• No results found

Asymmetry of stock price reactions on oil price movements Oil price sensitivity of stocks and indices in the Low Countries

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Asymmetry of stock price reactions on oil price movements Oil price sensitivity of stocks and indices in the Low Countries"

Copied!
177
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

Asymmetry of stock price reactions on oil price movements

Oil price sensitivity of stocks and indices in the Low Countries

Pieter Lont (1350269)

University of Groningen

Master’s Thesis MBA Finance (Corporate Financial Management)

December 11

th

2009

Jel codes: C22, E44, G12, Q40, and Q43

Key words: oil prices, asset pricing, asymmetry, consumer expenditures, macroeconomy

Abstract

(2)

Introduction

Media, policymakers and economists give special attention to oil prices. Some

explanations for this large interest are that oil prices are relatively volatile compared

to other goods and services, the demand for oil is relatively inelastic, oil price

fluctuations are largely determined by exogenous forces to the economy, and oil

prices are often utilized as an instrument to explain movements in the economy

(Awerbuch & Sauter, 2006; Kilian, 2008a). Kilian & Park (2009) report strong

presumption in the financial press that oil prices also drive stock markets. Up to

midway 2008 the oil price increased above €90,- a barrel (~+100% in a single year).

At the same time companies operating in the energy sector reported very high profits,

while in general the stock markets moved down. During the global credit crunch and

the subsequent economic recession the oil price dramatically decreased to about €35,-

a barrel midway April 2009 (~-60% in a single year). In the same timeframe stock

markets declined considerably as well, oil producing companies stocks being no

exception. Stock price reactions appear to depend on the direction of the oil price

movement, at least for certain industry sectors. There has been a continuing interest

by researchers in the role and impact that oil has on the general economy as well as

financial markets and how these relations evolve. Extensive literature is available on

the oil-GDP relationship (e.g. Hamilton, 1983; Tatom, 1987; Hamilton, 1988a; Mork,

1989; Mork et al., 1994, Lee et al., 1995; Hooker, 1996; Hunt et al., 2001; Hamilton,

2003; Barsky & Killian, 2004). These papers suggest that oil price increases and oil

price volatility are responsible for lower economic growth (recessions), reduced

productivity, higher inflation, higher wages and higher unemployment. By affecting

actual as well as expected economic activity, the cost of production, corporate

earnings, balance of wealth between oil-consuming countries and oil-producing

countries, inflation, and monetary policy, changing oil prices are also expected to

have implications for equity and bond valuations

1

, currency exchange rates and

government financing (e.g. Yurtsever & Zahor, 2007). Stocks should be valued for the

net present value of its future cash flows discounted using their risk characteristics

(Schleifer, 2000). Rising oil prices increase production costs and lower cash flows and

with that stock prices (Sadorsky, 2008). Furthermore rising oil prices often lead to

higher interest rates, which will lead to higher discount rates. Higher interest (discount)

1

(3)

rates make stocks less attractive and therefore normally lead to a fall in stock prices

(Basher & Sadorsky, 2006). The International Monetary Fund (IMF, 2000, 2004,

2007) reports that the transfer of income from oil consumers to oil producers will lead

to a fall in aggregate demand, which also leads to revaluations of equity and debt. The

sensitiveness of oil-importing countries depends on the degree to which they are net

importers and the oil intensity of their economies. A rise in the cost of production puts

pressure on profit margins. The consequences for the price level and inflation will

depend on monetary policies, consumers that seek higher wage increases, producers

that seek to restore profit margins, and the creditworthiness of oil-importing countries.

Currencies would adjust to changes in trade balances

2

. This would raise the costs of

external debt and the oil-import bill. A loss of business and consumer confidence,

inappropriate policy responses and higher prices of other commodities would amplify

these economic effects. According to Kilian (2008a) oil prices rises could affect the

input (supply) as well as the output (demand) as it raises the marginal cost of

production, and reduces the demand for output. The negative oil price sensitivity will

be greatest in industries with a relatively high proportion of their costs devoted to

oil-based inputs. Also companies for which the costs of transportation are high are

affected. Furthermore some industries derive considerable revenue from oil-related

products (Faff & Brailsford, 1999). However the impact of oil on the general

economy is far larger than can be explained by means of these direct effects, as the

share of oil in production is relatively small. However oil prices could also induce

indirect effects (Lee & Ni, 2002). Killian (e.g. 2008a) and Hamilton (e.g. 2009b)

imply that the oil price changes affect the economy primarily through their effect on

consumer expenditures and firm expenditures. Multiple papers on the relation

between oil and the macro-economy report on an asymmetric response of the

economy in case of up and down movements of the oil price. Important explanations

for asymmetry are adjustment costs or sectorial shifts, financial stress, monetary

policy responses, changing demand composition, and investment under uncertainty

(Sadorsky, 2008). Market participants are in need of a framework that shows the

transmission mechanisms along which oil price changes will affect stock market

returns (Malik & Ewing, 2009). In this paper I will investigate whether oil returns are

an important factor in explaining stock returns, and whether the asymmetric relation

2

(4)

identified for economic output also translates into stock prices. There are multiple

views possible on the relationship between oil returns and stock returns.

The first view: The response will be in line with the classic supply-side effect in

which rising oil prices are indicative of the reduced availability of a basic input to

production. Oil users have higher production costs, and oil producers will have higher

revenues. The direction of the relation will depend on whether the company is an oil

producer (oil explorer) or an oil consumer. This direct effect suggests that oil price

changes have generally very little impact on stock prices, as most business activities

are not very energy intensive.

The second view: Oil price changes lead to (are related to) economic upheavals and

economic downturns and with that cause changes in investment and consumption

behaviour for many products. The indirect effect of oil price fluctuations will

influence revenues, profits, investments and cash flows of many firms. Cyclical

companies could show large reactions, but the consumption of products of oil-users

and oil-based products is expected to be affected the most. Furthermore indirect

effects such as adjustment costs could also apply for the oil-related stocks.

The relation is expected to be mostly negative, as most companies are consumers of

oil and oil derivatives. But some firms might be able to minimize the negative impact

on profitability by incorporating the higher oil costs in consumer prices. And certain

companies, such as oil explorers and oil producers, are even expected to obtain larger

cash flows, as their final product (oil) is more highly valued. Certainly as the price

elasticity of oil demand is small. Both the downside and upside risks of oil price

changes need to be considered (Fan, et al., 2008). With regard to the shape of the

relation I will focus on whether positive oil returns have the same (symmetrical)

impact as negative oil returns on the returns of individual and groups of stocks

3

.

