• No results found

RISK TAKING BEHAVIOR: MANAGERS & DIRECTORS

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "RISK TAKING BEHAVIOR: MANAGERS & DIRECTORS"

Copied!
53
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

RISK TAKING BEHAVIOR:

MANAGERS & DIRECTORS

BY

KEN PAUL DE GUZMAN

University of Groningen

Faculty of Economics and Business

MSC – International Business & Management

(2)

RISK TAKING BEHAVIOR: MANAGERS & DIRECTORS

TABLE OF CONTENTS Page

ABSTRACT 2

INTRODUCTION 3

THEORY AND PROPOSITIONS 5 Introduction to Risk 5 Towards a Model of Risk Taking Behavior 7 MANAGERIAL DISCRETION & RISK TAKING 17

Managerial Discretion - Organizational Level 19 THE BOARD & RISK TAKING 23 Independence 23

Expertise 26

Board Tenure 28

CEO Duality 31

DISCUSSION 32

Implications for Practice 35 Implications for Research 36

Conclusions 37

REFERENCES 38

APPENDIX 53

ABSTRACT

The late 2000s financial crisis attracted more attention to managerial risk taking. Risk is widely recognized to be an essential element of strategic management hence the interest of researchers in finding its determinants. From an agency theory perspective, corporate governance failed to provide a safe guard to excessive risk taking which resulted in the financial crisis. But risk taking warrants attention from other fields such as psychology or econometrics. In this thesis, the concept of risk will be unpacked and a model for risk behavior is proposed. Furthermore other factors, which are related to the risk taking by firms, will be elaborated. The thesis can serve as a foundation for more a holistic research in risk taking behavior.

Keywords: risk taking behavior, managerial discretion, upper-echelon theories, corporate governance, supervisory board

Research theme: Risk Taking Behavior

(3)

INTRODUCTION

This thesis finds its motivation in the criticism of the corporate governance practices of the boards of financial institutions during and after the financial crisis. While the scrutiny of the boards ex-ante the crisis is limited, the aftermath shows a common perspective pointing at excessive risk-taking as the main problem. Moreover excessive risk-taking as a result of management action coherently ratified by the board, with the shareholders or governments bearing the costs of bailouts or decreased share value in the end. Plath (2008) points out lax board oversight of risk management, executive compensation promoting excessive risk taking, or simply corporate governance deficiencies as the main reason for the banks failure. The papers of Erkens, Hung and Matos (2009) as well as Wymeersch (2008) are in line with these conclusions, identifying corporate governance as the root of the problem.

The previously mentioned authors approached corporate governance from an agency perspective. The definition of corporate governance for that context is well defined by Shleifer and Vishny (1997) who argues that corporate governance deals with the way in which the capital suppliers (principals) expect returns of the money invested from the agents, who are the management in this case. This notion of separation between

(4)

(2009) confirms, corporate governance mechanism failed to prevent excessive risk-taking. For the previous researches mentioned before the overlapping theme is to examine

whether the agency problems are correctly addressed by looking at key elements present in the board of directors, compensation and ownership structure. When certain elements are present it is assumed that these will lead to a certain outcome. For example an independent board of director should lead to less risk taking as monitoring will be more effective and an independent board will be more difficult to be captivated by management (Larker, Richardson and Tuna, 2005). As the mentioned researches investigated this area, a gap still exists for the executive side as the focus is on the supervisory board or CEO only. Moreover a larger gap exists when exploring factors below the surface-level demographics and the relation to risk-taking. Coherently researches concerning risk

taking mostly examine a particular area at a time, providing opportunity for improvement. Consequently exploring how risk-taking behavior comes to existence is one

contribution of this thesis. Firstly, by utilizing previous theories about risk decisions, a model of risk taking behavior will be proposed. This will provide insight why individuals act as they do. Secondly, areas, which affect risk taking such as theories about managerial discretion and director’s characteristics, will be explored. As these outside factors also shapes an individual behavior. The main goal is to provide propositions concerning the main question of:

What are the elements involved in risk taking and which board characteristics can be attributed to excessive risk taking?

(5)

thesis will only investigate the dynamics at the highest level (board) and will therefore not address the extended agency problem (Thomas, 2008). Finally, the aim is to provide the reader with an overview of elements, which matters concerning the risk taking in organizations. The paper will prove to be useful to shareholders when electing their representatives and provides a different perspective to understanding risk taking in firms.

THEORY AND PROPOSITIONS Introduction to Risk

In order to understand why certain management or board characteristic affects risk one must first understand the concept of risk. Financial research papers’ concerning risk taking in banks often does not specifically define risk but use the operationalization of risk as its definition (Laeven & Levine, 2009; Jiménez, Lopez, & Saurina, 2007; Mehran & Rosenberg, 2007; Erkens et al, 2009). Therefore in these papers, indicators for the degree of bank stability define the level of risk in the banks. Lowering of capital levels, increasing of financial leverage, or taking on more credit risk in the product portfolio are examples of riskier bank policies. Another measure for risk taking exploited before (Laeven & Levine, 2009; Erkens et al, 2009) is for example the equity to assets ratio (higher equity to assets ratio indicating lower default risk) as it captures leverage, which is one of the prime often used measure of risk taking in financial and economics papers.

(6)

course disagree with this usage of the word risk, as risk in his point of view refers to actions (or ventures) with consequences, which are virtually unknown. That is, when speaking of ventures, could either succeed or fail dependent on effort, and skills but less on chance. Like there is different risk by looking at semantics, one can argue for the existence of different type of risk. For example the previously mentioned risk as a probability is the so-called absolute risk, i.e. risk without any context. Clearly to examine how management characteristics are related to the risk taking in bank there is a need to identify risk first. What is risk taking? How does it come to existence? The following section addresses the concept of risk in context and risk taking by elaborating it from other field of studies besides the previously discussed risk taking in finance. The common notion across the different disciplines is that risk is a function of choices, decisions, and consequences made under uncertainty.

(7)

consumer choice theory, as choices are inseparable from risk, (Fischhoff, Watson, & Hope, 1990). When speaking about risk in the field of consumer behavior, most often it refers to ‘perceived risk’, i.e. risk which individuals assess in a certain context, (Haddock, 1993). This means risk is also about the individuals perception of uncertainty and outcomes (Dowling & Staelin, 1994). Moutinho (2000) states, risk (in the context of tourist behavior) includes the following: uncertainty inherent in the product, uncertainty in place and mode of purchase, degree of financial and psychosocial consequences and the subjective uncertainty experienced by the tourist. It is composed of factors, which are internal and will affect the decision maker like the degree of consequences and how risk is assessed as well as external factors, which creates uncertainty.

Towards a Model of Risk Taking Behavior

(8)

propensity, defined as an individual’s trait of “willingness to take risk” (MacCrimmon &Wehrung, 1990) is argued to affect risk perception, while risk perception on its turn is influenced by previous decisions made and their outcomes, the so called outcome history (March & Shapira, 1987; Osborn & Jackson, 1988; Thaler and Johnson, 1990). The variables outcome history, problem framing, risk perception and propensity show that risk-taking behavior is not solely due to the nature and/or traits of an individual. Several studies identified different circumstances, which might influence the degree of risk taking.

