• No results found

‘The effect of market dynamism, cooperation and firm age on R&D investments of family firms: an empirical analysis’

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "‘The effect of market dynamism, cooperation and firm age on R&D investments of family firms: an empirical analysis’"

Copied!
34
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

‘The effect of market dynamism, cooperation and firm

age on R&D investments of family firms: an empirical

analysis’

By: Laura Kursten

University of Groningen Faculty of Economics and Business

MSc BA Strategic Innovation Management

20 June 2017

Supervisor: Prof. Dr. Faems

Co-assessor: Dr. de Faria

S2102978

(2)

2

Abstract

Family firms are an important form of ownership in today’s world. As family firms make

decisions not only based on firm goals but also based on feelings, the characteristics of family

firms are different from non-family firms. However, family firms cannot be seen as a

homogenous form of ownership. This paper focused on the differences in their risk-averse

behaviour and their long-term orientation to maintain their business. I researched the relation

of market dynamism, cooperation and firm age on the R&D investments of family firms. This

paper found a significant effect between firm age and family firms’ R&D investments. Furthermore, market dynamism influences the relation between cooperation and family firms’

R&D investments. This paper provides evidence that there are differences in the field of family

firms and provides ideas for further research in this field.

Keywords: Family firms; innovation; R&D investments; cooperation; firm age;

(3)

3

Introduction

It is acknowledged that family firms play an important role in the world's leading economies

(Miller & Le Breton-Miller, 2005; Zahra, 2003). Characteristically in family owned SMEs is

that family members play the role of both manager and owner (Munari, Oriani, & Sobrero,

2010). A family firm is defined by: ‘A family’s involvement in ownership and governance and a vision for how the firm will benefit the family, potentially over generations.’ (Chrisman &

Patel, 2012, p. 976) Family firms not only make decisions based on their economic goals but

typical for family firms is that they also make a lot of decisions based on their noneconomic

goals (Chrisman & Patel, 2012). Growth and survival are essential goals for family firms

because they enable family firms to be passed on to later generations (Kellermanns et al., 2008).

An important factor for firms and their ability to grow and survive is innovation (Damanpour

& Evan, 1984). According to De Massis, Frattini & Lichtenthaler (2013), there is a growth in

that family firms use technological innovation to nurture their competitive advantage and to

overcome economic and financial downturns.

Empirical research about innovation in family firms is scarce (Llach & Nordqvist, 2010). And

even though scholars have long realized that family firms are not homogenous, current literature

is mostly focused on the differences between family firms and non-family firms (Sharma,

Chrisman & Chua., 1997). Instead of focusing on the heterogeneity of family firms, literature

focused on the attributes shared by family firms to compare family firms with non-family firms

(Sharma et al., 1997). This paper will focus on the saying by Chua et al. (2012), that a theory

of the family firm must not only be able to distinguish between family and non-family firms

but must also be able to explain the differences and variations among family firms. Family firms

entail both strengths and weaknesses and the article of Cassia, De Mizzo & Pizzurno (2012)

considers that further empirical investigation is an important issue to better understand family

(4)

4

(Llach & Nordqvist, 2010). This contradictory findings may be caused by the conflicting

relationship between family firms and innovation. This is caused by the commixture of a family firm’s long-term orientation and their conservative nature (Zahra, Hayton & Salvato, 2004).

Their long-term orientation allows them to dedicate resources to innovation and risk-taking.

Whereas their conservative nature may hold them from innovation because they are afraid of

destroying their family wealth (Zahra et al., 2004). Because of this conflicting relationship of

being long-term oriented on the one hand but also risk-averse towards innovation on the other

hand (Zahra et al., 2004), this paper assumes that there will be differences in the field of family

firms.

This paper will focus on the variables market dynamism, cooperation, and firm age. In dynamic

markets, it is more important to stay progressive and dynamic instead of cautious and stable

(Cassia, De Massis & Pizzurno, 2011). That is why this paper will study if there is a difference

in R&D investment behaviour when a family firm is in a dynamic market. This paper will look

into the relation between cooperation and family firms’ R&D investments because cooperation

networks are a way of speeding up innovation (Fukugawa, 2006). Finally, I will focus on firm

age because founders of family firms, who desire to build a lasting legacy, may become more

conservative in their decisions because of the high risk of failure of entrepreneurial ventures

(Morris, 1998). Younger generation family firms adopt a more professional style and try to

reinvent themselves (McConaughy & Phillips (1999); Dyer (1988); Jaffe & Lane, 2004). In this

paper, I will answer the following question: To what extent does cooperation, market dynamism

and firm age has an effect on the R&D investments of family firms?

The first variable that will be discussed in this paper is market dynamism. In dynamic markets

the competitive landscape shifts quickly and change must be promoted to survive (Eisenhardt

& Martin, 2000). If a firm is rather conservative and risk averse, this will make them inflexible,

(5)

5

2010). Flexibility is important in a dynamic market in order to adapt to changing circumstances

and face continuous innovation (Zahra et al., 2004). That is why I will assume that in a dynamic

environment, family firms will invest more in R&D to keep up with the continuous innovation.

This paper will assume that family firms that cooperate more with external partners will invest

more in R&D. Because of external cooperation, a family firm can get access to external

resources and knowledge. Therefore family firms can build an innovation network, where the

firm is able to exchange knowledge, skills and resources that the firm cannot develop on their

own (Bullinger, Auernhammer & Gomeringer, 2004). Hereby, they may can spread the risk that

R&D investments entail.

Researchers have expressed concern that over time, some family firms become resistant to

change and follow conservative strategies that limit their future growth and profitability (Dunn,

1996; Lee, 2006; Schulze et al., 2001). This would mean that older family firms are more risk

averse than younger family firms. As they are more risk averse, they are more focused on

stability and survival (Lee; 2006, Schulze et al., 2001) The risk-taking preferences can shift

through different generations (Zahra, 2004). Little is known about the different stages of the

life cycle of family firms. Litz & Kleysen (2001) state that innovation in family-owned

companies is a responsibility for the younger generations. And that to pursue this objective, the

younger generations need to be properly trained and left free to innovate (Litz & Kleysen, 2001). This consequently has a positive effect on the family firm’s innovation (Beck et al.,

2011). I will assume that older firms will invest less in R&D investment because of their risk

aversion and conservative nature. Young firms will be more long-term oriented and will,

therefore, invest more in R&D.

This study attempts to expand our understanding of family involvement in firms. To answer my

research question, I will use the Innovation Benchmark North-Netherlands 2017, a survey that

(6)

6

Innovation Survey. The survey was sent to 5447 SMEs located in the North-Netherlands and

624 firms filled in the survey. To test the conceptual model, 3 hypotheses were developed. The

hypotheses will be tested using the negative binomial regression.