Asymmetry in this model means that positive oil returns lead to negative

consequences for most companies, while negative oil returns do not have a positive

impact of the same magnitude. The asymmetric reaction could be the consequence of

direct as well as indirect effects on the input as well as the output side of firms. This

will affect expected cash flows.

3

(5)

The following two main hypotheses are proposed:

1. Oil returns have a negative relationship with (most) stock returns.

2. Oil returns have asymmetric effects on (most) stock returns.

Transmission mechanisms

(6)
(7)
(8)

of crude oil are far less important for understanding changes in stock prices. Changing

types of oil shocks explain why regressions of macroeconomic aggregates on oil

prices tend to be unstable (Kilian & Park, 2009). The recent oil shock (2007/2008)

was driven primarily by global aggregate demand instead of by supply disruptions,

and therefore did not directly cause a recession

4

. Apergis & Miller (2009) indicate

that there are differences in the impact between oil demand and oil supply shocks, but

all contribute significantly in explaining stock market returns. Kilian & Park (2009)

report that further insights can be gained from considering the responses of

industry-specific stock returns to global demand and supply shocks. Their results suggest that

appropriate portfolio adjustments depend on the underlying cause of the oil price

change. Outside the energy sector, the strongest responses are found in sectors for

which oil price shocks affect the demand for goods and services (in line with

Hamilton, 1988a).

Increasingly more researchers pay attention to the relationship between oil prices and

stock prices, also considering possible asymmetry

5

(e.g. Huang et al., 1996; Sadorsky,

1999; Nandha & Hammoudeh, 2007; Sadorsky, 2008; Kilian & Park, 2009). These

papers indicate that for certain companies and sectors oil returns are an important

factor. Furthermore there is some empirical evidence of asymmetry in the reaction of

stock returns on the sign and volatility of the oil returns. Most studies relating oil

prices to financial market activity only examine the impact of oil price shocks on

stock prices across the entire market, rather than concentrating on individual stocks or

groups of stocks (Faff & Brailsford, 1999). Analysis at the aggregate level may hide

stock and sector specific sensitivities (Sadorsky, 2001). This study tries to fill this gap.

I choose to directly analyse the relationship between oil returns and stock returns as

well as sector/index returns, but am aware of the underlying complexity of this

relation. Incorporating all kinds of macroeconomic variables and different types of

shocks would make the model complex, which is beyond the intension of this paper.

Furthermore as weekly and monthly are used, it is difficult to obtain reliable data on

these variables. The main variables are the oil return variables in both the upward and

the downward direction and the oil volatility variable. The oil price volatility could

cause erratic behaviour of investors. A market factor is included to partially capture

4

(9)

the general macroeconomic situation. Exchange rates, interest rates and interest

spreads are often considered as explanatory variables of stock market returns

(Grinblatt & Titman, 2004), and are therefore also included as control variables to

give a rich picture of what drives stock returns. The data analysis will be quantitative

as well as qualitative. Correlations between the variables are determined and summary

statistics of the firms and sectors are provided. For every individual stock and sector a

separate regression is performed. There will be made use of time series data to study

the size and shape of the relation between company stock returns and oil price

movements. I want to obtain long term coefficients, but I will perform parameter

stability tests to check whether the relation dramatically changes over time. I will look

for differences between individual companies and industry groups in the reaction on

oil prices. Furthermore I will consider the impact of firm characteristics like size,

sector, and P/E ratio effects in a separate portfolio analysis. On the basis of the results

I can come to a conclusion on which transmission mechanisms are dominant. The

Dutch and Belgian stock markets are selected as the Netherlands and Belgium have

very open economies and are sensitive to other markets, especially to the US market.

Furthermore they are largely dependent on oil imports

6

and are relatively energy

intensive. Therefore it is expected that the Belgium as well as the Dutch stock market

and with that most individual stocks will show a clear negative relation with the oil

price. An important question is whether oil price risk is a global factor risk or actually

a firm-specific risk factor that can easily be diversified away. I expect a negative

relation for most firms/sectors, except a few like oil producers and oil explorers, as oil

prices rises have a negative impact on the economy, and as oil is a direct or indirect

input for many industries. Asymmetry is widely expected as the uncertainty on the

consequences for the total market and the individual companies will lead to panic

reactions. Especially for the stocks with operations closely related to oil a significant

as well as asymmetric relation is expected, as both direct and indirect effects could

reinforce each other. The results will further the understanding of the interaction

between oil returns and equity returns and with that the scale of oil price risk, which

could be useful for investors, hedgers, managers, and policymakers (Basher &

Sadorsky, 2006). The empirical findings are useful to investors who need to

5

By symmetry, it is meant that irrespective of an estimated coefficient’s sign, the magnitudes of the

estimated coefficients are the same (Sadorsky, 2008).

6

(10)

understand the exact effect of oil price changes on certain stocks across industries, to

determine an optimal savings and investment strategy. And also for managers of

certain firms in order to evaluate the efficiency of oil price risk hedging policies

(Devlin & Titman, 2004). Maybe even more interesting to investors is the possible

appearance of asymmetry. It could be argued whether asymmetry in the long run

actually is sustainable, as this suggests that price changes that are fully reversed will

leave net effects that are not neutral (Tatom, 1993). But the consequences for the cash

flows of firms could well be non-linear. With respect to asymmetry it also important

whether oil price changes are temporarily or permanent (Devlin & Titman, 2004).

Furthermore stock prices often are temporarily mispriced cause of noise trading or

erratic behaviour (uncertainty effect), which could provide interesting arbitrage

opportunities for rational investors. However a large variety of factors simultaneously

affect stock prices, so it is difficult to determine whether a stock is mispriced. It is

important for investors to know which stocks have oil price risk and also show

asymmetric behaviour, so they can cover that risk by taking measures and make

optimal portfolio allocation decisions. When oil price risk is a market wide factor

diversification is not that well possible. But a portfolio of oil-producing stocks and

oil-consuming stocks could capture some or even most of this risk, and be a good

hedging tool against possible asymmetry.