(9)

intensifies the effect of new losses. In terms of risk taking its means that people with recent gains will act more risky while recent loss results into more risk averse decisions. Linville and Fisher (1991), further examined the “house money effect” concluding that people are more affected by losses following losses, but gradually recover from the risk averse state over time. In a recent study, Seo, Goldfarb & Barrett (2010) examined the effects of emotion on the risk attitude changing effects of recent gains and losses. They discovered that affective states of individuals mediated the house money effect. Experiencing pleasant feelings with recent gains reduced the risk averseness while both pleasant and unpleasant feelings reduced the risk seeking effect of recent losses as affective states changes subjective utilities of each outcome. Delgado-Garcia, Fuente-Sabate & Quevedo-Puente (2010) investigated the effect of bank CEO’s emotional traits on risk taking. Albeit not in the context of recent gains or losses, they also observed that emotion do play a role in the level of risk taking. Specifically, positive affective traits did not influence risk attitude while negative affective traits correlates to more risk averseness.

By combining prospect theory, behavioral theory and theories of social cognition a modified model of Sitkin & Pablo (1992), where the mediating role of risk propensity and risk perception are posited, is proposed:

--- Insert Figure 1 about here ---

(10)

behavior proves to have more powerful explanatory value than examining the antecedent variables individually. However, Sitkin & Weingart (1995) results shows that risk propensity’s effect on behavior actually was mediated by risk perception (predicted by the original reconceptualization, arrow ‘a’ in figure 1) but have no significant direct effect on the risk behavior. Furthermore, problem framing was found to not only have an indirect effect on the risk taking behavior but a direct one (arrow ‘b’, figure 1) as well. This is in line with an extensive amount of literature about the interaction effect of problem framing. The general idea is that decision makers are more sensitive/ responsive to information cues after a failure (Bateman, 1986; Bateman & Zeithalm, 1989; Staw & Ross, 1978) or are more affected by negative signals (Beach and Strom, 1990; Fiske, 1980; Lewicka, 1997; Peeters & Czapinski, 1990; Wong and Weiner, 1981). Therefore, the manner of how problems are presented or perceived (mediating effect of risk perception) is affecting the actual decision. In line with prospect theory decision makers opt to exhibit risk-averse preferences when a selection need to be made among positively framed prospects, while risk-seeking behavior is exhibited when identical situations are framed negatively (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979; McCue, 2000; Wiseman and Gomez-Mejia, 1998).

This will lead to the first four propositions (relating to arrow a, b, and c):

Proposition 1: The higher the level of risk propensity the riskier the individual’s decision will be.

(11)

Proposition 3: Risky decisions are negatively associated with the individuals perceived level of risk.

Proposition 4: Positively framed outcomes led to the making of risk- averse decisions, whereas negatively framed outcome lead to risk seeking.

The other antecedents, which are argued to influence behavior through risk perception, are the following (arrow e, figure 1):

Homogeneity of top management: The compositions of top management teams are

argued to limit the risk perception of individual decision makers. The roots of this notion find it base in theories concerning group decisions, where it is argued that group dynamics affects decision quality. For example (Janis, 1972), argues dysfunctional individual decision-making when groups are too homogenous or when norms foster groupthink. In the same paper Janis (1972) hypothesize homogenous groups’ tendency to perceive judgments, which are consensual, as correct. Sitkin & Pablo (1992) further argues that (Stoner, 1968) ‘risky or cautious shift’ groups implies that individual members of a more homogenous team will perceive risk as more extreme. Lastly as suggested by Hambrick and Mason (1984) team heterogeneity will be positively associated with profitability in turbulent, discontinuous or risky environments. Therefore, team composition is argued to affect risk through risk perception:

(12)

Social influence: Organizations are argued to dominate other influences of individual

perceptions and behaviors (Davis-Blake & Pfeffer, 1989; Snyder & Ickes, 1985) by channeling individual attention and activity. Individuals are socialized into the organizations culture, viewing the world from their organizations lens. More importantly the cultural risk values will be seen as a guideline when confronting uncertainty (Douglas & Wildavsky, 1982; Hofstede, 1980; Louis, 1980). Also role models are seen as a guideline of what is expected, what is acceptable or what will be rewarded (Gaertner, 1988; Grey & Gordon, 1978; Schein, 1985; Wildavsky, 1988). Leading to the following proposition:

Proposition 6: Organizations cultural risk values are in line with individuals risk perception

Problem domain familiarity: Cumulative experience from past decisions regardless of

(13)

Proposition 7: Low and high problem domain familiarity creates a less accurate perception of risk than moderate level of problem domain familiarity.

Organizational Control Systems: This is how the organizational system rewards

behavior. For example Ouichi (1977) identifies two types of control systems. Process oriented in which the individual follow organizational guidelines and get rewarded independently of the outcome. The individual might bear no risk while the organization will be responsible. On the other hand, outcome oriented systems focus on the actual result, rewarding individuals bearing greater risk, and therefore potentially receiving bigger rewards or punishment. Perception of risk will then be different for individuals in different control systems. Sanders & Hambrick (2007) examined the effect of CEO stock options on risk behavior. The empirical results show that CEO stock options bring about corporate performance, which are more extreme (bigger gains and bigger losses). Where bigger losses are more common. Albeit their data did not give insight in this deterioration of performance they argued for a shift in the CEO’s risk perception, with option-loaded CEOs being more focused on prospective gains, neglecting early signs of failure. These may suggest the following propositions:

Proposition 8a: Individuals within outcome-oriented organizations will perceive higher level of risk.

(14)

For Risk Propensity, the general tendency of the decision maker to take risk, the antecedents suggested by past researches are the following (arrow d, figure 1):

(15)

employed professionally and those in non-professional occupations (Grey & Gordon, 1978; Haliassos & Bertaut, 1995) where the notion is that professionally employed possess more risk tolerance. This is perhaps related to prior literature about one’s formal education and risk taking. The general consensus for this relationship is a positive one, increased formal education also increase a person’s risk tolerance (Grable & Lytton, 1998; Shaw, 1996). Therefore the general risk orientation of an individual is positively related to the tendency of taking risk:

Proposition 9: Risk preference is positively associated with risk propensity.

Inertia: Overtime individuals develop a stable pattern of risk handling (Baron, Leider

& Stack, 2008; Kogan & Wallach, 1964; Rowe, 1977; Slovic, 1972). Risk averseness will therefore lead to more risk averseness while risk seekers continues to be risk seeking in their next decisions. Therefore the following proposition is suggested:

Proposition 10: Overtime inertia is exhibited in an individual’s risk propensity.

Outcome history: New decisions involving risk are influenced by the outcome of

previously made decisions. Decisions, which resulted in a positive outcome, would make similar decision more likely to be made in the future. (March & Shapira, 1987; Osborn & Jackson, 1988; Thaler and Johnson, 1990).