Findings indicate that firm age has a negative effect on family firms’ R&D investments. No

significant effect was found between market dynamism and family firms’ R&D investments and between cooperation and family firms’ R&D investments. Furthermore, this paper found

that there is a significant relation between market dynamism and R&D investments of

non-family firms. The relation between cooperation and R&D investments of non-non-family firms is

significant as well. Lastly, an interaction effect was found for family firms between cooperation

and market dynamism. This research contributes to existing literature by filling the literature

gap about heterogeneity in family firms.

The structure of this paper is as follows. The next section describes the existing literature about

the field of family involvement in firms and R&D investment. In this part, the hypotheses and

the conceptual model will be presented. After that, the methodology will be explained followed

by testing the hypotheses. I will use the results of the research to write the discussion and future

research directions. Finally, the paper will end with a conclusion.

Literature review

In this part of the research, I will take a closer look at the research field of innovation in family

firms and the different variables of the conceptual model. During this literature review, the

conceptual model and a number of hypotheses will be presented.

Family firms

Family ownership is the dominant form of ownership around the world (La Porta, Lopez‐de‐

Silanes & Shleifer, 1999). Family-controlled firms represent a unique bundle of resources that

(7)

7

focus on two characteristics of family firms that will be explained later on. The definition of a

family firm by most authors is based on three criteria. The first criterium is ownership, 50% of

the firm has to be owned by the family. The second criterium is governance, the family has to

control the business. And the last criterium is management, a significant proportion of the senior

management has to be from the same family (Llach & Nordqvist, 2010). Llach & Nordqvist (2010) used the definition by Chua et al. (1999) ‘who assert that it is unreasonable to use a

family firm definition that excludes a large number of respondents who consider themselves family firms’ (p. 383). This paper will also use the definition by Chua et al. (1999). This

definition is also used in the article of Chrisman & Patel (2012): ‘A family firm is defined by a family’s involvement in ownership and governance and a vision for how the firm will benefit

the family, potentially over generations.’ (p. 976)

There are main differences between the goals and values of family businesses and those of

individuals working in a firm where there is no family connection (Cassia et al, 2011). The

integration of family and business is what makes a family firm unique (Habbershon & Williams,

1999). In this manner, a firm can create impressive and uncommon characteristics. One of the

main managerial factors that differentiate family firms from non-family firms is that family

firms are more long-term orientated than non-family firms. Family firms feel less pressure for

short-term paybacks and are more focused to ensure the lastingness of their business (Cassia,

et al., 2011). Their long-term orientation can affect the strategic decisions of the firm (Sharma,

et al.). This is caused because of the strategic behaviour of family firms. Most family firms are

concentrated on incremental, regional expansion rather than rapid or wider international

expansion (Cassia et al., 2011). Nonetheless, Bergfeld & Weber (2011) state that successful

family firms use radical and progressive innovation to secure their future and long-term

orientation.

(8)

8

radical and dynamic (Chrisman & Patel, 2012). This can be explained by their risk-averse

behaviour. An explanation for the risk-averse behaviour of family firms can be their

conservative behaviour (Cassia et al., 2011). The risk of losing family wealth withholds firms

from engaging in entrepreneurial activities (Sharma et al., 1997). Family firms tend to make

choices by noneconomic family goals that create socioemotional wealth for the family

(Chrisman & Patel, 2012). Some of their decision-making is based on feelings and emotions

instead of business logic (Stewart, 2003).

Family firms and R&D investment

On the one hand, innovation is an expensive, uncertain and risky business process that very

often requires several excellent capabilities and competences to be performed successfully. On

the other hand, it is the crucial base to increase competitiveness and business development

(Schumpeter, 1934). Crossan & Apaydin define innovation as ‘the production or adoption,

assimilation, and exploitation of a value-added novelty in economic and social spheres; renewal

and enlargement of products, services, and markets; development of new methods of

production; and establishment of new management systems. It is both a process and an outcome’ (p. 1155).

Innovation can have as output either new ways of doing things or new products, services, or

techniques (Porter, 1990). To develop new product innovations or service innovations, research

and development (R&D) expenditures are needed because of the high costs of implementing

new innovations (David, Hitt & Gimeno, 2001). Investments in R&D are sunk costs that have

a long payoff horizon and entail substantial risk (Chrisman & Patel, 2012). That is why, R&D

investments are focused on the long-term and they are inherently risky in nature (Chrisman &

Patel, 2012). A lot of firms don’t engage in R&D investments because they lack the financial

resources (Binz & Czarnitzki, 2008). The risk that R&D investments constitute, require trust,

(9)

9

Berchicci (2013) found that firms with greater R&D capacity perform better than those with a low R&D capacity.

The high costs and risk of R&D investments can be seen as a disadvantage by family firms because of their risk-averse behaviour of family firms. The outcomes of investing in R&D are not shown immediate and therefore, it is a risk-taking activity (Chen & Hsu, 2009). Nevertheless, risk taking is correlated to innovative and proactive behaviour (Naldi et al., 2009). On the other hand, the ability to innovate is important for family firms to enhance their

profitability and growth (Zahra, 2004). Innovation is a driver to create wealth and ensure firm’s

long-term survival (Acs & Armington 2004; Bruyat & Julien, 2000). Consequently, when

family firms focus on the long-term existence of their firms, innovation can be an important

mechanism for family firms as they may turn into a competitive advantage that is associated

with long-run success (Chen & Hsu, 2009). When the importance of long-term goals increases

in family firms, they are more willing to invest in their long-term wealth, even though the

short-term goals may be at risk (Chrisman & Patel, 2012).

The paper of Chen and Hsu (2009) investigated R&D investments in family firms and found a

negative relationship between family ownership and R&D investment. This suggests that either

family ownership discourages risky long-term R&D investment. It can also suggest that firms

with family ownership use their R&D investments more efficiently and that is why they need

fewer R&D investments (Chen & Hsu, 2009). When the latter one is true, that will be positive

for the innovation performance of the family firm. In the article of Chrisman & Patel (2012), they found that the variability of family firms’ R&D investments is greater than that of

non-family firms, this depends on the goal-setting of the firm. When performance is at or above the

desired level, family firms are expected to invest less in R&D than non-family firms (Chrisman

& Patel, 2012).

(10)

10

Nonetheless, literature tends to focus on the homogeneity of family firms, whereas there are

many differences between family firms (Melin & Nordqvist, 2007). Family firms are

heterogeneous as they differ in terms of the extent and mode of family involvement in

ownership and management (Melin & Nordqvist, 2007). I assume that this heterogeneity of

family firms will affect their behaviour towards innovation and in particular R&D investments.

Therefore this paper developed the following conceptual model. Below, this paper will explain

the different variables that are part of the conceptual model.