This paper is organised as follows. First there is reported on the general importance of

oil, including oil price risk hedging. In the next two sections theoretical and empirical

literature is examined to investigate the importance of oil for the macroeconomy as

well as in financial markets. A differentiation is made in the strength and shape of the

relationship. There is elaborated extensively on the exact routes to asymmetry. The

next section explains the methodology, model and data that will be applied. The

actual results are discussed in the next section. In a separate section also the

robustness of the results is checked. And the last section concludes the results and

gives some recommendations for further research. In the Appendix more extensive

graphs and tables on macroeconomic variables and tables with results are presented,

including a table on the companies selected

7

. Every new section starts on a new page

to get a clear structure in the paper.

7

(11)

Importance of oil

Oil and oil-derivatives are used by almost all companies and consumers. Oil is needed

as an energy resource for industrial production, electric power generation, and

transportation. Oil price fluctuations are likely to influence all industrial sectors in

modern developed countries (Sadorsky, 1999). The price elasticity of demand is low

(e.g. Atkeson & Kehoe, 1999). Energy expenditures account for about 4% of GDP in

most industrial nations (Faff & Brailsford, 1999). According to the IMF (2004), a 10$

oil price increase will decrease world GDP with about 0.5% and inflation will rise

with 0.5%, and also unemployment is expected to increase

8

. Oil is heavily traded

daily on spot and futures markets. Oil prices fluctuate from month to month because

of changes in expectations on supply and demand. Important factors are changes in

global economic conditions, political tensions in oil-producing countries, wars,

terrorist attacks, natural disasters, embargo’s, OPEC price agreements, the amount of

oil inventories, possible cutbacks in production, monetary policies that have an

inflationary effect, value change of US dollar, technological changes, decrease in oil

dependency, new oil discoveries, uncertainty on supplies from mature fields,

availability of substitute fuels, usage of alternative energy resources, increases in

spare capacities, stronger incentives for conservation, and oil consumption growth in

developing countries (e.g. IMF, 2004; Marimoutou, et al., 2009;)

9

. When price

changes are considered permanent, the present value of future revenues is strongly

affected by changes in spot prices. The best strategy to deal with oil price volatility is

the use of market-based risk instruments (Devlin & Titman, 2004). Figure 1 shows the

oil price development of some oil spot and future series

10

. The price of WTI is

normally higher than Brent oil as it is sweeter and lighter. The oil spot and futures

return series reveal significant volatility clustering. These different series show

similar behaviour, but the volatility is somewhat higher for the spot and short-term

futures. During the last decade the oil price increased from €10,- to €40,- a barrel,

with a peak of about €90,- a barrel. This oil price rise has been caused by a high

dependency on oil, world oil depletion and steady increase of world oil consumption.

The recent economic recession has sent the oil price back down, but the general

tendency is that oil demands and with that oil prices keep rising.

8

In Figure A2 the development of some macroeconomic variables like GDP, inflation and

unemployment are displayed for the Netherlands, Belgium and the Eurozone.

9

(12)

Figure 1: Multiple oil spot and oil future futures series (WTI & Brent euro prices)

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 Date Pr ic e ( eu ro) OILWTX OILWTXI OILWTX2 OILBREN OILBRNI OILBRNT

Figure 2 shows the oil returns and oil price volatility

11

. The sudden fluctuations in oil

price during the last year and around 9/11/2001 are clearly visible.

Figure 2: Oil returns and oil volatility (monthly data)

-0.5 -0.4 -0.3 -0.2 -0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 Date R et u rn /V ol at il ity OILRETEU OILVOLMONTH

Figure 3 shows the stock returns for AF-KLM and RD-Shell. AF-KLM is a large oil

consuming (aviation) company, and is expected to have a clear negative relation with

oil returns. RD-Shell is an oil producer, and is expected to show a clear positive

relation with oil returns. It seems that the returns of AF-KLM and RD-Shell have an

opposite direction. The oil returns and stock returns show similar patterns, which

suggests that oil returns influence stock returns. However other variables could also

be simultaneously at work.

10

I have converted the US dollar prices into euro, in order to clear out the effect of currency differences.

11

(13)

Figure 3: Stock returns of AF-KLM and RD-Shell (monthly data)

-0.4 -0.3 -0.2 -0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 Date Re tu rn AF-KLM RD-SHELL

Table 1 shows data on the oil consumption over the period 1998-2008 for certain

regions of the world. The oil usage in the Low Countries shows large increases and is

relatively high. The increase in energy efficiency has occurred because of reduced

energy intensity and more reliance on a diversified range of energy sources.

Table 1: Oil consumption (thousands of barrels per day)

Cons.

1998-2008

Cons.

Barrels/million

1998-2008

2008

% change

p/p 2008 USD GDP 2008

% change

World

84455

14.7

5

510

-43.1

US

19419

2.7

24

506

-34.0

Europe & Eurasia

20158

1.7

9

294

-59.4

European Union

14765

-0.6

11

291

-51.7

Belgium & Luxemb.

836

27.6

28

509

-36.2

Netherlands

982

15.0

22

398

-49.0

France

1930

-4.3

12

243

-50.4

Germany

2505

-14.1

11

247

-51.3

UK

1704

-2.1

10

230

-49.3

Asia Pacific

25339

29.6

2

617

-30.8

China

7999

89.2

2

664

-52.7

India

2882

46.8

1

877

-51.0

Japan

4845

-12.0

14

361

-29.9

Region/Country

Source: BP Statistical Review of World Energy, June 2009 (www.BP.com). GDP is according to

the International Monetary Fund.

Impact of higher oil prices on global economy

(14)
(15)

Figure 4: World oil production/demand 2001-2009 (million barrels per day)

70 75 80 85 90 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 Date M Il li on ba rr el s a day SUPPLY DEMAND

Source: Energy Information Administration (www.eia.doe.gov/emeu/ipsr). Notes: For the oil

supply monthly figures for the world are used. For the oil supply of 2008 an eight month average

is used. For the oil demand the OECD demand is scaled up to a monthly world demand, by

means of the average annual world demand. For the oil demand of 2009 there is not enough data.

