• No results found

Intertemporal speculation, shortages and the political economy of price reform

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Intertemporal speculation, shortages and the political economy of price reform"

Copied!
26
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

Tilburg University

Intertemporal speculation, shortages and the political economy of price reform

van Wijnbergen, S.

Publication date:

1993

Document Version

Publisher's PDF, also known as Version of record

Link to publication in Tilburg University Research Portal

Citation for published version (APA):

van Wijnbergen, S. (1993). Intertemporal speculation, shortages and the political economy of price reform.

(Reprint Series). CentER for Economic Research.

General rights

Copyright and moral rights for the publications made accessible in the public portal are retained by the authors and/or other copyright owners and it is a condition of accessing publications that users recognise and abide by the legal requirements associated with these rights. • Users may download and print one copy of any publication from the public portal for the purpose of private study or research. • You may not further distribute the material or use it for any profit-making activity or commercial gain

• You may freely distribute the URL identifying the publication in the public portal Take down policy

If you believe that this document breaches copyright please contact us providing details, and we will remove access to the work immediately and investigate your claim.

(2)

~ti

CBM

?

R

for

gg23

mic Research

1993

~ ~IïJI"n(II II`I II

I~I~~I~II IIIII II~II~ ~III~I~I ~I~II ~~I~I II~II ~~~I I~~I

Intertemporal Speculation,

Shortages and the Political

Economy of Price Reforrn

by

Sweder van Wijnbergen

Reprinted from The Economic Journal,

Vol. 102, No. 415, 1992

~ ~~

J~,~P

Repri nt Series

(3)

CENTER FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH

Board

Harry Barkema Helmut Bester

Eric van Damme, chairman Frank van der Duyn Schouten Jeffrey James

Management

Eric van Damme (graduate education) Arie Kapteyn (scientific director)

Marie-Louise Kemperman ( administration) Scientitic Council

Anton Barten Eduard Bomhoff Willem Buiter Jacques Drèze Theo van de Klundert Simon KuiPers Jean-Jacques Laffont Merton Miller Stephen Nickell Pieter Ruys Jacques Sijben

Université Catholique de Louvain Erasmus University Rotterdam Yale University

Université Catholique de Louvain Tilburg University

Groningen University

Université des Sciences Sociales de Toulouse University of Chicago University of Oxford Tilburg University Tilburg University Residential Fellows Lans Bovenberg Werner Guth Anna-Maria Lusardi Jan Magnus Theodore To Karl W~rneryd Research Coordinators

Eric van Damme

Frank van der Duyn Schouten Harry Huizinga

Arie Kapteyn

CentER, Erasmus University Rotterdam University of Frankfurt

Princeton University

CentER, LSE

University of Pittsburgh

Stockholm School of Economics

Address : Warandelaan 2, P.O. Boz 90153, 5000 LE Tilburg, The Netherlands

(4)

Q~i'i c

~Q~~Í~

for

Economic Research

Intertemporal Speculation,

Shortages and the Political

Economy of Price Reform

by

Sweder van Wijnbergen

Reprinted from The Economic Journal,

Vol. 102, No. 415, 1992

(5)

Thr F.enrtanrr Jneernal, to2 ~:Vae~rnebo rr~r~ti, r~ir~,, r.to~i Pnnled in Grrn! Bn[nm

I~TERTE~IPORAL SPECULATI0~1,

SHORT:`GES A~D THE POLITICr~L EC0~10~IY

OF PRICE REFOR~~I~`

,Sr.ueder uan 66'ijnber~rn

Hvw should prices be decuntrolled, slvwly or in a bi,g bang? Whv is it that Governments committed tv eventual price flexibility so often seem to be unable to let go of `temporary' contrvls? How can one explain that after price increases early in a proqrammc of price controls, output often rises while at the same time shortages also increase (Bresser, sg87?? This paper argues that intertemporal speculation, hoardin,g and the pvlitícal economy of price reform go a long way towards explainin.g all these puzzles. ~Ve show that the interaction between shortages and pvlitical vulnerabilitv of reformist s;overn-ments to early perceptivns of failure make lór a strong ar,gument Rgainst gradualism in the decvntrol of prices.

Price controls are often used as substitutes for, rather than complements of, regular fiscal and monetary restraint; thev thus ended up suppressing rather than curing infiation. More recently they have scen more sophisticated use, as transitional devices in stabilisation programmes that also encvmpassed orthodox components ~Mexico and Israel are successful examples).

The literature on price controls has focused on their potential macro-economic rationale (Dornbusch and Simonsen, tg87; Persson and van 1Nijnbergen, 1 g8g}. This paper abstracts from the question of why price controls are used. Instead it asks a difíerent question, one that is perhaps of greater practical importance: how to escape from a period of controls? The issue is of much wider importance than the stabilisation policy examples suggest; all of Eastern Europe has been living under price controls, imposed for a verv difïerent reason. How should countries like Poland or the ex-L' SSR move towards price Hexibility, gradually or in a`big bang'?

Two factors complicate the issue. Often price controls focus on commodities that are storal~le and thus can be used in intertemporal speculation. This was acute in Braail, where in tg8~ price controls were introduced which were verv much seen as temporary. Bresser (tg87), who was the finance minister at the time, states: `There was shortage of inerchandise in stores at the [same] time that stocks were accummulating in the factories'.

The second factor is that opposition to rapid dismantling of controls is often based on claims of low supply~ response, and greatly bolstered if a strong

supply-' Fnr claboration on some of the more technical details of this paper tha readcr is referred to the workinq paper senion ican Wijnbergcn, tggt i, s.hich is as~ailable on request from the author. I am indebted to `tax Corden, Ales Cukierman, .~ntonio Estachq Arye Hillman, Santiago Lecs, Dani Rodrik, Lars Svensson and seminar participants at the ~Vorld Bank, the IMF, Princcton, Pennsyhania State and the wharton School for helpful comments. The ciews esprcssed in this paper do not necessaril~. coíncide with those of the institutions I am affiliated with.

(6)

1396 THE ECONOMIC JOURAAL ~NOVEMBER response indeed fails to materialise. This is especiall~~ relevant in places like Eastern Europe, where experience with price responsive markets is limited. A less benign argument also lends support to a link bet„'een low supply response and opposition to relaxing controls. Shortages create rents, and rents will attract lobbyists in favour of continuation of those policies that create the rents.

We show the difficulties that these two factors create for gradual decontrol of prices. We endogenise the probability of a collapse of the reform programme along the lines of the recent literature about the impact of political considerations on economic policy (see in particular Alesina and Cukierman ( t ggo) ) and show that such endogeneity in thé presence of intertemporal speculation leads to a strong case against gradualism.

I. SPECULATION AND SUPPLI' RESPONSE TO GRADUAL

PRICE DECONTROL

I. t. The Basic Model

The traded sector uses labour only, and at constant returns to scale; thus the real wage w is fixed in terms of traded goods. Returns to scale are decreasing in the non-traded sector, because of a fixed factor in the background (land). There are many producers, s0 individual producers cannot affect the price, or, in the case ofcontrols, aggregate shortages. Non-traded output toda}~ equals I', and output tomorrow y. The cost function far current (future) non-traded

production equals C' (c) :

i7) Capital ( lower casej letters represent first {second~ period variables.

Output produced todav can be sold toda~. or stored for sale tomorro~ti-. Since there are only two periods, output produced tomorrow will be full~. sold. CToods stored toda~., S', lead to goods available from stora,,e in period ~ according to the technolog}. ~:

S- rr~(S) i ~(O) - O, O G~i' C I, ~!" G O. (~)

Part Of goods stored goes t0 waste due to spoilage, pests and so on. Thus there are positive marginal costs of storage (yi' e t j. ~~'e also assume that the marginal costs increase with the amount stored ~~" c o).

