• No results found

What is rhe relationship between the development of microfinance institutions and economic growth?

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "What is rhe relationship between the development of microfinance institutions and economic growth?"

Copied!
31
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

   

What  is  the  relationship  between  the  development  of  microfinance  institutions  and   economic  growth?     Rose  Barzilai*   June  2016     Abstract  

In  this  paper  the  direct  effect  of  the  development  of  microfinance  institutions  and  economic   growth  is  studied  using  an  empirical  approach.  Various  indicators  of  the  development  of   microfinance  institutions  and  control  variables  are  used.  Economic  growth  is  regressed  to   one  indicator  in  each  regression  with  a  bunch  of  control  variables.  The  growth  equation  has   been  estimated  using  a  pure  cross-­‐section  sample  by  averaging  among  the  2001-­‐2007  time   dimension.  From  the  regression  results  it  can  be  concluded  that  the  development  of   microfinance  institutions  is  an  important  determinant  of  economic  growth.    

   

*Student  BSc  Economics  and  Business,  specialization  Economics  and  Finance,  Faculty  Economics  and  Business,   University  of  Amsterdam,  Amsterdam,  The  Netherlands.  

Student  number:  10572449.  Supervisor:  Rui  Zhuo  

(2)

Statement  of  originality  

This  document  is  written  by  Rose  Barzilai  who  declares  to  take  full  responsibility  for  the   contents  of  this  document.  

I  declare  that  the  text  and  the  work  presented  in  this  document  is  original  and  that  no   sources  other  than  those  mentioned  in  the  text  and  its  references  have  been  used  in   creating  it.    

The  Faculty  of  Economics  and  Business  is  responsible  solely  for  the  supervision  of   completion  of  the  work,  not  for  the  contents.  

                               

(3)

Table  of  Content  

1  Introduction……….4  

2  Literature  review……….…….……..………6  

  2.1  Microfinance  institutions………..………..6  

    2.2  Theoretical  review………..………..………..8  

          2.2.1  Microfinance  institutions  and  financial  development……….…….……….8  

      2.2.2  Financial  development  and  economic  growth……….….………..9  

      2.2.3  Microfinance  institutions  and  economic  growth……….……….…..11  

  2.3  Empirical  results……….………….…….12  

3  Data  and  Methodology……….……….………..………15  

  3.1  Data………..………15     3.2  Methodology………..……..……….……15   4  Empirical  results……….…..……….18       4.1  Control  variables……….18       4.2  Explanatory  variables………19   5  Conclusion……….……..……….……21   6  References……….……..……….……23   7  Appendix……….……..……….……27        

(4)

1.  Introduction  

“The  poor  stay  poor,  not  because  they  are  lazy  but  because  they  have  no  access  to  capital”   Milton  Friedman  quoted.  Hermes  and  Lensink  (2007)  stated  that  many  people  in  developing   economies  remain  poor  because  of  the  lack  of  access  to  credit.  Lending  to  this  group  is  not   profitable  because  the  poor  cannot  put  acceptable  collateral  and  the  costs  of  screening  and   monitoring  the  activities  and  of  enforcing  their  contracts  are  too  high  (Hermes  and  Lensink,   2007).  

  Microfinance  has  been  introduced  as  a  policy  option  to  reduce  poverty.  It  can  be   defined  as  financial  instruments  such  as  loans,  savings,  insurances  and  other  instruments   that  are  only  for  clients  that  have  been  excluded  from  the  formal  banking  sector.  The   majority  of  the  borrowers  use  the  financial  instruments  to  finance  self-­‐employment   activities  and  taking  loans  as  small  as  $75,  repaid  over  several  months  or  a  year  (Morduch,   1999).  James  Wolfensohn,  president  of  the  World  Bank,  pointed  out  that  helping  100  million   households  means  that  500-­‐600  million  poor  people  could  benefit  (Morduch,  1999).  The  first   microfinance  institutions  have  been  established  in  the  1980s  such  as  the  Grameen  bank   founded  by  Muhammad  Yunus.  

    The  central  question  of  this  paper  is  what  is  the  relationship  between  the  

development  of  microfinance  institutions  and  economic  growth?  Plenty  of  literatures  focus   on  the  relationship  between  microfinance  institutions  development  and  financial  

development.  Also  the  link  between  financial  development  and  economic  growth  is  a   popular  research  question  as  well.  This  may  suggest  an  indirect  effect  of  microfinance   institutions  development  on  economic  growth  via  the  financial  development,  but  not  much   work  has  been  done  to  prove  the  direct  effect.  Therefore,  this  research  aims  to  provide  

(5)

some  evidence  to  the  direct  impact  of  microfinance  institution  development  on  economic   growth.    

Barr  (2005)  argues  that  microfinance  plays  an  important  role  in  financial   development.  Hermes,  Lensink  and  Meesters  (2009)  state  that  the  relation  between   microfinance  institutions  may  be  positive  or  negative.  Moreover,  from  the  theoretical  and   empirical  literature,  it  is  expected  that  there  is  a  positive  link  between  the  financial  

development  and  economic  growth.  However,  the  evidence  of  the  direct  effect  of   microfinance  institutions  on  economic  growth  is  limited  supported  by  the  literature.   However,  the  study  offers  no  definitive  evidence  that  micro  enterprises  directly  drives   economic  growth  (Leegwater  and  Shaw,  2008).  

In  this  paper,  the  direct  link  between  microfinance  institutions  development  and   economic  growth  is  studied  using  an  empirical  approach.  This  researches  defines  various   indicators  of  microfinance  institutions  development  and  regresses  the  economic  growth  to   one  indicator  in  each  regression  with  a  bunch  of  control  variables.  A  cross-­‐section  data  set  is   constructed  by  30  developing  countries  where  microfinance  got  extensively  applied  during   the  time  period  2001-­‐2007.  Then  the  relevant  coefficients  are  estimated  by  OLS.    

From  the  regression  results  it  can  be  concluded  that  the  development  of  

microfinance  institutions  is  an  important  determinant  of  economic  growth.  The  variables   MFI,  ASSETS  and  GLP  have  a  positive  significant  effect  on  GDP  growth.  However,  the  variable   BOR  does  not  have  a  significant  effect  on  economic  growth.  This  may  be  caused  by  the  small   number  of  countries  and  the  critical  aspects  that  were  not  taken  into  account.  

The  rest  of  the  paper  organizes  as  follow.  Section  2  gives  an  overview  of  the  relevant   theoretical  and  empirical  work  done  so  far.  Section  3  describes  the  data  selection  and  the  

(6)

methodology  for  the  empirical  analysis.  Subsequently,  Section  4  gives  an  overview  of  the   empirical  results.  In  section  5  an  answer  to  the  research  question  is  formulated.    