Importance of oil for the Netherlands and Belgium

Belgium and the Netherland are large net importers of fossil fuels

12

. Furthermore they

are not running ahead in the usage of sustainable energy resources. The risk from oil

price changes in these countries is thus likely to play a large role in the development

of these economies and their financial markets. Oil is mainly used by the Industry and

Transport sectors. The energy intensity of the Dutch economy gradually decreased the

last decades, mainly for energy intensive sectors. The Dutch and Belgium economies

both are prosperous (high GDP/citizen), open, and highly dependent on foreign trade.

Furthermore they have large scale service and energy companies. The natural gas

discoveries in the Netherlands in the 1960s have lead to this sectorial dependence

13

. In

the Netherlands services account for over half of the national income and are

primarily in transportation, distribution, and logistics, and in financial areas, such as

banking and insurance. Industrial activity generates about 20% of the national product

and is dominated by the metalworking, oil refining, chemical, and food-processing

industries. The same more or less holds for Belgium

14

.

12

Even while the Netherlands is a large producer of natural gas.

13

Gas benefits of the Netherlands are ~

10 billion annually, ~7% of total revenues of the Government.

14

(16)

Oil price risk hedging

(17)

Theoretical literature review

(18)
(19)

firms (Sadorsky, 2003). This will lead to changes in investment as well as

consumption behaviour (e.g. Kilian, 2009).

(20)

volatile than the underlying stocks as they more heavily react on price changes cause

of changed expectations and options will expire without execution or are far out of the

money. While for a put option always holds that at least a fee is obtained, without

actually always having to deliver the stock. So options prices show asymmetric

behaviour as a reaction on underlying asset price changes. Furthermore companies

often have long-term oil contracts with suppliers. These prices are much less volatile,

and give protection against temporary higher oil prices.

(21)

it makes products more costly to manufacture (supply). Somewhat problematic is that

the greatest effects of an oil shock do not appear until about a year after the shock,

and strong recovery is observed within a couple of years also when oil prices remain

high (e.g. Hamilton & Herrera, 2004). According to Aguiar-Conraria & Wen (2007)

these models are not able to explain this accelerator effect. They propose a model to

explain the multiplier accelerator effect by including investment demand, which

depends on the production level of other firms. Hickman et al. (1987) state that the

aggregate price level responses are proportional to the magnitude of the oil price

shock. This implies that energy price changes have a symmetric effect on the

economy. When oil prices rise, energy-using capital is rendered obsolete, unless (1)

product prices adjust sufficiently, (2) product demand is unaffected, and (3) other

low-cost methods of production are unavailable (Tatom, 1987). If this is not the case,

alterations in the optimal employment of capital resources occur. Oil price shocks

reduce productivity by effectively destroying capital resources. Output and

employment can be altered only after sufficient time has passed. Such inelastic factor

proportions increase the short-run output loss associated with a rise in energy prices.

Relevant is to what extend capital and labour are considered interchangeable, as there

is a period of adjustment to a lowered desired capital/labour ratio. The dispersion

hypothesis posits that a considerable amount of unemployment can be accounted for

by sectorial shifts in demand, which require time for reallocation of labor and capital.

Sectorial shifts and short-run technological or nominal rigidities are likely to play an

important role in accounting for the correlations between oil prices and the economy

and underlying stock prices. Reallocation costs either across or within sectors could

result in a negative response. Hamilton (1988b) and Balke et al. (2002) state that

asymmetry could be the result of adjustment costs, as these lower economic activity in

both directions. Such adjustment costs could arise from sectorial imbalances

(Loungani, 1986), coordination failures between firms (Huntington, 1998) or because

the energy-to-output ratio is set in the capital stock (Atkeson & Kehoe, 1995, 1999).

For putty-clay energy intensive capital goods

15

a change in oil prices could have

negative output consequences as firms adjust to new energy prices (Atkeson &

Kehoe, 1995, 1999). It is all about adjustment costs associated with shifts among

economic sectors in response to supply shocks (Loungani, 1986; Hamilton, 1988b).

15

(22)
(23)

decreases. For example because wages and other prices are downward sticky. Balke,

et al. (2002) report that the effect of oil prices on output is reflected primarily through

interest rates. The relatively fluid market rates move in anticipation of asymmetric

real effects in the future. Bernanke et al. (1997) report that contractionary monetary

policy accounts for the decline in aggregate economic activity following an oil price

increase. If prices are sticky downward, an oil price increase leads to important GDP

losses if monetary authorities do not maintain nominal GDP constant by means of

unexpected inflation. After a decline in oil prices, real wages must grow to obtain a

new market equilibrium. However also interest rates respond asymmetrically to oil

price shocks. Monetary policy can accommodate an oil price increase by raising

aggregate demand and lessen the negative effect on output, but at the cost of higher

prices. Central banks can reduce aggregate demand and lessen the price effect, but at

the cost of lower output. Furthermore also the short-term interest rate response

suggests substantial asymmetry as they incorporate the asymmetric response of the

Fed through the term structure, the expectation of financial markets on the real effect

of oil price changes, and financial stress cause of the oil price shock.

Killian (2008a) and Hamilton (e.g. 2009b) report there is general consensus that the

primary transmission mechanism involves a reduction in the demand for goods and

services. According to Kilian (2008a) higher oil prices cause both a reduction in

aggregate demand and a shift in expenditures. Kilian (2008a) and Edelstein & Kilian

(2009) report that oil price changes affect consumer expenditures, as they:

1. Could change discretionary income, as consumers have more or less money to

spend after paying their energy bills.

2. Could create uncertainty about the development of oil prices, causing

consumers to postpone purchases of consumer durables.

3. Could reduce consumption, as consumers increase their precautionary savings.

4. Could reduce consumption of energy-using durables even more than other

durables, as these durables require energy which is more costly.

(24)

Literature suggests that it depends on the sector whether oil price shocks will mainly

affect supply or demand. Real balance effects, monetary policy, and income transfers

have to do with the supply side, while consumer and firm expenditures have to do

with the demand side. The real balances, income transfer and potential output effects

are expected to have a symmetric relationship between oil price changes and output

growth. Monetary policy will cause non-linear output responses if central banks

tighten policy in response to oil price increases but do not pursue expansionary policy

in the face of oil price declines. Both the sectorial shocks and uncertainty effect can

explain the asymmetry if oil price shocks produce increased volatility and uncertainty.

The increased volatility in case of sharp rises of oil prices reinforces the other

negative effects, while volatility generated by falling oil prices offsets the other

positive effects.

