• No results found

How do different sources of knowledge iinfluence dynamic capabilities?

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "How do different sources of knowledge iinfluence dynamic capabilities?"

Copied!
49
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

   

 

 

 

How  do  different  sources  of  knowledge  influence  dynamic  

capabilities?  

                Master  thesis    

MSc.  Business  Administration  -­‐  Strategy  track   University  of  Amsterdam  

Author:  Maaike  Vogel   Student  ID:  6039049  

Supervisor:  Sebastian  Kortmann  

Final  Version  submitted  on  31st  of  January  2015    

(2)

Abstract  

This  paper  explores  the  commonalities  of  dynamic  capabilities  cross  effective  

development  teams.  Thereby  it  focuses  on  the  role  of  knowledge  resources.  According   to  the  latest  strategy  literature,  firms  should  be  able  to  reconfigure  their  resources  in   favour  of  the  new  market  trends  and  developments.  This  is  done  with  dynamic   processes  and  routines  defined  as  dynamic  capabilities.  Although  the  resource   configurations  resulting  from  dynamic  capabilities  are  unique,  the  foundations  for   efficient  dynamic  capabilities  seem  to  be  quit  homogenous  across  firms.  In  dynamic   markets  the  processes  that  manipulate  knowledge  resources  are  especially  important.   Therefore,  this  thesis  investigates  commonalities  regarding  dynamic  capabilities  that   (1)  gain,  (2)  integrate  and  (3)  reconfigure  knowledge  resources.  The  focus  is  on   dynamic  capabilities  in  the  product  development  process.  

By  addressing  this  agenda,  attempt  is  made  to  support  current  dynamic  

capabilities  literature  with  empirical  evidence  and  connect  this  literature  with  that  of   specific  dynamic  processes.  

The  conceptual  model  proposes  a  direct  effect  of  team  tenure  and  use  of  explicit   knowledge  sources  on  the  dependent  variable  innovative  output.  In  addition,  the   indirect  effect  of  implicit  knowledge  present  in  the  inventor  team  is  investigated.  The   hypotheses  are  answered  using  a  patent  database  of  the  US  mobile  telecom  industry.    

Similar  to  prior  research  commonalities  are  found  across  firms  in  dynamic   processes  gain,  integrate  and  reconfigure  knowledge  resources.  The  conceptual  model   explains  a  variance  of  the  dependent  variable  significantly.  Team  tenure,  gaining  of   explicit  knowledge  externally  and  knowledge  brokering  are  proven  to  be  important  for  

(3)

Statement  of  originality  

 

This  document  is  written  by  Maaike  Vogel  who  declares  to  take  full  responsibility  for   the  contents  of  this  document.    

I  declare  that  the  text  and  the  work  presented  in  this  document  is  original  and  that  no   sources  other  than  those  mentioned  in  the  text  and  its  references  have  been  used  in   creating  it.    

The  Faculty  of  Economics  and  Business  is  responsible  solely  for  the  supervision  of   completion  of  the  work,  not  for  the  contents.    

 

                       

(4)

Table  of  contents  

1.    Introduction  ...  5   2.  Literature  review  ...  8   2.1.  Dynamic  capabilities  ...  8   2.2.  Knowledge  resources  ...  12   2.3.  Gaining  resources  ...  13  

2.4.  Integration  of  resources  ...  15  

2.5.  Reconfiguration  of  resources  ...  17  

3.  Conceptual  model  and  hypotheses  ...  20  

3.1.  Team  tenure  ...  21  

3.2.  Explicit  knowledge  ...  22  

3.3.  Implicit  knowledge  ...  24  

4.  Data  and  Method  ...  26  

4.1.  Use  of  patent  data  ...  26  

4.2.  Sample  ...  28  

4.3.  Dependent  variable  ...  29  

4.4.  Independent  variables  ...  31  

4.5.  Control  variables  ...  32  

5.  Results  ...  34  

5.1.  Direct  effect  of  team  tenure  and  explicit  knowledge  on  innovative  output  ...  34  

5.2.  Mediating  effect  of  implicit  knowledge  ...  37  

6.  Discussion  ...  38  

6.1.  Discussion  of  results  ...  38  

6.2.  Implications  and  future  research  ...  40  

6.3.  Limitations  ...  41  

7.  Conclusion  ...  43  

(5)

1.    Introduction  

Throughout  the  years  strategy  scholars  have  been  trying  to  find  out  what  kind  of  firms   outperform  others  and  what  are  the  sources  of  their  competitive  advantage.    According   to  the  resource-­‐based  view  owning  valuable  assets  and  resources  is  essential  to  be   competitive  (Barney,  2001;  Collis  &  Montgomery,  1999;  Priem  &  Butler,  2001).   However  recent  studies  (Buderi,  1999;  Eisenhardt  &  Martin,  2000;  Teece,  Pisano,  &   Shuen,  1997)  claim  just  owning  valuable  resource  is  not  enough  in  markets  where  the   competitive  landscape  is  constantly  changing.  Firms  should  be  able  to  create  and  renew   asset  and  resource  configurations  to  gain  competitive  advantage.  Especially  in  

industries  where  competition  is  fierce  and  technologies  change  rapidly,  innovation  has   become  crucial  for  firms  to  survive  (Nonaka  &  Takeuchi,  1997).    

The  ability  to  constantly  reconfigure  internal  and  external  competencies  in  order   to  be  innovative  is  called  ‘dynamic  capability’.  The  theory  by  Eisenhardt  and  Martin   (2000)  states  that  dynamic  capabilities  are  processes  that  integrate,  reconfigure,  gain   and  release  resources  to  match  or  create  market  change.  Examples  of  these  processes   are  product-­‐development,  strategic  decision-­‐making  and  alliancing,  which  are  mostly   performed  on  individual  or  team  level.  These  capabilities  often  have  substantial  

research  streams  related  with  them.  Prior  research  shows  effective  dynamic  capabilities   have  commonalities  across  effective  firms.  This  thesis  attempts  to  identify  such  

commonalities.    

Dynamic  capabilities  are  present  in  all  shapes  and  sizes,  however  this  study   focuses  on  dynamic  processes  in  which  knowledge-­‐based  resources  are  reconfigured,   gained  or  integrated.  Knowledge-­‐based  resources  are,  more  than  other  kinds  of   resources,  subject  to  change.  The  value  of  knowledge-­‐based  resources  decays  in  time  

(6)

very  quickly  compared  to  other  resources,  like  capital-­‐  or  location-­‐based  resources.   Therefore,  it  is  crucial  that  the  knowledgebase  is  renewed,  reconfigured  and  integrated   in  an  efficient  manner.  Nonaka  (1994)  even  claims  that  innovation  is  synonym  for   creation  or  recombination  of  knowledge.    