Market dynamism

Nowadays, the competitive world firms operate in is highly dynamic and uncertain. Therefore

Hamel, 2000, claims that innovation is required to survive as a firm. Dynamic markets are

markets in which the competitive landscape shifts quickly and change must be promoted to

survive (Eisenhardt & Martin, 2000). For family firms, it is important to have an

entrepreneurial mindset in order to determine and exploit opportunities present in an uncertain

environment (Shane & Venkataraman, 2002).

According to Dunn, 1996, family firms are more inwardly directed. Nevertheless, in dynamic

and competitive environments, companies need a high level of strategic flexibility in order to

secure their assets and resources and to take advantage of emerging opportunities (Zahra, et al.,

(11)

11 and growth (Eisenhardt & Martin, 2000).

Strategic flexibility is important to all firms, but as family firms often been described as

conservative and slow to recognize and respond to changes in their environment, strategic

flexibility may be particularly interesting for family firms (Zahra et al., 2008). A family firm's

personal ties and strong commitment can enable them to react to environmental shifts (Zahra et

al., 2008). Staying intensely involved in the market is a manner that reduces the tendency of

family firms to stay passive and risk averse (Eddleston, Kellermanns & Sarathy, 2008). As

follows they can respond to the strategic contingencies.

Changes in the competitive, technological and global landscapes have challenged family firms

to look out for new systems and strategies to innovate and keep their market positions (Zahra

et al., 2008). This way a firm has the capacity to adapt to changing circumstances by for

instance, adopting emerging technologies (Volberda, 1996). Especially in a dynamic

environment, if family firms stay involved and active in the market, firms can stay alert and

face continuous innovation (Zahra et al., 2008).

That is why I expect that family firms in a dynamic environment will invest more in R&D to

stay innovative and adapt to the circumstances of the changing environment in order to survive

in the long-run. This will help them in their long-term orientation because growth and survival

are essential goals for family firms to maintain their business (Kellermans et al., 2008).

That is why I propose the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 1: Market dynamism has a positive effect on family firms’ R&D investment. Cooperation

Participating in external cooperation networks is gaining huge popularity among firms of all

sizes (Hagedoorn, 2002). That is because there are multiple advantages why family firms should

(12)

12

networking can be needed for a firm to achieve economies of scale or to integrate diverse skills,

technologies and competencies (Mancinelli & Mazzanti, 2008).

Another reason for family firms to develop external relationships in order to network is to

secure needed resources that the family firm does not own and are difficult to develop within

the family firm (Nordqvist & Goel, 2008).

Lastly, through growing interaction in a network, SMEs can tackle the insecurity they are

experiencing from development and use of technologies (Bullinger et al., 2004). By creating a

link between different companies, research facilities, suppliers and customers SMEs can create

a solid innovation network where they can share knowledge and profit from complementary

resources (Bullinger et al., 2004). The resources and knowledge that SMEs could gain from

external innovation partnerships might contribute to the stimulus and capacity firms need to

innovate (Hewitt-Dundas, 2006).

Keeping in mind the risk-averse behaviour of family firms, this paper assumes that cooperating

with different partners can reduce the risk of investing on your own in the needed resources.

Therefore this paper assumes that because of the new knowledge and expertise gained from the

cooperation with external partners, family firms that participate in cooperation will be more

willing to invest in R&D, whereas firms that do not cooperate a lot will be more hesitant to

invest in R&D.

That is why I propose the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 2: Cooperation has a positive effect on family firms’ R&D investments Firm age

When looking at academic literature of family firms, noticeable is that different generational

stages in a family differ in their innovation-oriented culture (Zahra, 2005). When later

(13)

innovation-13

oriented culture in the firm (Zahra, 2005). First-generation family firms show more risk-averse

behaviour in comparison with later-generation family firms. This is because of their desire to

keep the business within the family and maintain family wealth. Family firms have less pressure

for short term paybacks and more attention to ensure the longevity of the business (Cassia et

al., 2011). Consequently, founders might shy away from investing in new business development

(Zahra, 2005). This risk-averse behaviour and resistance to change might affect their innovative

behaviour and consequently R&D investments. They want to protect their legacy for future

generations. Founders of family firms favour their own children and family members over

competent employees (Chrisman & Patel, 2012).

Younger generation family firms feel the need to push for new ways to do things more than

older generation family firms (Kepner, 1991). The younger generation is more

innovation-oriented because they are more left free to innovate and long-term innovation-oriented (Litz & Kleysen,

2001). Young and relatively small start-ups engage intensively in R&D activities (Shefer &

Frenkel, 2005).

R&D investments are consequently a long-term investment (Chrisman & Patel, 2012). This

may yield competitive advantages associated with long-run success. Managers of family firms

may opt for this approach despite the associated risks (Chen & Hsu, 2009). Because of the

long-term orientation of younger generations, the family firm will become more innovation oriented.

That is why I propose the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 3: Firm age has a negative effect on family firms’ R&D investment.

Methodology

As mentioned by Van Aken, Berends & Van der Bij (2012), a theory testing approach should

be used if the literature streams are already elaborated and not scattered, but there is still a

literature gap in the theoretical explanations. In the following section the measurement of the

(14)

14

Data collection

In order to test the hypotheses mentioned in the literature review, an already available survey

is used. At the beginning of 2017 (February) an email was send to a sample of SMEs located

in the North of the Netherlands with an invitation to participate in the ‘Benchmarking innovation in the North of the Netherlands project’. Most of the questions in the survey are

based on the Community Innovation Survey (CIS). The CIS is a survey of innovation activity

in enterprises.

In 2017, the survey was send to 5447 SMEs and substantially completed by 624 companies.

This means that there is a response rate of 11,45%. Two students tried to increase the response

rate by calling the non-respondent firms in the beginning of March. The results presented in

this paper will be based on the responses of the participating companies. 49,7% of these

companies are family firms. 50,3% of the companies are non-family firms.

Variables

Dependent variable family firms’ R&D investments R&D investments will be

measured by asking firms (1) what percentage of the revenue was spend on internal R&D

activities, (2) what percentage of the revenue was spend on external R&D activities. For this

dependent variable the final questionnaire ‘Innovation benchmark North-Netherlands’ is used.

To measure the R&D investments, I will use the sum of these two questions to measure the total

percentage of R&D investments. I exclude 9 faulty responses who indicated spending more

than 100% of their revenue on R&D activities.

Independent variable market dynamism When measuring market dynamism, a set of

five statements is used. The statements are rated on a 5-point Likert scale ranging from very

(15)

15

market there are continuous changes.’ ‘Not a lot changes in our market during the year.’ ‘In our

market, volumes and delivery rates of products and services change quickly and regularly.’ These statements are derived from the final questionnaire ‘Innovation Benchmark North

Netherlands’.