(16)

The modified model here also propose a less stable concept of risk propensity. Where Sitkin & Pablo (1992) and Sitkin & Weingart (1995), already propose risk propensity as an emergent property of the decision maker, which can change over time, and less as a stable attribute as argued by (Fischhoff, Lichtenstein, Slovic, Derby, & Keeney, 1981; Rowe, 1977). Risk propensity therefore can change due to for example recent gains/losses (arrow f, figure 1). Keeping in line with the framing effect under prospect theory (Kuhberger, 1995), individuals will tend to avoid risk in the domain of gains (above their reference point), while seeking risk under loss (below point of reference).

Proposition 12: Recent gains decrease risk propensity while recent losses increase risk propensity.

Seo et al. (2010), identifies affective state as moderating this effect of recent gains / losses (arrow g, figure 1). This is in line with existing research identifying human affect as an important individual-level factor. Experiencing pleasant feelings with recent gains reduced the risk averseness while both pleasant and unpleasant feelings reduced the risk seeking effect of recent losses. This research suggest the proposition:

Proposition 13: Affective state diminishes the framing effect.

(17)

events or outcomes (Johnson & Tversky, 1983). Moreover the mood congruence effect argues for more individual awareness of the negative / positive implications of the decision. Meaning that affective state influence risk perception through problem framing. (arrow h, figure 1).

Proposition 14: Affective state affects problem framing.

MANAGERIAL DISCRETION & RISK TAKING

While the model proposed above explains how the process of behavior concerning risk comes into place, within organizations the actual relationship between an individual’s role and an outcome is also influenced by other factors. As Hambrick and Finckelstein (1987) already explain, top executives can only influence their companies in proportion to the amount of discretion (manager’s latitude of action) they possess. The empirical evidence further shows the importance of discretion to actual outcomes (Crossland & Hambrick, 2007; Crossland & Hambrick, 2011; Finkelstein & Boyd, 1988; Finkelstein & Hambrick, 1990; Li & Tang, 2010). These prior research shows that the scope of managerial discretion is determined by individual as well as environmental, organizational and national factors. Broadly, these different level factors relate to different types of constrains which limits the executive’s discretion.

(18)

Finckelstein, 1987; Tushman & Romanelli, 1985). Even though the willingness to undertake a certain action exists within the executives, organizational factors might limit their power to shape the organization accordingly. For example larger organizations are more likely to have established routines (Nelson & Winter, 1982) or difficulties in implanting large changes (Aldrich, 1979). Other organizational factors relates to the degree of power the executives have in relation to their principals or key stakeholders. For example factors which can increase ‘information asymmetry’, a well-known concept in agency theory (Eisenhardt, 1989; Bebchuck & Fried, 2003), or factors decreasing board vigilance like chair-CEO duality (Crossland & Hambrick, 2007) will surely increase managerial discretion. The role of the board is therefore of great influence in risk taking within organizations as they can limit managerial discretion. This will be discussed in a later section.

Concerning national factors, normative constraints and institutions are the key elements. Hambrick and Finkelstein (1987), argues that executives have discretion as long the action falls within the ‘zone of acceptance’ of stakeholders with power. Managerial discretion will then diminish according to degree to which the action is seen as objectionable and the relative power of those who perceive it as objectionable. At national level, formal and informal institutions affect these two factors (Crossland & Hambrick, 2007; Crossland & Hambrick, 2011). Traditions, customs and social norms constrain behavior to provide structure to interactions (Colson, 1974), and because of the guidelines institutions provide, constrains are also created (Nelson & Nelson, 2002). Informal institutions, defined by (Helmke & Levitsky, 2006: 5) as “socially shared rules,

(19)

actions (Crossland & Hambrick, 2011). Whether societies will perceive certain actions as objectionable will therefore be dependent on norms and conventions within that society.

On the other hand, formal institutions, defined as “rules and procedures that are

created, communicated, and enforced through channels widely accepted as official”

(Helmke and Levitsky, 2004: 727), relates to the power of key stakeholders. Executives will adhere to these formal rules to avoid state-controlled sanctions. Across varying national systems, managerial discretion will then differ due to the different legal rights and responsibilities of executives relative to the company’s stakeholders (Crossland & Hambrick, 2011). The two factors, perceived objectionability and power of stakeholders shows the importance of corporate governance and the role of the board as they can be seen as controllers of decisions, the one who ratifies and control the actions of top management (Fama & Jensen, 1983).

Managerial Discretion - Organizational Level

(20)

Existing theory points out different roles of the board. Probably the most well known role and the most relevant for risk management is the monitoring function of the board, which has its theoretical underpinning in agency theory. The board serves as a control instrument for its shareholders (Fema & Jensen; Williamson, 1996), monitoring the management, controlling decisions, and replacing inefficient executives (Barnhart, Marr, & Rosenstein, 1994; Raheja, 2005). With respect to the shareholders, the board is believed to be the first line of defense against below-par performing management (Weisbach, 1988) and or the second best remedy (Weisbach & Hermalin, 2003).

Besides the monitoring role the board also has a strategic function to fulfill. Where the board actively participates in decision making and decision evaluation. Judge and Zeithaml (1992) emphasize the discretion managers and boards have to adapt their organization to the environment. Indicating that board members are also players in the strategic decision process. This strategic role of the board is also posited by Goodstein, Gautam and Booker (1994) elaborating that taking decisions which helps the company adapt to its environment as the strategic function of both the management and the board.

(21)

controlling each other activities, coordination increases, which is a solution to the problem of interdependence and uncertainty. This is in line with Huse (1994), which states that trust and interdependence are central elements of relational contracting.

Clearly these functions of the boards affect risk taking in firms by two ways. Firstly as discussed in the previous section, one of the factors relating to managerial discretion is the power of the stakeholders relative to the management. If board members represent shareholders then the ownership structure of the firm will be a relevant factor to consider as shareholders often have the power to appoint the director. Diversified owners are believed to opt for more risk taking than managers (Demsetz & Lehn, 1985; Esty, 1998; Galai & Masulis, 1976; Jensen & Meckling, 1976), as they do not have a large personal stake in the firm. Where diversified owners are more powerful than non-shareholding managers, even though there will be less managerial discretion, there might be a tendency for greater risk taking. This means that lower managerial discretion do not only relates to less risk taking but can actually promotes it. Besides the diversification of owners, the ownership concentration also affects the power balance. Executives can exercise greater discretion when there is a dispersion of owners (Crossland & Hambrick, 2007), while concentrated ownership provides incentives and means for the shareholders to impose decisions and constrain managerial actions (Demsetz & Lehn, 1985; Shen & Cho, 2005).

(22)

goals but do have to take into account the interests of different stakeholders (constrain is at the level of means) (Shen & Cho, 2005). Coherently due to the multiple interests of different shareholders, which all have to be balanced, managers are more limited from taking radical actions in civil law countries (Crossland & Hambrick, 2011).

(23)

mentioned above clearly influence all major players with respect to their perceptions of actions, which fall in the zone of acceptance (Hambrick and Finkelstein, 1987).