 

2.  Literature  review  

In  this  literature  review  the  relationship  between  the  development  of  microfinance   institutions  and  economic  growth  will  be  examined.  First,  details  about  microfinance   institutions  is  provided.  Second,  a  review  of  theoretical  work  on  how  the  rising  of  

microfinance  affects  growth  of  a  country  is  conducted.  Finally,  the  empirical  results  on  this   topic  are  summarized.    

2.1  Microfinance  institutions  

Microfinance  institutions  are  financial  intermediaries  that  provide  small  collateral-­‐free  loans,   saving  deposits,  insurances,  remittances,  leasing  and  money  transfers  to  low  income  citizens   that  are  used  to  support  their  family  business  or  productive  activities  (Armendariz  de  Aghion   &  Morduch,  2005).  These  tiny  family  businesses  financed  with  microfinance  loans  improve   their  knowledge  and  skills,  health,  housing  and  have  alternative  employment  opportunities.   The  microfinance  institutions  have  been  introduced  in  many  developing  countries  like,  the   Grameen  Bank  in  Bangladesh,  Banco  Sol  in  Bolivia  and  Bank  Rakyat  in  Indonesia.  The  number   of  microfinance  institutions  increased  from  618  in  December  1997  to  3133  in  December   2005.  During  the  same  period  the  number  of  people  who  received  credit  from  these  

microfinance  institutions  increased  from  13.5  million  to  113.3  million  (Hermes  and  Lensink,   2007).    

    There  are  two  approaches  of  microfinance:  the  institutional  approach  and  the   welfarist  approach.  Each  approach  differs  in  how  the  services  of  microfinance  institutions   should  be  derived,  on  the  technology  they  should  use  and  on  how  their  performance  should  

(7)

be  assessed.  The  microfinance  industry  is  dominated  by  the  institutional  approach  (Brau  and   Woller,  2004).  The  institutional  approach  focuses  on  serving  clients  who  are  underserved  by   the  formal  financial  systems  and  want  to  achieve  finance  self-­‐sufficiency.  Brau  and  Woller   (2004)  concluded  that  for  the  provision  of  financial  services  to  low  income  citizens  

institutional  sustainability  is  needed  and  that  financial  self-­‐sufficiency  was  a  necessary   condition  for  institutional  sustainability.  Morduch  (2000)  estimated  that  only  1  percent  of   the  microfinance  institutions  are  currently  financial  self-­‐sustainable  and  no  more  than  5   percent  would  ever  be.  In  contract,  the  welfarist  approach  focuses  on  improving  the  well-­‐ being  of  participants  and  focus  on  reaching  the  poorest  and  help  alleviate  poverty  (Bhatt  &   Thang,  2001).  Their  methods  are  intended  to  determine  whether  the  institutions  are   achieving  poverty  reduction.  Welfarists  claim  that  microfinance  institutions  can  achieve   sustainability  without  financial  self-­‐sufficiency  (Brau  and  Woller,  2004).  This  debate  between   the  institutionists  and  the  welfarists  is  called  the  “microfinance  schism”  (Morduch,  2000).  It   looks  like  two  nations  divided  by  a  common  language  (Woller  and  Dunford,  1999).  According   to  Ledgerwood  and  White  (2006)  many  studies  found  a  strong  link  between  sustainability   and  outreach.  Debates  on  the  achievement  of  social  as  well  as  financial  goals  are  hindered   by  a  lack  of  information  on  social  performance.  Therefore,  there  has  been  tendency  to   emphasize  the  financial  objectives  of  microfinance.  The  social  objectives  seem  to  cause  over   lending  by  not  providing  microfinance  to  the  right  people  (Zeller  and  Meyer,  2003).    

Microfinance  institutions  operate  with  two  different  forms  of  microfinance  programs   which  are  joint  liability  group  lending  and  individual-­‐based  lending  (Hermes  and  Lensink,   2007).  The  joint  liability  group  lending  is  the  most  well-­‐known  innovation  in  the  microfinance   programs.  Microfinance  institution  focus  on  social  collateral  via  group  lending,  because   borrowers  do  not  have  physical  capital  (Brau  and  Woller,  2004).  There  is  a  joint  

(8)

responsibility  for  the  loan  which  results  in  lower  levels  of  default.  When  one  member  is  not   able  to  repay  the  loan,  the  other  members  are  required  to  cover  the  loan,  otherwise  they   lose  access  to  future  loans.  Also  the  dynamic  incentives,  regular  payment  schedules  and   collateral  substitutes  provide  successful  repayments  (Gutiérrez-­‐Nieto  et  al.,  2007).           2.2  Theoretical  review  

The  growth  of  microfinance  institutions  has  an  impact  on  financial  development,  which  will   be  summarized  first.  Next,  the  growth  effect  of  financial  development  in  general  will  be   examined.  Combining  these  two  branches  of  literatures  gives  the  indirect  channel  of  

microfinance  institutions  development  on  economic  growth.  Then,  researches  on  the  direct   link  between  microfinance  institutions  and  economic  growth  will  be  reviewed.    

2.2.1  Microfinance  institutions  and  financial  development    

Barr  (2005)  argues  that  microfinance  plays  an  important  role  in  financial  development.  First,   microfinance  institutions  might  achieve  financial  self-­‐sustainability  and  attract  private  capital   flows,  which  are  attractive  because  governments  have  to  spend  less  on  development  aid.   Second,  microfinance  institutions  might  be  an  important  development  strategy  in  the  face  of   weak,  incompetent  or  corrupt  governance.  Third,  microfinance  institutions  can  strengthen   the  banking  system  and  therefore  promote  the  financial  development.  Last,  MFI’s  play  an   important  role  in  the  domestic  demand  for  the  better  governmental  and  market  institutions   required  for  financial  development.  Barr  (2005)  suggests  that  thinking  about  financial   development  from  a  microfinance  point  might  increase  the  probability  that  financial   development  contributes  to  poverty  alleviation.    

According  to  Hermes,  Lensink  and  Meesters  (2009)  microfinance  institutional   performance  is  related  to  financial  development.  This  relationship  may  be  positive  or   negative.  There  are  different  arguments  for  the  positive  relationship.  First,  financial  

(9)

development  leads  to  an  increase  in  commercial  banks  and  their  services,  therefore  the   loans  of  microfinance  institutions  may  also  increase.  Furthermore,  microfinance  institutions   may  be  stimulated  to  reduce  costs  and  increase  efficiency  of  the  operations  by  the  increased   competition.  Second,  there  may  be  positive  spill-­‐over  effects  like  improving  skills  caused  by   commercial  banks.  Third,  financial  development  helps  improving  the  efficiency  of  

microfinance  institutions  because  of  the  sophisticated  regulation  and    the  supervision  of   financial  institution    (Hermes,  Lensink  and  Meesters,  2009).  