Independent variable cooperation Cooperation is measured by asking firms if they

cooperated with different types of partners in the period 2014-2016. This question is derived

from the Communication Innovation Survey (CIS) and used in the final questionnaire ‘Innovation Benchmark North Netherlands’. The type of partners are (1) customers (2)

consultancy firms (3) suppliers (4) direct and indirect competitors (5) universities (6) companies

in another sector. Firms are asked whether they cooperated with the partners on a binary yes/no

scale.

If the firm cooperated with a partner, the variable measure reads a ‘1’. If the firm did not

cooperate with a partners, the variable measure reads a ‘0’. In order to use the variable in the

analysis, the paper created a count variable by summing up all the different partners. So the

count data can vary from 0 to 6 as 6 partners are identified in the questionnaire.

Independent variable firm age For this independent variable I use the final

questionnaire ‘Innovation Benchmark North Netherlands’. I asked firms to fill in the year of

establishment of their firm. To use this data, this paper adjusted the data for the measured year

by subtracting the year of establishment of the year this paper is written, 2017.

Control variables In this paper I will control for a number of variables that possibly

can influence R&D investments. The variables this paper is controlling for are introduction of

new product innovation, introduction of new process innovation, education level and firm size.

Introduction of new product innovation is measured by asking firms if they introduced any new

(16)

16

innovation is measured by asking firms if they introduced any new or strongly improved

services during the period 2014-2016. These questions are derived from the Communication

Innovation Survey (CIS). Whether a firm introduced a new innovation or not can influence the

R&D investments of that firm. For the control variable education level, this paper looked at the percentage of FTE’s in the firm that had a high level education (HBO/WO). Education level

can control for R&D investments because a high level education can foster innovation (Stam &

Wennberg, 2009). Firm size is measured in number of employees in full time employments (FTE’s). This variable has a range from 0 to 250 FTE’s. The range of 0-250 FTE’s is the most

common used range to define an SME (Ayyagari, Beck & Demirguc-Kunt, 2007). Firm size

can influence family firms’ R&D investments because large firms are more likely to secure the

funding that is needed to improve R&D (Ettlie & Rubenstein, 1987).

Method selection

For this paper, a theory-testing approach is followed as the literature field is already elaborated,

not scattered as mentioned before. For the conceptual model, the most appropriate method to

use is the Poisson regression or the Negative Binomial regression. These tests are used to

measure a dependent variable which consists of count data with a high number of zero’s. R&D

investments is positively skewed with a skewness of 2,35.

If you want to use the Poisson regression, the mean and the variance of the dependent variable

have to be similar. The difference between the Poisson regression and the Negative Binomial

regression is that the Negative Binomial has a dispersion parameter. This dispersion parameter

adjusts the variance independently of the mean, hereby overdispersion is taken into account

(Gardner, Mulvey & Shaw, 1995; Lawless, 1987). Our dependent variable family firms’ R&D

investments has a mean of 13,56 and a variance of 21,47. So in this case the Negative Binomial

(17)

17

In order to use the Negative Binomial Regression, a few assumptions have to be met. First, as

mentioned before, the dependent variable has to exist of count data with a high number of zero’s. R&D investments. From the 483 firms that filled in the questions about R&D

investments, 173 firms answered that they don’t spend any revenue on R&D investments. So

there are 173 zero’s in the variable. Count data is data, you can count instead of rank, also count

data can’t have measurements below 0. As we measure R&D investments in percentage of

revenue, we can state that this is count data. Lastly, independence of observations is required

when applying the Negative Binomial regression. As all the firms independently filled in the

questionnaire, this paper can state that there indeed is an independence of observations.

Results

Before starting to analyse the data, this paper first recoded the variable market dynamism. A

set of five statements is used as a measurement for market dynamism. Factor analysis showed

that the five statements are indeed part of the same factor. The Cronbach Alpha of all the five

items is 0,779, this means is it allowed to combine the statements. Therefore by using factor

analysis a new variable is made to combine the statements.

Descriptive statistics and correlations

As seen in table 1 below, the mean of the dependent variable R&D investments is 13,56. This

implies that family firms on average spend 13,56% of their revenue on internal and external

R&D activities. A standard deviation of 21,47 implies that the variation of R&D investments is

high. 173 family firms answered that they do not spend any revenue on R&D investments. As

reported in the table, the mean of firm size 19.82. This implies that family firms on average have 19,82 FTE’s with a standard deviation of 33.46.

Also remarkable is the high variation of high educated FTE’s in family firms. 36,83% of FTE’s

(18)

18

mean of 29,98 with a standard deviation of 36,23. Firm size has a mean of 19,82 with a standard

deviation of 33,46. When looking at cooperation, the table shows that the mean is 2,14 and the

standard deviation is 1,79. the count data of cooperation can vary from 0 to 6. So a mean of

2,14 is quite low and means that most firms do not cooperate with a lot of partners.

By looking at the correlation analysis, a first indication of interaction between variables is

provided. As shown in the table, almost all variables correlate with the dependent variable R&D

investments. Market dynamism is the only variable that does not correlate with R&D

investments. Also the correlation between firm size and firm age (0,389**) is quite high. In the

table below, you can find the means, variances and correlations of all the variables used in this

paper.

Table 1. descriptive statistics and correlation analysis

Variable Mean S 1 2 3 Correlations 4 5 6 7 8 1 R&D investments 13,56 21,47 1,000 2 Firm age 29,98 36,23 -,243** 1,000 3 Market dynamism -0,25 1,02 ,016 ,030 1,000 4 Cooperation 2,14 1,79 ,146* ,005 -,037 1,000 5 Introduction of product innovation 1,46 0,50 -,303** -,037 -,033 -,267** 1,000 6 Introduction of process innovation 1,50 0,50 -,154* ,116 -,205** -,142* ,195** 1,000 7 Education level 36,83 33,77 ,340** -,295** -,045 ,094 ,054 -,159* 1,000 8 Firm size 19,82 33,46 -,149* ,389** ,074 ,035 -,155** -,045 -,263** 1,000

* Correlation is significant at the 0,05 level ** Correlation is significant at the 0,01 level

Hypotheses testing

Table 2 presents a summary of the results of the Negative Binomial Regression. The omnibus

test shows that the overall model is significant and therefore a good fit. Model 1 only includes

our control variables. All the control variables correlate significantly and positively with R&D

(19)

19

positive significant relation between introduction of a process innovation and family firms’

R&D investments disappears.

In model 2, the independent variables are added to the model. Hypothesis 1 presents the

relationship between market dynamism and family firms’ R&D investments, comparing the

ordinal data from market dynamism with the count data from R&D investments. In model 2 it

is clear that there is no significant relation between cooperation and family firms’ R&D

investment. So, hypothesis 1 will be rejected.

Hypothesis 2 presents the relationship between cooperation and family firms’ R&D investment.

