixed  effects.  We  assume  EBITDA  to  

(17)

run   the   regression,   find   a   significant   and   positive  𝜃  and   conclude   that   a   change   in   P&L   headlines  indeed  significantly  affects  analysts’  forecasts.    

However,  inferring  a  pure  causal  relationship  between  ∆𝐸𝐵𝐼𝑇𝐷𝐴!,!  and  ∆𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑐𝑎𝑠𝑡!,!!!,!  is  

unlikely.  A  change  in  the  company’s  EBITDA  is  probably  correlated  with  variables  in  the  error   term  that  are  difficult/impossible  to  observe,  which  in  turn  are  also  correlated  to  the  change   in   forecasts   by   the   analyst.   For   example,   imagine   company   A   whose   factory   burns   down.   This  won’t  only  directly  impact  A’s  EBITDA  because  they  produce  less,  it  also  impacts  other   company  variables  (e.g.  reputation,  safety/insurance  expenses  go  up,  CEO  of  A  gets  fired,   legal  expenses  etc.).  The  analyst  adjusts  his  forecasts  for  A,  but  not  because  of  the  changed   EBITDA,   but   because   of   the   burnt   down   factory   and   its   consequences   for   all   kinds   of   variables.  The  factory  burning  down  is  an  endogenous  event.  It  simultaneously  changes  a  lot   of   (unobservable)   variables   in   the   regression   model   and   probably   leads   us   to   biased   estimates   of  𝜃.   Using   this   model   we   could   not   conclude   whether   the   analyst   changed   his   forecasts  because  he  thoroughly  analyzed  of  the  consequences  of  the  burnt  down  factory  or   only  observed  the  EBITDA  change.  

The  setting  that  will  be  used  to  obtain  causal  coefficients,  is  the  2005  introduction  of  the   accounting  standard  FAS  123-­‐R  as  an  exogenous  event,  similar  to  Ladika  and  Sautner  (2014).   The   Financial   Accounting   Standards   Board   mandated   all   firms   to   treat   their   (granted)   employee  stock  options  as  an  expense  in  the  first  quarter  of  their  first  full  fiscal  year  as  of   June   2005.   Not   all   firms   use   the   calendar   year   as   fiscal   year,   so   there   is   variation   in   the   compliance   date   for   FAS   123-­‐R.   Some   firms   have   to   comply   in   2005,   while   for   others   the   accounting   rule   takes   effect   in   2006.   Before   proceeding,   the   following   conditions   will   be   tested:  

Condition  1.  The  variation  in  firms’  fiscal  year  ends  is  sufficiently  large  to  derive  a  treatment  

and  a  control  group.    

Condition  2.  The  treatment  and  control  group  have  no  significant  differences  in  observable  

firm  characteristics.1    

                                                                                                                         

1  The  first  condition  is  important  because  it  shows  the  control  group  is  large  enough  to  avoid  small  sample  size  

(18)

We  will  use  a  Two-­‐Stage  Least  Squares  (2SLS)  Model,  similar  to  Ladika  and  Sautner  (2014).  In   version  A  of  the  2SLS,  FAS  123-­‐R  effective  is  a  variable  that  indicates  whether  the  law  is  in   effect  or  not.  It  is  set  equal  to  0  in  all  years  and  months  before  FAS  123-­‐R  takes  effect,  and  it   is   equal   to   1   for   all   years   and   months   once   the   law   has   taken   effect.   The   date   that   the   variable   changes   from   0   to   1   differs   from   firm   to   firm,   as   it   depends   on   their   fiscal   year.   Appendix  A-­‐3  provides  an  illustration  of  the  compliance  of  rule  FAS  123-­‐R.  In  version  B,  FAS   123-­‐R  takes  effect  is  a  variable  that  indicates  whether  the  law  took  effect  that  year  or  not.  It   is  set  equal  to  0  in  all  years  other  than  the  year  that  FAS  123-­‐R  took  effect,  and  it  is  equal  to   1  if  FAS  123-­‐R  took  effect  in  that  year.  After  this  year  the  value  again  takes  on  0,  as  the  law   can   only   take   effect   once.   The   year   that   the   variable   takes   on   a   1   differs   between   firms,   because  it  also  depends  on  the  firm's  fiscal  year  end.  

