• No results found

NUDGING THE EUROPEAN CONSUMER: A PERSPECTIVE OF EU AND BUSINESS NUDGING

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "NUDGING THE EUROPEAN CONSUMER: A PERSPECTIVE OF EU AND BUSINESS NUDGING"

Copied!
46
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

NUDGING  THE  EUROPEAN  CONSUMER:  A  PERSPECTIVE  OF  EU  

AND  BUSINESS  NUDGING

 

Richard  Nan  10222820  

 

 

MA Thesis in European Studies

Graduate School for Humanities

Universiteit van Amsterdam

Main supervisor: Dr. P.W. Zuidhof

Second supervisor: Dr. M.E. Spiering

03/07/2017

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(2)

What  is  the  role  of  the  European  

private  sector  in  the  nudging  of  the  

European  Citizen?  

 

Abstract  

Over   the   last   10   years,   behavioural   economics   and   its   implications   have   found   their   way   into   different  fields  of  policy  and  have  assisted  these  policy  fields  on  different  levels.  Within  the  scope  of   behavioural   economics,   nudging   has   become   a   method   used   by   both   European   policymakers   and   multinationals  operating  within  Europe,  to  steer  the  European  citizen  in  ways  that  meet  the  goals  of   these  institutions.    This  paper  investigates  whether  insights  from  behavioural  economics  and  nudging   have  had  an  effect  on  the  European  consumer,  contributing  ultimately  to  the  question;  What  is  the   role  of  the  European  private  sector  in  the  nudging  of  the  European  Citizen?

 

By  gathering  primary  research  and  consulting  relevant  literature  within  this  niche  field,  this  paper  has   attempted  to  answer  the  research  question.    

 

ABBREVIATIONS    

BI                                                                                              Behavioural  Insights

 

BIAP                                                                                    Behavioural  Insights  Applied  to  Policy

 

BE                                                                                            Behavioural  Economics

 

EC                                                                                            European  Commission

 

EU                                                                                            European  Union

 

JRC                                                                                        Joint  Research  Centre

 

PEF                                                                                        Product  Environmental  Footprinting    

 

(3)

Contents  

I    Introduction  ...  3  

II      Behavioural  Economics  Theory  ...  5  

II.1    Behavioural  Economics  ...  6  

II.1.2.    Essential  Behavioural  Insights  ...  7  

II.1.2.1      Choice  Architecture  ...  7  

II.1.2.2.    Default  Options  ...  8  

II.1.2.3      Incentives  of  search  ...  9  

II.1.2.4.    Myopic  Decisions  ...  10  

II.1.2.5.    Loss  Aversion  ...  11  

II.1.2.6.      Choice  and  information  Overload  ...  11  

II.1.2.7.      Heuristics  ...  12  

Summary  ...  16  

II.2      Nudging  ...  17  

I.2.1      Definition  of  nudging  ...  17  

II.2.2      Insights  of  nudging  ...  19  

II.2.3        Behavioural  economics  and  nudges  applied  to  consumer  policy  ...  21  

1.2.3.1  Libertarian  Paternalism  ...  21  

Summary  ...  22  

II.3      Nudge  and  European  Policy  ...  23  

II.3.1      EU  Nudging  Theory  ...  24  

II.3.2     BE  and  nudging:  Practical  implications  on  EU  policy  ...  27  

II.3.4        Summary  ...  30  

II.4      Nudging  and  the  Private  Sector  ...  31  

II.4.1      Private  Nudging  Theory  ...  31  

II.4.2   Practical  Implications  Private  Sector  ...  32  

II.4.4    Summary  ...  35   IV      Conclusion  ...  36   Annexes  ...  38   Bibliography  ...  39    

 

(4)

I  

 

Introduction  

 

Imagine  your  favourite  deodorant  suddenly  decreases  50%  in  size,  whilst  the  price  stays  the  same.   Would   you   still   be   willing   to   buy   the   product?   Probably   not.   Instead,   you   would   probably   find   a   different  deodorant  that  has  the  familiar  size  that  you  always  buy.  But  what  if  the  packaging  of  the   new  smaller  size  deodorant  would  explain  that  the  volume  of  the  bottle  has  stayed  the  same,  but  the   gas   in   the   bottle   is   compressed,   for   environmental   and   sustainability   reasons?   Still   you   would   probably   buy   the   bigger   deodorant,   because   you   feel   comfortable   with   that   size.   It’s   the   size   you   always  buy.    