A  distinction  can  be  made  between  two  types  of  knowledge,  explicit  and  implicit   knowledge  (Smith,  2001).  Explicit  knowledge  is  codified  information  that  can  be  

transferred  through  tangible  media  like  academic  papers  and  manuals.  With  efficient   dynamic  capabilities,  explicit  knowledge  sources  can  be  combined  for  new  purposes,   also  known  as  knowledge  brokering.  Implicit  knowledge  is  captured  within  individuals   in  the  form  of  know-­‐how.  Personal  contact  is  essential  for  transfer  of  implicit  

knowledge  from  one  person  to  another.  To  manage  the  gaining,  integration  and   reconfiguration  of  resources  effectively,  dynamic  capabilities  are  needed.    

This  study  investigates  the  common  features  among  effective  dynamic   capabilities.  Thereby,  the  focus  is  on  dynamic  capabilities  that  gain,  integrate  or   reconfigure  knowledge  resources.  The  research  question  is  therefore:  What  types  of   implicit  and  explicit  knowledge  sources  have  positive  effect  on  dynamic  

capability  of  a  development  team?    

The  theory  of  dynamic  capabilities  is  often  criticized  as  being  non-­‐specific,  vague   and  tautological  (Mosakowski  &  McKelvey,  1997;  Priem  &  Butler,  2001).  In  this  

research  attempt  is  made  to  contribute  to  the  dynamic  capabilities  literature  by   empirically  supporting  the  statement  (Eisenhardt  &  Martin,  2000)  that  dynamic   capabilities  are  concrete,  identifiable  processes,  rather  than  an  abstract  concept.  In   addition,  a  connection  is  made  between  the  dynamic  capabilities  literature  and  the   literature  streams  connected  to  the  specific  dynamic  processes  like  knowledge  

(7)

brokering  and  team  organization.  Thereby,  common  features  among  effective  firms  and   project  groups  are  identified.  The  outcomes  of  the  research  can  be  useful  for  further   research  into  the  commonalities  among  dynamic  capabilities.  Managers  can  use  the   information  to  understand  and  optimize  their  own  dynamic  capabilities.  

In  order  to  answer  the  research  question,  a  patent  database  of  the  U.S.  wireless   telecom  industry  from  1971  till  2006  is  used.  The  wireless  telecom  industry  is  suitable   for  this  research  because  it  is  a  high-­‐velocity  and  high-­‐tech  industry.  The  need  to   innovate  for  firms  in  this  industry  is  high;  therefore  the  innovative  activity  is  clearly   visible  in  patent  data.  Dynamic  capability  is  measured  by  the  amount  of  forward   citations  a  patent  received.  This  gives  a  good  indication  of  the  economic  value  of  the   patent  and  thus  the  efficiency  of  a  firm’s  dynamic  capability.  Patent  data  is  a  widely   accepted  measure  for  innovative  activity.  In  contrast  to  R&D  expenditures,  patent  data   measures  the  inventive  output  instead  of  its  input.  

In  the  first  chapter,  the  different  views  of  dynamic  capabilities  and  several   processes  that  use  knowledge  resources  are  discussed.    Secondly,  the  findings  from   prior  research  are  connected  in  the  proposed  conceptual  model  and  hypotheses.  In  the   fourth  chapter  the  use  patent  data  as  research  method  is  discussed  and  the  different   variables  are  presented.  Next,  the  empirical  tests  and  results  will  be  described.  The   meanings  of  the  results  are  presented  in  the  discussion,  as  are  the  strengths  and   weaknesses  of  this  research.  Lastly,  a  conclusion  of  the  entire  study  is  given.  

 

 

   

(8)

2.  Literature  review  

The  objective  of  this  literature  review  is  to  give  a  clear  idea  of  what  dynamic  capabilities   are  and  which  specific  dynamic  processes  manipulate  knowledge  resources.  Thereby,   the  dynamic  capabilities  literature  and  the  literature  streams  of  knowledge-­‐based   processes  are  linked.  Through  this,  common  features  of  dynamic  capabilities  are   identified.  First,  the  different  theories  of  dynamic  capabilities  are  discussed.  Next,  the   difference  between  explicit  and  implicit  knowledge  is  addressed.  Finally,  the  processes   of  gaining,  integrating  and  reconfiguring  knowledge  resources  are  discussed.  

 

2.1.  Dynamic  capabilities  

In  the  existing  literature  there  are  several  different  views  on  dynamic  capabilities.    The   most  important  theories  are  discussed  in  this  chapter.  In  1997,  Teece  and  others  first   introduced  the  dynamic  capabilities  as  the  ability  to  constantly  reconfigure  internal  and   external  competencies  in  order  to  be  innovative  (Teece  et  al.,  1997).  Later,  Teece  (2007)   continues  investigating  dynamic  capabilities  and  states  enterprise  success  depends   upon  the  discovery  and  development  of  opportunities.  In  a  rapidly  changing  

environment,  gains  from  one  single  opportunity  decay  in  time  and  the  firm  will  have  to   come-­‐up  with  something  new.  For  an  organization  to  obtain  sustainable  competitive   advantage,  innovation  should  become  a  strategy  and  a  continuous  process.    

In  his  model  of  dynamic  capabilities,  Teece  subdivides  the  dynamic  processes   into  three  categories;  sensing  (and  shaping),  seizing  and  transformational  activities.   Sensing  is  recognizing  windows  of  opportunity  or  shaping  your  own  opportunities.   Sensing  new  opportunities  is  about  scanning,  learning  and  interpretation  of  existing  

(9)

fitting  service  or  product  and  commercialize  it  with  an  innovative  business  model.   Lastly,  as  a  firm  grows  through  innovation  it  has  more  assets  to  manage.  

Transformational  activities  are  related  to  the  effective  management  and   reconfiguration  of  these  assets.    

Zollo  &  Winter  (2002)  claim  dynamic  capabilities  result  from  several  learning   mechanisms.  They  define  the  concept  of  dynamic  capabilities  as  “a  learned  and  stable   pattern  of  collective  activity  through  which  the  organization  systematically  generates  and   modifies  its  operating  routines  in  pursuit  of  improved  effectiveness”.  In  addition  to  the   explanation  of  what  dynamic  capabilities  are,  Zollo  &  Winter  address  how  dynamic   capabilities  evolve.  They  state  dynamic  capabilities  develop  through  three  learning   mechanisms  namely;  tacit  accumulation  of  past  experience,  knowledge  articulation,  and   knowledge  codification  processes.  For  example,  a  firm  developing  an  effective  joint   venture  based  on  prior  experiences  in  cooperating  with  other  firms,  has  effective   dynamic  capability.      