Concerning perception of the shareholders the board with their monitoring and strategic function plays a major role as long as they can fulfill these duties efficiently. However, several researches points out that managers can exercise considerable power which can affect the board and its functioning. For example Baliga & Moyer (1996) discovered that management is able to influence board composition and control information flows therefore increasing managerial discretion. CEO-duality as another example is also found to increase managerial discretion, as board vigilance will be weaker. (Hayward & Hambrick, 1997; Li & Tang, 2010; Mizruchi, 1983). With respect to this power play between managers and board members certain board characteristics and or compositions are found to have a positive effect on the functioning of the board. The following section will discuss these board characteristics.

THE BOARD & RISK TAKING Independence

(24)

to the power of managers in appointing who sits on the boards, the interest of outside directors will be more likely aligned with the managers (Mace, 1986; Jensen, 1993) or managers might even succeed in reserving positions for incompetent outside directors (John & Senbet, 1998). These two differing views concerning independent directors only affirm the monitoring function of the board. When an efficient board is in place (for this case having competent outside directors), managerial discretion will be less. For example badly performing managers are more likely removed by outside-dominant boards (Weisbach, 1988). Hermalin and Weisbach (1988) discovered that more independent directors are appointed after a period of poor stock performance, indicating that the presence of outside directors also serves as a positive signal to the outside world, more specifically to the firm’s investors. This is further confirmed by the studies of Byrd and Hickman (1992), who found that independent directors have a neutralizing effect on the negative reactions of the market to the announcement of a take-over. While Brickely, Coles and Terry (1994) discovered that independent directors also neutralize the negative effect of the adaptation of anti-takeover measures by the management. Furthermore outside directors are associated with better oversight of the financial processes within the firm (Klein, 2002), indicating more reliable financial reports (Anderson, Mansi & Reeb, 2004), and less chance on financial statement fraud (Uzun, Szewczyk & Varma, 2004). The papers of Block (1999), Cotter, Shivdasani and Zenner (1997), and Hermalin and Weisbach (2003) further argue that independent directors, when correctly functioning, will promote the interests of the shareholders.

(25)

taking will be dependent on the risk decision-making behavior of the executives in relation to the stakeholders the outside directors are representing. That of course would be the ideal situation, implying that the outside directors’ risk preference and risk perception (see figure 1, appendix), are the same as the stakeholders they are representing. Pathan (2009), for example argues that on average firms with independent boards would have less risk taking as independent directors are also more independent from shareholders (who wants more risk taking) and are therefore more sensitive to regulatory compliance (to avoid lawsuits).

Furthermore the risk behavior of the outside directors needs to be different than that from the executives. Coherently this will be the case when comparing the individual elements in figure 1.

Firstly, by examining risk propensity, difference between the outside directors and executives can be found. As risk preference is different for each individual it is unlikely to be the same for both directors and executives. When this general risk orientation turns out to be similar, it is still unlikely that both inertia and outcome history are similar as well. Outside directors from different firms, having encountered different outcomes in their own business would have faced a different path than the firm they are monitoring. Furthermore as outside directors have no business or personal relation with the firm, previous results (whether gain/loss, positive/negative) would be interpreted differently than the executives leading to different outcome history.

(26)

less informational asymmetry as the outside directors (Huang, 2006). Therefore outside directors with different information as the executives would have a different risk perception i.e. different estimation of how risky a situation is in terms of probabilities of the situational uncertainty, the controllability of the uncertainty and the confidence in those estimates (Baird & Thomas, 1985; Bettman, 1973).

Expertise

(27)

hedging found the practice to be corresponding with firms whose board members hold degrees surpassing the bachelor level (Smith and Stulz, 1985).

(28)
(29)

Board Tenure

Concerning how board tenure is related to risk taking, prior literature is split in two contrasting streams. Firstly like the effects of intra-firm experience, multiple years of directorship in the same board is reasoned to be associated with greater experience, commitment and competence (Buchanan, 1974; Vafeas, 2003; Vance, 1983). Looking back at the study of Sirmon et al (2008), longer board tenure in the same firm means a better understanding of that specific industry and will therefore result in recognizing or preferring certain (familiar) strategies while being critical of other. Opposing these ‘greater expertise theories’ is the ‘management friendly’ board theories. According to Vance (2003), the longer the board tenure the more likely directors befriend management leading to less monitoring. This is further argued to be more often the case in firms controlled by powerful CEOs (involved in the nomination process, significant voting power, extended tenure in the CEO position). The outsider director becomes more similar to insider director when this happen. Lipton and Lorsch (1992) further supports this statement by advocating term limits for directors, as they recognize that in time directors might even attempt to usurp some of the CEO’s function. Canavan, Jones, & Potter (2004) reason that while longer board tenure has benefits, many of these also have a flip side. Besides personal ties that directors develops (affecting their independence), seasoned directors are more prone to defend policies and decisions they supported in the past, fail to keep up with the changing business environment, lack fresh ideas and critical thinking new directors can bring to the board.

(30)

in firms with more powerful CEOs. This might possibly be explained by relationships, which have been developed. The finding from Core, Holthausen and Larcker (1999), that directors who are appointed in the current CEO’s tenure are more generous with respect to the compensation partially supports this statement. CEO’s tenure is one of the most cited indicators of CEO power within the firm. As outside directors are not involved with the day to day business of the company one can argue that the longer the CEO’s tenure the more information asymmetry with the board can exist. Relating to Core et al (1999) seasoned CEO’s may also gain more influence in board member selection (Westphal & Zajac, 1995). Furthermore, overtime the board might trust the CEO implicitly (Shen, 2003), weakening their monitoring. Some prior literature suggests that longer tenure means the CEO is conforming to the shareholders interests (Brickley, Coles, Jarrell 1997; Shwenk, 1993), and requires less monitoring. While other researches conclude that in the case of a ‘fresh’ board, CEO tenure is negatively associated with risk taking (Pathan, 2009; Walters, Kroll, & Wright 2007) while a more tenured board would advocate for greater risk taking.

Board size

(31)

less risk taking activities which confirms that larger boards are related to less alignment with the interest of shareholders. However other researchers such as Singh and Harianto (1989) argue that larger boards might actually reduce CEO domination. This reasoning is in alignment with the findings that firms with strong insider control have a smaller board generally (Bagha & Black, 1996; Gertner & Kaplan, 1997) or those firms, which still have the founder as CEO, also have smaller boards (Agrawal & Knoeber, 1999). With respect to board efficiency Klein (2002), argue in favor of larger boards with the reason that the committees in larger boards would be more effective as there will be more directors to spread around.

CEO Duality

(32)

entrenchment. However, the findings of Finkelstein & D’Avine (1994), shows that boards are more concerned with unity of command than CEO entrenchment, contradicting agency theory. Furthermore in the same research it is elaborated that the informal power of the CEO and also positive firm performance, is of great influence in the tendency for CEO entrenchment (which is in favor of agency) theory.

This is an indication that CEO duality on its own will not always lead to greater risk taking or weaker board vigilance. It stresses out that psychological and situational factors are as equally important (Wasserman, 2006). Finally, Shen (2003) suggest that boards should focus on leadership development of fresh CEOs and enhance monitoring as the CEO becomes more tenured, as it takes time to build authority and trust from other directors needed to pursue one’s own interests.