  The  main  argument  for  the  negative  relationship  is  the  substitution  effect.  Borrowers   may  substitute  their  loans  from  microfinance  institution  for  loans  from  commercial  banks   because  of  the  lower  costs,  the  flexibility  and  the  larger  amount  of  loans  that  can  be   borrowed  (Hermes,  Lensink  and  Meesters,  2009).    

2.2.2  Financial  development  and  economic  growth  

The  existence  of  the  correlation  between  financial  development  and  economic  growth  has   been  researched  first  by  the  economic  historians  Cameron  (1967),  Goldsmith  (1969)  and   McKinnon  (1973).  Financial  development  causes  a  more  efficient  allocation  of  capital  and   therefore  improves  macroeconomic  performance  (Levine,  2005).  More  developed  countries   have  more  developed  financial  markets.  Therefore,  it  is  expected  that  there  is  a  positive  link   between  the  financial  development  and  economic  growth  (Kahn  and  Senhadji,  2001).  

Levine  (2005)  reviewed  theoretical  and  empirical  work  on  the  relationship  between   microfinance  institutions  and  economic  growth.  Levine  (2005)  researched  that  better   developed  financial  systems  ease  external  financing  constraints  and  this  alleviates  the   mechanism  through  which  financial  development  influences  economic  growth.  

There  are  five  functions  that  may  have  an  effect  on  saving  and  investment  decisions.  First,   mobilizing  and  pooling  savings  leads  to  higher  return  activities  with  positive  implications  for  

(10)

economic  growth.  Second,  producing  information  ex  ante  about  possible  investments  and   allocating  capital  lead  to  economic  growth.  Third,  monitoring  investments  and  exerting   corporate  governance  improves  efficiency.  Fourth,  facilitating  the  trading,  diversification  and   management  of  risks  promote  economic  growth  through  enhanced  liquidity,  reduced  

liquidity  risk  and  increased  liquidity.  Last,  facilitating  the  exchange  of  goods  and  services   promotes  specialization,  technological  innovation  and  growth.  Because  these  functions  have   an  effect  on  savings  and  investment  decisions  they  also  have  an  effect  on  economic  growth   (Levine,  2005).    

Zhuang  et  al.  (2009)  reviewed  theoretical  and  empirical  literature  on  the  role  of   financial  sector  in  facilitating  economic  growth  and  supporting  poverty  reduction.  They   found  the  following  conclusions.  First,  evidence  from  cross-­‐country  and  country-­‐specific   studies  generated  that  financial  sector  development  plays  a  vital  role  in  facilitating  economic   growth.  The  empirical  study  also  found  that  currency  crises  are  easier  to  avoid  in  financial   developed  countries.  Moreover,  the  effects  of  financial  effects  of  financial  sector  

development  on  economic  growth  are  more  persistent  and  larger  in  developing  countries   than  in  developed  countries.  Last,  industries  composed  of  smaller  firms  grow  faster  in   economies  with  a  better  developed  financial  sector.  The  second  conclusion  is  that  financial   sector  development  contributes  to  poverty  reduction,  through  the  major  channel  of  

economic  growth.  Also  Rousseau  and  Wachtel  (2000)  find  a  positive  link  between  indicators   of  bank  and  stock  market  development  and  economic  growth.      

 Nevertheless,  there  were  significant  disagreements  on  the  financial  development   and  economic  growth  nexus.  Some  economists  argued  that  correlation  does  not  imply   causality.  So  the  question  was  whether  financial  sector  development  causes  economic   growth  or  economic  growth  generates  the  need  for  financial  sector  development  (Zhuang  et  

(11)

al.,  2009).  For  example,  Robinson  (1952)  argues  that  finance  does  not  cause  growth,  but  it   responds  to  demands  from  the  real  sector.    

2.2.3  Microfinance  institutions  and  economic  growth  

Microfinance  has  been  growing  fast  since  the  1970s  with  the  aim  to  reduce  poverty   and  to  stimulate  economic  growth.  Levine  (2004)  states  that  financial  systems  facilitates   growth  through  five  functions  as  mentioned  above.  These  five  functions  promote    

private  sector  development,  public  sector,  consumption  smoothening,  infrastructure  and  the   household’s  ability  to  invest  in  human  capital.  This  is  a  channel  through  which  microfinance   contributes  to  economic  growth.  The  production  created  by  small  entrepreneurship,  

improvement  in  human  development  indicators  like  health,  nutrition  and  education  and   reduction  in  poverty  effects  economic  growth  (Ravallion,  2001).  For  example,  Kai  and   Hamori  (2009)  showed  that  microfinance  institutions  tend  to  reduce  income  inequities   directly  by  easing  credit  constraints  of  low  income  citizens.  They  used  cross-­‐sectional  data   from  61  developing  countries  for  2007  and  used  the  number  of  microfinance  institutions  as   the  measure  for  microfinance  intensity.  They  also  used  the  2005-­‐2007  pooled  data  for   regression  with  the  number  of  borrowers  as  the  measure  of  microfinance  intensity.    

Leegwater  and  Shaw  (2008)  explored  the  relationship  between  micro  enterprises  and   economic  growth  by  averaging  the  1997-­‐2005  time  period.  It  was  the  first  empirical  study  to   examine  cross-­‐country  evidence  for  micro  enterprises.  The  study  tests  two  hypotheses.  First,   countries  with  larger  micro  enterprises  sectors  have  more  rapid  economic  growth  in  per   capita  income  than  their  counterparts,  even  after  controlling  for  other  known  sources  of   economic  growth.  Second,  greater  micro  enterprises  prevalence  actually  causes  more  rapid   growth  in  per  capita  income.  They  used  OLS  regression  models  and  the  IV  approach  to  test   the  hypotheses.  They  defined  microenterprises  as  firms  with  fewer  than  10  employees  and  

(12)

as  firms  with  fewer  than  20  employees.  From  the  OLS  estimation  it  can  be  concluded  that   there  is  no  significant  relation  between  micro  enterprises  and  economic  growth.  Moreover,   the  evidence  of  a  causal  relationship  for  the  10-­‐  and  20-­‐employee  definition  lacks  statistical   evidence.  Therefore,  the  study  offers  no  definitive  evidence  that  micro  enterprises  directly   drive  economic  growth.  Last,  they  found  that  the  business  environment  may  matter  more   for  the  larger  of  the  manufacturing  micro  enterprises.  Hypothesis  2  is  supported  for  micro   enterprises  with  fewer  than  20  employees.    