 

The  above-­‐sketched  scenario  describes  an  insight  in  the  behaviour  of  humans,  and  the  economical   background  that  comprehends  the  fact  that  you  still  make  the  choice  to  buy  the  bigger  can  is  called   behavioural  economics.  Large  multinationals  deal  with  these  kinds  of  situations  and  human  choices   every  day,  and  struggle  with  the  dilemma  this  brings  forth.  On  one  hand,  these  companies  are  trying   to  drive  their  business  in  a  sustainable  fashion  and  aim  to  be  forthcoming  to  the  well-­‐being  of  the   European  consumer,  a  goal  that  is  largely  constructed  by  policy  and  regulation  imposed  by  the  EU.   On  the  other  hand,  these  multinationals  need  to  be  profitable  to  secure  their  presence  in  the  market.   The  EU  is  faced  with  the  same  dilemma.  Their  main  goal  is  to  ensure  the  wellbeing  of  the  European   consumer  so  they  attempt  to  create  and  sustain  a  consumer  market  that  is  as  beneficial  as  possible   to  that  same  consumer.  Nevertheless,  policy-­‐makers  are  forced  to  consider  how  well  their  decision   to   install   policy   or   regulation   is   going   to   be   received   by   multinationals.   After   all,   these   immense   companies  hold  great  influence  and  power  over  the  market.  

 

To  explain  and  answer  the  dilemmas  multinationals  and  policy-­‐makers  are  faced  with,  behavioural   and  psychological  sciences  have  found  their  way  into  the  process  of  policy-­‐making.  Over  the  last  few   decades   these   sciences   have   been   instrumental   in   getting   commercial   companies   to   understand   consumer  behaviour  and  rationality,  and  over  the  last  decade  the  EU  has  recognised  and  used  the   insights  from  these  sciences  to  steer  the  European  consumer  in  the  direction  it  believes  is  serving  the   European  consumer  the  best.  But  exactly  how  do  consumers  make  decisions  and  how  should  the  EU   and   multinationals   engage   in   steering   this   decision-­‐making   process?   Questions   like   these   have   puzzled   academics   for   years   and   a   vast   body   of   research   and   information   about   these   topics   has   emerged  over  the  years.  Academic  works  like  ‘Nudge’  by  Thaler  and  Sunstein  (Thaler,  Sunstein,  2008)   and   ‘Prospect   Theory:   An   analysis   of   Decision   under   Risk’   by   Kahneman   and   Tversky   (Kahneman,   Tversky,  1979)  have  been  instrumental  in  defining  this  extensive  research  field.  

(5)

 

Generally,  people  are  viewed  as  rational  creatures  that  make  rational  choices.  However,  this  idea  has   been   debated,   as   people   are   not   always   rational.   People   also   tend   to   make   irrational   choices   at   times,   for   instance   when   they   are   seduced   by   in-­‐store   advertising   for   a   product.   Therefore,   the   former  assumption  might  also  be  the  reason  that  in  the  past  some  policies  have  not  been  as  effective   as   they   could   be.   Studies   on   human   behaviour   can   offer   useful   insights   to   policy-­‐makers   by   generating   the   evidence,   which   can   enhance   existing   policies   or   lead   to   new   policy-­‐making.   Such   studies   are   applicable   to   a   wide   range   of   EU   policy   areas,   wherever   a   behavioural   element   exists.   Whether   policy-­‐makers   aim   at   changing   behaviour   or   designing   better   regulations,   greater   knowledge  on  how  people  are  likely  to  behave  should  serve  them  well.  People’s  behaviour  is  also   quite  relevant  to  EU  policy.  Sometimes,  the  objective  of  a  policy  will  be  to  change  behaviour  for  the   common  good.  Tax  on  cigarettes  and  alcohol  exemplifies  this,  as  it  aims  to  benefit  public  health.  On   other  occasions  policies  can  be  used  to  protect  the  consumer  from  buying  misleading  products.  This   contains  retail  products,  but  also  for  example  financial  products.  Policies  might  also  be  used  to  steer   people  into  a  more  healthy  way  of  thinking  and  living,  where  ‘quit-­‐smoking’  campaigns  are  a  good   example  of  this  implication  of  policy.  In  all  these  cases,  behaviour  is  a  key  element  for  the  success  of   a  policy  initiative.  The  policy  can  be  said  to  have  a  relevant  behavioural  element.  Good  policy-­‐making   should   identify   this   element,   assess   its   importance   for   the   effectiveness   of   a   policy,   and   try   to   understand  it  better.  