DISCUSSION

(33)

factors at organizational and even national level (Crossland & Hambrick, 2011). In turn outcomes and individual factors such as affective state play a role in future decisions.

Risk taking in firms has been shown to be a function of individual factors such as risk preference and organizational level factors such as award systems and team composition. Moreover, the board of directors plays a large role in monitoring and directing executive behavior. While these all take place in a certain environment, which is dependent on certain characteristics within a country. Therefore future research should try to take most, if not all, of these factors into account.

Consequently difficulties will be encountered in disentangling intercorrelations and in attributing cause and effect. Other methodological concerns are the changing composition of management or board while there is a lag in outcomes of decisions. Also researchers need to be careful in their choice of measure for risk or other variables as the context can be of great importance. For example Sirmon et al. (2008) points out, that directors prior board experience have an effect on their preferred strategy. A measure of risk not capturing this preference might bring false result. The current position of the firm is regarding prospect theory also a factor to consider. Managers of firms with above target level will then behave differently than in below target level firms.

By examining all of the factors considered in this paper as a whole, an improvement in predictive models can be accomplished. Predictions about corporate risk taking will be more accurate which is beneficial to shareholders, directors and top management and ultimately to society.

(34)

provide the firm with strategic directions, lower level employees are still the one who has to carry the day-to-day activities. How risk taking is converted top-down in an organization have not been covered albeit this also deserves attention. For example, examining leaders personal characteristics and traits, that helps foster a culture of risk taking or risk avoidance will surely be of relevance and will further improve predictions about risk taking in firms.

Implications for Practice

This study has several implications for top management, directors and owners of an organization. When searching for a right top management or director candidate, experience is often highly valued. This research shows that decision makers should be aware that higher experience should not always been given priority. Where lack of experience can lead to incorrect assumptions about risk, abundant experience might result into overconfidence. Coherently the type of experience brings different risk preferences to the board. Experience accumulated from the same industry or company will bring specific market knowledge, preferring investment strategies to aggressive market strategies (Sirmon et al, 2008). This can bring about incorrect results for scholars using investment or certain strategies as a measure for risk taking. Lastly when headhunting for top-level executives special attention needs to be given to how this would affect the team homogeneity. For that the candidates’ prior experience, surface-level attributes and deeper-level factors should be examined.

(35)

to one’s own risk preference. As Pathan (2009) argues independent boards might be independent from the management but perhaps too independent from the shareholders as well. Risk taking in a firm is the result of interplay between the managers, supervisors and shareholders as well as environmental and national factors. Shareholders should aim for an efficiently functioning supervisory board but should not neglect to provide sufficient managerial discretion to managers.

Implications for Research

(36)

in literature, I also want to direct attention to exploring the link between psychological attributes and problem framing. This is particularly important as problem framing is considered to be closely related to risk taking. Furthermore the interplay between psychological attributes and ‘social influence’ as well as ‘organizational control systems’ seems to be promising. ‘Social influence’ or how organizations affect one’s behavior and perception is surely different for different psychological attributes. Likewise one’s behavior with respect to the way organizations rewards certain behavior deserves more attention.

Prospect theory (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979), which suggest that in the area of gains decision makers tend to be more risk averse, is thought to be influenced by a person’s affective state (Seo et al. 2010) either reducing or enhancing the effect. In the proposed model this is depicted as the feedback loop from the outcome of a decision to risk propensity. However one can argue that emotions experienced by an outcome is related to one’s psychological profile. Where somatic theories argues that emotions are simply the feelings of certain bodily changes as a result of perception of some fact (Ellsworth, 1994), cognitive theories (Mindler, 1984; Solomon, 1993) discuss that; judgments, thoughts, and evaluations are necessary for an affective state to establish. Further studies between the interplay of emotions, and psychological factors are necessary considering this under investigated area. Affect research combined with models of risk taking can produce new insights.

(37)

affect the person’s managerial discretion when evaluated by stakeholder. Coherently psychological traits and characteristics might further change an individual’s perception of his discretion and therefore affects outcome.

Conclusions

(38)

REFERENCES

Aldrich, H. 1979. Organizations and environments. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

Agrawal, A., & Knoeber, C. 1999. Outside directors, politics, and firm performance. Working Paper, North Carolina State University.

Anderson, R. C., Mansi S. A., & Reeb, D. M. 2004. Board characteristics, accounting report integrity, and the cost of debt. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 37: 315-342.

Baird, I. S., & Thomas, H. 1985. Toward a contingency model of strategic risk taking. Academy of Management Review, 10: 230-243.

Baliga, B. R., & Moyer, C. 1996. CEO duality and firm performance: What’s the fuss? Strategic Management Journal, 17: 41-53.

Bhagat, S., & Black, B. 1997. Do independent directors matter? Working Paper, Columbia University.

Bhagat, S., & Black, B. 2002. The non-correlation between board independence and long-term firm performance. Journal of Corporation Law, 27: 231-273.

Bakshi, G. S. & Chen, Z. 1994. Baby boom, population aging, and capital markets. Journal of Business, 67: 165-202.

Bajtelsmit, V. L. & Bernasek, A. 1996. Why do women invest differently than men? Financial Counseling and Planning, 7: 1-10.

Barnhart, S.W., Marr, M.W., & Rosenstein, S. 1994. Firm performance and board

composition: Some new evidence. Managerial and Decision Economics, 15: 329-340. Baron, G., Leider, S., & Stack, J. 2008. The effect of safe experience on a warning’s

impact: Sex, drugs, and rock-n-roll. Organizational behavior and human decision processes, 106: 125-142.

(39)

Bateman, T. S. 1986. The escalation of commitment in sequential decision making: situational and personal moderators and limiting conditions. Decision Sciences, 17: 33-49.

Bateman, T. S., & Zeithaml C. P. 1989. The psychological context of strategic decisions: A model and convergent experimental findings. Strategic Management Journal, 10:

59-74.

Bauer, R. A. 1967. Consumer Behavior as Risk Taking. In D. Cox (Ed.), Risk taking and information handling in consumer behavior: 23-33 Reprint, Boston: Harvard

University Press.

Beach, L. R., & Strom, E. 1990. A toadstool among the mushrooms: Screening decisions and image theory's compatibility test. Acta Psychologica, 72: 1-12.

Bebchuk, L.A. & Fried, J. M. 2003. Executive compensation as an agency problem. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17: 71-92.

Berry, J. W. 1967. Independence and conformity in subsistence-level societies. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 7: 415-418.

Bettman, J. R. 1973. Perceived risk and its components: A model and empirical test. Journal of Market Research, 10: 184-190.

Block, S. 1999. The role of non-affiliated outside directors in monitoring the firm and the effect on shareholder wealth. Journal of Financial and Strategic Decisions, 12(1): 1-8.

Booth, J., & Daniel, D. 1999. On executives of financial institutions as outside directors. Journal of Corporate Finance, 5: 227-250

Borokhovich, K., Brunarski, K., Crutchley, C., & Simkins, B. 2004. Board composition and corporate use of interest rate derivatives. The Journal of Financial Research, 27: 199-216.