In model 2 there is no significant relation between cooperation and R&D investments. This

means that hypothesis 2 will be rejected.

Hypothesis 3 presents the relationship between firm age and family firms’ R&D investments.

In model 2, there is a negative significant relation between firm age and family firms’ R&D

investments (p<0,05). This indicates that older firms invest less in R&D (β =-0,008).

Hypothesis 3 is therefore supported

Table 2. Negative Binomial Regression for Family firms

Variables Model 1 Model 2

β SE β SE Control variables Introduction of product innovation 1,099** 0,193 1,114** 0,202 Introduction of process innovation 0,499** 0,195 0,314 0,217 Education level 0,012** 0,002 0,911** 0,003 Firm size -0,003 0,003 0,000 0,003 Independent variables Market dynamism 0,130 0,099 Cooperation 0,020 0,052 Firm age -0,008** 0,003 N 145 145 Wald chi-square 124,72 100,13 Log-likelihood -501,977 -496,836

(20)

20

In table 3, another Negative Binomial Regression is performed. In this table the results are

shown for non-family firms. When analysing this table, noticeable is that there are differences

and similarities between family firms and non-family firms.

When looking at the control variables the significant effects of introduction of product

innovation, introduction of process innovation and education level are the same in table 2 in

comparison with table. However as shown in model 2 of table 3, there is a negative significant

effect between firm size and R&D investments. In table 2, this effect is nonsignificant.

When looking at the independent variables, the differences between family firms and

non-family firms are noticeable. The significant effect between firm age and non-family firms’ R&D

investments as shown in table 2, is non-existent in table 3. There is no significant effect between

firm age and the R&D investments of non-family firms. However, there is a positive significant

effect between market dynamism and R&D investments of non-family firms (β=0,234).

Furthermore, there is a positive significant effect between cooperation and R&D investments

of non-family firms as shown in model 2 of table 3 (β=0,275). When looking at table 2, there

is no significant effect between market dynamism and family firms’ R&D investments or

between cooperation and family firms’ R&D investments. This means that when non-family

firms operate in a dynamic market, they will invest more in R&D. Also, when non-family firms

cooperate with a lot of partners, the R&D investments will go up. For family firms, this effect

(21)

21

Table 3. Negative Binomial Regression for non-family firms

Variables Model 1 Model 2

β SE β SE Control variables Introduction of product innovation 0,579** 0,188 0,401* 0,194 Introduction of process innovation 0,090 0,192 -0,220 0,205 Education level 0,017** 0,003 0,014** 0,003 Firm size -0,008** 0,002 -0,006** 0,003 Independent variables Market dynamism 0,234* 0,101 Cooperation 0,275** 0,056 Firm age -0,005 0,005 N 133 133 Wald chi-square 79,34 36,30 Log-likelihood -501,977 -490,917

* Correlation is significant at the 0,05 level ** Correlation is significant at the 0,01 level

Post hoc analyses

Additionally, I researched if there is an interaction effect between the different independent

variables. The interaction effect is shown in table 4 and table 5. I tested the interaction effect

for all the three independent variables. As shown in the tables the interaction effect is tested for

family firms and non-family firms. In model 3, the interaction effect between market dynamism

and cooperation is tested. In model 4, the interaction effect between market dynamism and firm

age is tested. Lastly, in model 5, I tested the interaction effect between cooperation and firm

age.

As shown in table 4, the interaction effect between market dynamism and cooperation is

significant (p<0,01) in model 3. The interaction effect in model 3 is a negative interaction effect

(β=-0,142). Below, the interaction effect is shown in a figure in order to interpret the effect.

Furthermore there is no interaction effect found between market dynamism and firm age. In

(22)

22

Table 4. Negative Binomial regression: Interaction effects for family firms

variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5

β SE β SE β SE β SE β SE Control variables Introduction of product innovation 1,099** 0,193 1,114** 0,202 1,020** 0,204 1,086** 0,202 1,113** 0,201 Introduction of process innovation 0,499** 0,195 0,314 0,217 0,148 0,223 0,325 0,217 0,306 0,219 Education level 0,012** 0,002 0,911** 0,003 0,013** 0,003 0,011** 0,003 0,011** 0,003 Firm size -0,003 0,003 0,000 0,003 -0,001 0,003 0,000 0,003 0,000 0,003 Independent variables Market dynamism 0,020 0,052 0,486** 0,158 0,020 0,133 0,134 0,099 Cooperation 0,130 0,099 0,061 0,053 0,024 0,052 0,005 0,066 Firm age -0,008** 0,003 -0,008** 0,003 -0,009** 0,003 -0,009* 0,004 Interaction effect Market dynamism X Cooperation -0,142** 0,051 Market dynamism X Firm age 0,003 0,002 Cooperation X Firm age 0,001 0,002 N 145 145 145 145 145 Wald chi-square 124,72 100,13 84,03 97,51 81,72 Log-likelihood -501,977 -496,836 -492,837 -496,046 -496,768

* Correlation is significant at the 0,05 level ** Correlation is significant at the 0,01 level

The interpretation of the interaction effect can be found in figure 1. Because the interaction

effect between market dynamism and cooperation is significant, a graph was made in order to

interpret the effect. When looking at the figure, it shows that when market dynamism is low,

R&D investments will go up when the level of cooperation increases. On the other hand, when

there is a high level of market dynamism, R&D investments go down when the level of

(23)

23

Figure 1. Interaction effect

As shown in table 5, there are no significant interaction effects between market dynamism and

cooperation or between market dynamism and firm age. This is different from table 4 where a

significant negative interaction effect between market dynamism and cooperation on R&D

investments for family firms was found. The interaction effect between market dynamism and

firm age is not significant as well. This result is in line with the result for family firms in table

4. In model 5 is shown that the interaction effect between cooperation and firm age is not

(24)

24

Table 5. Negative Binomial regression: Interaction effects for non-family firms

Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5

β SE β SE β SE β SE β SE Control variables Introduction of product innovation 0,579** 0,188 0,401* 0,194 0,401* 0,194 0,433* 0,195 0,403* 0,194 Introduction of process innovation 0,090 0,192 -0,220 0,205 -0,218 0,206 -0,201 0,205 -0,220 0,205 Education level 0,017** 0,003 0,014** 0,003 0,014** 0,003 0,014** 0,003 0,014** 0,003 Firm size -0,008** 0,002 -0,006** 0,003 -0,006** 0,003 -0,007** 0,003 -0,006* 0,003 Independent variables Market dynamism -,275** 0,056 0,229 0,131 0,334* 0,139 0,236* 0,103 Cooperation 0,234* 0,101 0,274** 0,058 0,280** 0,056 0,282** 0,135 Firm age -0,005 0,005 -0,005 0,005 -0,006 0,005 -0,005 0,008 Interaction effect Market dynamism X Cooperation 0,003 0,056 Market dynamism X Firm age -0,006 0,005 Cooperation X Firm age 0,000 0,003 N 133 133 133 133 133 Wald chi-square 79,34 36,30 35,51 97,51 Log-likelihood -501,977 -490,917 -490,916 -496,046