 

To  get  a  better  overview  of  what  the  influence  of  behavioural  economics  is  on  policy-­‐making,  and  in   particular,   how   nudging   is   influencing   the   European   consumer,   this   research   will   focus   on   the   following  question:  

 

What  is  the  role  of  the  European  private  sector  in  the  nudging  of  the  European  Citizen?

 

 

This  question  will  be  investigated  by  first  giving  a  theoretical  analysis  on  the  subject.  In  chapter  II.1   the  essential  insights  of  behavioural  economics  will  be  reviewed.  Chapter  II.2  will  focus  on  the  crucial   theory   of   Nudging.   Chapter   III   will   assess   nudging   from   two   different   perspectives,   where   chapter   III.1  will  focus  on  nudging  performed  by  the  European  Union  and  its  member  states  and  chapter  III.2   will  focus  on  nudging  performed  by  the  private  sector.  In  chapter  IV.1  the  overall  conclusion  to  the   research   question   is   presented,   followed   in   chapter   IV.2   by   recommendations   that   were   derived   from  the  conducted  theoretical  and  practical  research.    

(6)

II  

 

 

Behavioural  Economics  Theory  

 

Behavioural   economics   (BE)   is   a   term   we   have   seen   develop   in   the   media   and   in   academics   increasingly  over  the  last  ten  years.  Nudging  can  be  seen  as  an  application  of  behavioural  economics   insights  aiming  at  influencing  people´s  behavior.  

Major  world  leaders  like  Barack  Obama  and  David  Cameron  have  been  focusing  on  the  science  and   insights   of   behavioural   economics,   respectively   with   Obama’s   Executive   Order   (The   White   House,   2015)   and   Cameron’s   Behavioural   Insights   Team.   These   developments   can   be   seen   as   a   sign   that   behavioural  economics  is  creating  traction  on  the  international  platform  and  are  obtaining  a  valuable   position   next   to   classical   economics.   This   chapter   will   focus   on   the   insights   of   which   the   field   of   behavioural   economics   consists.   This   analysis   of   the   different   insights   is   crucial,   as   it   forms   the   theoretical  basis  to  answer  the  research  question  of  this  research:  ‘What  is  the  role  of  the  European   private  sector  in  the  nudging  of  the  European  citizen?’  Subsequently,  the  focus  will  be  on  Nudge  as  a   phenomenon  and  how  it  is  being  used  as  a  strategy  to  influence  the  European  community.    

 

Rational  choice  

Before   discussing   behavioural   economics,   understanding   the   framework   upon   which   behavioural   economics  theory  is  built  is  imperative.  As  behavioural  economics  diverts  from  classical  economics   theory   in   the   assumption   of   human   choice,   explaining   the   concept   of   rational   choice   theory   is   relevant.  Rational  choice  theory  is  designed  to  analyze  and  predict  social  and  economic  behaviour  of   a   rational   subject.   The   theory   is   described   extensively   in   the   1955   article   ‘A   Behavioural   Model   of   Rational  Choice’  by  Herbert  A.  Simon,  in  which  the  author  elaborates  on  the  architecture  of  rational   choice   (Simon,   1955,   p.   102).   The   terms   for   a   rational   decision   are   stated   as   follows:   ‘a   set   of   behavioural  alternatives  (behavioural  choices)  is  required.  Within  this  set  of  behavioural  alternatives,   a  subset  of  alternatives  is  to  be  considered  by  the  chooser.  The  next  step  in  the  process  is  the  notion   of  outcomes  of  the  choice  made,  in  which  one  can  make  a  difference  between  perceived  and  actual   outcome.  After  that  the  reward  of  the  choice  needs  to  be  considered  and  the  information  given  to   predict  which  outcomes  actually  occur  is  assessed.  The  final  step  is  to  assess  the  probability  that  a   particular  outcome  will  follow.  It  can  be  inferred  that  this  is  the  most  important  step  in  the  process   as  it  can  determine  the  level  of  rationality  one  uses  to  make  a  choice.  It  can  be  argued  for  instance   that   the   level   of   rationality   is   lower   when   one   is   influenced   by   external   factors,   such   as   ‘advertisements’  (Simon,  1955,  p.  102).  