Bowman, E. H. 1980. A risk/return paradox for strategic management. Sloan Management Review, 21(3): 17-31.

(40)

Brealey, R., & Myers. S. 1981. Principles of corporate finance. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Co.

Brickley, J. A., Coles, J. F., & Terry, R. L. 1994. Outside directors and the adoptions of poison pills. Journal of Financial Economics, 35: 371−390.

Brickley, J. A., Coles, J. F., & Jarrell, G. 1997. Leadership structure: Separating the CEO and chairman of the board. Journal of Corporate Finance, 3(3): 189-220.

Brown, D. P. 1990. Age clienteles induced by liquidity constraints. International Economic Review, 31: 891-912.

Buchanan, B. 1974. Building organizational commitment: The socialization of managers in work organizations. Administrative Science Quarterly, 19: 533–546.

Byrd, J. J., & Hickman, K. A. 1992. Do outside directors monitor managers? Journal of Financial Economics, 32: 195−221.

Canavan, J., Jones, B., & Potter, M. J. 2004. Board tenure: how long is too long? Directors and Boards, 28(2): 39-42.

Carpenter, J. A., & Westphal, J. D. 2001. The strategic context of external network ties: Examining the impact of director appointments on board involvement in strategic decision-making. The Academy of Management Journal, 44(4): 639-660.

Chaganti, R., Mahajan, V., & Sharma, S. 1985. Corporate board size, composition and corporate failures in retailing industry. Journal of Management Studies, 22: 400-417. Chatterjee, A., & Hambrick, D. 2007. It’s all about me: Narcissistic chief executive

officers and their effects on company strategy and performance. Administrative Science Quarterly, 52: 351-386.

Cheng, S. 2008. Board size and the variability of corporate performance. Journal of Financial Economics, 87(1): 157-176.

Cohen, M. D., March, J. G., & Olsen, J. P. 1972. A garbage can model of organizational choice. Administrative Science Quarterly, 17: 1-25.

Colson, E. 1974. Tradition and Contract: The Problem of Order. Chicago, IL: Aldine. Cooper, C., Fletcher, J., Gilbert, D., & Wanhill, S. 1998. Tourism principles and practice

(41)

Core, J. E., Holthausen, R. W., & Larcker, D. F. 1999. Corporate governance, chief executive officer compensation, and firm performance. Journal of Financial Economics, 51(3): 371-406.

Cotter, J., Shivdasani, A., & Zenner, M. 1997. Do independent directors enhance target shareholder wealth during tender offers? Journal of Financial Economics, 43: 195-218.

Crossland, C., & Hambrick, D. 2007. How national systems differ in their constraints on corporate executives: A study of CEO effects in three countries. Strategic

Management Journal, 28: 767-789.

Crossland, C., & Hambrick, D. 2011. Differences in managerial discretion across countries: How national-level institutions affect the degree to which CEOs matter. Strategic Management Journal, forthcoming.

Davis-Blake, A., & Pfeffer, J. 1989. Just a mirage: The search for dispositional effects in organizational research. Academy of Management Review, 14: 385-400.

Dearborn, D. C., &. Simon, H. A. 1958. Selective perception: A note on the departmental identification of executives. Sociometry, 21: 140-144.

Delgado-Garcia, J. B., Fuente-Sabate de la, J. M., & Quevedo-Puente de, E. 2010. Too negative to take risks? The effect of the CEO’s emotional traits on firm risk. British Journal of Management, 21: 313–326.

Demsetz, H. & Lehn, K. 1985. The structure of corporate ownership: Causes and consequences. Journal of Political Economy, 93: 1155-1177.

Desai, A., Kroll, M., & Wright, P. 2003. CEO duality, board monitoring, and acquisition performance: a test of competing theories. Journal of Business Strategies, 20(2): 137-156.

Douglas, M., & Wildavsky, A. 1982. Risk and culture. Berkeley: University of California Press.

Dowling, G., & Staelin, R. 1994. A model of perceived risk and intended risk-handling activity. Journal of Consumer Research, 21(1): 119-35.

(42)

Eisenhardt, K. M. 1989. Agency theory: An assessment and review. Academy of Management and Review, 14(1): 57-74.

Ellsworth, P. C. 1994. William James and emotion: Is a century of fame worth a century of misunderstanding? Psychological Review, 101(2): 222-229.

Erkens, D., Mingyi, H., & Pedro, M. 2009. Corporate governance in the 2007-2008 financial crisis: Evidence from financial institutions worldwide. Working Paper University of Southern California, Marshall School of Business, Los Angeles.

Esty, B. 1998. The impact of contingent liability on commercial bank risk taking. Journal of Financial Economics, 47: 189-218.

Fama, E. F. 1980. Agency problems and the theory of the firm. Journal of Political Economy, 88: 715−732.

Fama, E. F., & Jensen, M. C. 1983. Seperation of ownership and control. Journal of Law and Economics, 26(2): 301-325.

Fich, E., & White, L. 2005. Why do CEOs reciprocally sit on each other's boards? Journal of Corporate Finance, 11: 175-195.

Fiegenbaum, A., & Thomas, H. 1988. Attitudes toward risk and the risk-return paradox: Prospect theory explanations. Academy of Management Journal, 31: 85-106.

Finkelstein, S., & Boyd, B. 1998. How much does the CEO matter? The role of

managerial discretion in the setting of CEO compensation. Academy of Management Journal, 41: 179-199.

Finkelstein, S., & D’ Aveni, R. A. 1994. CEO duality as a double-edged sword: How boards of directors balance entrenchment. Academy of Management Journal, 37(5): 1079-1108.

Finkelstein, S., & Hambrick, D. 1990. Top management team tenure and organizational outcomes: The moderating role of managerial discretion. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35: 484-503.

Fischhoff, B., Lichtenstein, S., Slovic, P., Derby, S. L., & Keeney, R. L. 1981. Acceptable risk. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press.

(43)

Fiske, S. T. 1980. Attention and weight in person perception: The impact of negative and extreme behavior. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 38: 889-906. Gaertner, K. N. 1988. Managers' careers and organizational change. Academy of

Management Executive, 2(4): 311-31

Galai, D., & Masulis, R. 1976. The option pricing model and the risk factor of stock. Journal of Financial Economics, 3: 53-81.

Geletkanycz, M. A., & Hambrick, D. C. 1997. The external ties of top executives:

Implications for strategic choice and performance. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42: 654-681.

Gelfand, M. J., Nishii, L. H., & Raver, J. L. 2006. On the nature and importance of cultural tightness- looseness. Journal of Applied Psychology, 91: 1225-1244. Gertner, R., & Kaplan, S. N. 1997. The value-maximizing board. Working Paper,

University of Chicago.

Gibbs, P. A. 1993. Determinants of corporate restructuring: The relative importance of corporate governance, takeover threat, and free cash flow. Strategic Management Journal, Summer Special Issue 14: 51−68.

Grable, J. E. & Lytton, R. H. 1998. Investor risk tolerance: Testing the efficacy of demographics as differentiating and classifying factors. Financial Counseling and Planning, 9(1): 61-74.