2.3  Empirical  results    

There  is  a  lot  empirical  work  on  the  relationship  between  financial  development  and   economic  growth.  The  seminal  work  on  this  relationship  is  done  by  Goldsmith  (1969).  He   used  the  value  of  financial  intermediary  assets  standardized  with  GNP  to  measure  financial   development.  He  assumed  that  the  size  of  the  financial  system  is  positively  correlated  with   the  provision  and  quality  of  financial  services.  He  used  cross-­‐country  data  on  35  countries   over  the  1860-­‐1963  time  period.  He  found  evidence  of  a  positive  trend  of  the  ratio  of   financial  institutions  assets  to  GDP.  However,  his  research  has  some  weaknesses.  First,  his   work  involves  limited  observations.  Moreover,  the  size  of  financial  intermediaries  may  not   correctly  measure  the  functioning  of  the  financial  system.  Last,  the  direction  of  the  causality   between  the  size  of  the  financial  system  and  economic  growth  is  not  identified.    

King  and  Levine  (1993b)  used  purely  cross-­‐country  regressions  using  data  averaged   over  the  1960-­‐1989  period  and  a  pooled  cross-­‐country  time-­‐series  study  using  data  averaged   over  the  1960s,  1970s  and  1980s  so  that  each  country  has  3  observations.  The  lack  of  

financial  data  and  elimination  of  major  oil  exporters  restricts  the  analysis  to  80  countries.     Indicators  of  the  level  of  financial  development  are:  1)  the  size  of  formal  financial  

(13)

3)  the  percentage  of  credit  allocated  to  private  firms  and  4)  the  ratio  of  credit  issued  to   private  firms  to  GDP.  They  found  that  the  indicators  of  financial  development  are   importantly  and  robustly  linked  to  economic  growth.  Moreover,  they  found  that  the   predetermined  components  of  these  indicators  significantly  predict  values  of  growth   indicators.  

  Luintel  and  Kahn  (1999)  used  a  multivariate  vector  auto  regression  framework  with   10  sample  countries  to  examine  the  long  run  relationship  between  financial  development   and  economic  growth.  The  VAR  consists  of  four  variables:  1)  Financial  depth  measured  as  a   ratio  of  total  deposit  liabilities  of  deposit  banks  to  one  period  lagged  nominal  GDP,  2)  the   logarithm  of  real  per-­‐capita  output  measured  as  a  ratio  of  real  GDP  to  total  population,  3)   the  logarithm  of  real  per  capita  capital  stock  and  4)  the  real  interest  rate.  They  analyzed  10   sample  countries  and  used  annual  data  with  a  time  span  that  ranges  from  a  minimum  of  36   years  to  a  maximum  of  41  years.  The  heterogeneity  in  the  sample  period  across  countries  is   dictated  by  the  availability  of  the  data.  VAR  is  treated  cross-­‐sectionally  by  averaging  over  the   sample  period  and  generating  one  mean  observation  for  each  country.  The  results  show  the   long  run  financial  depth  is  positively  and  significantly  related  to  the  real  income  per  capita   and  the  real  interest  rate.    

  Levine,  Loayza  and  Beck  (2000)  evaluated  whether  the  exogenous  component  of   financial  intermediary  development  influences  economic  growth.  Two  econometric   approaches  are  used.  First,  generalized  method  of  moments  (GMM)  dynamic  panel  

estimators  are  used  to  deal  with  problems  of  past  studies  like  simultaneity  bias  and  omitted   variable  bias.  Also  pure  cross-­‐sectional  instrument  variable  is  used  as  a  consistency  check.   The  three  indicators  of  financial  intermediary  development  are:  1)  liquid  liabilities  of  the   financial  system  divided  by  GDP,  2)  the  degree  to  which  commercial  banks  versus  the  central  

(14)

bank  allocate  society’s  savings  and  3)  the  value  of  credits  by  financial  intermediaries  to  the   private  sector  divided  by  GDP.  The  pure  cross-­‐sectional  analysis  found  that  exogenous   components  of  financial  intermediary  development  are  positively  related  to  economic   growth  using  five  year  averages  over  the  period  1960  to  1995  across  74  countries.  They  also   used  GMM  estimators  developed  for  dynamic  models  of  panel  data.  The  panel  consists  of  74   countries  over  the  period  1961-­‐1995.  They  averaged  data  over  five  year  periods,  so  that   there  are  seven  observations  per  countries.  The  dynamic  panel  estimates  that  the   exogenous  component  of  financial  intermediary  exerts  a  positive  impact  on  economic   growth.  

    Khan  and  Senhadji  (2001)  re-­‐examined  the  empirical  evidence  on  the  relationship   between  financial  development  and  economic  growth.  The  dataset  includes  159  countries   and  covers  the  period  1960-­‐1999.  They  used  a  pure  cross-­‐section  sample  by  averaging  along   the  time  dimension  and  five-­‐year-­‐average  panels.  They  measured  financial  depth  with  the   following  indicators:    

(i)   fd1:  domestic  credit  to  the  private  sector  standardized  with  GDP   (ii)   fd2:  fd1  plus  the  stock  market  capitalization  standardized  with  GDP  

(iii)   fd3:  fd2  plus  the  private  and  public  bond  market  capitalization  standardized  with   GDP  

(iv)   stock:  stock  market  capitalization      

They  found  a  positive  and  statistically  significant  relationship  between  financial  depth  and   growth  in  the  cross  section  analysis.  This  result  is  robust  to  the  four  different  financial  depth   indicators.  The  results  were  weaker  when  a  time  dimension  was  introduced  to  the  model.  A  

(15)

possible  explanation  may  be  that  a  linear  model  is  not  appropriate  for  explaining  growth   dynamics  of  individual  countries.  Moreover,  there  is  a  concave  relationship  between   financial  depth  and  growth.  This  may  reflect  that  poor  countries  tend  to  grow  faster  than   rich  countries.      

 

3.  Data  and  Methodology  

The  purpose  of  this  study  is  to  examine  the  direct  relationship  between  the  development  of   microfinance  institutions  and  economic  growth.  First  the  data  sources  and  variables  will  be   explained.  After  this,  the  regression  model  and  estimation  method  employed  in  this  analysis   will  be  introduced.    