 This  thesis  will  be  mainly  based  on  the  dynamic  capabilities  theory  of  

Eisenhardt  &  Martin  (2000,  p.1107).  Their  theory  originates  from  the  resource-­‐based   view,  in  which  unique  assets  and  resources  are  thought  to  be  source  of  competitive   advantage.    Eisenhardt  and  Martin  state  that  in  a  changing  market  environment,  a  firm   will  not  be  able  to  sustain  competitive  advantage  from  merely  owning  valuable  

resources.  To  stay  competitive,  a  firm  must  constantly  adapt  and  create  unique  and   valuable  resource  configurations.  They  define  dynamic  capabilities  as  follows:  

“The  firm’s  processes  that  use  resources—specifically  the  processes  to  integrate,   reconfigure,  gain  and  release  resources—to  match  and  even  create  market  change.   Dynamic  capabilities  thus  are  the  organizational  and  strategic  routines  by  which  firms  

(10)

achieve  new  resource  configurations  as  markets  emerge,  collide,  split,  evolve,  and  die.”    Eisenhardt  and  Martin  make  three  claims  about  dynamic  capabilities.  First,   dynamic  capabilities  are  identifiable  processes  and  routines  that  react  to,  or  create   change  in  the  marketplace.  They  categorise  these  processes  as  those  that,  1)  gain  and   release,  2)  integrate  and  3)  reconfigure  resources.  Gain  and  release  of  resources  is   done  knowledge  creation  processes,  exit  routines  exemplify  a  release  process.  An   example  of  a  process  that  integrates  resources  is  the  product  development  process.   Different  skills  and  experiences  are  integrated  to  create  profitable  new  products  and   services.  Dynamic  capabilities  that  focus  on  reconfiguration  of  resources  are  mainly   knowledge-­‐based  processes.  For  example  brokering  of  knowledge  from  previous   inventions  to  combine  it  into  new  solutions.    

The  categories  by  Eisenhardt  and  Martin  and  those  proposed  by  Teece  (2007)   can  be  related  to  each  other.    A  firm  should  gain  knowledge  about  their  customer’s   needs  and  wants  and  to  sense  opportunities  in  the  marketplace.  Next,  it  should   integrate  skills  and  experience  to  create  new  products  and  services  to  seize  these   opportunities.  Lastly,  it  should  constantly  reconfigure  its  resource  configurations  to  be   innovative  and  stay  competitive  in  a  changing  marketplace.  In  short,  it  can  be  said  that   the  categories  by  Eisenhardt  and  Martin  (2000)  describe  the  process  itself  and  Teece   (2007)  describes  the  purpose  of  these  processes.  

   The  second  claim  made  by  Eisenhardt  and  Martin  is  that  these  processes  have   commonalities  across  effective  firms  and  project  teams.  In  the  product  development   process  for  example,  teams  that  have  joint  experiences,  such  as  working  together  on  a   task  or  brainstorm  session,  are  more  efficient.  The  actual  synergies  created  between   different  team  members  are  however  different  from  case  to  case.  Because  the  

(11)

functionality  of  effective  capabilities  can  be  copied  across  firms  their  value  lies  in  the   resource  configurations  (synergies)  they  create,  and  not  in  the  capabilities  themselves.   According  to  this  theory,  dynamic  capabilities  are  necessary  for  competitive  advantage   but  having  efficient  dynamic  capability  is  not  a  competitive  advantage  by  itself.  

Lastly,  it  is  noticed  that  there  are  several  differences  in  dynamic  capability   patterns  between  moderately  dynamic  markets  and  high-­‐velocity  markets.  Moderately   dynamic  markets  are  markets  with  stable  industry  structure,  clear  market  boundaries   and  players.  Change  in  moderately  dynamic  markets  is  roughly  predictable.  The   dynamic  capabilities  therefore  are  stable,  detailed  and  efficient  processes.  They  rely   mostly  on  existing  knowledge  and  rules  of  thumb.    

In  high-­‐velocity  markets,  industry  boundaries  are  blurred,  players  are  

ambiguous  and  changes  are  unpredictable.  As  a  consequence,  dynamic  capabilities  are   rather  simple  routines  based  on  new  knowledge.  Technologies  and  trends  shift  quickly   and  processes  have  to  adjust  accordingly.  Simple  routines  should  provide  just  enough   structure  to  guide  people  through  the  dynamic  processes  and  create  situation-­‐specific   knowledge.  

In  this  thesis,  attempt  is  made  to  support  the  statements  made  by  Eisenhardt  and   Martin  with  empirical  evidence.  Three  specific  dynamic  capabilities  will  be  investigated,   namely  processes  that  integrate,  gain  and  reconfigure  knowledge  resources.  This  

research  will  try  to  confirm  that  there  are  commonalities  among  effective  dynamic   capabilities;  the  goal  is  to  discover  antecedents  that  enable  effective  resource  

reconfiguration,  integration,  and  gain.  The  claims  made  regarding  capabilities  in  high-­‐ velocity  markets  are  taken  in  account  since  the  industry  investigated  is  the  high-­‐velocity   mobile  telecom  industry.  

(12)

2.2.  Knowledge  resources  

According  to  the  resource  based  view  (RBV)  (Barney,  2001;  Collis  &  Montgomery,   1999),  valuable  resources  can  take  variety  of  forms;  they  can  be  tangible,  like  capital   and  a  strategic  manufacturing  location;  or  intangible,  like  brand  name  or  access  to   relevant  knowledge.  In  this  thesis  the  focus  will  be  on  dynamic  capabilities  that  are   integrating,  reconfiguring  and  gaining  knowledge  resources.  Company  archives,  

scientific  papers,  construction  manuals,  R&D  reports  and  even  employee  experience  are   all  knowledge-­‐based  resources.  As  stated  before,  dynamic  capabilities  are  processes   that  update  and  upgrade  resource  configuration  in  order  compete  in  changing   environment.  The  value  of  knowledge-­‐based  resources  decays  in  time  very  quickly   (Nonaka  &  Takeuchi,  1997).    Therefore,  the  manipulation  of  knowledge  resources,  in   particular,  is  critical  in  dynamic  markets,  especially  compared  to  other  kinds  of   resources  like  capital.  Prior  research  shows  the  ability  to  create  gain  knowledge  from   outside  the  firm  as  well  as  within  the  firm  has  substantial  impact  on  the  innovative   capability  of  the  firm  (Caloghirou,  Kastelli,  &  Tsakanikas,  2004).  