Grey, R. J., & Gordon, G. G. 1978. Risk-taking managers: Who gets the top jobs? Management Review, 67(11): 8-13.

Grewal, D., Gotlieb, J., & Marmorstein, H. 1994. The moderating effects of message framing and source credibility on the price-perceived risk relationship. Journal of Consumer Research, 21(1): 145-153.

Goodstein, J., Gautam, K., & Boeker, W. 1994. The effects of board size and diversity on strategic change. Strategic Management Journal, 15: 241-250.

Haddock, C. 1993. Managing risks in outdoor activities. Wellington: New Zealand Mountain Safety Council.

(44)

Hambrick, D. C., & Finkelstein S. 1987. Managerial discretion: A bridge between polar views of organizational outcomes. In B. Staw & L. Cummings, (Eds.), Research in Organizational Behavior (Vol. 9): 369-406. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

Hayward, M., & Hambrick, D. 1997. Explaining the premium paid for large acquisitions: Evidence of CEO hubris. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42: 103-127

Helmke, G., & Levitsky, S. 2004. Informal institutions and comparative politics: A research agenda. Perspectives on Politics, 2: 725-740.

Helmke, G., & Levitsky, S. 2006. Informal Institutions and Democracy: Lessons from Latin America. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Hermalin, B. E., & Weisbach, M. S. 1988. The determinants of board composition. Rand Journal of Economics, 19: 589−606.

Hermalin, B. E. & Weisbach, M. S. 2003. Boards of directors as an endogenously

determined institution: A survey of the economic literature. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review, April: 7-26.

Higbee, K. L. & Lafferty, T. 1972. Relationships among risk preferences, importance, and control. The Journal of Psychology, 81: 249-251.

Higgs, D. 2003. Review of the role and effectiveness of non-executive directors. London: The Stationery Office.

Hiller, N., & Hambrick, D. 2005. Conceptualizing executive hubris: The role of (hyper-) core self-evaluations in strategic decision-making. Strategic Management Journal, 26: 297-319.

Hofstede, G. 1980. Culture's consequences: International differences in work related values. London: Sage.

Hofstede, G. 2001. Culture's Consequences: Comparing Values, Behaviors, Institutions, and Organizations across Nations (2nd ed.). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.

Hoover, R. J., Green, R. T., & Saegert, J. 1978. A cross-national study of perceived risk. Journal of Marketing, 42(3): 102-108.

(45)

Huse, M. 1994. Board-management relations in small firms: The paradox of simultaneous independence and Interdependence. Small Business Economics, 6: 55-72.

Ingene, C. A., & Hughes, M. A. 1985. Risk management by consumers. In J. Sheth (Ed.), Research in Consumer Behavior (Vol. 1): 103-158, Greenwich, CT JAI.

Cohn, R. A., Lewellen, W. G., Lease, R. C., & Schlarbaum, G. G. 1975. Individual financial risk aversion and investment portfolio composition. Journal of Finance, 30: 605-620.

Janis, I. L. 1972. Victims of groupthink. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

Jemison, D. B., & Sitkin, S. B. 1986. Corporate quisitions: A process perspective. Academy of Management Review, 11: 145-163.

Jensen, M. C. 1993. The modern industrial revolution, exit and the failure of internal control systems. The Journal of Finance, 48: 831−880.

Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3: 305-360.

Jiménez, G., Lopez, J. A., & Saurina, J. 2007. How does competition impact bank risk-taking? Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco: Working Paper Series.

John, K. and Senbet, L. 1998. Corporate governance and board effectiveness. Journal of Banking & Finance, 22: 371-403.

Johnson, E., & Tversky, A. 1983. Affect, generalization, and the perception of risk. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 45: 20–31.

Johnson, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. 2000. Tunneling. American Economic Review, 90: 22-27.

Judge, W. Q., & Zeithaml, C. P. 1992. Institutional and strategic choice perspectives on board involvement in the strategic decision making process. Academy of Management Journal, 35: 766-794.

(46)

Klein, A. 2002. Audit committee, board of director characteristics, and earnings management. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 33: 375-400.

Kirkpatrick, G. 2009. The corporate governance lessons from the financial crisis. OECD Journal: Financial Market Trends, 3(1): 61-87.

Kogan, N., & Wallach, M. A. 1964. Risk taking: A study in cognition and personality. New York: Holt, Rinehart, & Winston.

Kosnik, R. D. 1987. Greenmail: A Study of Board Performance in Corporate Governance, Administrative Science Quarterly, 32: 163-185

Kroll, M., Walters, B. A., & Le Son, A. 2007. The impact of board composition and top management team ownership structure on post-IPO performance in young

entrepreneurial firms. Academy of management Journal, 50(5), 1198-1216. Kuhberger, A. 1995. The framing of decisions: A new look at old problems.

Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 62: 230–240.

Laeven, L., & Levine, R. 2009. Corporate governance, regulation, and bank risk taking. Journal of Financial Economics, 93(2): 259-275.

Langer, E. J. 1975. The illusion of control. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 32: 311-328.

Langer, E. J. 1978. Rethinking the role of thought in social interaction. In J. Harvey, W. Ickes, & R.F. Kidd (Eds.), New directions in attribution research, 2: 35-58. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.

Larcker, D., Richardson, S., & Tuna, I. 2005. How important is corporate governance? Working Paper no. 1-84, The Wharton School University of Pennsylvania,

Philadelphia, PA.

Lefcourt, H. M. 1973. The function of the illusion of control and freedom. American Psychologist, 28: 417-425.

Lewicka, M. 1997. Is hate wiser than love? Cognitive and emotional utilities in decision Making. In R. Ranyard, W. R. Crozier & O. Svenson (Eds.), Decision Making: Cognitive Models and Explanations, New York, NY: Routledge.

(47)

Linville, P., & Fisher, G. 1991. Preferences for separating or combining events. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 60: 5-23

Lipton, M., & Lorsch, J. W. 1992. A modest proposal for improved corporate governance. Business Lawyer, 48: 59-77.

Louis, M. R. 1980.Surprise and sense making: What newcomers experience in entering unfamiliar organizational settings. Administrative Science Quarterly, 25: 226-251. MacCrimmon, K. R., & Wehrung, D. A. 1990. Characteristics of risk taking executives.

Management Science, 36: 422-435.

Mace, M. 1986. Directors: Myth and Reality. Boston: Harvard Business School Press. March, J. C, & Shapira, Z. 1987. Managerial perspectives on risk and risk-taking.

Management Science, 33: 1404-1418.

March, J.G., &Simon, H.A. 1958. Organizations. New York: Wiley.

Mallette, P., & Fowler, K. L. 1992. Effects of board composition and stock ownership on the adoption of "poison pills." Academy of Management Journal, 35: 1010-1035. McCue, C. P. 2000. The risk-return paradox in local government investing. Public

Budgeting & Finance, 20(3): 80-101.

Mehran, H., & Rosenberg, J. 2007. The effect of CEO stock options on bank investment choice, borrowing, and capital. Working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Meyer, J. D., Gaschke, Y. N., Braverman, D. L., & Evans, T. W. 1992. Mood-congruent judgment is a general effect. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 63, 119-132.