First  Stage:     A.:  𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑠!,! = 𝜋!∗ 𝐹𝐴𝑆123𝑅  𝐸𝑓𝑓𝑒𝑐𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒!,! + 𝜋!∗ 𝑥!,!!!+ 𝜇!+ 𝑢!,!   B.:  ∆𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑠!,! = 𝜋!∗ 𝐹𝐴𝑆123𝑅  𝑡𝑎𝑘𝑒𝑠  𝑒𝑓𝑓𝑒𝑐𝑡!,!+ 𝜋!∗ 𝑥!,!!!+ 𝜇!+ 𝑢!,!   ∆𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑠!,! = 𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑠!,!− 𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑠!,!!!   Second  Stage:     A.:  𝐹𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑐𝑎𝑠𝑡!,!!!,! = 𝛾!∗ 𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑛𝚤𝑛𝑔𝑠!,!+ 𝛾!∗ 𝑥!,!!!+ 𝜇!+ 𝑣!,!   B.:  ∆𝐹𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑐𝑎𝑠𝑡!,!!!,! = 𝛾!∗ ∆𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑛𝚤𝑛𝑔𝑠!,!+ 𝛾! ∗ 𝑥!,!!!+ 𝜇!+ 𝑣!,!   ∆𝐹𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑐𝑎𝑠𝑡!,!!!,! = 𝐹𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑐𝑎𝑠𝑡!,!!!,!− 𝐹𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑐𝑎𝑠𝑡!,!!!,!!!                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                              

selection  bias  occurs.  It  is  expected  that  both  conditions  will  not  be  rejected  because  Ladika  and  Sautner  also   test  similar  hypotheses  and  find  no  evidence  against  them.  If  both  conditions  are  satisfied  the  variation  in  fiscal   year   ends   will   be   used   as   a   valid   and   relevant   instrument   in   the   identification   strategy.   Ladika   and   Sautner   (2014)  also  use  this  identification  strategy  to  identify  the  effect  of  mandated  ESO  expensing  on  accelerated   vesting  of  options.  Van  Binsbergen,  Graham  and  Yang  (2010)  use  the  variation  in  firms’  fiscal  year  endings  to   establish  a  causal  effect  of  the  tax  reform  TRA86  on  firms’  marginal  cost  of  debt.    This  strategy  is  also  similar  to   Daske  et  al.  (2008).  They  identify  the  effect  of  IFRS  on  liquidity  by  using  the  fact  that  IFRS  applied  to  firms  on   different  dates  depending  on  their  fiscal  year  end.  Michels  (2015)  uses  this  identification  strategy  to  estimate   the  effect  of  disclosure  versus  recognition.  

(19)

Where  ∆𝐹𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑐𝑎𝑠𝑡!,!  is  a  measure  of  change  in  analyst  forecast  for  period  t+1  for  firm  f  at  

time  t.  𝜇!  is  a  control  variable  for  time  fixed  effects.  ∆𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑛𝚤𝑛𝑔𝑠!,!  is  the  estimated  value  of  

Change   in   Earnings   (either   Net   Income   or   EBITDA)   from   the   1st   stage   regression.   This   regression  model  is  similar  to  the  Ladika  and  Sautner  (2014)  model.    𝑥!,!!!  is  a  vector  of  firm  

characteristics   at   time   t-­‐1,   they   are   from   the   previous   year   to   assure   that   they   are   not   affected  by  FAS  123-­‐R.    

The  vector  of  firm  level  controls  include  firm  size,  measured  by  Log(Assets).  As  larger  firms   tend   to   provide   their   managers   with   a   higher   fraction   of   equity-­‐based   pay   (Gabaix   and   Landier,  2006),  the  variable  is  expected  to  carry  a  negative  coefficient.  The  control  variable   Log(Assets)²     will   also   be   included   because   this   relationship   is   thought   to   be   inverted   U-­‐ shaped,  hence  will  carry  a  positive  coefficient.    Book  to  Market  Ratio  will  also  be  controlled   for,  because  analysts  will  likely  punish  growth  firms  (low  P/B)  more  severely  than  value  firms   (high  P/B)  when  they  miss  earnings  growth  targets  (Skinner  and  Sloan,  2002).    As  firms  with   higher   leverage   ratios   are   more   likely   to   face   constraints   from   earnings-­‐based   covenants   (Billet,   King   and   Mauer,   2007),   analysts   may   also   treat   their   missed   earnings-­‐targets   differently,  so  we  control  for  Debt/Assets.  Using  the  variables  Stock  Return  and  Volatility,   we  control  for  the  firms  performance  and  risk  respectively.  Firms  with  lower  stock  returns   will  likely  have  lower  employee  stock  option  expenses.  So  the  higher  the  stock  return,  the   larger  the  effect  of  FAS  123-­‐R  on  the  firms  EBITDA  or  Net  Income,  thus  a  negative  coefficient   is   expected.   Finally,   we   control   for   the   Option   Grant   Value,   as   the   impact   of   the   new   accounting  rule  is  increasing  with  this  value  we  expect  a  negative  coefficient.      

Sub-­‐H1:   FAS   123-­‐R   significantly   impacts   the   earnings   of   companies   that   belong   to   the  

treatment  group  after  controlling  for  firm  characteristics  𝑥!,!!!  and  time  fixed  effects  𝜇!.  