To  clarify  what  different  kinds  of  knowledge  are  of  influence  for  dynamic   capabilities,  a  distinction  is  made  between  two  types,  explicit  and  implicit  knowledge   (Smith,  2001).  Implicit  knowledge  is  ‘know-­‐how’  acquired  by  any  kind  of  personal   experience  in  for  example  university  or  work  practice.  The  work  practice  where  implicit   knowledge  is  used  is  often  spontaneous  and  responds  to  change.  Implicit  knowledge   includes  the  skill  of  creative  and  flexible  thinking,  which  develops  new  insights  and   eventually  explicit  knowledge.  An  important  characteristic  of  implicit  knowledge  is  the   fact  that  it  cannot  be  documented;  it  can  only  be  transferred  from  people-­‐to-­‐people   (Smith,  2001).      

(13)

Explicit  knowledge  is  ‘know-­‐what’  described  in  text  or  other  media  to  be  

transferred  to  other  people.  For  example,  knowledge  generated  from  scientific/business   journals,  which  proved  to  have  significant  influence  on  innovative  activity  (Caloghirou   et  al.,  2004).  Explicit  knowledge  is  often  codified  in  organised  routines  and  work   processes.  Explicit  knowledge  assumes  a  predictable  environment  (stable  competition   and  customer  needs)  and  creates  knowledge  objects  like  scientific  papers  or  work   manuals.    

To  continue,  specific  dynamic  capabilities  that  manipulate  implicit  and  explicit   knowledge  sources  will  be  discussed.  Thereby,  these  capabilities  will  be  categorized  as   processes  that  gain,  integrate  and  reconfigure  resources.  

 

2.3.  Gaining  resources  

As  mentioned  before  some  dynamic  capabilities  focus  on  gaining  resources.  Gaining  of   knowledge  resources  is  done  in  knowledge  creation  routines  and  acquisitions.  These   capabilities  are  particularly  important  in  industries  where  cutting-­‐edge  knowledge  is   essential  for  performance.  In  previous  research  several  commonalities  are  recognized   among  firms  with  effective  knowledge  gaining  routines  (Caloghirou  et  al.,  2004;   Hargadon,  2002;  Smith,  2001).  

Knowledge  resources  can  be  created  in-­‐house  via  research  or  can  be  gained   externally.  According  to  Caloghirou,  Kastelli,  &  Tsakanikas  (2004)  it  is  equally   important  for  upgrading  innovative  performance  to  be  open  towards  knowledge   sharing  as  it  is  to  have  knowledge  in-­‐house.  Eisenhardt  and  Martin  (2000)  state  that  in   moderately  dynamic  markets,  dynamic  capabilities  are  mostly  dependent  on  existing  

(14)

information,  while  in  high-­‐velocity  markets  they  are  mostly  dependent  on  new   knowledge.    

 Turbulent  environments  require  firms  and  processes  to  react  quickly  to  changes   in  the  market  place.  Thereby,  it  cannot  rely  only  on  its  own  knowledge  base  but  needs   to  benefit  from  the  experience  and  knowledge  of  other  economic  actors  (Schulz,  2001).   Acquiring  external  knowledge  requires  fewer  resources  than  internal  knowledge   creation.  In  addition,  internal  knowledge  creation  often  entails  managerial  challenges.   Hereby,  the  process  of  gaining  knowledge  externally  is  a  relatively  simple  process  that   is  easy  to  adjust  to  market  changes.  Thus,  gaining  knowledge  externally  contributes  to   effective  dynamic  capability  by  ensuring  strategic  flexibility  and  potential  first  mover   advantages  (Caloghirou  et  al.,  2004).  

 Examples  of  explicit,  external  knowledge  sources  are  scientific  papers,   conferences,  customer  evaluation  forms,  newspapers  etc.  These  sources  are  mostly   available  to  the  public  and  can  be  easily  gained  in  libraries  or  Internet.  Implicit   knowledge  however  can  only  be  transferred  from  people-­‐to-­‐people  it  can  only  be  

gained  externally  via  recruitment  of  experts  or  acquisition  of  other  firms.  Unfortunately,   the  dataset  used  for  this  research  does  not  contain  any  information  about  newly  

recruited  personal  or  acquisitions.  Therefore,  the  search  is  limited  to  gaining  of  explicit   knowledge.    

Explicit  knowledge  can  be  divided  in  two  categories,  technical  knowledge  and   market  knowledge.  This  research  focuses  on  sources  of  technical  nature,  because   technical  knowledge  is  the  knowledge  that  is  actually  gained  and  transformed  by   dynamic  capabilities  in  the  development  process.  Market  knowledge  is  used  for   application  and  commercialization  of  technological  knowledge  (Lichtenthaler,  2009).  

(15)

Beside  the  fact  that  gaining  knowledge  externally  is  an  easy  to  adapt,  dynamic   process:  gathering  information  that  is  already  out  there,  not  only  in  your  own  domain   but  also  outside  the  industry  borders,  can  help  to  overcome  a  narrow  search  horizon.   Overcoming  a  narrow  search  horizon  is  extremely  important  because,  the  more   different  kinds  of  knowledge  gained  the  more  new  combinations  can  be  made.  In   addition,  new  insights  can  reframe  and  upgrade  existing  knowledge  routines.  A   common  pitfall  for  firms,  is  to  become  prisoners  of  their  own  deeply  ingrained   assumptions,  information  filters,  and  problem-­‐solving  (Teece,  2007).  Katz  &  Allen   (1982)  call  this  pitfall  the  ‘not-­‐invented-­‐here-­‐syndrome’;  a  (project)  group  tends  to   believe  it  possesses  the  monopoly  of  knowledge  in  the  field.  Other  studies  describe  the   false  belief  that  the  same  practice  that  led  to  a  past  success  will  necessary  lead  to  a   future  one,  as  ‘the  lock-­‐out  effect’  or  ‘competency  trap’(Levitt  &  March,  1988;   Lichtenthaler,  2009).  

In  short,  use  of  externally  gained  explicit  knowledge,  and  especially  technical   knowledge,  can  have  positive  influence  on  dynamic  capability  because  looking  at  the   knowledge  that  is  out  in  the  field  can  help  overcome  a  narrow  local  search  horizon.   Secondly,  gaining  knowledge  externally  requires  fewer  resources  than  creating  it   internally.  In  addition,  it  is  an  easier  and  more  flexible  task  to  manage  from  a  

managerial  point  of  view.  Therefore,  it  can  be  easily  adapted  and  changed  in  order  to   react  to  changes  in  the  marketplace.  

 

2.4.  Integration  of  resources  

The  next  category  of  dynamic  capabilities  is  concerned  with  integration  of  resources.   Working  in  a  team  to  develop  new  products  or  ideas  is  such  a  dynamic  process.  

(16)

Different  skills,  expertise  and  backgrounds  are  integrated  to  make  an  effective   development  team.  Assuming  group  members  don’t  have  identical  experience,  cross   fertilization  of  knowledge  and  ideas  within  a  group  makes  a  team  more  effective  than  an   individual  (Ancona  &  Caldwell,  1992;  Horwitz  &  Horwitz,  2007;  Katz,  1982).  