(7)

As  touched  upon  above,  classical  economic  theory  is  built  on  the  assumption  that  people  are  homo   economicus,   or   as   named   in   the   book   ´Nudge´,   people   are   Econs   (Thaler,   Sunstein,   2008,   pp.   7-­‐9)   Econs   can   be   seen   as   ‘unboundedly   unscrupulous’   (Thaler,   2013).   In   more   simple   language,   this   roughly   means   that   Econs   are   only   interested   in   themselves,   whereas   Humans   (terminology   introduced  by  Thaler  and  Sunstein)  are  influenced  by  the  environment  around  them.  Econs  are  to  be   seen   notoriously   as   the   most   intelligent   economists   around   and   whilst   they   are   not   influenced   by   their  environment,  humans  are.  Humans  are  not  all  as  naturally  bright  as  Econs,  and  often  are  absent   minded  and  have  limited  attention,  including  problems  relating  to  self-­‐control,  according  to  Thaler.   These  and  other  human  traits  cause  humans  to  deviate  from  the  ‘Econ’  path  and  the  choices  which   are   then   made,   form   the   research   grounds   of   behavioural   economics.   With   regard   to   European   policy,  it  can  be  inferred  that  when  policy  makers  constantly  refer  to  the  rational  choice  theory  as  a   reference   of   social   and   economic   behaviour,   policy   will   not   be   fully   adjusted   to   the   actions   of   the   subjects  that  policy  tries  to  affect.  

 

II.1    

Behavioural  Economics  

 

As   mentioned   above,   crucial   insights   that   derive   from   the   field   of   behavioural   economics   must   be   understood  before  acknowledging  how  they  are  used  in  the  practice  of  nudging.  More  specifically,   nudging  within  the  European  Union  and  its  effects  on  the  consumer  market  must  also  be  understood.   In  this  light,  this  section  provides  the  insights  that  behavioural  economics  has  brought  forth.      

Over  the  last  decades,  behavioural  economics  has  gradually  gained  an  important  status  within  the   general   field   of   economics.   But   how   the   field   of   BE   should   be   grasped   must   be   questioned.   Behavioural  economics  as  referred  to  in  this  thesis  is  ‘a  scientific  discipline  that  applies  psychological   insights  into  human  behaviour  to  explain  economic  decision-­‐making’  (Ciriolo  et  al.,  2016,  p.  10).  Since   the  beginning  of  BE  in  the  early  fifties  many  experiments  on  the  human  psyche  in  relation  to  choice   have  been  conducted  which  forms  the  basis  for  BE  theory.  In  the  wide  array  of  economics  theories,   BE  theory  can  arguably  be  seen  as  standing  alone  amongst  other  theories.  According  to  Stigler,  an   accurate  economic  theory  consists  of  three  attributes  and  should  be  evaluated  along  those  measures   (Stigler,  1965,  p.  380).  These  attributes  are  reality,  generality  and  tractability,  where  generality  is  the   singular   attribute   that   does   not   consistently   acquire   the   same   function   in   BE   theory   as   it   does   in   other  theories.  In  economic  theory,  one  of  the  research  goals  is  to  provide  a  depiction  that  is  as  close   to   reality   as   possible,   and   look   for   a   general   ‘rule’   or   ‘law’   that   can   be   derived   from   numerous   experiments.   Theories   that   make   use   of   general   assumptions   are   assumed   to   be   more   tractable,  

(8)

because   they   try   to   keep   the   number   of   used   limitations   rather   small.   Experiments   in   BE   studies   inherently   have   to   make   use   of   behavioural   suppositions,   which   gives   them   more   assumptions   to   deal  with.  Even  though  these  studies  might  not  fully  fit  Stigler’s  criteria,  many  valuable  behavioural   insights  have  formed  over  the  years  (Camerer,  Loewenstein,  2002,  pp.  2-­‐3).  

 

II.1.2.    