The market clearing price in period t f2) is P~` 'p~`1. Controls are imposed in the non-traded sector only. Beforr the announcement of decontrol, prices were set at P, - p„ C P~`,~i~`, G'old turlcey drennlrol implies immcdiate transition to market prices in both periads. Cradual deconlrol implies a pricc- increasr in lieriud t that falls short of;oing to market prices: P~ e P~` ; whilc a full move tu markc~t prices is announced for period two.

Call p the probability that the decontrol program will be abandoned. 11'e assumc that when the programme of gradual decontrol is abandoned in pcriod ~., the controls will be kept at their levrl of pcrir~d t, i.e. in that ca;e ~~9 - 1'p. A

(7)

Igg2~ POLIT[(:AL ECONO~il' OF PRICE REFORM t397 collapse ol thc c.old turkcy clecontrol programme does not have such an ohvious delàult position; we assume that if the cold turkey programme collapses, prices in period two will he sct at thc pre-decontrol Ievel P~. Both producers and consumers takc P as uivcn.

Producers ha~e to choose today's output and level of inventories before knowing whethcr the C,vvernment will implement its announcements for period two or whether the programme will coliapse halfway. However second period output can be chosen after period 1 Government policies have become clear. The second perioci pmduction decision is thus a simple static optimisation

problem:

Nocollapse: ~Iax(p~`[y~`f~(,S)]-c(w,y~`)iyCy(y~`) -p~`,

Colla Se: ~Iax;PP~ ~(y~-F-4~(,5') ]-clw,y~)f'-yc !„ y~) -P.,

(3)

[n general p9 ~ p~. ~1~'e will however omit the subscript.

In period one producers have to choose output Y and the part of output put in storage. S, knowing that in period two thev will follow the rules laid out in

(3). This leads to the following masimisation problem:

íV1ax ( Y-S1 Pp-C'(w, Y) fa',P{(y~-~(.S)]p-c(w,yj} subject to o~.S c Y

,~, s

(4) rs - t ~( t f r) with r the exogenous world real interest rate in terms of traded

goods. ~r7 is the expectations operator. The first order conditions are:

CY-Po~~' ~

-P9fS~'~up-~.l-fc - o. ~ (~)

.l(~e) is the shadow price associated with tkie constraint S 1 o(S e Y). (~) indicates that output will be increased until its marginal cost equals the value of an extra unit of output. This latter value equals the price plus any additional shadow price picked up by im-entories if they are constrained by the fact that additions to inventories cannot exceed total production.

Inventories are chosen so as to equalise the value of an extra unit of output today ( P~) with the discounted value of an ertra unit tomorrow (drr5'rB9 pl. Of course if inventories hit a corner solution ( o or Y), that equality cannot be brought about and either.t or,te becomes positive, driving a wedge bet~veen the marginal benefit of an extra sale today versus an extra sale tomorrow. Clearly, higher prices lead to higher output in each period:

~

dP - C:.

D

~ o, p~ - cYy(y~`) ~ o~ dPo - cYV (y~) ~ o.

(6)

The analysis for `cold turkev' decontrol follows along similar lines.

(8)

1398

THE ECONOMIC JOURNAL ~NOVEMBER describes aggregate consumer behaviour' ; without rationing, this function gives the minimum level of expenditure necessary to reach welfare level U:

E- E[n (P'~ t), an(p~`, t), Cr]- (7)

The derivatives of E with respect to prices yield tlie Hicksian demand functions. 17 and n are exact price indices for current and future consumption corresponding to the utility structure underlying ( ~). However, when price controls are binding, consumer demand is not met at quoted prices. Define

virtual prices as the prices at which consumers would willingly consume the

rations allocated ( see Neary and Roberts ( t g8o) ):

aE[II(P„ t),...] -

h

dE[...,~r(pr, t),U] - n

()

Pt'. ~p - AR; ~r~ ~` - ar, ~

where AR ;a;) is the ration allocated in period t 'pfe~riod 2).

Under gradualism, consumers' intertemporal budget constraint is:

3T f Poí Y-S) -Cf óóo[p( y-1-si -c] - E (g)

while under a cold turkey approach we get:

3T-~P~`(~'-S)-Cfb~Pr,[p(y-~s~-c] - E (to)

3T is output in the T sector. The welíàre gain due to a small increase in the ratiun is proportional to the wedge benveen controlled and virtual prices:

i

Er.d~,, - ( P,.-Poi. (tt) x

For given collapse prubability p(which will be endogenised in the next section), the model is closed in each period by either a market clearing equation

for the :~'T market in case market prices prevail, or by an equation defining

virtual prices if price controls are operating and binding (equations (8)). ~~'ithout price controls, market prices follow from .1'T market eyuilibrium:

Y-S -

c~E

~E y f ~ (-S) - c-jj~ .

aP

(t2)

I.2. Aggregale S'upply Resj~onse, Hoardin; and Gradualism

Consider first the case where the inventory problem has an interior solution .S'~`, and .l - fe - o lFig. t;; van ~Nijnbergrn ( t yy t) shuws that if S~` e~iscs, it is uniyue. Difièrentiati~ic; ~,5) indicates the rclation betwren thr optimal level of hoarding .S~` and the cullapse probability p:

d.S

~~ll~~`-P„)

~ yj~

cu.

~t3)

dp ~"'

~!' - t -

"~

.

r~I~hi~ ia an appruxirnatiun bcc:.usc une slrould u.~r rlrc ccn:.inl~ cyuivalrnr uf thr .ccuud Ex.riod pricc

(9)

Tt~C)~2~ P~)LI'I'iI:,SL h;f;~)NOMY t)F PRICE RECORH I:jJ(~

A'I --- ----

---0

Ai I Low Po: H.S'

0 P I

Fiq. i. Nrt aGqrc~atr ~upply .ind ihe prnbability nf crillap~c.

If there is a collapse, anticipated capital gains will not materialise, because in that case controls remain. Theretbre, a greater likelihood of collapse implies a,;reater likelihood of no price rise between today and tomorrow, and thus reduced hoarding incentives. So as credibility declines (p increases), hoarding declines and the observed supply response Y-S increases ( HS, Hoarding Schedule, Fia. t).

If credibility is very low, a cornr.r solution may be reached where no

intertemporal speculation is profitable, S- o and ~l ~ o í the Aat segment in

Fig. t). This will clearly obtain lor the extreme case of no credibility at all (p - t). At p- t, prices are not expected to rise, there will therefore not be any hoarding and the H.S curve intersects the p - t axis at Y'~.

Compare now two stabilisation programmes, each `gradualist' : prices are

moved partially in period one but fully liberalised in period two. One programme is more gradualist tlian the other in that the initial price response is smaller ~`Low Pg' versus `High PQ'). A higher first period control price P9 increases the optimal level of first period output for given incentives to hoard

~cf (5) ). This means that the flat part of the hoarding schedule ! where hoarding

is zero and output at Y~), shifts up by the increase in Yp:

J~-dP -C;,;,~o. (14i

9

Also, higher initial prices mean lower percentage capital gains once the market is liberalised. Thus the incentive to hoard will decline:

dS

- (p}`Bsp~P9) ~~ c o.

dPg Noae - ~"~ci~

Therefore .~2 1;~1, with ~1.2 defined as indicated in Fig. t:

dS

(t5)

~., - ~t-dpQ

l pest ~ Ol. ( t6)

(10)

1400 THE ECONOMIC JOURAAL ~NOVEMBER there will be less first period rationing, and hence less spill over into the market for second period home goods (EyP ~ o). Thus p~ will be lower, further reducing hoarding incentives; hence the area H.here .l - o shifts even further left. Thus for given collapse probability p, bolder decontrol programmes (larger initial price increases) will lead to less hoarding, larger increases in output, and as a consequence, much less problems .vith shortages.