  The  experience  and  skills  an  individual  possesses  can  be  seen  as  implicit  

knowledge  resources  (Nonaka  &  Takeuchi,  1997).  When  integrating  implicit  knowledge   in  a  development  team,  communication  is  very  important.  Implicit  knowledge  cannot  be   documented  but  only  transferred  face-­‐to-­‐face.  Prior  research  claims  that  interpersonal   communications  is  the  primary  means,  rather  than  scientific  research  and  other  written   documents,  to  collect  and  transfer  important  information  and  new  ideas  in  development   teams  (Allen,  1977;  Katz,  1982).    

The  better  the  individuals  are  connected  the  more  efficient  the  development   process  will  be  (Brown  &  Eisenhardt,  1995).  Many  studies  have  investigated  which   team  characteristics  lead  to  high  performance  (Ancona  &  Caldwell,  1992;  Horwitz  &   Horwitz,  2007;  Huckman  &  Staats,  2011).  There  are  two  team  characteristics  that  are   said  to  have  influence  on  the  knowledge  sharing  and  communication  within  a  team,   namely,  team-­‐size  and  team  tenure.    

Team  organization  stimulates  the  transfer  of  implicit  knowledge  from  one  team   member  to  other  team  members  (Zucker,  Darby,  &  Armstrong,  2002).  The  transfer  of   implicit  knowledge  requires  one-­‐on-­‐one  communication,  which  becomes  more  difficult   when  the  team  size  increases.  Team  size  should  balance  between  sufficiently  large  for   individuals  to  be  able  to  create  mutual  synergies,  while  not  greater  than  sufficient  to   keep  internal  communication  effective.    

(17)

A  characteristic  that  can  increase  internal  communication  and  thus  transfer  of   implicit  knowledge  is  team  tenure.  Katz  &  Allen  (1982)  found  that  performance   increased  up  to  16  months  average  tenure  but  that  group  performance  gradually   decayed  with  increasing  higher  levels  of  group  stability.  Familiarity  can  help  group   members  to  set  common  goals  and  priorities.  Concrete  experiences  with  others  on  the   development  team  create  a  common  experience  base  and  language  that  facilitates   communication  among  functionally  distinct  people  (Eisenhardt  &  Martin,  2000).  

 Thus,  communication  between  group  members  and  external  professional   communication  first  increases  with  familiarity.  However,  communication  declines  after   a  certain  breakpoint  (Ancona  &  Caldwell,  1992;  Huckman  &  Staats,  2011).  After  this   breakpoint,  the  team  becomes  more  and  more  isolated  from  external  (knowledge)   sources  and  team  members  become  less  receptive  for  ideas  that  contradict  with  the   familiar  work  practice.  The  team  becomes  conservative,  what  is  not  effective  for   dynamic  capabilities.    Thus,  tenure  might  have  a  two  sided,  curvilinear  effect  on  group   performance.  

 

2.5.  Reconfiguration  of  resources  

Lastly,  processes  that  reconfigure  knowledge  resources  will  be  discussed.  A  well-­‐known   name  for  the  process  of  reconfiguring  knowledge  resources  is  knowledge  brokering   (Hargadon,  2002;  Schulz,  2001;  Zollo  &  Winter,  2002).  Knowledge  brokering  is  the   routine  by  which  existing  knowledge  is  collected  from  different  sources  and  combined   in  new  ways,  resulting  in  synergy.  The  knowledge  combined  can  be  implicit  or  explicit.   However,  Reconfiguration  of  explicit  knowledge  begins  with  internalizing  it  as  implicit   knowledge.  Thereafter,  it  is  used  to  broaden,  reframe  the  existing  implicit  knowledge.  

(18)

Explicit  knowledge  sources  can  also  directly  be  reconfigured  to  explicit  knowledge,  like   an  accountant  collects  financial  information  and  puts  it  together  in  a  financial  report.   However,  this  will  not  lead  to  breakthrough  innovations  (Nonaka  &  Takeuchi,  1997).  

Knowledge,  in  particular  explicit  knowledge,  is  mostly  context  specific.  However,   with  analogic  thinking  (finding  similarities  in  non-­‐similar  things)  new  knowledge  can  be   created  by  moving  it  from  one  context  to  another  (Hargadon,  2002).  

Explicit  knowledge  can  be  gained,  copied  and  reconfigured  from,  Internet,   scientific  resources,  and  existing  products  and  technologies.  By  brokering  explicit   knowledge  it  will  become  implicit  knowledge  when  it  becomes  embedded  in  human   behaviour.  At  this  point  it  can  be  applied  to  a  wider  variety  of  local  situations  and  thus   becomes  more  effective  for  dynamic  capability  (Zollo  &  Winter,  2002).  

 Implicit  knowledge,  as  mentioned  before,  is  ‘know-­‐how’  acquired  by  personal   experience  in  practice.  Experience  can  be  seen  as  brokering  of  knowledge  trough  time.   From  a  philosopher’s  point  of  view:  ‘experiences  act  upon  a  blank  slate  to  imprint   knowledge  or  wisdom  like  a  sculptor  moulds  soft  clay’.  In  this  case  there  is  no  distinction   between  experience  and  knowledge  (QUIŃONES,  Ford,  &  Teachout,  1995).    

It  is  already  widely  accepted  that  experience  increases  (job)  performance   (Ancona  &  Caldwell,  1992;  Schmidt,  Hunter,  &  Outerbridge,  1986).  Experience  leads  to   the  acquisition  of  skills,  techniques  and  methods.  The  primary  effect  of  experience  is   accumulation  of  implicit  knowledge  that  in  turn  leads  to  better  performance.    

Ernst  et.  al.  (2000)  call  this  experience  effect,  knowledge  duplication:  the  amount   of  ideas  an  individual  can  develop  depends  on  the  amount  of  ideas  he  or  she  had  before.   When  the  amount  of  ideas  grows,  the  possible  combinations  of  prior  ideas  are  

(19)

from  one  context  in  another.  This  means  that  once  an  inventor  gains  more  experience  or   explicit  knowledge,  his  productivity  will  grow  exponentially.  In  longer  term  this  causes   a  skewed  distribution  of  performance  among  development  teams.  Only  few  teams  will   be  responsible  for  most  of  the  innovative  output  (Lotka,  1926).  Lotka’s  law  states  that   the  number  of  authors  making  n  publications  is  about  1/n2  of  those  making  one  

contribution.    Thus,  1/3rd  of  the  people  who  make  one  publication  make  three  

publications  and  1/5th  make  five,  etc.  Lodka’s  law  also  applies  for  productivity  of  

development  teams.  Brokering  knowledge  or  experience  will  positively  contribute  to   efficient  dynamic  capability.  Zollo  and  Winter  (2002)  even  claim  that  dynamic  

capabilities  are  shaped  by  accumulation  of  experience.  In  their  opinion  routines  are  an   outcome  of  trial  and  error  learning  and  are  a  way  to  codify  implicit  knowledge.    