* Correlation is significant at the 0,05 level ** Correlation is significant at the 0,01 level

Robustness checks

To make sure that the results in this paper are also significant when performing the tests in a

different way, a few robustness checks are performed. First, when looking at the variable

cooperation, there is another way of measuring this using the final questionnaire ‘Innovation

Benchmark North-Netherlands’. To measure cooperation, firms were asked: ‘Has your

company collaborated with other companies or institutions for its innovation activities in the

period 2014-2016?’ Cooperation is measured on a binary yes/no scale. If the firm collaborated with other firms or institutions, the variable measure reads a ‘1’. If the firm did not collaborate

(25)

25

when applying this alternative measurement. The relation between firm age and family firms’

R&D investments is still significant and also the interaction effect between market dynamism

and cooperation on family firms’ R&D investments is still significant. All the other effects are

insignificant.

The second robustness check this paper performed was excluding the variable firm size from

the analyses. As shown in table 1, the correlation between firm size and firm age is quite high

(0,389**). By excluding firm size in the Negative Binomial regression, I will check if the

results of the analyses are robust. Looking at the results without the variable firm size, no

significant changes are spotted. This means that the results of the analyses are robust.

Discussion

For this study, different effects on family firms’ R&D investments were researched. One of the

hypotheses is supported, where as other hypotheses got rejected. First, there was no significant

relation between cooperation and family firms’ R&D investments. This is in contradiction with

the hypothesis in which this paper predicted that there would be a positive relationship between cooperation and family firms’ R&D investment. I predicted that this relationship would be

positive because the resources and knowledge gained from external cooperation can contribute

to the stimulus and capacity to innovate of a family firm (Hewitt-Dundas, 2006). When looking

further into the literature the article of Acquaah (2012), stated that that on the one hand family

firms have an actively involved management, nonetheless, they are also considered to have an

inexperienced and ineffective management. So, family firms can be involved in external

cooperation networks, nonetheless if you do not use those networks effectively they will not

have value for the firm.

Also, no significant effect was found between market dynamism and family firms’ R&D

(26)

26

R&D investments. According to literature, it is important to stay involved in a dynamic market

(Eddleston et al., 2008). By use of R&D investments, it is possible for family firms to adapt to

the changing circumstances in the market (Volberda, 1996). However this statement is not

supported in this research.

Furthermore, this paper found a negative significant effect between firm age and family firms’

R&D investments. This confirms the literature saying that there is a difference between younger

generations involved in the family firm and older generations (Zahra, 2005). By focusing on

protecting their legacy, older family firms may miss the opportunity to invest in R&D and be

more innovation-oriented (Zahra, 2005).

By analysing the results, the research question can be answered. For one part of the research

question it can be stated that there is a significant effect on family firms’ R&D investments as firm age showed a positive significant relation with family firms’ R&D investments. The

Negative Binomial regression showed a small but significant effect (β=-0,008), whereas no

significant relations were found for the other variables. Concluding, to answer the research

question, this paper states that firm age is the only variable that affects the R&D investments

of family firms.

In the results section, on top of the results between the different variables and family firms’

R&D investments, this paper looked at the results for non-family firms. A comparison is made

between family firms and non-family firms. Here we can see that there are differences between

the relationships with R&D investments between family firms and non-family firms. Family

firms and non-family firms differ a lot in how they manage their organizational structures,

entrepreneurial orientation, risk taking and innovation (Naldi et al., 2007). So, it is not that

uncommon that the results between family firms and non-family firms differ. Whereas family

(27)

short-27

term profit maximization (Acquaah, 2012). A remarkable difference was that in non-family

firms, a significant relation was found between cooperation and R&D investment, whereas in

family firms this relationship was not significant. When the level of cooperation go up the

investments in R&D for non-family firms will go up as well. Moreover, the relation between

market dynamism and R&D investments was found positively significant. So when non-family

firms operate in a highly dynamic market, there investments in R&D will go up. Lastly, no

relation was found between firm age and R&D investments. So firm age does not have an effect

on the height of R&D investments of non-family firms. Whereas this relationship had a positive

significant effect for the R&D investments of family firms. This may be caused by the

long-term orientation of family firms. The strategy of family firms is more focused on being cautious

and stable, whereas non-family firms may be more progressive and dynamic (Chrisman & Patel,

2012). Because of this strategy, non-family firms might take more risk overall, not taking in

mind the age of the firm. Because of differences in ownership structure of family firms and

non-family firms, different outcomes can occur because they make different choices (De Massis

et al., 2012). Non-family firms focus more on profit and economic measures to main the firm,

whereas goals of family firms are more focused on protecting and maintaining the family

members (Cassia et al., 2011).

This paper performed post-hoc analyses where the interaction effect between the independent

variables was tested. In table 3, an interaction effect was found between market dynamism and

cooperation. In figure 1, the interpretation of the interaction effect is shown, where we can see

that when market dynamism is low, R&D investments will go up when the level of cooperation

increases. The decision to cooperate with a diverse pallet of external partners depends on the

behaviour of main decisionmakers in a firm (Classen et al., 2012). So, the interaction effect

may be explained through the risk-taking behaviour of the family firm. In a dynamic market,

(28)

28

firm. When cooperating with external partners, there can be a risk of leaking information

(Belderbos et al., 2004).

Theoretical implications

This paper contributes to existing literature by analysing various variables that differentiate

family firms from each other. Hereby, this paper advances our understanding of family firms. I

used two mechanisms in order to develop the hypotheses, on the one hand long-term orientation

and on the other hand risk-averse behaviour. This paper provides an indication that older family

firms invest less in R&D than young family firms. Furthermore, this paper provides an

indication that market dynamism affects the relation between the level of cooperation and family firms’ R&D investments. This indicates that in a highly dynamic market, when the level

of cooperation goes up, this will result in declining R&D investments. Keeping in mind that

more research has to be done to and this research is a small contribution in the field of research

on family firms. This paper filled in the literature gap of the heterogeneity of family firms

towards their R&D investment behaviour. This paper provided evidence by looking at different

variables in the field of family firms. By looking at the heterogeneity of family firms about

R&D investments in family firms (Chrisman & Patel, 2012), this paper contributes to existing

research.

Managerial implications

Regarding this research, this paper came up with managerial implications for family firms to

look into. A key finding of this research is that older firms invest less in R&D. R&D investments

are a long-term investment that focuses on innovation within the firm. As a firm it is important

to focus on R&D investments because these investments can benefit the firm in the long-term.