II. SHORTAGES AND THE PROBABILITY OF REFORM FAILURE

In most of the literature, credibility of policy reforms is exogenous. But assuming exogenous credibility clearly limits the usefulness of the analysis, since the impact of an.~ polic}- will most likely depend on whether it is going to be sustained or not. Ize and Ortiz ( t g87) and Dornbusch ( I g8g) endogenise credibilitv, linking credibility to various macroeconomic variables. The equilibria they consider have primajacie plausible features. But their reliance on an arbitrary relation between programme credibility and macro variables makes one ..~onder whether that relation itself, for all its empirical plausibility, would not be afíected b}. economic policy.

ln this paper we break new ground by drawing on recent innovations in the analysis of the impact of political considerations on economic policy. Intuition suggests a link between aggregate shortages in the earl}~ stages of the programme and the likelihood that the programme will be abandoned halfwa~~. Reform programmes can be aborted for many reasons. Government officials mav be bribed by lobbyists seeking the rents created by the price controls. A balance of payments crisis mav make it impossible to continue the exchange rate policy on w~hich many such de-contrul programmes are built. The political opposition may gather strength if the initial results are disappointing. ~'e focus on the latter argument, arguably the most relevant one for Eastern Europe.

At the beginning of period 2, before the Government can implement the second stage of its reform programme, it faces a vote which determines whether it can continue or whether the opposition takes over in period 2. p is the probability that the latter happens. The ke. questiun is, what determines ~i? The vote is de jac~o a vote for or against price controls, since the opposition will reimpose (or continue) them. Voters vote for or against dependíng on the impact of controls in period 2 on their personal welfare. Pricr rises have a negative welfare eflect proportional to the initial ration receivrd. But the} will be beneficial to the extent they raise supply, since at the margin, marginal utility of one extra unit (P~) exceeds the posted price Po:

n

EudPo--Ait}(P`-Pu) ~~t~

(11)

I~92~ POL!'1'ICAL F.(;OYOA1ti' UF PRICE REFUR~1 t~r1l continuum ofvoters, indexed by s. Deline.x - d( ~"-.Sj~dP. Voters entcr period one ~~ith a particular prior distribution on x, and observe output respon~e in period one. "Chev use that information to updnte their prior into a posterior distribution used to assess the welfàre eRècts ofcontrolled versus uncontrulled prices in period s. [n rrpdatin~ their prior, voters use Baves~ rulc. Thev are ranked in ascendins; ordcr of their prior beliefon the value of x. Equation ~ r 7 ~ vields the x at which price chan~eti have zeru wrlCare eHèct, x~:

h

a- .~f ,t

~ t 8 i

` IP~-P~)~

~~-elfare maximisin~ voters will vote ves or no depending on w~hether their posterior mean is greater or smallcr than a~.

There is simple majority voting, and voters' preferences ocer the various alternatives are single peaked. Thercfore the median voter, sm, casts the decisi~e vote.' Voters know their own estimate of a and form rational expectations about econumic a~J7rel;ates, but thev do not know e~ery other voter's estimate of x. In particular thev do not know the magnitude of ,x~ sm), the rnedian voter's estimate of the supply elasticitv. ~'oters' beliefs on thc ma~nitude of a~sn,) are summarised bv a density function f. which we assume to be the same scross voten.' Since the median voter determines the election outcome, the probabilitv that the Government will be voted out before the second part of ics decontrol programme equals the probabilin. that a(s,~) e a~:

~0 I~r~ ~XJm C a~)

-J

3t f(~.srn) IÍx,m. ~ 19)

xam-- z

To assess how hoarding in period I affects the probabilitv of collapse of the programme of price decontrol, consider how the updating process w.ill affect

f(am). Voters do not know each other's individual preferences, but they do

know that each voter updates his prior with Bayesian updating. li pdating w~ill

shift f(am) such that f contracts towards the voter who has a prior mean equal

to the value observed in period t. But the voter with prior mean x~ is more relevant, since that is the cut-off point for the voting procedure.

The voter at a~ will shift up, down or stay ~vhere he is depending on whether

the observed supply elasticity in period t exceeds, talls short of, or equals a~. All voters whose prior mean esceeds the supply elasticitv actuallv observed in period I revise their estimate of a downward. Thus if enough hoarding takes place to make the net supply response smaller than a,., the voter with prior mean eqttal to a~ shifts to the left and more weight is concentrated in the part

off defined over (- oo, a~) . The probability of collapse therefore increases if

there is enough hoarding to cause a net supply response below a~ and uice t.ersa if the actual suppl,v response exceeds a~. Withf' the distribution function of a.,m i A votc carly in a major reform programme is likelv to tx dominated bv ~.~hether voters do or do not support the proqramme. ~~'ith such a singte issue contest, median voter models are plausible descriptions o( how voting mechanisms are likeh~ to work icL Enelow and Hinnich ~ ~q8{)j.

(12)

14os

THE ECONOMIC JOURNAL ~NOVEMBER

after the shift triggered by the incorporation of new information at the end of period I, we get:

Y-Y-S

.Í~(a.,~)~ -.Í~(a.," f 0.~.) ~ ~.m - ( t -'~) ( oPa oPo -a,m

a~

~ p(Yo- Yo-S) -p~ao(Po-Po)~ -

~Í(a.m)~-.Ï(a,m)~ darm

a.w--m

a~

J

- y0-yo gJla.tn) ualtn

,`a~tci-tri

PI-Po

7 o if (Yo-Yo-S)~(Pp-Po) c a~

(so)

G o if (Yo-Yo-S)~(Po-Po) ~ a~.J

Equation ( so) indicates a negative relation between p and net aggregate supply response (the schedule VDS, for Voters Dissatisfaction Schedule, in Fig. ~.

0

P

Fig. s. Impact of aggrcgate supply response on collapsc probabiliry.

Which way will this locus shift when a more gradual reform is implemented

(i.e. a smaller price increase (Po - Po) in period t)? Difíerentiating (so)

indicates the answer:

J

Y'-Yo-fY-Y

S)(I-~)

aiP(Yp-Yo-S)-p~a~(Po-Po)~} -

Po-Po

'

o-aPp

-

(Po-Pa)~

colp(Yo-Yá-S)~ co ~ oJ ~ o. (2I)

(13)

[r~t~~!~ PULITI(;AL Et;U!~U~1ti' nF PRICE REFURM I.}r)`j is smaller. 'I~his implics a lar~;rr shift to the left Ídowmvard revision nf prior means! and thus a hi~hcr culLtpse probahilit}~ in the low P9 casr than in thr high P~ case ~111 this makes li,r a cuunterclockwise rotation oCthe [~DSschrcíule, tr, ['D.ti' in Fig. ~~, in rrspunse to a murc~ ,gradualist llower Pq~ dcct,ntrr,l pru~ramrnr.

III. GRADUALISM, HOARlllNG AND THE POL["rICAL ECONOMY OF PRICE REFORM

~~'ith thc twt~ building blocks (the Hoarding Schcdule HS' and the Voters Dissatisfàctiun Schedule G'D.Sj derived, w-e can e~camine the consequrnces for credibility and supply response Of a gradual price decontrol progamme.