Mandler, G. (1984). Mind and body: Psychology of emotion and stress. New York: Norton.

Mitchell, V. W. 1999. Consumer perceived risk: Conceptualizations and models. European Journal of Marketing, 33(1/2): 163-195.

(48)

Mol, M. 2001. Creating wealth through working with others: Inter-organizational relationships. The Academy of Management Executive, 15(1): 150-152.

Moutinho, L. 2000. Consumer behavior in tourism, strategic management in tourism. New York: CABI.

Neale, M. A., Bazerman, M. H., Northcraft, G. B., & Alperson, C. 1986. "Choice shift" effects in group decisions: A decision bias perspective. International Journal of Small Group Research, March: 33-42.

Nelson, R., & Winter, S. 1982. An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Nelson, R. R., & Nelson, K. 2002. Technology, institutions, and innovation systems. Research Policy, 31: 256-272.

OECD. 1998. Corporate governance and corporate performance. Ad hoc Task Force on Corporate Governance, Report SG/CG: (98) 7.

Osborn, R. N., & Jackson, D. H. 1988. Leaders, riverboat gamblers, or purposeful unintended consequences in the management of complex dangerous technologies. Academy of Management Journal, 31: 924-947.

Palsson, A-M. 1996. Does the degree of relative risk aversion vary with household characteristics? Journal of Economic Psychology, 17: 771-787

Pathan, S. 2009. Strong boards, CEO power and bank risk-taking. Journal of Banking and Finance, 33(7):1340-1350.

Pfeffer, J. 1972. Size and composition of corporate boards of directors: The organization and its environment. Administrative Science Quarterly, 17: 218-228.

Pfeffer, J. 1973. Size, composition, and function of hospital boards of directors: A study of organization-environment linkage. Administrative Science Quarterly, 18: 349-364. Pfeffer, J. & Salancik, G. R. 1978. The external control of organizations. New York:

Harper & Row.

(49)

Raheja, C.G. 2005. Determinants of board size and composition: A theory of corporate bonds. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 40(2), 283.

Rasiel, E. B., Weinfurt, K. P. & Schulman, K. A. 2005. Can prospect theory explain risk-seeking behavior by terminally ill patients? Medical Decision Making, 25: 609-613. Rechner, P. L., & Dalton, D. R. 1991. CEO duality and organizational performance: A

longitudinal analysis. Strategic Management Journal, 12: 155-160.

Roehl, W. S., & Fesenmaier D. R. 1992. Risk perception and pleasure travel: An explanatory analysis. Journal of Travel Research, 30 (4): 17-26.

Rosenstein, S., & Wyatt, J. G. 1990. Outside directors, board independence, and shareholder wealth. Journal of Financial Economics, 26: 175−192.

Rosenstein, S., & Wyatt, J. G. 1997. Inside directors, board effectiveness, and shareholder wealth. Journal of Financial Economics, 44: 229-250.

Rowe, W. D. 1977. An anatomy of risk. New York: Wiley.

Roszkowski, M. J. 1998. Risk tolerance in financial decisions. In D. M. Cordell (ed.), Readings in Financial Planning : 281-328. Bryn Mawr, PA: The American College. Sarkar, J., & Sarkar, S. 2009. Multiple board assignments and firm performance in

emerging economies: Evidence from India. Pacific-Basin Financial Journal, 17(2): 271-293.

Schein, E. H. 1985. Organizational culture and leadership. San Francisco: Jossey-Bas. Schoorman, F., Bazerman, M., & Atkin, R. 1981. Interlocking directorates: A Strategy for

reducing environmental uncertainty. Academy of Management Review, 6: 243-251. Schwartz, S. H. 1994. Beyond individualism/collectivism: New cultural dimensions of

values. In U. Kim, H. C. Triandis, C. Kagitcibasi, S. C. Choi & G. Yoon (Eds.),

Individualism and Collectivism: Theory, Method, and Applications: 85-119. Sage: Thousand Oaks, CA.

(50)

Seo, M. G., Goldfarb, B., & Barett, L. F. 2010. Affect and the framing effect within individuals over time: Risk taking in a dynamic investment simulation. Academy of Management Journal, 53(2): 411–431.

Shaw, K. L. 1996. An empirical analysis of risk aversion and income growth. Journal of Labor Economics, 14: 626-653.

Shen, W. 2003. The dynamics of the CEO – board relationship: An evolutionary perspective. Academy of Management Review, 28(3): 466-476.

Shen, W., & Cho, T. S. 2005. Exploring involuntary executive turnover through a managerial discretion framework. Academy of Management Review, 30: 843-854. Shivdasani, A. 1993. Board composition, ownership structure and hostile takeovers.

Journal of Accounting and Economics, 16: 167-198.

Shivdasani, A., & Yermack, D. 1999. CEO involvement in the selection of new board members: An empirical analysis. The Journal of Finance, 54(5): 1829-1853.

Shleifer, A. & Vishny, R. 1997. A survey of corporate governance. Journal of Finance, 52(2): 737-783.

Singh, J. 1986. Performance, slack, and risk taking in organizational decision making. Academy of Management Journal, 29: 562-585.

Singh, H., & Harianto, F. 1989. Management-board relationships, takeover risk, and the adoption of golden parachutes. Academy of Management Journal, 32: 7-24.

Sirmon, D. G., Fraser, D. Tuggle, C. S., Haynes, K. T., & Baradwaj, B. G, 2008. Exploring how directors' prior extra- and intra-industry board experiences affect the formulation of functional strategies. Academy of Management Best Paper

Proceedings: 1-6.

Sitkin, S. B., & Pablo, A. L. 1992. Reconceptualizing the determinants of risk behavior. Academy of Management Review, 17: 9-39.

Sitkin, S. B., & Weingart, L. R. 1995. Determinants of risky decision-making behavior: A test of the mediating role of risk perceptions and propensity. Academy of

Management Journal, 38(6): 1573-1592.

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

In the jointly determined CEO stock and stock option compensation package, I find that a higher sensitivity of CEO wealth to stock price (delta) will decrease corporate

Reflecting the primary studies, the Market and Opportunity category typically described either the market characteristics, such as environmental dynamism, environmental

When automated steering is deactivated by the system because of system limitations, some systems warn with an auditory warning, some fall out of automation silently (visual

The presented approach for a target oriented integration of Industrie 4.0 in lean production systems integrates design thinking elements into the value stream mapping

System optimization requires research on antenna parameters, propagation mechanism, diversity, chan- nel parameters, modulation techniques and coding.. While specialization is

This is the subject of future research, EurSafety Health Net; the development of an online communication platform to support all stakeholders (patients, payers, policy-makers,

ze, aansturing en faciliteiten van de teams bogen. De voorstellen van de werkgroepen zijn samengebracht in een handreiking voor de sociale wijkteams om zo een zekere uniformering

Comparison of catalytic performance of the NiMo and CoMo catalysts Both the NiMo and CoMo catalyst on alumina are active for the hydrotreatment of the pyrolysis liquids obtained