(25)

Empirical literature review

Many researchers have studied the strength and shape of the relationship between oil

and the economy (e.g. Tatom, 1981; Mory; 1993; Mork et al., 1994; Lee et al., 1995;

Ferderer, 1996; Huntington, 1998; Davis & Haltiwanger, 2001; Hunt et al., 2001;

Balke et al., 2002; Hamilton, 2003) and mostly found a non-linear relationship.

Increasingly more researchers also study the impact of oil prices on stock markets

(e.g. Hamilton, 1988a; Huang et al., 1996; Jones & Kaul, 1996; Sadorsky, 1999;

Papapetrou, 2001, Jones et al., 2004; Bachmeier, 2008). New papers of Hamilton

(2009) and Kilian (2008/2009) study whether the response to the more recent oil price

shocks (and economic downturn) is similar. However few studies have attempted to

determine through what transmission mechanisms oil price shocks exactly operate to

produce an asymmetric response in aggregate economic activity and stock prices.

Historical oil prices rises have generally resulted in falling aggregate output (GDP), a

higher price level, and higher interest rates. As is shown in Table 2, the best

explanation is a classic supply-side effect in which rising oil prices are indicative of

the reduced availability of a basic input to production. However the basic supply

shock effects can only partially explain the large effect that oil price shocks have on

aggregate economic activity. Additional explanations for the intensity of the response

are proposed, such as restrictive monetary policy, adjustment costs, coordination

externalities, and financial stress. The different effects are consistent with observed

facts, and may be contemporaneously at work (Brown et al., 2004). The effects of

systematic monetary policy are not as important (anymore) as historically suggested

(e.g. Bachmeier, 2008; Herrera & Pesavento, 2009).

Table 2: Expected response to rising oil price

Economic theory

Real GDP

Price Level

Interest Rate

Historical Record

DOWN

UP

UP

Classis Supply Shock

DOWN

UP

UP

Aggregate Demand Shock

DOWN

DOWN

DOWN

Monetary Shock

DOWN

DOWN

UP

Real Balance Effect

DOWN

DOWN

UP

(26)

Evidence on oil-GDP relationship

Most studies initially focused on the relation of oil prices with economic activity.

Hamilton (1983) reports on statistically significant correlation between high crude oil

prices and historical recessions. The acceptance of a linear relationship has led to the

widespread usage of oil prices as a macroeconomic variable (Hooker, 1996). However

Mork (1989) found evidence that rising oil prices slow down economic activity more

than falling oil prices stimulate it. Also later studies (e.g. Hamilton, 2003; Lee et al.,

1995; Sadorsky, 1999; Jones et al., 2004) report on clear evidence of a non-linear

relation between oil price changes and GDP growth. Multiple researchers report clear

negative correlations between oil prices and aggregate measures of economic activity

such as recession, excessive inflation, low productivity and low economic growth.

Furthermore they find significant correlations between oil prices and microeconomic

data on output, employment, and real wages (e.g. Hunt et al., 2001; Papapetrou, 2001;

Barsky & Kilian, 2004). Huntington (1998) finds that the timing and the pattern of

product price movements as a reaction on oil price changes are different:

1. A significant part of the asymmetry is found in the energy sector.

2. Consumer prices respond asymmetrically to energy price changes.

3. Aggregate output responds asymmetrically to crude oil price changes.

(27)
(28)

utilization is sensitive to oil prices and supplies. Hamilton (2009b) therefore

concludes that the oil price has also contributed to the recent economic recession.

Multiple researchers have investigated the development of the shape and strength of

the relation over time:

1. Nonlinearity in the relation: Oil price increases have a bigger effect on the

economy than oil price decreases (e.g. Hamilton, 2003).

2. The causes (type) of the oil price shock: Higher global demand has a less

disruptive effect than lower global supply (e.g. Killian, 2009).

3. A changing relation over time: The modern economy knows better how to

cope with an oil price shock than previously (e.g. Blanchard & Gali, 2008).

Evidence on oil-stock relationship

(29)
(30)

Apergis & Miller (2009) show that different types of oil shocks all play a significant

but small role in explaining the adjustments in stock market returns. Nandha & Faff

(2008) argue that oil shocks can have adverse effects on output as well as profitability

of firms, especially for those firms where oil is used as an input. Driesprong et al.

(2004) report evidence that investors in stock markets underreact to oil price changes

in the short run. Increasing oil prices lower future stock market returns. This

predictability effect is less strong for oil-related sectors. Oberndorfer (2009) finds that

the relation over time between the oil returns and the oil and gas portfolios is not

restricted to a linear relationship. While the oil price change positively impacts both

oil and gas stock returns, oil volatility has a strong negative effect on stock returns.

This suggests that an increase in oil price volatility is only relevant to oil and gas

corporations. Yurtsever & Zahor (2007) specifically study the impact of oil on the

Dutch stock market, but restricted the study to some large capitalization companies

and sectors. They find that oil shocks have a negative impact on stock returns of some

industries and individual companies whereas they have a positive impact on oil and

gas companies. Furthermore their analysis shows that oil price increases and

decreases have an asymmetric effect on the equity markets. Huang, et al. (1996) find

evidence for significant causality from oil futures to stocks of individual oil

companies, but find no impact on the entire index (S&P500). However Nandha &

Hammoudeh (2007) find significant nonlinear causality from crude oil futures returns

to S&P500 index returns. Huang et al. (2005) find that the optimal threshold level

seems to vary with the dependency of the economy on imported oil and the attitude

towards adopting energy-saving technology. There are many possible scenarios as to

how oil returns and stock returns are linked, including feedback effects, lead-lag

relationships, and market price and volatility spillovers across markets. Huang et al.

(1996) find that stock index futures lead the underlying stock prices within the day,

but there is no feedback from stocks to oil futures. Also Sadorsky (1999) states that

the economic activity has little impact on oil price. This suggests that oil futures are a

good vehicle for diversifying stock portfolios.

(31)

Methodology and regression model

Multiple studies make use of multi-factor market models (e.g. Basher & Sadorsky,

2006; Sadorsky, 2008). In a multi-factor market model expected returns are linearly

related to risk factors and risk premiums (Basher & Sadorsky, 2006). A multi-factor

market model is in line with both the arbitrage pricing theory (APT) and a multi-beta

capital asset pricing model (CAPM). An important question for this research is

whether oil price risk should be seen as a common factor, or as a firm-specific factor.