H.S' in Fig. g indicates, for a given collapse probabilitv p, how much producers chouse to hoard. A higher collapse probabilitv leads to lower expected future prices and thus gives less uf an incentive to hoard. The H.S' locus thrrefore slopes up. But more huarding luwers thr perceived supply elasticity and therrfore strengthens the voters' assessment that the programme is failing; this in tw-n increases the probability that the Government will be voted out. Thus the political economy schedule G'DS slopes downward.

Y,-Yo-P

Fig. 3. Hoarding, cullapse probabilics and price decontroL a rational expectations equilibrium.

Rationality requires that the probability of programme collapse used in producers' hoarding decisions will indeed come out if those hoarding decisions are in fact implemented. This will be the case at E, the intersection of the Hoarding Schedule and the Voters Dissatisfaction Schedule. Thus E represents a rational expectations equilibrium for a given gradual decontrol policy that sets first period prices at Po and promises to liberalise in period s. At pB, producers hoard SE for a total ( negative} supply response Yp,E-Yo-SE. In turn, such a negative supply response leads to a private revision of the collapse probability that exactly matches pE.

The equilibrium at E has many plausible features. Output rises, as current prices increase.~ Thus the initial unemployment costs of such a decontrol will ' Sce Ortiz ; t qgo), Brasv ( t g87) and Hclpman ! t q881, on rcspectively Macico, Brazil and Israel. In each

(14)

1404 THE ECOIvOMtC JOL'R1AL ~NOVEMBER be quite small or even absent. How~ever, in spite of increased output and higher prices, net suppl}~ actually reaching the market declines as producers increase inventories, hoping for later capital gains. Therefore, shortages develop, to the point that the net observed suppl~ elasticitp is in fact negative.

This in turn generates pressure against the decontrol policy, increasíng the

probabilitv that the programme will have to be abandoned for a prolonged period of controls before the final deregulation phase is reached.

Consider the consequences of a more cautious start of the programme (a lo~,.er initial period level of the controls). A lower initial price, for given collapse probabilit~ p, results in larger capital gains once prices are liberalised. Thus for given p, hoarding will in fact increase: HS shifts down to HS' in Fig. 2. If p would not change, the new equilibrium would be at .9 in Fig. 2. Uf course more hoarding implies a more negative perceived supply elasticit}~, which in turn leads to a higher p. Thus, if the I'DS schedule itself would not shift, a new equilibrium would emerge at 9', w~ith more hoarding and higher collapse probabilitv: p,,- ~

Pe-But there is more: for given nct aggregate suppl~~ response, a lower elasticity is implied. because it is in response to a smaller price change; priors thus get revised do".nw~ards more than they would under the less gradual decontrol programme and the collapse probability incrrases í T'D.S' shifts out to T'DS'). Thus the new- eyuilibrium is at E', with an unambiguously higher probabilit}- of collapse: pF. 1 p~. ) pE. Thus a more gradual approach !o price decontro! actually

increase.s the collapse probabilily.

Huwever, although there will be an unambiguousl}~ lower output response to more gradual decontrol, the impact on net aggregate supply is less clear. Un the one hand, there is more hoarding for given p since the capital gain then iticrcases; but on the other hand there will be less hoarding brcause p increases, thus reducing the likelihood that this larger capital gain "~ill in fact materialise. But it is clear from Fig. ~ that the net supply responsr inclusive of hoarding „~i11 remain nrgative if it was so to begin ,,.ith.

The samr machinerv c~m be used to assess' culd turkr~ ~ clrconn-ol approaches (Fig. .~). L~nder a cold turkev appruach, prices are immediatrl,- and full,~

(15)

tgg~] POL[TICAL ECONOb1Y UP PRIGE REFOR~1 [~Oj liberalised. Tluts if thr. appruach is m:tintaincd, prices will be market determined in both periods. C;ndcr tlte assumptions made, the first period frce market price P~ will equal the second period price~ p~`. Thus withuut credihilitv problems, there would be no hoarding, as waitin,S Ibr tomorrow will not brin,~, higher prices to ofTset storage and interest costs.

Credibilitv problems strengthen this result. If p J o, there is a positive probability that second period prices will be lnwer than first period prices, in case controls get reimposed; this would lead to capital losses on inventories carried into period ~z. Thus with a`cold turkey' approach, there are strong

disincenliues to lioard.

Therefore, if dis-hoarding would be possihle, a cold turkey approach would lead to a mu~.h larger observed net supply response than under gradualism.

This is because in that case, if there is any credibility problem at all, goods will

in fact be pulled out of inventories, for sale today rather than tomorrow. But distioarding is not possible in our set-up, so under 'cold turkey' decontrol, the zero-inventory-build-up case ( .~ - o) will ahvays obtain. This means that the line labeled HS~~ in Fig. ~}, a horizontal line at Y~t- Y~ ~ Y9-Yo 1 0, represents the cold turkey case. Thus lhere will be no áoarding under lhe cold tiv-key

approach.

The second clear result relates to credibility ( the equilibrium ~.alue of p~. Since P' ~ Py, the G'DS schedule rotates further, clockwise and still crossing thc same zero point ( compare VDS~~ with b'DSQ in Fig. 4 1. The cold turkev equilibrium is at the intersection of VD.S~~ and HS~~, at E~,. Since there is no hoarding under a cold turkey approach, there will be a high obser~~ed supply elasticitv and thus a low probabiliry of progrnmme collapse p~, ~lower, for example, than p(o)).

For comparison of the cold turkev decontrol strategy with a gradualist approach, consider two possible configurations for the latter. If the initial distortion is so small that there would be no hoarding at all in the gradual case either ( i.e. ~l - o and net supply equals Yy~, Cr.,.,. ~ o would imply a smaller supply response per unit of price increase than obser~-ed under the CT approach.

This in turn would impl}' a larger assessed probabilitv of collapse. So even if

there is no hoarding under gradualism i mild initial distortions and ~1 - o!, gradual programmes will be less credible than cold turke~~ programmes if

Cy.},}, G o. Vloreover, since ~1 - o cases have been excluded í we onlv consider

se~~erelv dístorted cases), there will always be hoarding under gradualism. Therefore, there is more of a downward revision of~ the supply elasticitv than in the.l - o case, reinforcing the result just derived for the,~ - o case. In terms of Fig. .}, HS9 falls below the line Y~- Yo at least for its initial ses;ment, and cuts

VDS9 more to the ri,ght. But a lower observed suppl}- elasticitv implies a higher

likelihood oi~ programme collapse!

(16)

1406 THE ECONOMIC JOURNAL ~NOVEMBER iggs~

Thus cold turkey programmes will unambiguously be more credible than gradual

programmes that actually cause increasing shortages in their initial phase ( pEg ~ p(o)); and even tJgradual programmes do not cause increasing shortages ( pED ~ p(o)), cold turkey decontrol programmes will still be more credible if C}1,}. G o.

IV. CONCLUSION

Should price controls be abolished `cold turkey' or can a case be made for gradualism' Two factors complicate the issue and are at the core of this paper. Price controls often focus on commodities that are storable and can thus be used in intertemporal speculation. Second, opposition to dismantling of controls is often based on claims of low supply response, and greatly bolstered if a strong supply response fails to materialise. This is especially relevant in Eastern Europe, where experience writh markets is limited.

We shoH' the difficulties that these two factors create for gradual decontrol of prices. ~~-e endogenise the probability of a collapse of the reform programme and show- that such endogeneity in the presence of intertemporal speculation leads to a strong case against gradualism. The smaller the initial price increase, the lower the observed supph' elasticity and the greater the probability that the programme of reform w'ill be abandoned.