Sub   hypothesis   1   is   not   rejected   if  𝜋!  in   the   first   stage   regression   is   significant.    𝜋!  is  

expected  to  be  negative  and  significant  because  the  treatment  group  has  to  expense  their   employee  stock  options.  Ceteris  paribus,  when  expenses  are  higher  (operating)  earnings  will   be   lower.   Because   of   condition   2   and   Sub-­‐H1   it   may   be   concluded   that   the   decreased   earnings   in   the   treatment   group   are   because   of   FAS   123-­‐R,   and   nothing   else   has   actually   changed   in   the   company.   The   coefficient   of   interest   is  𝛾!.   A   significant   value   for   this  

(20)

for   the   treatment   group,   although   nothing   has   truly   changed   in   the   firm.   We   expect   the   value   to   be   positive,   because   we   expect   earnings   forecasts   to   be   positively   related   to   reported  earnings.  Correspondingly:  

𝐻!: 𝛾! = 0.    

𝐻!: 𝛾! > 0.    

With   the   introduction   of   FAS   123-­‐R   in   2004   no   new   information   on   the   cost   of   option   compensation   came   to   light,   it   was   just   easier   to   observe.   The   unrevised   statement   from   1995   (FAS-­‐123)   recommended   firms   to   adopt   fair   value   accounting.   It   also   mandated   the   disclosure,   rather   than   expensing,   of   option   compensation.   From   then   on,   firms   had   to   disclose  their  cost  of  option  compensation  in  a  footnote.  With  the  2005  revision  of  the  FAS-­‐ 123  statement,  the  contents  of  this  footnote  moved  to  the  profit  and  loss  statement.  This   increased  visibility.  With  a  significant  positive  𝛾!,  it  seems  that  when  information  on  option  

expenses   is   easy   to   observe,   analysts   use   it   in   their   forecasting.     However,   when   it   was   hidden  in  a  footnote  they  didn’t  bother.    

5.  Data  and  Descriptive  Statistics  

 

The  panel  data  used  for  this  research  is  obtained  from  four  databases;  Compustat,  Eugene   Fama   and   Ken   French   industry   classifications   database,   I/B/E/S   and   CRSP.   Compustat   is   a   database   that   contains   financial   and   statistical   market   information   on   active   and   inactive   companies   from   all   around   the   world.   It   covers   99%   of   the   world’s   total   market   capitalization   and   its   first   observations   date   back   to   1962.   We   will   only   use   data   on   U.S.   based   firms   as   FAS   123-­‐R   is   a   U.S.   accounting   rule.   The   two   scholars   Fama   and   French   constructed   a   database   that   assigns   each   NYSE,   AMEX,   and   NASDAQ   stock   to   an   industry   portfolio  at  the  end  of  June  of  year  t  based  on  its  four-­‐digit  SIC  code  at  that  time.  There  are   48  industries,  and  we’ll  be  using  them  in  our  tests  to  see  if  FAS  123-­‐R  had  different  effects   on   several   specific   industries.   We   also   classify   several   industries   as   tech   and   especially   scrutinize  this  group  of  firms.  The  I/B/E/S  database  provides  consensus  and  detail  forecasts   from  security  analysts  for  all  kinds  of  metrics,  though  we  will  only  be  using  their  earnings   per  share  forecasts  as  those  are  issued  for  the  vast  majority  of  firms  in  our  sample.  If  we  

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

In elektronische vorm beschikbaar gemaakt door de T BC van A−Eskwadraat.. Het college WSIB101 werd in 2004/2005 gegeven

plaats Vrije Universiteit, Amsterdam info www.feweb.vu.nl/ectrie/nl/vwo.html 20–21 januari. ❑ Workshop The Economics & Finance of

Deze zullen worden vernietigd van zodra de betrokken persoon niet langer aan een veiligheidsonderzoek kan worden onderworpen of wanneer de redenen waarom ze worden verzameld

We merken inderdaad op dat voor de betrokken persoon de mogelijkheid ontbreekt een zaak aanhangig te maken voor een rechtbank tegen het filiaal dat gelegen is in het bevoegde

a) wanneer de betrokkene schriftelijk heeft toegestemd in een dergelijke verwerking met dien verstande dat deze toestemming te allen tijde door de betrokkene kan worden ingetrokken;

Penelitian kaJi ini menyelidiki pengaruh dari pemberlakuan Syarial Islam secara Kaffah di Nanggroe Aceh Damssalam terhadap isi atau materi program Penyiaran Musik

contractual obligations linked to performance measures (Shleifer and Vishny, 1997). A higher proportion of debt, therefore, enables creditors to have more power to monitor

One of the most important features of XΥMTEX version 4.02 is that new stereochemical functions are supported, where a pair of wedged bonds/hashed dash bonds, a pair of