A characteristic of family firms is that they are focused on growth and survival to pass on their

(29)

29

longevity of the family business. Therefore, it is important for managers of a family firms to

invest in R&D, even when the result is not immediately showable. It can eventually ensure the

longevity of the business. By better control and evaluation, family firms can calculate the

risk-taking beforehand in order to minimize the risk (Naldi et al., 2009). However, risk-risk-taking cannot

be entirely controlled by a firm, it is also about being flexible and informality, so family should

not try to control everything (Naldi et al., 2009).

Limitations and future research

Regarding to this research, a few limitations and future research subjects were found that are

discussed below. The amount firms spend every year on R&D investments can differ. The ‘Innovation Benchmark North Netherlands’ is focused on the time period 2014-2016. If a firm

spends a lot of their revenue on R&D in one year. It can happen that in another year, the firm

wants to focus on developing another department of the firm. R&D investments are a risky

long-term investment. furthermore R&D requires a large amount of sunk-cost investment (Kor,

2006). So because of the sunk-costs that are part of the R&D investments, it might happen that

the amount firms spend on R&D is really diverse every year. This can have an impact on the

results. As already argued by Chrisman & Patel (2012), R&D investments are focused on the

long-term. Looking at R&D investments in a longer period, may give more reliable results.

Due to time and available resources, this paper was limited to SMEs in the north of the

Netherlands. Future research can focus on a larger region to see if the results would also be

robust when you apply them to different regions or larger regions. By focusing on a larger

region or a different country, the research can become more diverse. In this way, the results

become more reliable.

The measurement of R&D investments can differ from other methods and may influence the

(30)

30

investments by R&D investments divided by sales and R&D investments divided by assets.

Using multiple ways to measure a variable makes a research more robust.

Lastly, when looking at the results and the comparison between family firms and non-family

firms. It is confirmed that there are differences between the two types of firms. In future

research, the different outcomes in the different tables regarding the interaction effect between

market dynamism and cooperation on R&D investments can be further explored. When

performing qualitative research and using interviews as a research method, further research can

explore how come this interaction effect exists and why it is not applicable to non-family firms.

Conclusion

This study provides an insight in the research of family firms. The purpose of the study was to

provide statistical evidence for different variables on family firms’ R&D investments. To

conclude, this papers shows that firm age has a negative effect on R&D investments of family

firms. Furthermore, different significant results were found between family firms and

non-family firms, as cooperation and market dynamism have a positive significant effect on R&D

investments for non-family firms. Lastly, significant results were found in the interaction effect

between market dynamism and cooperation. Their long-term orientation helps them to focus on

innovation, but there risk-averse behaviour can hold them back and might make the firm

inefficient. This paper contributes to the literature of family firms by looking at heterogeneity

in family firms related to R&D investments. This study provides opportunities for further

research to look into the interaction effect between market dynamism and cooperation.

(31)

31

References

Acquaah, M. (2012). Social networking relationships, firm‐specific managerial experience and firm performance in a transition economy: A comparative analysis of family owned and nonfamily firms. Strategic Management Journal, 33(10), 1215-1228. Acs, Z., & Armington, C. (2004). Employment growth and entrepreneurial activity in cities.

Regional Studies, 38(8), 911-927.

Ayyagari, M., Beck, T., & Demirguc-Kunt, A. (2007). Small and medium enterprises across the globe. Small business economics, 29(4), 415-434.

Beck, L., Janssens, W., Debruyne, M., & Lommelen, T. (2011). A study of the relationships between generation, market orientation, and innovation in family firms. Family

Business Review, 24(3), 252-272.

Belderbos, R., Carree, M., Diederen, B., Lokshin, B., & Veugelers, R. (2004). Heterogeneity in R&D cooperation strategies. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 22(8), 1237-1263.

Berchicci, L. (2013). Towards an open R&D system: Internal R&D investment, external knowledge acquisition and innovative performance. Research Policy, 42(1), 117-127. Bergfeld, M. M. H., & Weber, F. M. (2011). Dynasties of innovation: Highly performing

German family firms and the owners’ role for innovation. International Journal of

Entrepreneurship and Innovation Management, 13(1), 80-94.

Binz, H. L., & Czarnitzki, D. (2008). Financial constraints: routine versus cutting edge R&D Investment.

Block, J. H. (2012). R&D investments in family and founder firms: An agency perspective.

Journal of Business Venturing, 27(2), 248-265.

Bruyat, C. and Julien, P-A. (2000), “Defining the field of research in entrepreneurship”,

Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 16, pp. 165-80

Bullinger, H., Auernhammer, K. and Gomeringer, A. (2004). Managing innovation networks in the knowledge-driven economy. International Journal of Production

Research, 42(17), pp.3337-3353.

Cassia, L., De Massis, A., & Pizzurno, E. (2011). An exploratory investigation on NPD in small family businesses from Northern Italy. International Journal of Business,

Management and social sciences, 2(2), 1-14.

Cassia, L., De Massis, A., & Pizzurno, E. (2012). Strategic innovation and new product development in family firms: An empirically grounded theoretical framework.

International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behavior & Research, 18(2), 198-232.

Chen, H. L., & Hsu, W. T. (2009). Family ownership, board independence, and R&D investment. Family business review, 22(4), 347-362.

Chirico, F., & Nordqvist, M. (2010). Dynamic capabilities and trans-generational value creation in family firms: The role of organizational culture. International Small

(32)

32

Chrisman, J. J., & Patel, P. C. (2012). Variations in R&D investments of family and nonfamily firms: Behavioral agency and myopic loss aversion perspectives.

Academy of management Journal, 55(4), 976-997.

Chua, J. H., Chrisman, J. J., & Sharma, P. (1999). Defining the family business by behavior.

Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, 23(4), 19-19.

Chua, J. H., Chrisman, J. J., Steier, L. P., & Rau, S. B. (2012). Sources of heterogeneity in family firms: An introduction. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 36(6), 1103-1113.

Crossan, M. M., & Apaydin, M. (2010). A multi‐dimensional framework of organizational innovation: A systematic review of the literature. Journal of management studies, 47(6), 1154-1191.

Damanpour, F., & Evan, W. M. (1984). Organizational innovation and performance: the problem of"organizational lag". Administrative science quarterly, 392-409.

David, P., Hitt, M. A., & Gimeno, J. (2001). The influence of activism by institutional investors on R&D. Academy of management Journal, 44(1), 144-157.

De Massis, A., Frattini, F., & Lichtenthaler, U. (2013). Research on technological innovation in family firms: Present debates and future directions. Family Business Review, 26(1), 10-31.

Dunn, B. (1996). Family enterprises in the UK: a special sector?. Family Business

Review, 9(2), 139-155.

Dyer, W. G. (1988). Culture and continuity in family firms. Family Business Review, 1(1), 37-50.