This implies that the policy that makes most sense from a microeconomic point of view' (decontrol immediately) is also advisable from a macroeconomic point of view'. Credibility problems, which are at the core of the transitional output losses that characterise most stabilisation programmes, will be much less under a cold turke}' approach and so will therefore transitional unemployment.

The ti4'orld Bank and CEPR

Date ojrereipt ojfnal typescript: April iggs

REFERENCEs

Alesina, A. and Cukicrman, A. ( rggo). 'Thc politia of ambiguity.' Qumtaty Journat nf Economirs, vol. 4, PP. 8zy-5 t .

Rresscr, T. r iqlt~i. 'Incrtial inFlatinn and thr Cruzado plan.' 11'nrtd Drudopmrnt, vol. tg, pp. in3,i-q4. Dornbusch, R tryi3yi. 'Crcdibility and stabilization.' NBER 1h'orking Papcr z7yo.

Dornbusch, R. and Simonsen, M. (rg87). 'Inflxtion stabilization with incomes policy support.' NBFR ~ti'orking Papcr 2r53

Enelow and Hinnich (tq84). Asuanca rn Spatiet Throry of Voting. Cambridqr. Cambridgr linivenity Press. Helpman, E. (ty88~. 'Macroeconomic efïects of price controls: the role of market structure.' EcoxoMrc

JOURNAL, vol. y8, pp. 34~55.

Ize, A. and Ortiz, G. i, rg87). ' Fiscal rigidities, public debt and capital flight.' IMF .Staff Papns, vol. 34. PP. 3r r-3r.

Ncary, P. and Roberts, K. ( tg8oj. ' Theory oChouschold behavior under rationing.' Europran Ecortomir Rmitru, vol. r 3. PP. z5-4z.

Ortiz, G. ( r gqo). ' Mczico beyond thr debt crisis: towards sustainablc growth with price stability.' In Lecsoes

on Economic Stabilimlion crtE itr AJtermath (ed. M. Bruno). CambridRc, Ma: MIT Prrss.

Penson, T. and van 1Vijnbergcn, S. ( rg8g). 'Signalling, wagc controls and monctary disinflation policy.' NBER 4~'orkint! Paper z93y.

van 1t'ijnlirrgcn, S. ' i gqr I. ' Intcrtrmporal spcrulation, shortagcs and tbc Iwlitical cronnmy of pricc rcform : a casr. aGain.a gradualism.' CE!'R Uisrussion !'apcr No. 5io.

S'irkrn, I~~l~n ;:qA(i). 'Si~nallinG in a mudcl of munctan poliry with inrpmlilCtr information.' O.rjorE

(17)

Reprint Series, CeatER, Tilburg University, The Netherlands:

No. 1 G. Marini and F. van der Ploeg, Monetary and fiscal policy in an optimising model with capital accumulation and finite Gves, 7Tu Economic Joumal, voL 98,

no. 392, 1988, PP. 772 - 786.

No. 2 F. van der Plceg, International policy coordina[ion in interdependent monetary economies, Joumal of Internationa! Economics, vol. 25, 1988, PP. 1- 23. No. 3 A.P. Barten, The history of Dutch macroeconomic modelling (1936-1986), in W.

Driehuis, M.M.G. Fase and H. den Hartog (eds.), ChaUcngu jor Macroeconomic

Modelling, Contributions to Economic Malysis 178, Amsterdam: North-Holland,

1988, PP. 39 - 88.

No. 4 F. van der Plceg, Disposable income, unemployment, inflation and state spending in a dynamic political-economic model, Public Choice, vol. 60, 1989, pp. 211 - 239. No. 5 Th. ten Raa and F. van der Plceg, A statisticai approach to the problem of negatives in input-output analysis, Economic Modelling, vol. 6, no. 1, 1989, pp. 2 - 19.

No. 6 E. van Damme, Renegotiation-proof equilibria in repeated prisoners' dilemma,

Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 47, no. 1, 1989, pp. 206 - 217.

No. 7 C. Mulder and F. van der Ploeg, Trade unions, investment and employment in

a small open economy: a Dutch perspective, in J. Muysken and C.. de Neubourg (eds.), Unemployment in Europe, L.ondon: The Macmillan Press Ltd, 1989, pp. 200

- 229.

No. 8 Th. van de Klundert and F. van der Plceg, Wage rigidity and capital mobility in

an optimizing model of a small open economy, Dc Economirt, vol. 137, nr. 1,

1989, pp. 47 - 75.

No. 9 G. Dhaene and A.P. Barten, When it all began: the 1936 Tinbergen model revisited, Economic ModcUing, voL 6, no. 2, 1989, pp. 203 - 219.

No. 10 F. van der Plceg and AJ. de Zeeuw, Contlict over arms accumulation in markct and command economies, in F. van der Plceg and AJ. de Zeeuw (eds.), Dynamic

Policy Games in Economicr, Contributions to Economic Analysis 181,

Amster-dam: Elsevier Science Publishers B.V. (North-Holland), 1989, pp. 91 - 119. No. 11 J. Driffill, Macroeconomic policy games with incomplete information: some

extensions, in F. van der Plceg and A.J. de Zeeuw (eds.), Dynamic Policy Gamu in Economics, Contributions to Economic Analysis I81, Amsterdam: ELcevier Science Publishers B.V. (North-Holland), 1989, pp. 289 - 322.

(18)

No. l3 RJ.M. Alessie and A. Kapteyn, Consumption, savings and demography, in A. Wenig, K.F. Zimmermann ( eds.), Demographic Change and Economic Development, Berlin~Heidelberg: Springer-Verlag, 1989, pp. 272 - 305.

No. 14 A. Hoque, J.R. Magnus and B. Pesaran, The exact multi-period mean-square forecast error for the first-order autoregressive model, Joumal oj Econometrics, vol. 39, no. 3, I988, pp. 327 - 346.

No. i5 R. Alessie, A. Kapteyn and B. Melenberg, The effects of liquidiry constraints on

consumption: estimation from household panel data, European Ecnnomic Review,

vol. 33, no. 2~3, 1989, pp. 547 - 555.

No. 1G A. Holly and J.R. Magnus, A note on instrumental variables and maximum

likeli-hood estimation procedures, Annalts d'Économie et de Statistique, no. t0,

April-June, 1988, pp. 121 - 138.

No. 17 P. ten Hacken, A. Kapteyn and I. Woittiez, Unemployment benéfits and the labor market, a micro~macro approach, in B.A. Gustafsson and N. Anders Klevmarken (eds.), T!u Politica! Economy oj Socia! Securiry, Contributions to Economic Analysis 179, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers B.V. (North-Holland), 1989, pp. 143 - 164.

No. 18 T. Wansbeek and A. Kapteyn, Estimation of the etror-components model with incomplete panels, Jouma! oj Econometrics, vol. 41, no. 3, 1989, pp. 341 - 361.

No. 19 A. Kapteyn, P. Kooreman and R. Willemse, Some methodological issues in the implementation of subjective poverry defmitions, The lournal oj Human

Raources, vol. 23, no. 2, 1988, pp. 222 - 242.

No. 20 Th. van de Klundert and F. van der Ploeg, Fiscal policy and fmite lives in interdependent economies with real and nominal wage rigidity, Osforá Economic

Papers, vol. 41, no. 3, 1989, pp. 459 - 489.

No. 21 J.R. Magnus and B. Pesaran, The exact multi-period mean-square forecast ercor for the fu-st-order autoregressive model with an intercept, lourna! of

Econometricr, voL 42, no. 2, 1989, pp. 157 - 179.