Essential  Behavioural  Insights  

 

To   grasp   a   more   substantial   grounding   in   the   components   of   behavioural   economics,   one   must   understand   the   basic   insights   that   are   currently   utilized.   This   cannot   be   understood   without   understanding   the   predominant   academic   literature.   Conventional   economic   theory   assumes   that   every  consumer  can  be  regarded  as  an  ‘economic  man’,  or  one  ‘who  makes  choices  on  the  basis  of   what   is   cheapest,   most   supplementary,   most   efficient   and   so   on’   (Simon,   1955,   p.   99).   If   we   only   think   of   how   we   make   consumer   choices   ourselves,   it   is   hard   to   see   yourself   continuously   making   choices  in  that  way.  People  tend  to  make  choices  because  they  are  influenced  by  different  thoughts,   persuasions  and  incentives.    

Behavioural   insights   were   initially   used   as   part   of   a   discussion   between   economists   from   different   schools,   but   generally   the   behavioural   insights   were   used   as   a   mirror   towards   classical   economic   theory.  Over  time  these  insights  have  gained  presence  in  EU  policy.  Since  2008  there  has  been  an   influx  of  research  and  academic  insights  in  behavioural  economics  and  the  insights  and  applications   of  nudging.  According  to  Zuidhof  this  development  ‘undeniably  has  far-­‐reaching  consequences  for  EU   policy  making’  (Zuidhof,  2016,  p.  4).  This  is  exactly  what  the  science  of  behavioural  economics  tries  to   take   into   account   when   looking   at   choices   people   make   from   an   economic   perspective.   The   non-­‐ rational  choice  pattern  of  people  can  be  recognized  in  the  following  essential  behavioural  insights,   which  are  categorized  by  Ciriolo  (Ciriolo,  2011,  p.  1).  

 

II.1.2.1    

 Choice  Architecture  

 

Thaler   et   al.   see   choice   architecture   as   ‘organizing   the   context   in   which   people   make   decisions’   (Thaler   et   al.,   2014,   p.   428).   By   this   context   they   mean   the   environment   in   which   a   person   makes   choices,   or   the   influence   of   environment   on   the   subject’s   brain   when   one   makes   a   decision.   Unsurprisingly,   all   elements   are   crucial   in   the   decision-­‐making   process.   Every   contextual   or   environmental  influence  exposes  the  subject  to  choices,  either  instinctual  or  rational.  One  interesting  

(9)

and  amusing  test  that  shows  the  workings  of  or  battle  between  instinctual  and  rational  choice  is  the   Stroop   test   (MacLeod,   1991).   The   version   used   today   is   entirely   simple,   yet   effective.   Subjects   are   positioned  in  front  of  a  computer  screen  and  shown  a  number  of  words  that  either  appear  in  red  or   green.  If  the  word  shown  on  the  screen  is  red,  the  subject  is  instructed  to  press  the  right  button  on   his  keyboard,  if  shown  in  green  the  subject  needs  to  press  the  green  button  (Ibid,  p.  249).  This  could   be   assumed   as   a   simple   task   to   perform   and   whilst   this   might   be   correct,   it’s   only   until   a   new   component  is  introduced.  Hidden  in  the  set  of  words,  there  is  the  word  GREEN  in  RED  and  the  word   RED  in  GREEN.  One  could  say  that  this  is  irrelevant,  as  the  subject  is  focussing  on  the  colour  and  not   on   the   actual   word   shown   on   the   screen.   Nevertheless,   once   shown   on   screen,   response   time   increases   and   more   errors   are   made.   In   the   frame   of   choice,   the   Stroop   test   depicts   the   trade-­‐off   occurring  in  a  human’s  brain  between  instinctual  or  rational  choice.    

By   deconstructing   the   implications   of   choice   architecture,   it   is   important   to   also   understand   that   choice  architecture  should  be  seen  as  a  framework  to  influence  the  behaviour  of  humans.  Within  this   framework,  there  are  practical  methods  to  influence  behaviour.  These  methods  are  described  below.  

 

II.1.2.2.  