Brokering  knowledge  or  experience  will  positively  contribute  to  efficient   dynamic  capability.  Zollo  and  Winter  (2002)  even  claim  that  dynamic  capabilities  are   shaped  by  accumulation  of  experience.  In  their  opinion  routines  are  an  outcome  of  trial   and  error  learning  and  are  a  way  to  codify  implicit  knowledge.    

Concluding,  the  reconfiguration  of  knowledge  resources  is  called  knowledge   brokering.  In  this  process  existing  knowledge,  explicit  or  implicit,  is  combined  in  new   ways  through  analogic  thinking.  Knowledge  from  one  context  is  transformed  and  used   for  solutions  in  another  context.  Personal  experience  of  inventors  can  be  seen  as   implicit  knowledge  accumulation  and  therefore  leads  to  better  dynamic  capabilities.   Experience  and  gaining  explicit  knowledge  has  an  exponential  effect  on  performance   whereby  more  knowledge  or  experience,  leads  to  even  more  possible  reconfigurations.      

(20)

3.  Conceptual  model  and  hypotheses  

The  aim  of  this  study  is  to  examine  the  effects  of  implicit  and  explicit  knowledge  on   dynamic  capabilities.  The  process  displayed  in  the  conceptual  model  is  an  example  of  a   dynamic  process  resembling  the  product  development  process.  Innovative  output  is   proposed  as  the  outcome  of  effective  dynamic  capabilities.  Innovation  and  effective   dynamic  capabilities  are  closely  related.  Dynamic  capabilities  are  processes  that   continuously  create  new  products,  new  organizations  forms  in  reaction  to  changes  in   the  market  place.  According  to  Schumpeter  (Ruttan,  1959)  innovation  is  setting  up  a   new  production  function  which  covers  new  products,  new  organization  form,  mergers   and  more.  Effective  dynamic  capability  is  thus  a  prerequisite  for  innovation.  Therefore,   by  testing  innovative  output,  the  effectiveness  of  dynamic  capabilities  is  tested.    

As  mentioned  before  the  definition  of  dynamic  capabilities  used  in  this  thesis  is   as  follows:  

“The  firm’s  processes  that  use  resources—specifically  the  processes  to  integrate,   reconfigure,  gain  and  release  resources—to  match  and  even  create  market  change.   Dynamic  capabilities  thus  are  the  organizational  and  strategic  routines  by  which  firms   achieve  new  resource  configurations  as  markets  emerge,  collide,  split,  evolve,  and  die.”  

The  development  process  is  chosen  because  it  includes  three  out  of  four  types  of   dynamic  capabilities,  namely  gaining,  integration  and  reconfiguring  of  resources.  The   three  processes  and  their  mutual  dependence  are  displayed  in  figure  1.  Next,  the   antecedents  and  the  proposed  hypotheses  are  discussed.  

(21)

  Figure  1:  Conceptual  model  

3.1.  Team  tenure  

 The  first  antecedent  in  the  model  is  team  tenure.  Routines  that  evolve  when  working  in   a  team  can  be  seen  as  processes  that  integrate  knowledge  resources.  These  routines   like  brainstorming,  performance  evaluation  and  also  casual  lunch  conversations,  are   expected  become  more  effective  when  the  team  formation  stays  the  same  over  a  longer   period  of  time  (Katz  &  Allen,  1982).  Individual  scientist  or  inventors  with  different   skills,  expertise  and  backgrounds  are  put  together  in  a  team  to  work  on  a  project.  The   longer  these  team  members  work  together,  the  better  their  different  specialties  will   create  synergies.  Through  learning  by  trail  and  error,  team  members  will  develop   standard  work  patterns  that  are  familiar  and  comfortable  and  thereby  result  in  effective   knowledge  sharing.    For  example,  by  sharing  individual  experiences  and  opinions,  team   members  will  create  a  better  mutual  understanding  and  as  a  result  more  efficient  

(22)

knowledge  sharing  (Katz,  1982).  This  corresponds  to  the  theory  of  Zollo  and  Winter   (2002)  that  effective  dynamic  capabilities  evolve  from  learning.  

    As  written  in  the  literature  review,  cross  fertilization  of  knowledge  and  ideas   within  a  group  makes  a  team  more  effective  than  an  individual.  Team  organization   stimulates  the  transfer  of  implicit  knowledge  from  one  team  member  to  other  team   members  (Zucker  et  al.,  2002).  This  can  be  seen  as  a  process  by  which  integration  and   combination  of  implicit  knowledge  leads  to  effective  output.  

 

H1:  Team  tenure  will  lead  to  efficient  integration  of  implicit  knowledge  and  thus   innovative  output.  

 

3.2.  Explicit  knowledge  

Members  of  the  development  team  collect  external  explicit  knowledge  sources  to   increase  and  broaden  its  search  for  creative  solutions.  This  is  a  process  of  gaining   external  resources.  It  is  stated  before  that  gaining  of  external  knowledge  sources  is   beneficial  for  effectiveness  of  dynamic  capabilities  for  the  following  reasons.  First,  use   of  externally  gained  explicit  knowledge,  and  especially  scientific  research,  can  have   positive  influence  on  dynamic  capability  because,  looking  at  the  knowledge  that  is  out  in   the  field  can  help  overcome  a  narrow  local  search  horizon.  Secondly,  the  process  of   gaining  external  knowledge  is  easier  to  adapt  to  a  changing  environment  than  creating   it  in-­‐house.  This  research  will  focus  on  technical  knowledge  sources  like  scientific   papers,  conferences  and  product  manuals.  In  addition,  this  model  only  investigates  the   externally  gained  knowledge  of  explicit  nature.  Technical  implicit  knowledge  is  much  

(23)

harder  to  gain  externally,  usually  only  via  mergers  or  acquisitions.    

There  are  several  reasons  why,  especially  technical  knowledge  of  explicit  nature,   is  expected  to  have  positive  effect  on  the  efficiency  of  dynamic  capabilities.  Firstly,  to   recognize  the  value  of  new  external  information,  process  it,  and  commercialize  the  end   product,  a  firm  should  have  so-­‐called  absorptive  capacity.  The  firm  needs  some  

knowledge  overlap  with  an  external  knowledge  source  to  successfully  gain  new   knowledge  (Schulz,  2001).  Narin,  Hamilton,  &  Olivastro  (1997)  claim  that,  in  order  to   have  absorptive  capacity,  a  firm  should  have  a  broad  base  of  background  knowledge.   This  knowledge  base  can  be  derived  from  scientific  research,  which  is  mostly  done  in   universities.    Caloghirou  et  al.  (2004)  compared  the  influence  of  the  use  of  journal   papers,  Internet,  patent  databases  and  attendance  at  conferences,  on  innovative  output.   They  found  journal  papers  where  most  effective.  