No. 22 F. van der Plceg, Two essays on political xonomy: (i) The political emnomy of overvaluation, 7ïee Economic Joumal, vol. 99, no. 397, 1989, pp. 850 - 855; (u) Election outcomes and the stockmarket, European loumal oj Political Economy, vol. 5, no. 1, 1989, pp. 21 - 30.

No. 23 J.R. Magnus and A.D. Woodland, On the maximum likelihood estimation of

multivariate regression models oontaining serially correlated error components,

Intenwtiona! Economic Review, vol. 29, no. 4, 1988, pp. 707 - 725.

No. 24 AJJ. Talman and Y. Yamamoto, A simplicial algorithm for stationary point

problems on polytopes, Marhenrarics oj Opemtionr Ruearch, vol. 14, no. 3, 1989,

pp. 383 - 399.

No. 25 E. van Damme, Stable equiGbria and fotward induction, lotuno! of Economic

(19)

No. 26 A.P. Barten and L.J. Bettendorf, Price tormation of fish: An application of an inverse demand system, European Economic Review, vol. 33, no. 8, 1989, pp. 1509 - 1525.

No. 27 G. Noldeke and E. van Damme, Signalling in a dynamic labour market, Review

oj Economic Studies, vol. 57 ( 1), no. 189, 1990, pp. 1- 23.

No. 28 P. Kop Jansen and Th. ten Raa, The choice of model in the construaion of input-output coefficients matrices, Intemationa! Economèc Review, vol. 31, no. 1,

1990. PP. 213 - 227.

No. 29 F. van der Plceg and A.J. de Zeeuw, Perfect equilibrium in a model of competitive arms aeeumulation, Internationo! Economic Review, vol. 31, no. 1,

1990, pp. 131 - 146.

No. 30 J.R. Magnus and A.D. Woodland, Separability and aggregation, Economica, vol. 57, no. 226, 1990, pp. 239 - 247.

No. 31 F. van der Plceg, International interdependence and poliry coordination in economies with real and nominal wage rigidiry, Creek Economic Rtview, vol. 10, no. 1, June 1988, pp. 1- 48.

No. 32 , E. van Damme, Signaling and forward induction in a market entry context,

OperarioruResearch Proceedings J989, Berlin-Heidelberg: Springer-Verlag, 1990,

. pp. 45 - 59.

No. 33 A.P. Barten, Toward a levels version of the Rotterdam and related demand systems, Condibutionr to Opemtiorts Researrh and Economics, Cambridge: MTT Press, 1989, pp. 441 - 465.

No.34 F. van der Ploeg, Intetnational coordination of monetary policies under

alternative exchange-rate regimes, in F. van der Plceg (ed.), Advanced Lectures in Quantitative Economics, London-Orlando: Academic Press Ltd., 1990, pp. 91

- 121.

No. 35 Th. van de Klundert, On socioeconomic causes of 'wait unemployment', European

Economic Review, vol. 34, no. S, 1990, pp. 1011 - 1022.

No. 36 R.J.M. Alessie, A. Kapteyn, J.B. van Lochem and T.J. Wansbeek, Individual effects in utiliry consistent models of demand, in J. Hartog, G. Ridder and J. Theeuwes ( eds.), Pane( Data and Labor Market Studies, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers B.V. (North-Holland), 1990, pp. 253 - 278.

No. 37 F. van der Ploeg, Capital accumulation, inflation and long-run conflict in international objectives, Oxford Economic Papers, vol. 42, no. 3, 1990, pp. 501

-525.

No. 38 Th. Nijman and F. Palm, Parameter identification in ARMA Processes in the presence of regular but incomplete sampling,loumal of Time Series Analysis, vol. 11, no. 3, 1990, pp. 239 - 248.

(20)

No. 40 Th. Nijman and M.F.J. Steel, Exclusion restrictions in instrumental variables equations, Econometric Reviews, vol. 9, no. 1, l9'Xl, pp. 37 - 55.

No. 41 A. van Soest, 1. Woittiez and A. Kapteyn, Labor supply, income taxes, and hours

restrictions in the Netherlands, Jounaal of Human Resources, voL 25, no. 3, 1990,

pp. 517 - 558.

No. 42 Th.C.M.J. van de Klundert and A.B.T.M. van Schaik, Unemployment persistence

and loss of productive capacity: a Keynesian approach, Joumal oj

Macro-economicr, vol. 12, no. 3, 1990, pp. 363 - 380.

No. 43 Th. Nijman and M. Verbeek, Estimation of time-dependent parameters in linear

models using cross-sections, panels, or both, Joumal of Economerriu, vol. 46, no.

3, 1990, pp. 333 - 346.

No. 44 E. van Damme, R. Selten and E. Winter, Alternating bid bargaining with a smallest money unit, Cames and Economic Behavior, vol. 2, no. 2, 1990, pp. I88

- 201.

No. 45 C. Dang, The D,-triangulation of R' for simplicial algorithms for computing solutions of nonlinear equations, Mathematier of Openurions Researich, vol. 16, no.

1, 1991, pp. 148 - 161.

No. 46 Th. Nijman and F. Palm, Predictive accurary gain from disaggregate sampling in ARIMA models, Journa! of Buriness á Economic Starirácr, voL 8, no. 4, 1990, pp. 405 - 415.

No. 47 J.R. Magnus, On certain moments relating to ratios of quadratic fotms in normal variables: further results, Sankhyrr The lndian Jounval ojSwtisrics, vol. 52, series

B, part. 1, 1990, pp. 1- 13.

No. 48 M.FJ. Steel, A Bayesian analysis of simultaneous equation models by combining

recursive analytical and numerical approaches, Joumd of Economerrics, vol. 48,

no. 1~2, 1991, pp. 83 - 117.

No. 49 - F. van der Ploeg and C. Withagen, Pollution oontrol and the ramsey problem,

Environmental and Resotur`e Economies, vol. 1, no. 2, 1991, pp. 215 - 236.

No.50 F. van der Ploeg, Money and capital in ínterdependent economies with overlapping generations, Economica, voL 58, no. 230, 1991, pp. 233 - 256.

No. 51 A. Kapteyn and A. de Zeetrvv, Changing incentives for economic research in the Netherlands, European Economic Revitw, vol. 35, no. 2~3, 1991, pp. 603 - 611. No. 52 C.G. de Vries, On the relation between GARCH and stable processes, Journal

oj Economerria, vol. 48, no. 3, 1991, pp. 313 - 324.

No. 53 R. Alessie and A. Kapteyn, Habit formation, interdependent preferences and demographic effects in the almost ideal demand system, The Economicloumal,

(21)

No. 54 W. van Groenendaal and A. de Zeeuw, Control, coordination and contlict on

international commoclity markets, Economic ModeUing, vol. 8, no. 1, 1991, pp. 90 - 101.

No. 55 F. van der Plceg and AJ. Markink, Dynamic policy in linear models with rational

expectations of future events: A computer package, Computer Science in Economics and Management, vol. 4, no. 3, 1991, pp. 175 - 199.

No. 56 HA. Keuzenkamp and F. van der Plceg, Savings, investment, government finance, and the current aocount: The Dutch experience, in G. Alogoskoufis, L. Papademos and R. Portes (eds.), Erternal Constmints on Macroeconomic Policy.~

The European Experience, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991, pp. 219

- 263.

No. 57 Th. Nijman, M. Verbeek and A. van Soes[, The efficiency of rotating-panel

designs in an analysis-of-variance model, Journa! of Econometrics, vol. 49, no. 3,

1991. Pp. 373 - 399.

No. 58 M.F.J. Steel and J.-F. Richard, Bayesian multivariate exogeneiry analysis - an application to a UK money demand equation, Journaloj Economerrics, vol. 49, no. 1~2, 1991, pp. 239 - 274.