 Default  Options  

 

Default  options  are  options  one  is  presented  with,  in  any  situation.    The  appearance  of  options  in   situations  forces  humans  to  make  choices,  and  according  to  Thaler  and  Sunstein  (Thaler,  Sunstein,   2008,   pp.   8-­‐9),   these   choices   are   factors   that   influence   the   rationality   of   the   human   mind.   The   choices   are   predetermined   ways   of   dealing   with   an   issue   that   will   come   into   force   if   the   decision-­‐ maker  does  not  influence  the  process.  Thaler  and  Sunstein  explain  default  options  by  the  following   example:    

‘When   you   get   a   new   cellphone,   for   example,   you   have   a   series   of   choices   to   make.   The   fancier   the   phone,   the   more   of   these   choices   you   face,   from   the   background   to   the   ring   sound   to   the   number   of   times   the   phone   rings   before   the   caller   is   sent   to   voicemail   the   manufacturer  has  picked  one  option  as  the  default  for  each  of  these  choices.  Research  shows   that  whatever  the  default  choices  are,  many  people  stick  with  them,  even  when  the  stakes   are  much  higher  than  choosing  the  noise  your  phone  makes  when  it  rings.  

Two   important   lessons   can   be   drawn   from   this   research.   First,   never   underestimate   the   power   of   inertia.   Second,   that   power   can   be   harnessed.   If   private   companies   or   public   officials   think   that   one   policy   produces   better   outcomes,   they   can   greatly   influence   the   outcome  by  choosing  it  as  the  default’  (Thaler  and  Sunstein,  2008,  pp.  8-­‐9).  

(10)

 

As   stated,   large   amounts   of   power   can   be   derived   from   the   knowledge   of   the   workings   of   default   options   on   the   human   mind.   Knowing   which   options   to   set   as   default   options   in   order   to   achieve   most   success   of   the   goals   set   by   private   companies   or   public   officials,   is   a   powerful   source   of   knowledge.  As  stated,  that  power  comes  from  the  workings  of  inertia,  but  one  might  question,  what   exactly  is  inertia.  Derived  from  Newton’s  first  law  of  motion  (or  often  referred  to  as  Newton’s  law  of   inertia),  inertia  is  the  assumption  that  ‘an  object  stays  at  rest  and  an  object  in  motion  stays  in  motion   with  the  same  speed  and  in  the  same  direction  unless  acted  upon  by  an  unbalanced  force’,  (Physics   classroom,  2016).    

Abiding  by  this  law,  it  can  be  understood  that  default  options  work  in  the  same  way.  People  stick   with  the  option  they  chose  when  first  introduced  to  the  array  of  options  and  see  the  change  of  these   options  as  effortful,  even  if  the  reward  of  that  (small)  effort  can  be  greatly  beneficial.  The  fact  that   most  people  keep  buying  a  newer  model  of  the  same  car  is  often  not  because  they  believe  it  to  be  a   particularly  good  car,  but  because  they  are  reluctant  to  invest  time  in  doing  market  research  about   other  comparable  cars.  Conducting  research  could  be  greatly  beneficial  from  a  financial  perspective,   however  the  human  mind  responds  easily  to  administering  change  in  that  sense.    

 

II.1.2.3    

 Incentives  of  search  

 

Incentives   refer   to   human   motivation,   the   act   of   doing   something   to   reach   a   goal.   An   interesting   thought  is  that  the  real  goal  isn’t  reaching  the  goal,  but  overcoming  the  struggles  to  get  to  that  goal.   Overcoming   a   real   struggle   or   pain   generates   that   sense   of   victory,   and   actually   enjoying   the   goal   that   has   been   grasped   is   usually   only   a   nice   addition   (Dan   Ariely   Ted   Talk   –   Predictably   Irrational,   2012).   Ariely   describes   two   conditions   that   play   a   role   in   human   motivation:   the   meaningful   condition   and   the   sisyphic   condition.   The   meaningful   condition   depicts   the   idea   of   building   something  that  is  durable  and  something  that  is  appreciated  in  a  way.  The  idea  of  building  something   meaningful  or  with  purpose  can  be  seen  as  motivation,  as  one  wants  to  keep  building  because  it  is   going  somewhere.  The  sisyphic  condition  is  named  after  Sisyphus,  the  legend  of  the  Greek  king  and   founder  of  Korinthe.  In  short,  the  Greek  gods  lay  the  punishment  of  moving  a  rock  up  a  mountain   upon  Sisyphus,  only  to  see  it  roll  down  again  once  he  makes  it  to  the  top.  This  Greek  legend  can  be   seen  as  a  metaphor  for  demotivation,  because  working  on  something  with  no  potential  of  reaching  a   goal   is   undeniably   demotivating.   Furthermore,   an   example   Ariely   poses   about   this   process   is   the   cake-­‐mix   example,   which   proves   that   people   need   to   exert   a   level   of   effort   to   feel   pleasure   from  