In many previous studies two-factor models are used including market returns and oil

returns to explain stock returns. But these models are somewhat underspecified as

exchange rates and interest rates are not included (Sadorsky, 2001). Factors can also

be estimated by using portfolios formed on the basis of firm characteristics (Grinblatt

& Titman, 2004). An oil price factor should be well visible in the Dutch and Belgian

financial markets. Both countries are largely dependent on oil imports, are relatively

energy intensive, have relatively open economies, and depend on the global market

conditions. The relationship between oil prices and stock prices will be analyzed on a

company specific (microeconomical) and sectorial (macroeconomical) level. I will

use the following (general) multi-factor model to investigate how the different risk

factors influence stock/indices/portfolio returns:

it t t t t t t t it

c

Rm

D

Ro

D

Ro

Ov

Rir

Ris

r

R

=

+

β

1

+

β

2 1

+

β

3

(

1

1

)

+

β

4

+

β

5

+

β

6

+

β

7

Re

+

ε

(1)

In equation (1) the dependent/endogenous variable are the stock/indices/portfolio

returns denoted as R

it

(i indicates the firm/index/portfolio and t indicates the time

period), and the independent/exogenous variables are the market returns Rm

t,

the oil

returns Ro

t

, the oil price volatility Ov

t,

the interest rate returns Rir

t

, the interest spread

returns Ris

t

, and the exchange rate returns Rer

t

. The betas indicate the different

coefficients that belong to the variables. The main variables are the variables on oil

returns and oil return volatility, and the other exogenous variables serve as control

variables. To analyse the asymmetrical behaviour the oil price changes are separated

into positive changes and negative changes. In equation (1) this is done by introducing

a Dummy. D

1

is a dummy variable that takes a value of one (zero) if oil price

movement is positive (negative). Henceforth

D

1

Ro

t

is replaced with

Rou (return oil

t

(32)

and interest spreads are included in the model to partially grasp the effects of

inflation. And by incorporating a market index there is partially reckoned with the

general economic situation. I have decided to directly test the influence of oil returns

on stock returns. The exact transmission mechanisms are not considered in the

regression model. Incorporating the type of oil price shock and macroeconomic

variables like GDP, unemployment and inflation is considered too complex, certainly

for weekly and monthly data

16

. Furthermore Apergis & Miller (2009) reported that the

different types of oil shocks only play a small role in explaining the adjustments in

stock market returns. Interpreting weekly and even monthly changes in business

environment and type of oil supply shock is very arbitrary, and goes beyond what can

be achieved with long-term statistics. I focus on the longer term relationship and

thereby also consider other sampling frequencies. For every firm/index/portfolio I will

perform the regression for a 10 year period using monthly and weekly data

17

. Daily

data contains too much noise, and shows some highly undesired behaviour like large

non-normality in the residuals. Separate portfolios are constructed to consider the

impact of firm characteristics like size, and sector more specifically for the monthly

data. The portfolio regressions are not performed for the weekly data, because of

limitations in Excel and Eviews. Furthermore the portfolios for the monthly data

already show very undesirable behaviour. Size is measured with market value and

sales as a proxy, as well as the stock market it is currently located (AEX, AMX,

ASCX, BEL20, BELMID, and BELSMALL). Also P/E ratios are included as this is

considered informational on stock returns. Sectors are determined on basis of the

classification and firm description of Euronext. Furthermore portfolios are constructed

on the oil usage and oil dependency, based on the firm descriptions of Euronext (see

Table A1

18

).

Research questions

I want to examine the strength and shape of the relationship between oil returns and

sector/stock return in the Low Countries. The relation is expected to depend on the

16

In Tables A2-A5 correlations are given between macroeconomic variables like GDP, inflation and

unemployment for the Netherlands, Belgium and the Euro-zone, with euro oil prices, the S&P1500

(market factor) and Euribor interest rates and interest spreads. It is difficult to filter out an exact

relation between these parameters and oil returns, certainly as the variables considerably differ between

countries. But it gives an impression of the suitability of the model.

17

I believe the sampling period sufficiently covers the multiple types of oil shocks and business cycles.

18

(33)

dependency on oil as an energy resource. The impact can differ, dependent on the

time scope of the sample and the related range and movement of the oil price. The

actual dependency and oil usage of the individual stocks will be an explorative

research. Conclusions will be drawn on the basis of the results. In the portfolio

analysis I will analyse whether there are differences between certain groups of

companies. Upfront I consider the oil price factor as a common factor which is widely

visible. The stocks and sectors directly related to oil are expected to show the largest

response. A differentiation is made in the direct impact of oil for oil dependent

companies, and the indirect route of oil affecting the investment and consumption

behavior (output) of many firms. The direct (allocative) effects mainly focus on the

supply/input side of firms, and the indirect (aggregate) effects concentrate on the

demand/output side of firms. Furthermore I expect clear asymmetric behaviour. For

the individual stocks it is a combination of the different theories that amplify each

other, such as sectorial shifts, adjustment costs, changing customer demands,

changing investment behaviour, financial stress, monetary policy responses, business

cycle asymmetry, and investment under uncertainty. On the supply side oil price rises

are not in the same way and as quickly integrated in product prices as oil price

decreases. Furthermore changing oil prices will lead to adjustment costs in the

operation mix. On the demand side oil price changes lead to changes in consumption

expenditures. Consumers continue to spend money on primary goods such as

transportation, but will safe on luxury goods. Customer demand will be lower for

many products, which will reduce cash flows. These indirect (aggregate) effects

suggest that asymmetry could be obtained throughout the whole market and not only

for specific sectors with operations closely related to oil. However product cost prices

and product consumption of companies and sectors that are very oil intensive are

expected to show the strongest reaction, as the consequences for their cash flows will

be the most dramatic. But oil price changes could lead to investor sentiment or noise

trading, and other non-rational investment strategies. It could be difficult for investors

to assess the impact of oil prices changes on cash flows of firms. The following two

main hypotheses are proposed:

Oil returns have a negative relationship with stock returns.