3.1  Data  

The  30  developing  countries  used  in  this  empirical  research  are  given  in  table  1.  In  these   developing  countries  microfinance  got  extensively  applied.  In  this  paper  the  outlier  removal   procedure  from  Beck  et  al.  (2005)  is  used  to  correct  for  undue  influence  of  outlying  data   points.  Therefore,  only  30  countries  are  used.  The  research  includes  the  years  2001  to  2007.   Within  this  time  period  the  financial  crisis  is  excluded.  The  data  is  obtained  from  three   different  sources.  The  Mix  Market  Database  gives  all  the  relevant  information  about   microfinance  institutions.  From  the  Economy  Watch  Database  and  Worldbank  Database  all   relevant  information  about  the  dependent  variable  and  the  control  variables  is  obtained.     3.2  Methodology  

In  this  section  all  the  variables  used  in  the  empirical  model  will  be  discussed.  First,  the   dependent  variable  used  in  the  empirical  model  is  the  real  GDP  growth.  GDP  in  constant   2005  U.S.  dollars  is  used  to  calculate  the  growth  rate.  

(16)

  The  explanatory  variables  used  in  this  empirical  model  are  the  indicator  of  

microfinance  institution  growth:  1)  the  number  of  microfinance  institutions  (MFI,  hereafter),   2)  gross  loan  portfolio  (GLP,  hereafter),  3)  net  assets  (ASSETS,  hereafter)  and  4)  the  number   of  active  borrowers  (BOR,  hereafter).  The  first  variable,  MFI,  is  the  number  of  microfinance   institutions  that  are  active  in  a  year  per  country.  The  services  of  microfinance  institutions   can  facilitate  economic  growth  (Zhuang,  Gunatilake,  Niimi  et  al,  2009).  Therefore,  the   number  of  microfinance  institutions  is  used  as  an  explanatory  variable.  Figure  1  shows  a   positive  relationship  between  the  number  of  microfinance  institutions  and  economic   growth.    

The  second  variable,  ASSETS,  is  the  sum  of  all  net  assets  accounts  of  the  microfinance   institutions.  Also  this  variable  is  standardized  with  GDP.  Microfinance  institutions  have  a   more  stable  financial  position  to  establish  their  services  when  they  have  more  assets.   Through  the  channel  of  financial  development  net  assets  can  facilitate  economic  growth   (Zhuang,  Gunatilake,  Niimi  et  al,  2009).  Therefore,  the  sum  of  net  assets  is  used  as  the  third   explanatory  variable.  Figure  2  shows  a  positive  relationship  between  the  net  assets  and   economic  growth.    

The  third  variable,  GLP,  adds  up  the  total  gross  loan  portfolios  of  the  active   microfinance  institutions.  Delinquent  and  renegotiated  loans  are  included,  but  loans  that   have  been  written  of  are  excluded.  This  variable  standardized  with  GDP.  More  loans  help   allocating  more  scarce  financial  resources  to  more  profitable  and  efficient  investment   projects  and  therefore  improves  macroeconomic  performance  (Levine,  2005).  Through  this   reallocation  of  resources,  the  economic  activity  is  expected  to  increase  (Lingelbach,  De  La   Vina  and  Asel,  2005).  Because  of  this  positive  effect  on  economic  growth,  GLP  will  be  used  as  

(17)

the  second  explanatory  variable.  Figure  3  shows  a  positive  relationship  between  GLP  and   economic  growth.  

 The  last  explanatory  variable,  BOR,  is  the  number  of  active  borrowers.  This  variable   describes  the  number  of  individuals  or  entities  that  have  currently  an  outstanding  loan   balance  with  one  of  the  microfinance  institutions  in  the  country  and  is  standardized  with  the   population  ratio.  The  economic  growth  can  be  stimulated  if  the  outstanding  resources  are   divided  among  many  borrowers.  Figure  4  shows  a  positive  relationship  between  the  number   of  active  borrowers  and  economic  growth.  

  The  control  variables  used  are  population  growth  (POP,  hereafter),  employment   (EMP,  hereafter),  investment  (INV,  hereafter)  and  the  domestic  credit  to  private  sector   (CRED,  hereafter).  POP,  is  the  annual  population  growth.  EMP  is  the  employment  to  

population  ratio.  INV  is  the  total  amount  of  investments  as  a  percentage  of  GDP.  CRED  refers   to  financial  resources  provided  to  the  private  sector  by  financial  corporation  as  a  ratio  to   GDP,  such  as  loans,  purchases  of  non-­‐equity  securities,  trade  credits  and  other  accounts   receivable  that  establish  a  claim  for  repayment.  This  variable  controls  the  channel  of   financial  development  on  economic  growth.  It  is  expected  that  there  is  a  positive   relationship  between  the  domestic  credit  to  private  sector  and  economic  growth.    

The  four  different  indicators  of  microfinance  institution  development  give  four   regression  models,  each  with  one  indicator  and  the  four  control  variables:    

Regression  1:  𝐺𝐷𝑃$ = 𝛽' + 𝛽)𝑀𝐹𝐼$+ 𝛽-𝑃𝑂𝑃$+ 𝛽/𝐸𝑀𝑃$+ 𝛽1𝐶𝑅𝐸𝐷$  +  𝛽5𝐼𝑁𝑉$+ 𝜀$   Regression  2:  𝐺𝐷𝑃$ = 𝛽' + 𝛽)𝐴𝑆𝑆𝐸𝑇𝑆$+ 𝛽-𝑃𝑂𝑃$+ 𝛽/𝐸𝑀𝑃$+ 𝛽1𝐶𝑅𝐸𝐷$  +  𝛽5𝐼𝑁𝑉$+ 𝜀$   Regression  3:  𝐺𝐷𝑃$= 𝛽'+ 𝛽)𝐺𝐿𝑃$+ 𝛽-𝑃𝑂𝑃$+ 𝛽/𝐸𝑀𝑃$+ 𝛽1𝐶𝑅𝐸𝐷$+  𝛽5𝐼𝑁𝑉$+ 𝜀$   Regression  4:  𝐺𝐷𝑃$= 𝛽'+ 𝛽)𝐵𝑂𝑅$+ 𝛽-𝑃𝑂𝑃$+ 𝛽/𝐸𝑀𝑃$+ 𝛽1𝐶𝑅𝐸𝐷$+  𝛽5𝐼𝑁𝑉$+ 𝜀$  

(18)

In  these  regression  models,  𝐺𝐷𝑃$  stands  for  the  annual  real  GDP  growth  in  period  t.  𝛽)   estimates  the  indicators  of  the  development  of  microfinance  institutions  in  period  t.   𝛽-, 𝛽/  and  𝛽1  estimates  the  control  variables  on  economic  growth  in  period  t.  𝜀$  (the  error   term)  takes  on  all  the  other  factors  that  are  not  in  the  equation  that  affect  economic  growth   in  period  t.  The  empirical  models  in  this  study  are  estimated  using  Ordinary  Least  Squares   (OLS).  

