• No results found

Partij in de marge : Oorlog, goud en de Nederlandsche Bank 1933 -2000

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Partij in de marge : Oorlog, goud en de Nederlandsche Bank 1933 -2000"

Copied!
7
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

Partij in de marge : Oorlog, goud en de Nederlandsche Bank 1933

-2000

Renselaar, C. van

Citation

Renselaar, C. van. (2005, October 27). Partij in de marge : Oorlog, goud en de

Nederlandsche Bank 1933 -2000. Uitgeverij Boom, Amsterdam. Retrieved from

https://hdl.handle.net/1887/4286

Version:

Corrected Publisher’s Version

License:

Licence agreement concerning inclusion of doctoral thesis in the

Institutional Repository of the University of Leiden

Downloaded from:

https://hdl.handle.net/1887/4286

(2)

To fund its megalomaniac ambitions the Third Reich needed gold and hard currency . In early , Reichsbank p resident H jalmar S chacht told H itler that G ermany w as on the brink of bank rup tcy . G erman rearmament had absorbed more than   % of all state sp ending ov er the p rev ious six y ears. D esp ite a rigid sy stem of foreign ex change controls, bilateral trade and clearing agreements, G erman gold and foreign ex change reserv es w ere nearing dep letion. A disaster for a country that, notw ithstanding the N az is’ attemp ts to create an autark y , remained dep endent on imp orts of strategic commodities. S chacht’s w arning cost him his job. In the N etherlands, businessman E rnst H eldring, a member of the S up erv isory B oard of D e N ederlandsche B ank (   ) since  , k ep t a close ey e on ev ents in G ermany . H e w as ex tremely concerned about the gold reserv e held by    , noting in his diary that the G erman gov ernment w ould ‘dearly lov e to p inch’ that gold. This study ex p lores the v icissitudes of the monetary gold of the N etherlands in the p eriod -    , the gold held by the central bank of the N etherlands as reserv e currency . The story begins in  w hen H itler came to p ow er in G ermany and ends in     w hen the N etherlands decided to rest its claim to the gold stolen during the w ar. B y far the greatest share of the gold p ossessed by the N etherlands in M ay   did not fall into G erman hands. D uring the occup ation, G ermany managed to get hold of   ,   k g of D utch gold, of w hich  ,   k g w as ev entually recov ered. The main q uestion adressed by this study is w hy less than half w as returned to    ’s v aults.

The reconstruction of the gold’s ody ssey is undertak en from the p ersp ectiv e of   , w hich acted as ow ner and, follow ing the nationalisation in   , as guardian of the gold.    and the S tate had, and hav e, a sp ecial relationship . The manage-ment of the gold reserv e follow s from    ’s shared resp onsibility w ith the gov ernment for effecting a sound financial sy stem. L .J .A . Trip ,    p resident from  to   , took a strict v iew of his role as administrator, finding that the gold belonged to the shareholders. H is successor, M .W . H oltrop , w ho took ov er at the helm in changed circumstances in   , also emp hasised    ’s p articular resp onsibility for the gold. F aced w ith a v ast currency shortage, he felt it w as his duty as    p resident to activ ely join in attemp ts to recov er the gold, ev en though the gov ernment w as p olitically resp onsible. That is ex actly w hy    made such strenuous efforts in the y ears -    . F irstly to bring the gold to safety w hen

Summary

(3)

it realised that Hitler was heading towards war, and then, when the war was over, to recover the stolen gold bars for the Netherlands.

, established in  as a trade bank and bank of issue, was a private institution with public tasks. Its public nature was especially evident in monetary affairs, and that made it difficult to clarify ownership of the gold. While the gold formed security for banknote circulation, its management also served to stabilise the exchange rate. The central bank gold thus secured the nation’s financial health. In a strictly legal sense, however, the gold was owned by  and, in the final instance, by the shareholders collectively. This situation did not change in  when the Netherlands became the last country to abandon the gold standard. But what did change was that the autonomy of monetary policy came to an end, with the government demanding to have the last say. Meanwhile, dark clouds were gathering above Europe and  was concerned about developments in nazi-Germany. In the months following the Anschluss,  became convinced that it was no longer wise to keep the entire gold reserve in the country. But the Nether-lands was neutral, so  had to be circumspect.