Several  studies  suggest  that  scientific  research  is  an  effective  benchmark  for   invention  and  innovation  (Hargadon,  2002;  Zucker  et  al.,  2002).  Scientific  research  is   mostly  widely  applicable  since  it  contains  generalizable  knowledge.  Therefore,  scientific   knowledge  is  a  flexible  kind  of  knowledge,  meaning  it  is  not  context  specific.  The  more   flexible  a  knowledge  base  is  the  more  easily  it  can  be  used  to  interpret  new  problems  or   invent  solutions  (Hargadon,  2002).  The  linear  model  of  innovation  suggests  that  

technology,  through  applied  research  originates  from  a  scientific  base  (Narin  et  al.,   1997).    

In  short,  externally  gained  knowledge  can  have  positive  influence  on  dynamic   capabilities  because  it  can  help  overcome  a  narrow  search  horizon.  Secondly,  the   process  of  gaining  external  knowledge  is  less  complicated  and  thus  easier  to  transform   to  a  new  environment.  In  addition,  externally  gained  knowledge  of  technical  and  explicit  

(24)

nature  knowledge  can  have  positive  influence  on  dynamic  capability  because  it  is   valuable  for  benchmarking  and  adds  to  a  firm’s  knowledge  base.  Scientific  research  in   particular  is  a  widely  applicable  and  flexible  kind  of  knowledge  and  therefore  positively   influences  the  innovation  process.  

 

H2:  Gaining  of  external  explicit  knowledge  resources  of  technical  nature  will  lead   to  innovative  output.  

 

3.3.  Implicit  knowledge  

As  discussed  before  Recombination  of  knowledge,  knowledge  brokering,  is  combining   existing  explicit  or  implicit  knowledge  in  new  ways,  through  analogic  thinking.  

Knowledge  from  one  context  is  transformed  and  used  for  solutions  in  another  context.   Reconfiguration  of  explicit  knowledge  begins  with  internalizing  it  as  implicit  

knowledge.  Thereafter,  use  it  to  broaden  and  reframe  present  implicit  knowledge.   When  implicit  knowledge  is  reconfigured  into  a  new  solution  it  can  be  articulated  as   explicit  knowledge  (Nonaka  &  Takeuchi,  1997).  This  articulation  of  reconfigured   knowledge  can  be  seen  as  innovative  output.  

  Schulz  (2001)  investigated  the  positive  effect  of  amount  of  knowledge  inflows  on   the  amount  of  knowledge  outflows.  He  stated  that  the  more  knowledge  a  team  gained   the  more  opportunities  for  brokering  and  thus  the  more  outflow  of  knowledge.  The   knowledge  duplication  theory,  which  states  gained  knowledge  or  experience  will  grow   exponentially,  supports  this  statement.  However,  Schulz  (2001)  did  not  find  empirical   support  for  this  hypothesis.  According  to  his  discussion,  this  outcome  could  be  due  to  

(25)

effectiveness  of  knowledge  brokering  will  be  retested.  

Concluding,  team  tenure  will  lead  to  more  implicit  knowledge  on  the  team   through  integration  of  skills  and  reconfiguration  of  collective  knowledge.  When  the   team  gains  explicit  knowledge,  and  effectively  internalizes  and  reconfigures  it,  this  will   also  lead  to  more  implicit  knowledge.  Increase  in  implicit  knowledge,  in  turn,  will  lead   to  effective  dynamic  capability.    

  Therefore,  implicit  knowledge  is  expected  to  be  a  mediator  between  team   tenure,  gaining  explicit  knowledge  and  innovative  output.    

   

H3a:  The  positive  effect  of  team  tenure  on  innovative  output  is  mediated  by  an   increase  of  implicit  knowledge  on  the  team.  

H3b:  The  positive  effect  of  explicit  knowledge  on  innovative  output  is  mediated  by   an  increase  of  implicit  knowledge  on  the  team.  

       

 

                       

(26)

4.  Data  and  Method  

There  are  many  ways  in  which  innovative  output  has  been  measured  in  earlier  research.   Namely,  R&D  measured  by  the  amount  of  laboratories,  amount  of  R&D  employees  or   R&D  expenditures.  However,  these  variables  are  more  likely  to  be  inputs  of  innovative   activity  than  outcomes.  Another  way  to  measure  innovative  output  is  patent  data.  A   limitation  to  patent  count  is  that  patents  are  inventions,  not  yet  innovations,  and  thus   do  not  represent  correct  economical  value.  Other  works  use  patent  citations  as  

indicators,  which  gives  a  better  idea  of  the  value  of  a  patent  (Clark,  Gertler,  &  Feldman,   2003).  In  this  study  this  last  method  will  be  used  to  indicate  the  level  of  innovative   activity.  In  this  section,  the  sample,  strengths  and  limitation  of  patent  data  research,  and   the  variable  constructs  are  discussed.  

 

4.1.  Use  of  patent  data  

Although  innovation  is  concept  hard  to  measure  in  hard  data,  patents  are  still  widely   accepted  indication  method  for  innovation  activity  (Buderi,  1999).  Especially  a  patent’s   forward  citations  and  amount  of  claims  can  give  a  good  indication  of  the  innovation’s   value.  Innovation  is  usually  an  incremental  process  with  sporadic  breakthroughs.  This   means  that  a  product  innovation  will  not  result  from  one  single  patent  but  rather  series   of  patents  build  on  each  other.  Patents  counts  are  more  of  an  indication  of  the  size  of   R&D  in  an  industry  or  firm  (Trajtenberg,  1990).    

Using  patent  statistics  as  an  indicator  of  innovative  activity  has  several  

limitations.  First,  invention  is  not  the  same  as  innovation.  Innovation  is  not  necessarily   only  technological  innovation  but  could  also  be  managerial  or  process  innovation  (Zollo  

(27)

but  for  an  invention  to  become  innovation  it  should  have  practical  value  in  a  product  or   process.  

Second,  not  all  inventions  are  patentable,  because  they  have  to  meet  the   patentability  criteria  set  by  USPTO:  Novelty,  non-­‐obviousness,  ornamentally,  

enablement  and  definiteness.  In  addition,  some  inventions  are  not  patented  because  the   inventors  decided  to  rely  on  secrecy  or  other  methods  to  appropriate  value  from  an   invention.  There  is  hardly  any  data  about  the  amount  and  characteristics  of  inventions   that  are  not  patented(Griliches,  1998).  