 

4.  Empirical  results  

In  this  paragraph  the  empirical  results  on  the  relation  between  the  development  of   microfinance  institutions  and  economic  growth  are  presented.  The  dataset  includes  30   countries  and  covers  the  period  2001-­‐2007.  The  growth  equation  has  been  estimated  using  a   pure  cross-­‐section  sample  by  averaging  among  the  time  dimension.  Table  2  and  table  3   provide  the  estimation  results  for  the  pure  cross-­‐section.  

4.1  Control  variables  

Table  2  shows  the  estimation  results  including  the  control  variable  CRED,  while  table  3   shows  the  estimates  without  the  control  variable  CRED.  From  table  2  it  can  be  concluded   that  CRED  is  not  significant.  The  most  important  issue  here  is  the  direction  of  causality   between  financial  development  and  economic  growth.  If  the  financial  development  and   growth  are  jointly  determined,  OLS  estimation  of  the  growth  equation  may  be  biased  (Khan   and  Senhadji,  2001).  Another  reason  is  that  the  relation  between  growth  and  financial  depth   may  involve  a  “threshold  effect”,  which  means  that  countries  may  need  to  reach  a  certain   level  of  financial  depth  before  there  is  a  significant  effect  on  economic  growth  (Berthélemy   and  Varoudakis,  1996).  Therefore,  the  control  variable  credit  is  excluded  from  the  multiple   regression  models  and  we  take  a  further  look  at  table  3.    

(19)

  Also  EMP  and  POP  are  not  significant  in  all  regressions.  The  small  number  of   countries  is  a  main  reason  for  the  insignificant  findings  of  these  control  variables.  Also  the   small  amount  of  control  variables  taken  into  account  may  lead  to  insignificant  results,   because  there  are  many  factors  that  influences  the  economic  growth  of  a  country.   4.2  Explanatory  variables  

The  results  indicate  a  connection  between  the  indicators  of  the  development  of  

microfinance  institutions  and  economic  growth.  Table  3  summarizes  the  pure  cross-­‐sectional   results  for  four  regressions  where  the  indicators  MFI,  ASSETS,  GLP  and  BOR  measures  the   development  of  microfinance  institutions.    

  The  first  multiple  regression  (1)  that  is  used  to  test  the  relationship  between  the   development  of  microfinance  institutions  and  economic  growth  includes  one  explanatory   variable  and  three  control  variables.  The  first  explanatory  variable,  MFI,  is  the  number  of   microfinance  institutions  that  are  active  in  a  year  per  country.  Noticeable  is  that  MFI  has  a   positive  effect  on  GDP  growth  and  this  effect  is  highly  significant,  i.e.  significant  at  the  1   percent  level.  Based  on  this  regression  it  can  be  stated  that  for  every  unit  increase  in  MFI,  a   0.0316  unit  increase  in  GDP  growth  is  predicted.  Therefore,  we  can  conclude  that  the   development  of  microfinance  institutions  has  a  significant  and  positive  influence  on   economic  growth.    

  The  second  multiple  regression  model  (2)  includes  the  explanatory  variable  ASSETS   and  the  control  variables.  The  regression  results  are  significant  at  1  percent.  The  coefficient   estimated  for  ASSETS  is  0.0131.  This  means  that  for  every  unit  increase  in  assets,  a  0.0131   unit  increase  in  GDP  growth  is  predicted.  This  positive  and  significant  relation  between   ASSETS  and  GDP  growth  shows  that  the  development  of  microfinance  institutions  has  a   significant  and  positive  influence  on  economic  growth.    

(20)

  In  the  third  multiple  regression  model  (3),  GLP  is  used  as  the  explanatory  variable.   The  results  for  the  third  explanatory  variable  are  significant  at  5  percent.  The  coefficient  for   GLP  is  0.0164.  This  means  that  for  every  unit  increase  in  GLP,  a  0.0164  increase  in  GDP   growth  is  predicted.  This  regression  model  shows  a  positive  and  significant  relationship   between  GLP  and  GDP  growth.  This  implies  that  the  total  gross  loan  portfolios  have  a   significant  effect  on  economic  growth.    

The  last  multiple  regression  model  (4)  includes  the  explanatory  variable  BOR  and  the   control  variables.  The  coefficient  of  BOR  is  0.0155,  which  means  that  for  every  unit  increase   in  BOR  there  is  a  0.0155  increase  in  GDP  growth.  However,  the  results  are  insignificant.   Therefore,  the  number  of  active  borrowers  has  no  significant  effect  on  economic  growth.    

Microfinance  institution  development  has  a  significant  positive  impact  on  economic   growth  if  the  explanatory  variables  MFI,  ASSETS  and  GLP  are  used  as  indicators.  However,   when  BOR  is  used  as  an  indicator  the  coefficient  is  not  significant.  This  reduces  the  

robustness  of  the  results.  It  must  be  stressed  that  it’s  very  difficult  to  measure  the  very  small   contribution  of  microfinance  institutions  on  economic  growth.  Moreover,  the  small  number   of  countries  is  a  main  reason  for  the  insignificant  findings  of  this  research.  Thereby,  there  are   many  critical  aspects  that  are  not  taken  into  account,  for  example  the  level  of  financial   development  was  excluded  because  of  the  insignificant  results.  Last,  there  are  only  three   control  variables  taken  into  account  in  the  multiple  regression  models,  while  there  are  many   factors  that  influence  the  economic  growth  of  a  country.    

  In  summary,  the  regression  analysis  shows  that  the  development  of  microfinance   institutions  is  an  important  determinant  of  the  economic  growth.  However,  not  all  the   explanatory  variables  are  significant.  MFI,  ASSETS  and  GLP  have  a  positive  significant  effect   on  economic  growth,  but  BOR  does  not  have  a  significant  effect  on  economic  growth.  This  

(21)

may  be  caused  by  the  small  number  of  countries  used  in  this  research.  Also  many  critical   aspects  were  not  taken  into  account,  like  the  control  variable  for  financial  development.  The   control  variable  was  excluded  because  of  the  direction  of  causality  of  financial  development   and  economic  growth  and  the  “threshold  effect”.    

  5.Conclusion  

Many  people  in  developing  countries  remain  poor  because  they  have  no  access  to  capital.   Microfinance  has  been  introduced  as  a  successful  method  to  deliver  financial  services  to  low   income  citizens  in  developing  countries.  Microfinance  institutions  contribute  to  poverty   reduction  and  may  stimulate  the  local  economy.    