Early in the autumn of , the first gold transport left the Netherlands with the government’s acquiescent support. O n the day of capitulation, May th,

almost % of the monetary gold was abroad, most of it in the U nited States. gold was the main source of income for the Dutch government which arrived in London without means. That was fraught with difficulties. In contrast to, say, the National Bank of Belgium,  had made no arrangements for the governing control of the gold in the event of a breakdown in communications between itself and the government. The foreign monetary gold was used in London for expen-ditures in the Dutch national interest. The Gerbrandy cabinet refused an urgent request from the British government for financial support during the Battle of Britain in the autumn of . The cabinet discussions at that time show little awareness that the fate of the Netherlands lay in Allied hands. This did nothing to further V an K leffens’ policy objective of positioning the Netherlands as a medium-sized power.

Meanwhile, the Germans were cunningly gaining control of the remaining monetary gold in the Netherlands. Since  was a private institution, the law of war did not permit the occupying force to confiscate the gold. It was therefore requisitioned under the pretence of a contribution to the costs of occupation. The financing of these costs, and the Nazis’ attempts to subsume the Dutch economy into the German one (V erflechtung ), would result in serious monetary chaos. During the war, Trip protested against the levy imposed by the Germans and refused to acknowledge them as valid under international law. His reservations paved the way for labelling the exorbitant German demands as ‘theft’; they enabled the Netherlands to fall in line with other victims under consideration by the Allies, who were then formulating the post-war restitution policy on stolen gold. Despite

      

(4)

its best efforts, the Netherlands was unable to exert any influence on the shaping of this policy.

At end-, the P aris Reparation C onference laid down the basic principles for the restitution of looted gold, and its distribution across the victim countries. The monetary gold discovered in Germany, and the stolen gold recovered from third countries, was deposited in a pool, managed by the Tripartite C ommission for the Restitution of Monetary Gold (   ). It was staffed by the United States, Britain and France who acted as Trustees.

The Dutch claim, of , kg monetary gold, was prepared by  and submitted by the Ministry of Finance. In  the Netherlands became involved in a conflict with the    over the , kg gold requisitioned from residents under the C urrency Bye-Law (June) . The C ommission’s well-founded argument was that  had taken the gold as an agent for the German occupying force, and not in the course of its normal statutory tasks. The C ommission could make this contention because  had not declared that the C urrency Bye-Law had been drawn up by the Dutch government and was ready for publication in the Staatsblad (Bulletin of Acts, Orders and Decrees) in May . Nor, and perhaps intentionally, had it mentioned the Emergency C urrency Measure issued by the De Geer cabinet on  May . In drawing up the claim neither , nor the Ministry of Finance or Ministry of Foreign Affairs, appear to have looked deeply into the exceptional circumstances of the German occupation and conse-quences thereof under civil law. The fact is that Reich C ommissioner Seyss-Inquart was assigned the highest governing authority on  May  and could use the Dutch administrative system to carry out his instructions. This determined the balance of power in the Netherlands. The occupying force held all the strings, as reflected for instance in the appointment of a German supervisor at  on  May .

The Ministry of Finance did not want to resign itself to the    ’s decision, but had to admit defeat in .  tacitly accepted the decision, but did not want to concede that it acted as a financial instrument for the Germans during the war. It did not face up to that fact until the late s.

Outside the official channel, the    ,  and the government themselves tried to enter into bilateral negotiations with countries where stolen Dutch gold had ended up. All these attempts ended in failure. The explanation lay in the P aris Reparation Treaty, namely in the article listing the United States, Britain and France as the countries responsible for arrangements with neutral states for the liquidation of stolen goods found there. Although the gold section of the Treaty did not name the three countries as being pre-eminently authorised to negotiate on monetary gold on behalf of third parties, it was credible, also in view of the prevailing political situation, that they should be the first to be called upon to do so. The Netherlands did not fully realise that when it signed the Treaty; it was subsequently unwilling to fully accept this fait acco m p li and even disputed it. In its attempts to launch bilateral negotiations with Switzerland, Sweden, Spain,



(5)

Portugal and Italy, the Netherlands repeatedly came up against the agreements which the Big Three had made, or were about to make, with these states. In all cases, the Dutch interest was made subordinate to the higher political objectives envisaged by the United States, the most powerful of the Three. The Dutch gold claim had to make way for more far-reaching military and politically strategic considerations, to which the Netherlands, as a member of the Atlantic alliance was also committed.