No. 59 Th. Nijman and F. Palm, Generalized least squares estimation of linear models

containing rational future expectations, Intenaational Economèc Review, vol. 32, no. 2, 1991, pp. 383 - 389.

No. 60 E. van Damme, Equilibrium selection in 2 x 2 games, Revísta. Espanola de

Economia, vol. 8, no. 1, 1991, pp. 37 - 52.

No. 61 E. Bennett and E. van Damme, Demand commitment bargaining: the case of apex games, in R. Selten (ed.), Came Equilibrium ModeLr 111 - Strotegic Ba~gaining, Berlin: Springer-Verlag, 1991, pp. 118 - 140.

No. 62 W. Guth and E. van Damme, Gorby games - a game theoretic analysis of disarmament campaigns and the defense efficiency - hypothesis -, in R. Avenhaus, H. Karkar and M. Rudnianski (eds.), Defense Decision Maldrtg -Analytica! Support and Cri.ris Management, Berlin: Springer-Verlag, 1991, pp. 215

- 240.

No. 63 A. Roell, Dual-capacity trading and the quality of the market, Jouma! of

Financial Intemtediation, vol. 1, no. 2, 1990, pp. 105 - 124.

No. 64 Y. Dai, G. van der Laan, AJ.J. Talman and Y. Yamamoto, A simplicial

algorithm for the nonlinear stationary point problem on an unbounded polyhedron, Siam Jouma! of Optimiuuion, vol. 1, no. 2, 1991, pp. I51 - 165.

No.65 M. McAleer and C.R. McKenzie, Keynesian and new classical models of unemployment revisited, The Economic lournal, vol. 101, no. 40ó, 1991, pp. 359 - 381.

No. 66 A.J.J. Talman, General equilibrium programming, NieuwArchiejvoor Wëskunde,

(22)

No.67 J.R. Magnus and B. Pesaran, The bias of forecasts from a first-order autoregression, Econometric Theory, vol. 7, no. 2, t991, pp. 222 - 235.

No. 68 F. van der Ploeg, Macroeconomic poliry coordination issues during the various phases of economic and monetary integration in Europe, European Economy

-The Economics of EMU, Commission of the European Communities, special

edition no. 1, 1991, pp. 136 - 164.

No. 69 H. Keuzenkamp, A precursor to Muth: Tinbergen's 1932 mode! of rational expectations, The Economic lounwl, vol. 101, no. 408, 1991, pp. 1245 - 1253. No. 70 L. Zou, The target-incentive system vs. the price-incentive system under adverse

selection and the ratchet effect, Journal ojPublic Economics, vol. 46, no. 1, 1991,

PP- 51 - 89.

No.71 E. Bomhoff, Between price reform and privatization: Eastern Europe in

transition, Firwnzntarkt und Portfolio Management, vol. 5, no. 3, 1991, pp. 241

-251.

No. 72 E. Bomhoff, Stabiliry of velocity in the major industrial countries: a Kalman fdter

approaeh, Intemational Monetary Fund Staff Papers, vol. 38, no. 3, 1991, pp. 626

- 642.

No. 73 E. Bomhoff, Currency convertibility: when and how? A contribution to the Bulgarian debate, Krcdit und Kapita[, vol. 24, no. 3, 1991, pp. 412 - 431.

No.74 H. Keuzenkamp and F. van der Ploeg, Perceived mnstraints for Dutch unemployment policy, in C. de Neubourg (ed.), The Art oj Ful! Employment

-Unemployment Policy in Optn Economies, Contrtbutions to Economic Analysis

203, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Pubtishers B.V. (North-Holland), 1991, pp. 7 - 37.

No. 75 H. Peters and E. van Damme, Characterizing the Nash and Raiffa bargaining solutions by disagreement point azions, Mathematics ojt7pemtions Research, vol.

16, no. 3, 1991, pp. 447 - 461.

No. 76 P.J. Dcschamps, On the estimated variances of regression ooefficients in misspecified error components models, Econometric Theory, vol. 7, no. 3, 1991,

pp. 369 - 384.

No. 77 A. de Zeeuw, Note on 'Nash and Stackelberg solutions in a differential game

model of capitalism', loumal of Economic Dynamics and Control, vol. 16, no. 1,

1992, pp. 139 - 145.

No. 78 J.R. Magnus, On the fundamental bordered matrix of linear estimation, in F. van der Ploeg (ed.), Advanced Lectttrcs in Quantitarive Economicr, London-Orlando:

Academic Press Ltd., 1990, pp. 583 - 604.

No. 79 F. van der Ploeg and A. de Zeettw, A differential game of international pollution

eontrol, Systems and Conttol Lenas, vol. 17, no. 6, 1991, pp. 409 - 414.

No. 80 Th. Nijman and M. Verbeek, The optimal choice of controls and

(23)

No. 8l M. Verbeek and Th. Nijman, Can cohort data be treated as genuine panel data?,

Empirica! Economics, vol. 17, no. l, h~I2, pP. 9- 23.

No. 82 E. van Damme and W. Guth, Equilibrium selection in the Spence signaling game,

in R. Selten (ed.), Gume EquiGbrium ModrLr !I - Methodr, MoroLr, and Markeu, Berlin: Springer-Verlag, 1991, pp. 263 - 288.

No. 83 R.P. Gilles and P.H.M. Ruys, Characterization of economic agents in arbitrary communication struaures, Nieuw Arehief voor Krirlautde, vol. 8, no. 3, 1990, pp.

325 - 345.

No. 84 A. de Zeeuw and F. van der Plceg, Difference games and poliry evaluation: a

conceptual framework, Oxjorá Economic Papers, vol. 43, no. 4, 1991, pp. 612

-636.

No. 85 E. van Damme, Fair division under asymmetric information, in R. Selten (ed.),

Rationa! Interaction - Essays in Honor ojlohn C Harsanyi, Berlin~Heidelberg:

Springer-Verlag, 1992, pp. 121 - 144.

No. 86 F. de Jong, A. Kemna and T. Kloek, A contribution to event study methodology with an appliration to the Dutch stock market, loumal of Banlszrtg and Finance, vol. 16, no. 1, 1992, pp. 11 - 36.

No. 87 A.P. Barten, The estimation of mixed demand systems, in R. Bewley and T. Van Hoa (eds.), Contributions to Consumer Demand and Econometricr, Essays in

HonourojHenri Theil, Basingstoke: The Macmillan Press Ltd., 1992, pp. 31 - 57.

No. 88 T. Wansbeek and A. Kapteyn, Simple estimators for dynamic panel data modeLs with errors in variables, in R. Bewley and T. Van Hoa (eds.), Conrribruions to

Consumer Demand and Econometricr, Essays in Honow of Henri Theil,

Basingstoke: The Macmillan Press Ltd., 1992, pp. 238 - 251.

No. 89 S. Chib, J. Osiewalski and M. Steel, Posterior inference on the degrees of

freedom parameter in mul[ivariate-t regression models, Economics Letters, vol.

37, no. 4, 1991, pp. 391 - 397.

No. 90 H. Peters and P. Wakker, Independence of irrelevant alternatives and revealed group preferences, Econometrica, vol. 59, no. 6, 1991, pp. 1787 - 1801.

No. 91 G. Alogoskoufis and F. van der Ploeg, On budgetary policies, growth, and

external deficits in an interdependent world, Journal of the Japanese and lntemational Economres, vol. 5, no. 4, 1991, pp. 305 - 324.