Eddleston, K. A., Kellermanns, F. W., & Sarathy, R. (2008). Resource configuration in family firms: Linking resources, strategic planning and technological opportunities to performance. Journal of Management Studies, 45(1), 26-50.

Eisenhardt, K. M., & Martin, J. A. (2000). Dynamic capabilities: what are they?. Strategic

management journal, 1105-1121.

Fukugawa, N. (2006). Determining factors in innovation of small firm networks: a case of cross industry groups in Japan. Small Business Economics, 27(2-3), 181-193.

Gardner, W., Mulvey, E. P., & Shaw, E. C. (1995). Regression analyses of counts and rates: Poisson, overdispersed Poisson, and negative binomial models. Psychological bulletin, 118(3), 392.

Habbershon, T. G., & Williams, M. L. (1999). A resource-based framework for assessing the strategic advantages of family firms. Family Business Review, 12(1), 1-25.

Hagedoorn, J. (2002). Inter-firm R&D partnerships: an overview of major trends and patterns since 1960. Research policy, 31(4), 477-492.

Hewitt-Dundas, N. (2006). Resource and capability constraints to innovation in small and large plants. Small Business Economics, 26(3), 257-277.

Jaffe, D. T., & Lane, S. H. (2004). Sustaining a family dynasty: key issues facing complex multigenerational business‐and investment‐owning families. Family Business Review,

(33)

33

Kellermanns, F. W., Eddleston, K. A., Barnett, T., & Pearson, A. (2008). An exploratory study of family member characteristics and involvement: Effects on entrepreneurial behavior in the family firm. Family Business Review, 21(1), 1-14.

Kepner, E. (1991). The family and the firm: A coevolutionary perspective. Family Business

Review, 4(4), 445-461.

Kor, Y. Y. (2006). Direct and interaction effects of top management team and board compositions on R&D investment strategy. Strategic Management Journal, 27(11), 1081-1099.

Lawless, J. F. (1987). Negative binomial and mixed Poisson regression. Canadian Journal of

Statistics, 15(3), 209-225.

Lee, J. (2006). Family firm performance: Further evidence. Family business review, 19(2), 103-114.

Litz, R. A., & Kleysen, R. F. (2001). Your old men shall dream dreams, your young men shall see visions: Toward a theory of family firm innovation with help from the Brubeck family. Family Business Review, 14(4), 335-351.

Llach, J., & Nordqvist, M. (2010). Innovation in family and non-family businesses: A resource perspective. International Journal of Entrepreneurial Venturing, 2(3-4), 381-399.

Mancinelli, S., & Mazzanti, M. (2009). Innovation, networking and complementarity: Evidence on SME performances for a local economic system in North-Eastern Italy.

The Annals of Regional Science, 43(3), 567-597.

McConaughy, D. L., & Phillips, G. M. (1999). Founders versus descendants: The profitability, efficiency, growth characteristics and financing in large, public, founding-family-controlled firms. Family Business Review, 12(2), 123-131.

Melin, L., & Nordqvist, M. (2007). The reflexive dynamics of institutionalization: The case of the family business. Strategic Organization, 5(3), 321-333.

Miller, D., & Le Breton-Miller, I. (2005). Management insights from great and struggling family businesses. Long Range Planning, 38(6), 517-530.

Munari, F., Oriani, R., & Sobrero, M. (2010). The effects of owner identity and external governance systems on R&D investments: A study of Western European firms.

Research Policy, 39(8), 1093-1104.

Naldi, L., Nordqvist, M., Sjöberg, K., & Wiklund, J. (2007). Entrepreneurial orientation, risk taking, and performance in family firms. Family business review, 20(1), 33-47.

Porta, R., Lopez‐de‐Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (1999). Corporate ownership around the world.

The journal of finance, 54(2), 471-517.

Porter, M. E. (1996). Competitive advantage, agglomeration economies, and regional policy.

International regional science review, 19(1-2), 85-90.

(34)

34

Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The theory of economic development: An inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest, and the business cycle (Vol. 55). Transaction publishers. Shane, S., & Venkataraman, S. (2000). The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of research.

Academy of management review, 25(1), 217-226.

Sharma, P., Chrisman, J. J., & Chua, J. H. (1997). Strategic management of the family business: Past research and future challenges. Family business review, 10(1), 1-35. Shefer, D., & Frenkel, A. (2005). R&D, firm size and innovation: an empirical analysis.

Technovation, 25(1), 25-32.

Stam, E., & Wennberg, K. (2009). The roles of R&D in new firm growth. Small Business

Economics, 33(1), 77-89.

Stewart, A. (2003). Help one another, use one another: Toward an anthropology of family business$. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 27(4), 383-396.

van Aken, J., Berends, H., & Van der Bij, H. (2012). Problem solving in organizations: A methodological handbook for business and management students. Cambridge

University Press.

Volberda, H. W. (1996). Toward the flexible form: How to remain vital in hypercompetitive environments. Organization science, 7(4), 359-374.

Zahra, S. A. (2003). International expansion of US manufacturing family businesses: The effect of ownership and involvement. Journal of business venturing, 18(4), 495-512. Zahra, S. A. (2005). Entrepreneurial risk taking in family firms. Family business review,

18(1), 23-40.

Zahra, S. A., Hayton, J. C., & Salvato, C. (2004). Entrepreneurship in family vs. Non‐Family firms: A Resource‐Based analysis of the effect of organizational culture.

Entrepreneurship theory and Practice, 28(4), 363-381.

Zahra, S. A., Hayton, J. C., Neubaum, D. O., Dibrell, C., & Craig, J. (2008). Culture of family commitment and strategic flexibility: The moderating effect of stewardship.

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

Although the effect for R&amp;D in Germany is not stronger than in the US, the results under the robustness tests provide evidence for a small, less negative (or

The result that ‘glamour firms’ earn significant negative abnormal returns in the post-acquisition period independent of the method of payment is in line with Rau and

Reminding, that age enhances strategic change, innovation such as R&amp;D investments is of high strategic importance and that R&amp;D is a risky investment, directors need

Data was gathered from three databases: the Thomson SDC database, Thomson Datastream, and Orbis. These databases helped to compile a sample of European firms and information

Tobin’s q is measured as the market value of common equity plus the book value of total assets minus common equity and deferred tax all divided by the book value of total assets..

Although firm-specific factors, such as tangibility, size, risk, profitability, and growth opportunities, are found to be strong and in line with capital

Finally, the use of PET tracers has advantages over [I-123]MIBG in cardiac sympathetic innervation imag- ing. Carbon-11 labelled meta-hydroxy-ephedrine [C- 11]mHED has been

According to results, political ties have significant influence on firms’ R&amp;D investment, whereas this paper does not observe an obvious effect of political ties on