  The  central  question  of  this  paper  is:  what  is  the  relationship  between  the  

development  of  microfinance  institutions  and  economic  growth?  The  literature  focuses  on   the  effect  of  microfinance  institutions  on  financial  development  and  the  effect  of  financial   development  on  economic  growth,  which  suggests  an  indirect  effect  of  microfinance   institutions  development  on  economic  growth  via  the  financial  development.  However,  not   much  work  has  been  done  to  prove  the  direct  effect.  Therefore,  this  research  provides  some   evidence  to  the  direct  impact  of  microfinance  institutions  development  on  economic  

growth.    

To  research  the  direct  effect  of  microfinance  institutions  development  on  economic   growth  four  regression  models  are  used.  Each  regression  model  includes  one  indicator  of   microfinance  institutions  development  and  three  control  variables.  The  explanatory   variables  are  MFI,  ASSETS,  GLP  and  BOR.  The  control  variables  are  POP,  EMP  and  INV.  The   control  variable  CRED  was  excluded  from  the  regression  models  because  of  the  insignificant   results.  These  insignificant  results  may  be  caused  by  the  direction  of  causality  of  financial  

(22)

development  and  economic  growth  and  the  “threshold  effect”.  The  dataset  includes  30   countries  and  covers  the  period  2001-­‐2007.  The  growth  equation  has  been  estimated  using  a   pure  cross-­‐section  sample  by  averaging  among  the  time  dimension.  

 The  regression  results  show  that  the  development  of  microfinance  institutions  is  an   important  determinant  of  the  economic  growth.  However,  not  all  the  indicators  of  the   development  of  microfinance  institutions  are  significant.  The  explanatory  variables  MFI,   ASSETS  and  GLP  have  a  positive  significant  effect  on  economic  growth  while  the  variable   BOR  does  not  have  a  significant  effect  on  economic  growth.  This  may  be  caused  by  the  small   number  of  countries  and  the  critical  aspects  that  were  not  taken  into  account.  

  More  extensive  and  advanced  research  is  needed  to  improve  the  findings  of  this   study.  More  countries  and  more  years  should  be  taken  into  account.  Also  the  effect  of   microfinance  institutions  on  financial  development  should  be  better  examined.                            

(23)

6.  References  

Aghion  B.A.,  Morduch  J.,  2005.  “The  economics  of  microfinance”,           Cambridge,  Mass.:  MIT  Press    

Barr  M.S.,  (2005),  “Microfinance  and  financial  development”,  Michigan  Journal  of         International  Law  Vol.26,  271-­‐296.  

Bhatt  N.,  &  Tang  S.Y.,  (2001),  “Delivering  microfinance  in  developing  countries:               Controversies  and  policy  perspective”,  Policy  Studies  Journal,  29(2),  319–333.     Beck  T.,  Demirgüç-­‐Kunt,  A.  and  R.  Levine,  (2005),  “SMEs,  Growth,  and  Poverty,”  NBER         Working  Paper  11224.    

Beck  T.,  (2008),  “The  econometrics  of  finance  and  growth”,  Policy  Research  Working         Paper  4608.  

Berthélemy  J.,  Varoudakis  A.,  (1996),  Financial  development  policy  and  growth  (Paris:  OECD).   Brau  J.C.,  Woller  G.M.,  (2004),  “Microfinance  institutions:  a  comprehensive    

    review  of  the  existing  literature.”  Journal  of  Entrepreneurial  Finance,  JEF,             ISSM  1551-­‐9570,  Vol.  9,  lss.  1,  pp.  1-­‐27.  

Cameron  R.,  (1976),  “Banking  in  the  early  stages  of  industrialization”,  Oxford           University  Press:  New  York.  

Goldsmith  R.,  (1969),  “Financial  structure  and  development”,  Yale  University  Press,         New  Haven.    

Gutierrez-­‐Nieto  B.,  Serrano-­‐Cinca,  C.  and  Molinero,  C.M.  (2007),  Microfinance      

    institutions  and  efficiency.  Omega:  The  International  Journal  of  Management             and  Science  35(2):  131-­‐  142.    

Hassan  M.  K.  and  Sanchez  B.,  (2009),  “Efficiency  analysis  of  microfinance    

(24)

    Paper  12.  

Hermes  N.,  Lensink  R.,  (2007),  “The  empirics  of  microfinance:  what  do  we  know?”     Economic  journal,  117  (February),  F1-­‐F10.      

Hermes  N.,  Lensink  R.,  Meesters  A.,  (2009),  “Financial  development  and  the         efficiency  of  microfinance  institutions”.

Kai  H.,  Hamori  S.,  (2009),  “Microfinance  and  inequality”.  Munich  Personal  RePEc           Archive  (MRPA)  Paper,  No.  1757,  1-­‐57.  

Khan  M.S.,  Senhadji  A.S.,  (2001),  “Financial  development  and  economic  growth:  an         overview”,  IMF  working  paper.  

King  R.G.,  Levine  R.,  (1993a),  “Finance  and  growth:  Schumpter  might  be  right”,  The         Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  Vol.  108,  No.  3  (Aug.,  1993),  pp.  717-­‐737.   King  R.G.,  Levine  R.,  (1993b),  “Finance,  entrepreneurship  and  growth:  theory  and         evidence”,  Journal  of  Monetary  Economics  32,  513-­‐542.  

Klasen  S.,  Lawson.,  (2007),  “The  impact  of  population  growth  on  economic  growth  and         poverty  reduction  in  Uganda”,  University  of  Hoettingen  Departmental  Discussion           Papers  133.  

Leegwater  A.,  Shaw  A.,  (2008),  “How  do  microenterprises  contribute  to  economic  growth  in         developing  countries?”,  AMAP  micro  report,  No  135.  

Levine  R.,  (1997),  “Financial  development  and  economic  growth:  views  and  agenda”,       American  Economic  Association  Vol  35,  No  2,  688-­‐726.  

Levine  R.,  (2005),  “Finance  and  growth:  theory  and  evidence”,  Handbook  of         Economic  Growth,  Amsterdam:  Elsevier  Science,  2005,  pp.  865-­‐934    

Lingelbach  D.,  De  La  Vina    L.  and  Asel  P.,  (2005),  “What’s  distinctive  about  growth-­‐oriented           entrepreneurship  in  developing  countries?”,  UTSA  College  of  Business  Center  for    

(25)

  Global  Entrepreneurship,  Working  Paper  No  1,  1-­‐10.    