(1)

(34)

The following additional hypotheses are also evaluated:

• Hypothesis 1: Market returns and stock returns are positively related

• Hypothesis 2: Oil returns are positively related with oil-producer stock returns

• Hypothesis 3: Oil price volatility is negatively related with stock returns

• Hypothesis 4: Oil price risk is a significant factor for many stocks/indices

• Hypothesis 5: The impact of positive oil returns is different from negative oil

returns.

The impact of oil returns on stock returns can be tested with the following hypotheses:

H0 = β

2

= 0;

H0 = β

3

= 0;

H1 = β

2

< 0

H1 = β

3

< 0

The symmetry hypothesis can be tested with the following hypotheses:

H0

= β

2

= β

3;

H1 = β

2

≠ β

3

(35)

Conversely a positive oil return sensitivity is expected in oil-related industries, in

which oil directly impacts revenues. Furthermore the impact of oil price changes on

equity prices will depend on the ability of firms to pass on the effect to customers. It

is also expected that oil price increases have a larger impact on stock returns than do

oil price decreases. I expect that oil price volatility will be negatively related to stock

returns, as higher volatility increases risk. Increases in the market returns are expected

to lead to increases in individual stock returns (Chen, 1991). Chen also signals the

interest rates should have a negative impact. Positive interest spread returns are

generally observed during economic upheavals and negative interest spread returns

are observed prior to periods of economic downturns. Positive exchange rate returns

are expected to lead to higher returns in the short run, but worsen the competitiveness

of firms. However the Low Countries have transactions in both directions with the US,

so the actual impact is difficult to assess. Summary statistics will be provided for the

microeconomical (individual stocks) and macroeconomical analysis (indices) as well

as the portfolios. Multiple correlation diagrams will be constructed for the correlations

between stock returns and the different factors. The regression model is estimated by

OLS. Preliminary test results suggest considerable heteroskedasticity. Therefore

White heteroskedasticity period robust standard errors are used in calculating the

F-statistics. Model adequacy is tested using various regression diagnostic tests to check

for non-normality, autocorrelation, heteroskedasticity and GARCH effects. The

returns in stead of the levels of the variables are selected to prevent possible problems

with unit root. For the interest spread variable the logarithmic returns are replaced

with simple returns, as the interest spread can also turn negative. Wald tests will be

used to test the symmetry of the oil price effects. For the sectorial and individual stock

regressions there will be made use of monthly data. Robustness is checked by also

considering weekly data. Furthermore portfolio regressions are executed to investigate

the relation between oil returns and firm characteristics like size and sector more

specifically using monthly data.

Regression diagnostic tests

(36)
(37)

Data

Data is needed on the different risk factors included in the multi-factor model, as well

as on the stock returns. The data cover the period January 1st, 1999, to May 31

st

2009

for a total of 125 monthly and 543 weekly observations respectively. High frequency

data increases sample size and will give a more detailed picture of the oil price and oil

price volatility sensitivity. Daily data samples are not considered as there could be a

lag in the incorporation of oil returns (new information) in stock returns. Furthermore

daily data also contains more noise and has some undesired properties. The data is

expressed in the local currency (Euro). Data only available in dollars in Datastream

are converted into euros by means of the exchange rate. Stock returns of all traded

Dutch and Belgium funds (AEX, AMX, ASCX, BEL20, BELMED, and BELSMALL

funds

19

), market returns of the S&P1500 index, oil futures prices, interest rates,

exchange rates, and firm sizes are obtained from Datastream. Euribor rates are used as

a proxy for the risk-free interest rate

20

. Operating sector classifications are obtained

from Euronext

21

. Continuously compounded stock/index/portfolio returns are the

dependent variable in each regression model. The data for the dependent variable

consists of monthly and weekly returns calculated out of the monthly and weekly

closing prices of the return index (prices including added back dividends) of mostly

Dutch and Belgium stocks and indices. Daily excess returns are calculated by

subtracting the yield of 3-month Euribor from the continuously compounded monthly

and weekly returns. For European investments the usage of Euribor rates for the

risk-free interest rate is common. For the risk-risk-free return, the average rate throughout the

period is taken, and transformed into weekly and monthly returns. Market returns are

measured in the same way as stock returns as the excess returns on the S&P1500

index

22

. The market return is a proxy for changes in aggregate economic wealth that

affects risk premiums and expected returns. Oil futures returns are measured as the

log difference of the daily return on the West Texas Intermediate (WTI) crude oil

futures contract which trades on the NYMEX. Oil futures prices are selected as they

are less affected by short-run price fluctuations. Oil price volatility could be

calculated using this data. For the monthly analysis, oil price volatility is measured by

19

These are 174 stocks.

20

www.euribor.org.

21

www.euronext.com.

22

(38)
(39)

Results

In this section I will present the main results. I make a differentiation in the individual

stock analysis, indices analysis, and portfolio analysis, using monthly data. This to

identify differences between the microeconomical and macroeconomical level, and

more specifically consider firm and market characteristics that could make the

relation more clear. For every group summary statistics, correlations, and regression

results are presented. In Table 3 the summary statistics are presented for the six

independent variables. The average market return is negative and the average oil price

return is positive

23

. Positive oil returns are by definition positive and negative oil

returns are by definition negative. Oil price volatility is always positive, as only the

magnitudes of the price changes are relevant and not the signs. It is defined as the sum

of a certain number of squared daily oil returns. The interest return on average is

negative. Interest rates have declined the last decade. Interest spreads have a positive

mean, which indicates that the interest spread between 12-mth and 3-mth Euribor has

increased in this period. The exchange rate has an average return which is just

positive which indicates that the Euro has somewhat increased in value against the US

Dollar.

Table 3 Summary statistics main (independent) variables (monthly data)

VARIABLE NO

MEAN

MEDIAN

SKEW

KURT

STDEV

T-VALUE

R

m

125

-0.005

-0.002

-0.351

-0.265

0.051

-0.997

R

o

125

0.012

0.033

-0.859

2.276

0.109

1.267

R

ou

75

0.081

0.074

1.395

3.815

0.056

12.481

R

od

50

-0.090

-0.076

-1.977

4.656

0.086

-7.415

R

ov

125

0.111

0.100

3.001

13.382

0.046

26.648

R

ir

125

-0.010

0.001

-2.264

7.068

0.073

-1.595

R

is

125

0.049

0.005

-7.381

76.552

2.945

0.185

R

er

125

0.001

-0.001

-0.049

1.159

0.030

0.558

Notes: The first column indicates the name of the variable. R

m

stands for market return, R

o

stands for oil price return, R

ou

stands for oil price return up, R

od

stands for oil price return down,

R

ov

stands for oil volatility return, R

ir

stands for interest rate return, R

is

stands for interest

spread return and R

er

stands for exchange rate return. The second column indicates the number

of data points (returns). The third to sixth row indicate the mean, median, skewness, and kurtosis

for the returns of the specific variable. The last two columns indicate the standard deviation in

returns and the T-statistic of the return distributions, which gives an idea of the significance.