Third,  patents  differ  greatly  in  their  quality.  Simple  patent  counts  are  merely  an   indication  of  the  R&D  expenditures  of  a  firm.  However,  in  a  study  by  Griliches  (1998)   the  non-­‐used  patents  appear  to  be  negligible.  But  even  if  all  patented  inventions  would   be  commercialized,  variance  in  economic  significance  is  enormous  (Trajtenberg,  1990).   Therefore  in  this  study,  the  forward  citation  will  be  used  as  a  weight  for  importance  of  a   patent.  Lastly,  patents  contain  limited  amount  of  information.  The  problem  is  inherent   with  the  use  of  secondary  data.  The  research  question  must  be  drawn  upon  the  

available  data.    

On  the  other  hand  there  are  many  advantages  in  using  patent  data  to  indicate   innovative  activity.  First,  the  data  is  easily  accessible  and  comparable  in  a  quantitative   and  thus  objective  manner.  Besides,  patents  cover  practically  every  field  of  innovation.   They  are  rich,  detailed  and  consistent  in  information.  Patent  data  has  been  stored  since   the  18th  century  and  thus  is  a  continuous  source,  where  large  number  of  data  is  

available  throughout  time  (Hall,  Jaffe,  &  Trajtenberg,  2001).  Although  mere  patent  count   is  not  a  good  indication  of  innovative  activity,  several  studies  (Ernst,  Leptien,  &  Vitt,   2000;  Trajtenberg,  1990)  proved  that  patent  counts  weighted  by  citations  are  highly  

(28)

correlated  with  innovations.  Innovation  is  an  incremental  process,  if  the  citations  keep   coming  the  innovation  originating  from  this  invention  must  be  valuable.  Lastly,  patent   data  are  supplied  on  a  voluntary  basis,  they  grant  (temporary)  monopoly  in  exchange   for  disclosure  and  therefor  more  reliable  than  other  types  of  economic  information.    

4.2.  Sample  

The  patent  dataset  used  to  answer  the  research  question  is  drawn  from  the  Delphion   patent  database.  The  dataset  contains  U.S.  Patent  and  Trademark  Office  (USPTO)   patents.  The  sample  consist  patents  from  the  U.S.  wireless  telecom  industry  granted   from  1971  till  2006.  Only  patents  applied  for  from  1971-­‐  2001(20945  patents)  will  be   used,  because  only  those  patents  were  granted  at  the  time  of  documentation.  In   addition,  in  2001,  the  industry  changed  with  the  introduction  of  UMTS  system.  These   patents  thus  cover  the  four  technological  standards  prevalent  during  that  time  period:   (1)  Advanced  Mobile  Phone  System  (AMPS),  a  1G  analog  mobile  phone  system  standard.   (2)  Global  System  for  Mobile  Communications  (GSM)  a  2G  standard,  (3)  Time  Division   Multiple  Access  (TDMA),  also  a  2G  digital  standard  used  in  cellular  telephone  

communication  that  divides  each  cellular  channel  into  three  time  slots  in  order  to   increase  the  amount  of  data  that  can  be  carried,  (4)  Code  Division  Multiple  Access   (CDMA),  a  competing  2G  digital  standard.    

The  wireless  telecom  industry  is  suitable  for  this  research,  because  it  is  a  high-­‐ velocity  and  high-­‐tech  industry.  The  need  to  innovate  for  firms  in  this  industry  is  high   and  because  the  innovations  are  mostly  related  to  technology,  the  innovative  activity  is   clearly  visible  in  patent  data.        

(29)

The  dataset  includes  information  about  the  amount  of  forward  and  backward   references,  application  and  publication  date,  applicant  location  (city,  state  and  country),   information  about  the  legal  representative,  the  inventors  on  the  team,  inventor  location   and  the  field  of  search.  Only  patents  applied  for  in  the  US  will  be  used,  to  control  for   country  variation.  The  dataset  is  still  fairly  large,  20945  patents,  which  can  lead  to   biased  significant  power  in  several  statistical  tests.  Therefore  a  random  sample  of  5%  of   the  total  amount  of  patents  is  taken  for  analysis.  980  patents  were  randomly  selected   from  the  complete  database.  

 

4.3.  Dependent  variable  

The  dependent  variable  in  this  study  is  innovative  output.  Effective  dynamic  capability   will  lead  to  innovative  output,  thus  by  measuring  innovative  output  an  conclusion  can   be  drawn  about  the  dynamic  capabilities  of  the  firm.  Patents,  weighted  by  their  forward   citations,  indicate  innovative  output.  As  mentioned  before,  patents  vary  greatly  in  their   economic  significance.  Forward  citations  are  proved  to  be  a  good  value  index  for  

patented  inventions  (Griliches,  1998;  Hall  et  al.,  2001;  Trajtenberg,  1990).    According  to   Usher,  major  inventions  are  emerging  from  the  accumulation  of  several  simple  

inventions.  Forward  citations  are  a  visible  effect  of  these  accumulations  (Ruttan,  1959).    If  a  new  invention  builds  on  technology  covered  by  an  existing  patent,  it  can  cite   the  patent  in  question  to  prevent  claims.  Thus  patent  citations  indicate  how  often  a   certain  innovation  is  used  for  further  research.  Because  of  the  legal  issues  concerned   with  citing  previous  patents,  one  can  assume  that  all  but  only  the  relevant  patents  are   cited.  As  a  consequence,  patent  citations  are  a  good  indication  of  the  economic  value  of  a   patent  (Trajtenberg,  1990).  As  shown  in  figure  2  the  frequency  distribution  of  patent  

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

In this sense, studies that rely on large-scale cross-national survey datasets and statistically test the effect of contextual characteristics on within-country relation- ships

Undoubtedly, these strange results give more than ample evidence that the performance of the social ties model is better than an inequity aversion model in explaining

Omdat er al veelvuldig onderzoek is gedaan naar cognitieve flexibiliteit als gemeten in het aantal seconde op de TMT-B, werd in dit onderzoek opnieuw gekeken naar de relatie

Results: In the current study we used a novel single-cell whole genome sequencing (scWGS) approach to assess aneuploidy in isolated neurons from the frontal cortex of normal control

Mixed land uses Infill planning Open Spaces Public Transport Zone 1 Public Transport Zone 2 Public Transport Zone 3 Public Transport Zone 4 Public Transport Zone 5

When HP and UPS wanted to implement a new ERP system for example, they frequently engaged in communication and knowledge sharing to ensure that the interfirm logistics process

Through different performance improvement projects and paths, and by using the structures of the theory of performance frontiers and the resource based view, the relationship

We explore how think tanks relate to academic knowledge through an em- pirical analysis of three Norwegian advocacy think tanks: Civita, Manifest and Agenda.. We examine