No. 92 R.P. Gilles, G. Owen and R. van den Brink, Games with permission structures: The conjunctive approach, Intemationa! Joumal oj Game Theory, vol. 20, no. 3, 1992, PP. 277 - 293.

No. 93 J.A.M. Potters, I.J. Curiel and S.H. Tijs, Traveling salesman games, Mathematical

Progrctmming, vol. 53, no. 2, 1992, pp. 199 - 211.

No. 94 A.P. Jurg, M.J.M. ]ansen, JA.M. Potters and S.H. Tijs, A symmetriza[ion for

finite two-person games, Zeiuchnfr fiir Operations Research - Methodr and Moctelr

(24)

No. 95 A. van den Nouweland, P. Borm and S. Tijs, Allocation rules for hypergraph communication situations, lntenaationa!lourna! ojGame Theory, vol. 20, no. 3, 1992, pp. 255 - 268.

No. 96 E.J. Bomhoff, Monetary refotm in Eastern Europe, European Economic Review, vol. 36, no. 2~3, 1992, pp. 454 - 458.

No. 97 F. van der Ploeg and A. de Zeeuw, International aspects of pollution control,

Environmmta! and Resourre Economies, voL 2, no. 2, 1992, pp. 117 - 139.

No. 98 P.E.M. Borm and S.H. Tijs, Strategic claim games corresponding to an NTU-game, Games and Economic Behavior, vol. 4, no. 1, 1992, pp. 58 - 71.

No. 99 A. van Scest and P. Kooreman, Coherency of the indirect translog demand system with binding nonnegativity constraints, louma! oj Econometrics, vol. 44, no. 3, 1990, pp. 391 - 400.

No. 100 Th. ten Raa and E.N. Wolff, Secondary products and the measurement of productivity growth, Regional Science and Urban Economics, vol. 21, no. 4, 1991, pp. 581 - 615.

No. 101 P. Kooreman and A. Kapteyn, On the empirical implementation of some game

theoretic models of household labor supply, Thelourna! ofHuman Resources, vol. 25, no. 4, 1990, pp. 584 - 598.

No. 102 H. Bester, Bertrand equiL'brium in a differentiated duopoly, lntenwtional

Economic Review, vol. 33, no. 2, 1992, pp. 433 - 448.

No. 103 JA.M. Potters and S.H. Tijs, The nudeolus of a matrut game and other nucleoli,

Marhematier oj t7pertttions Resca~lt, vol. 17, no. 1, 1992, pp. 164 - 174.

No. 104 A. Kapteyn, P. Kooreman and A. van Soest, Quantity rationing and concavity in

a flexible household labor supply model, Revrew of Economics and Sratistics, vol.

72, no. 1, 1990, pp. 55 - 62.

No. 105 A. Kapteyn and P. Kooreman, Household labor supply: What kind of data can

tell us how many decision makers there are?, Ettropean Economic Review, vol. 36,

no. 2~3, 1992, pp. 365 - 371.

No. 106 Th. van de Klundert and S. Smulders, Reconstructing growth theory: A survey,

De Economist, vol. 140, no. 2, 1992, pp. 177 - 203.

No. 107 N. Rankin, Imperfect oompetition, es~ectations and the multiple effects of monetary growth, The Economic lournal, vol. 102, no. 413, 1992, pp. 743 - 753. No. ]08 J. Greenberg, On the sensitivity of von Neumann and Morgenstern abstract

stable sets: The stable and the indívidual stable bargaining set, Internationa!

louma! oj Game Theory, vol. 21, no. 1, 1992, pp. 41 - 55.

No. 109 S. van Wijnbergen, Trade reform, poGry uncertainty, and the current account: A

non-e:tpected-utility approach, Amaican Economic Review, vol. 82, no. 3, 1992,

(25)

No. 1l0 M. Verheek and Th. Nijman, Testing for selectiviry bias in panel data models,

Intemutiona! Economic Review, vol. 33, no. 3, 1~)92, pp. 681 - 703.

No. lll Th. Nijman and M. Verbeek, Nonresponse in panel data: The impact on

estimates of a life rycle consumption funaion, lournal of Applied Econometrics,

vol. 7, no. 3, 1992, pp. 243 - 257.

No. 112 I. Bomze and E. van Damme, A dynamical characterization of evolutionarily stable states, Annalr oj Operation.t Research, vol. 37, 1992, pp. 229 - 244. No. 113 P.J. Deschamps, Expectations and intertemporal separabiliry in an empirical

model of consumption and investment under uncertainry, Empirical Econorniur, vol. 17, no. 3, 1992, pp. 419 - 450.

No. 114 K. Kamiya and D. Talman, Simplicial algorithm for computing a core element

in a balanced game, Joumal of the Opemtions Research, vol. 34, no. 2, 1991, pp.

222 - 228.

No. 115 G.W. Imbens, An efficient method of moments estimator for discrete choice models with choicebased sampling, Economerrica, vol. 60, no. S, 1992, pp. 1187 -1214.

No. 116 P. Borm, On perfectness concepts for bimatrix games, OR Spekaum, vol. 14, no.

1, 1992, pp. 33 - 42.

No. 117 A.P. Jurg, I. Garcia Jurado and P.E.M. Borm, On modifications of the concepts of perfect and proper equilibria, OR Spektnun, vol. 14, no. 2, 199z, pp. 8S - 90. No. 118 P. Borm, H. Keiding, R.P. McLean, S. Oortwijn and S. Tijs, The compromise

value for NTU-games, Intenwtional Joumol of Game Theory, vol. 21, no. 2, 1992, pp. 17S - 189.

No. 119 M. Maschler, JA.M. Potters and S.H. Tijs, The general nucleolus and the

reduced game property, lntemational Jouma! of Game Theory, voL 21, no. 1,

1992. PP. 8S - 106.

No. 120 K. Wárneryd, Communication, correlation and symmetry in bargaining,

Economics Letrers, vol. 39, no. 3, 1992, pp. 29S - 300.

No. 121 M.R. Baye, D. Kovenock and C.G. de Vries, It takes two to tango: equilibria in

a model of sales, Gumes and Economic Behavior, vol. 4, no. 4, 1992, pp. 493

-S 10.

No. 122 M. Verbeek, Pseudo panel data, in L. Máryás and P. Sevestre (eds.), The

Econometriu of Panel Data, Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1992, pp.

303 - 315.

No. 123 S. van Wijnbergen, Intertemporal speculation, shortages and the political economy of price reform, The Economic loumal, vol. 102, no. 415, 1992, pp. 1395

(26)

P.O. BOX 90153, 5000 LE TILBURG. THE NETHERLANDS

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

The results hint, albeit not statistically significant, that effects of labels are not straightforward and requires additional explanation: a normally priced Fair Trade product

In this case, the equilibrium price level is determined as the unique value that equates the real value of government debt to the expected present value of future

Not recalled/ Recalled/ recognized recognized Brand recognition 12.2% n.rn.. H1c,d: Online behavioural targeting of online native video advertisements has a negative effect on

With a simple example of a hospital with two primary wards, we have shown that open- ing an EOA Ward results in an increase of urgent patient admissions, but at the same time in

The socio-economic factors included as independent variables in the multivariate regressions consist of the home country gross domestic product (GDP) of the sponsoring

Er wordt onderzocht hoe aanvullende vegetatie gericht ingezet kan worden om belangrijke natuurlijke vijanden te stimuleren, zonder dat tegelijkertijd plagen bevorderd worden..

Als tijdens het ontwerpend onderzoek blijkt dat een bepaald concept of scenario afbreuk zal doen aan de krachtlijnen van de site, dan kunnen de onderzoekers eerst bekijken of het