23

(40)

In Table 4 the correlations are given for the monthly returns.

Table 4 Correlations between variables (monthly data)

R

s

R

m

R

o

R

ou

R

od

R

ov

R

ir

R

is

R

er

R

s

1.000

0.296

0.107

0.039

0.130

-0.074

0.036

0.014

0.050

R

m

0.296

1.000

0.237

0.288

0.230

-0.097

0.144

0.167

-0.412

R

o

0.107

0.237

1.000

1.000

1.000

-0.365

0.075

0.015

-0.169

R

ou

0.039

0.288

1.000

1.000

-

0.193

-0.079

0.044

-0.205

R

od

0.130

0.230

1.000

-

1.000

-0.750

0.460

0.220

-0.258

R

ov

-0.074

-0.097

-0.365

0.193

-0.750

1.000

-0.624

0.021

-0.055

R

ir

0.036

0.144

0.075

-0.079

0.460

-0.624

1.000

-0.058

-0.072

R

is

0.014

0.167

0.015

0.044

0.220

0.021

-0.058

1.000

-0.116

R

er

0.050

-0.412

-0.169

-0.205

-0.258

-0.055

-0.072

-0.116

1.000

Notes: The first row and the first column indicate the names of the variables. R

s

indicates the

total stock returns, R

m

indicates the return of the market (S&P1500), R

o

indicates the oil return

of the WTI, R

ou

indicates the positive oil returns of the WTI, R

od

indicates the negative oil returns

of the WTI, R

ov

indicates the oil volatility return of the WTI on the basis of daily oil returns, R

ir

indicates the interest return of 1-mth Euribor, R

is

indicates the interest spread return between

12-mth and 3-mth Euribor, and R

er

indicates the exchange rate return of Euro/US$.

(41)

Individual stock analysis

In Tables A7 and A8 the summary statistics and correlations are presented for the

individual stocks on a monthly basis. The average correlations of the sum of all

individual stocks with the independent variables are given in Table 5. Most stock

returns and oil returns are positively correlated. The correlations of stock returns and

positive oil returns deviate considerably from the correlations of stock returns and

negative oil returns. Correlations between stock returns and oil volatility returns are

mostly negative. Actual conclusions will be based on the regression results.

Table 5: Average correlations between stocks and variables (monthly data)

STOCK

R

s

R

m

R

o

R

ou

R

od

R

ov

R

ir

R

is

R

er

ALL STOCKS

0.278

0.371

0.147

0.052

0.168

-0.084

0.033

0.017

0.072

Regression results

I use the following (general) multi-factor model:

(42)

Table 6: Summary regression results, including regression diagnostic tests (monthly data)

VAR

TOTAL

MEAN

MAX

MIN

P 0,01

P 0,05

P 0,10

C

1

173

-0.006

0.185

-0.325

2

8

14

R

m

173

1.007

3.992

-1.806

131

156

162

R

ou

173

-0.001

3.368

-2.073

4

14

30

R

od

173

0.131

1.250

-3.183

6

26

42

R

ov

173

0.080

2.851

-2.837

2

9

16

R

ir

173

0.004

1.469

-0.707

2

13

18

R

is

173

0.002

0.850

-0.354

28

46

58

R

er

173

0.824

5.289

-4.711

60

91

112

WALD

173

224.310

9056.000

0.000

7

17

31

JB

173

156.719

9679.111

0.026

98

104

113

DW

173

370.855

3147.000

1.425

-

-

-BG

172

237.432

5011.000

0.012

12

29

44

WHITE

173

1518.176

68403.000

0.064

45

56

66

ARCH

173

257.672

13472.000

0.008

34

44

54

RAMSEY

172

395.387

26411.000

0.002

20

49

64

CHOW

169

535.909

48514.000

0.091

33

52

70

R

2

173

0.301

0.999

0.049

-

-

-ADJ R

2

173

0.232

0.989

-0.442

-

-

-Notes: The first column indicates the different variables and tests, including the explanatory

value of the model (R

2

). WALD means the WALD test of symmetry, JB means Jarque-Bera test

for normality, DW means Durbin Watson test for autocorrelation, BG means Breusch-Godfrey

test for serial correlation, White means White’s test for heteroskedasticity, ARCH means

Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity test for heteroskedasticity, Ramsey means

Ramsey RESET test for linearity, Chow means Chow test of parameter stability. The second

column indicates the number of stocks. The third to fifth column indicate the mean, maximum

and minimum values of the different coefficients for the variables. The last three columns

indicate the number of companies which have a relevant coefficient, or relevant value for a test,

at the 1%, 5% and 10% significance level respectively.

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

Results do show, though, a positive effect on the oil price exposure at the 10 percent significance level for the daily return horizon and suggests that hedging activities are

The World Bank (2004b) also concerns itself with building efficient and accountable public sector institutions because the Bank contends that dysfunctional public

Myoclonus can be classified by distribution (focal, segmental, multifocal, and generalized) [ 75 ], by localization of the ‘pulse generator’ (cortical, subcorti- cal, brainstem,

Post-hoc comparison using Fisher’s test show that the mean ratings of smile genuineness were significantly higher in smiles of longer apex time for both the male and the female

Three fold symmetric gelators based on the benzene tricarboxylic acid core The benzene triamide (BTA) motif A is a scaffold similar to that of the cyclohexane triamides, how- ever,

combined policies. The high market penetration in Norway has been achieved through a broad package of incentives, which include reductions in the cost differences between

There has not been much research on this specific subject: many a scholar has taken it upon themselves to write about the flaws in Sherlock Holmes’ use of forensic

De studie naar specifieke ethische technieken van het zelf in de klassieke oudheid wordt het hoofdonderwerp van Foucaults laatste werken – zijn werken vanaf