Luintel  K.B.,  Khan  M.,  (1999),  “A  quantitive  reassessment  of  the  finance-­‐growth  nexus:       evidence  form  a  multivariate  VAR”,  Journal  of  development  economics,  Vol  60  381-­‐       405.      

McKinnon  R.I.,  (1973),  “Money  and  capital  in  economic  development”,  Brookings         institution,  Washington,  DC.    

Morduch  J.,  (1999),  “The  Microfinance  Promise”,  Journal  of  Economic  Literature,             Vol.  XXXVII  1569-­‐1614.  

Morduch  J.  (2000),  “The  Microfinance  Schism”,  Elsevier  Science  Ltd.  Vol.  28,  No.  4,             pp.  617-­‐629.  

Pagano  M.,  (1993),  “Financial  markets  and  growth:  an  overview”,  European  Economic         Review  37,  613-­‐622.  

Ravallion  M.,  (2009),  “Growth,  inequality  and  poverty:  looking  beyond  averages”,         World  development,  29  (11),  23-­‐49.  

Robinson  J.,  (1952),  “The  generalization  of  the  general  theory”,  The  rate  of  interest         and  other  essays.  London:  Macmillan.    

Rousseau  P.L.,  Wachel  P.,  (2000),  “Equity  markets  and  growth:  cross-­‐country         evidence  on  timing  and  outcomes,  1980-­‐95.  Journal  of  Banking  and  Finance         24,  1933-­‐57.  

Stock  J.H.  and  Watson  M.W.,  (2015),  Introduction  to  Econometrics:  updated  third  edition,           Harlow:  Pearson  Education  Limited.    

Vanroose  A.,  and  Espallier,  B.,  (2009),  Microfinance  and  financial  sector  development,  CEB             Working  Paper  No.  09/040  

(26)

    Journal  of  Economic  Development,  29-­‐64.  

Zeller  M.,  Meyer  R.,  (2003),  “The  triangle  of  microfinance:  Financial  sustainability,  outreach           and  impact.  Washington,  D.C.:  The  international  food  policy  research  institute.     Zhuang  J.,  Gunatilake  H.,  Niimi  Y.,  et  al.,  (2009),  “Financial  sector  development,         economic  growth  and  poverty  reduction:  a  literature  review”,  ADB  Economics           Working  Paper  Series,  No.  173.    

                                                                   

(27)

7.  Appendix    

Table  1  Developing  countries  used  in  the  empirical  research    

Albania   Armenia   Benin   Bolivia  

Bosnia  and  Herzegovina   Brazil   Burkina  Faso   Cambodia   Cameroon   Costa  Rica   Dominican  Republic   Ecuador   Egypt   Ghana   Guatemala   Guinea   Haiti   India   Jordan   Kazakhstan   Kyrgyz  Republic   Lebanon   Madagascar   Nepal   Nicaragua   Paraguay   Peru   Senegal   Tanzania   Togo                        

(28)

Table  2  OLS  regression  for  all  explanatory  variables  separately   OLS  Regression  

Dependent  variable:  gross  domestic  product  

    (1)   (2)   (3)   (4)   Variables                   credit   0.0577   0.0531   0.0641   0.0736       (1.15)   (0.97)   (1.22)   (1.40)                       emp   2.138   0.940   1.115   1.300       (1.54)   (0.66)   (0.79)   (1.01)                       pop   -­‐0.388   -­‐0.502   -­‐0.467   -­‐0.201       (-­‐0.85)   (-­‐1.17)   (-­‐1.01)   (-­‐0.38)                       inv   0.262**   0.162*   0.197*   0.210*       (2.52)   (1.99)   (1.99)   (1.95)                       mfi   0.029**                   (2.41)                                   assets       0.0117**                   (2.53)                               glp           0.0153*                   (1.93)                           bor               0.0196                   (1.03)                       _cons   2.529*   3.857***   3.408**   2.777       (1.76)   (2.79)   (2.52)   (1.61)                       N   30   30   30   30   Notes:  

*  Statistically  significant  at  10%  level.     **  Statistically  significant  at  5%  level.   ***  Statistically  significant  at  0%  level.                

(29)

     

Table  3  OLS  regression  for  all  explanatory  variables  separately   OLS  Regression  

Dependent  variable:  gross  domestic  product  

    (1)   (2)   (3)   (4)   Variables                                       inv   0.268***    0.156**    0.198**    0.220**       (2.79)    (2.11)    (2.20)    (2.19)                       emp   2.202   0.887   1.076   1.1220       (1.43)   (0.58)   (0.70)   (0.86)                             pop   -­‐0.619*   -­‐0.718**   -­‐0.741**   -­‐0.602       (-­‐1.81)   (-­‐2.20)   (-­‐2.04)   (-­‐1.41)                             mfi   0.0316***             (2.64)                             assets       0.0131***                   (3.37)                               glp            0.0164**                   (2.03)                           bor                  0.0155                    (0.77)                       _cons   3.208***   4.573***   4.301***   4.175***       (2.60)   (4.50)   (4.35)   (3.23)                             N   30   30   30   30   Notes:  

*  Statistically  significant  at  10%  level.     **  Statistically  significant  at  5%  level.   ***  Statistically  significant  at  0%  level.                  

(30)

Figure  1  regression  line  GDP  MFI    

   

   

Figure  2  regression  line  GDP  ASSETS  

   

   

(31)

Figure  3  regression  line  GDP  GLP  

   

 

Figure  4  regression  line  GDP  BOR  

   

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

When we split the dataset into different stages of financial sustainability (financially unsustainable MFI's; MFI's growing in financial sustainability; and financially sustainable

We expect that the presumed negative effect of public debt on economic growth to be significantly larger in the years following a crisis, not only for the GIIPS

J aar lij ks wordt gemest met een comp ost g emaakt van stalmest vermen gd m et oogstafval en ander or gani sch m ateriaal dat bij het beheer vrijk omt.. Het

Mulisch en Claus werden in de jaren zestig voor twee problemen gesteld die grof- weg te verbinden zijn aan de twee niveaus waarop het literaire engagement zich manifesteert.. De

The next step in the methodology, after having found evidence of long-run cointegration relationships between stock market development, economic growth and investment, is the

Om de gedragstendens naar vrouwen toe te meten werd er een ANCOVA voor herhaalde metingen uitgevoerd voor de gemiddelde reactietijden voor vrouwelijke plaatjes met Groep (zeden

The distinction for Elder Douglas Headworth between First Nations traditional food practices and sport hunting is premised around the role of traditional foods as a way

Reflecting back on the research question, the most important key-criteria to provide a guideline in arsenic mitigation policy making in Bangladesh have been identified,