All of this emerged most distressingly in the negotiations with Switzerland, where the lion’s share of the looted Dutch gold had ended up. The Washington Accord, concluded between the Trustees and Switzerland in May , came about unbeknown to the Netherlands. That was an evil business: the Three treated Dutch interests carelessly and the Swiss deliberately failed to mention that they held far more stolen gold than they agreed to return to the gold pool. For their part, the Trustees not only knew that large quantities of gold had been stolen from the Netherlands, and that Germany had found its ideal principal banker in Switzerland, but – well before the start of the negotiations – had hard evidence that the Reichsbank had not only sold Belgian but also Dutch stolen gold to Switzerland. Owing to poor coordination and conflicts of interest between the American State Department and the Treasury, this information was not used against Switzerland. The French, aiming for a quick result, did not want to jeopardise an acceptable outcome by confronting the recalcitrant Swiss with their knowledge of Dutch stolen gold. But the Netherlands itself failed too. The press devoted much attention to the Allied/Swiss negotiations at the time. Despite all the press publicity, the Netherlands embassy in Washington, which, since the autumn of , had a memorandum on the gold theft drawn up by  and which had handed this paper to the State Department in December , apparently saw no reason to alert the Dutch government or to take any initiatives of its own. Headed by the Ministry of Finance, the Netherlands played for high stakes in the Swiss question and lost. On paper, the Netherlands was right, and it wanted to see that proved. That was an unrealistic goal, since it was obvious from the outset that the Trustees would never break open the Swiss Accord.

In the postwar political constellation only one path remained to the Netherlands to retrieve the gold stolen in the war, and that was through the . In all, , kg was recovered, representing .% of the total amount claimed, and .% of the acknowledged claim. The Netherlands did not formally accept the  decision until . The Commission had been dissolved two years earlier, on which occasion the Netherlands received the last small remainder of gold.

More than fifty years after the end of the Second World War, just over half of the gold stolen by the Germans had been returned to the vaults of . The missing share is the silent witness to a battle fought with vigour and frustration. The frustration stemmed in part from the government’s lack of insight into the political reality. The Netherlands was on the sidelines. It received a proportionate share of the pool, giving  and the government good reason to be pleased. In



(6)

the material damage caused by the German occupation was (rather liberally) estimated at almost    billion, including   . billion through confiscation and robbery. Only % of that amount flowed back to the Netherlands in some form of damage compensation. Seen in that light, efforts to recover the stolen monetary gold were glaringly successful.



(7)

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

Irony is clearly a complex concept that is difficult to define, as discussed above. In this chapter I will discern three subtypes of irony. These are theoretical, ideal types, in

In the assumption, I assume that the effects of risk shifting for the banks with a high capital adequacy ratio is relatively low, and the monetary policy and bank risk taking

I use non-performing loans, loan loss provisions and Z-score as measures for bank risk- taking, while for monetary policy the proxies are short-term interest

W at zou het schrijven van dit proefschrift moeizaam é n saai zijn gew eest zonder aanmoediging en b elangstelling van familie, mijn ouders en b roers, en vrienden en collega’s..

License: Licence agreement concerning inclusion of doctoral thesis in the Institutional Repository of the University of Leiden Downloaded from: https://hdl.handle.net/1887/4286..

Ik noem een ander voorbeeld: De kleine Mohammed van tien jaar roept, tijdens het uitdelen van zakjes chips voor een verjaardag van een van de kinderen uit de klas: ‘Dat mag niet,

In the analysis of the monetary multiplier a relationship is stated between an initial change in the supply of money and a consequently occuring change in the level of production

The World Bank's increasing ability to set the development and research agenda in Africa over the past two decades intimidated critics. Now however, protesting voices.. are