(11)

achieving   a   goal.   In   the   fifties   an   American   company   that   produced   cake   mix   with   eggs   witnessed   their  new  product  failing  which  could  not  be  explained.  Scientists  came  up  with  a  possible  solution  to   this   problem   and   advised   the   company   to   take   the   eggs   out   of   the   pre-­‐mixed   cake   mix.   Now   customers  had  to  add  eggs  to  the  cake  mix,  which  gave  them  a  feeling  of  achievement.  Customers   could  now  feel  happy  about  taking  credits  for  the  ‘self  made’  cake  and  sales  increased  significantly  as   a  result  of  this  method.  

Another   correlating   aspect   of   motivation   is   value,   meaning   how   much   value   does   one   assign   to   a   certain  goal.  The  effort  one  puts  into  achieving  a  goal  is  therefore  in  correlation  with  that  goal.  The   incentives   of   value   are   personal   and   can   for   instance   be   social   incentives   or   monetary   incentives   (Bandiera   et   al.,   2010).   Social   incentives   are   incentives   that   stimulate   social   contact   and   actual   interests,   and   can   be   powerful   incentives,   sometimes   more   powerful   than   monetary   incentives.   Subsequently,   monetary   incentives   are   incentives   that   use   gaining   money   as   a   goal   and   are   commonly   the   main   driver   for   motivation   (Kamenika,   2012,   p.21).     Kamenika   points   out   that   employees   working   on   a   commission   basis   are   significantly   more   likely   to   work   harder   and   work   towards   their   targets,   as   they   receive   instant   rewards   for   the   extra   work   they   undertake.   Subsequently,   Kamenika   points   out   that   inadequately   structured   incentive   schemes   might   lead   to   inefficiency  due  to  multitasking  problems,  which  means  that  workers  are  not  able  to  reach  targets  as   they   have   too   much   commission-­‐based   work   (Prendergast,   1999).     Furthermore,   Kamenika   argues   that  workers  might  also  not  fully  understand  incentives  that  generate  bonuses  and  therefore  are  not   inclined  to  hit  their  target.  

Lastly,  employees  might  be  influenced  by  loss  aversion,  meaning  that  they  are  not  willing  to  take  the   risk  of  doing  extra  work,  where  it  could  affect  the  quality  of  regular  work  they  would  otherwise  do  in   the  same  amount  of  time.  Other  reasons  for  the  weakening  of  incentives  might  be  the  inconsistency   of  work-­‐life  balance  that  targets  bring,  or  the  risk  of  demotivation  when  incentive  goals  are  too  high   and   seem   impossible   to   reach.   All   above   situations   prove   that   incentives   do   not   always   improve   productivity,  and  when  placed  incorrectly  they  can  potentially  deteriorate  productivity.  

 

II.1.2.4.  

 

Myopic  Decisions  

 

Myopic   decisions   are   decisions   based   on   an   inaccurate   estimation   of   time   and   how   much   time   something  will  cost.  The  inadequate  understanding  of  time  affects  choice  and  choice  structures  in  a   multiple   ways.   Firstly,   humans   tend   to   not   value   things   when   they’re   in   the   distant   future,   as   it   is   desirable  to  be  rewarded  in  the  foreseeable  future.  This  can  lead  to  choices  that  are  not  necessarily  

(12)

beneficial   to   the   individual   in   the   long   term,   but   provide   quick   results.   Secondly,   humans   tend   to   focus   on   one   particular,   preferable   outcome   of   the   options   presented   of   things   to   happen   in   the   future.   This   outcome   is   fundamentally   the   most   profitable,   but   is   not   always   the   most   likely.   However,   individuals   tend   to   focus   on   that   one   outcome   and   are   sure   it   will   materialise,   thereby   discarding   all   second-­‐choice   outcomes.   Thirdly,   perhaps   the   most   ‘humane’   of   insights,   is   that   humans   tend   to   be   overoptimistic   about   the   future.   They   tend   to   assume   that   the   outcome   they   desire   will   undoubtedly   be   delivered   and   thereby   also   overestimate   the   time   and   money   they   will   have  to  spend  in  the  future.  This  insight  is  arguably  the  biggest  danger  in  making  decisions.  

II.1.2.5.  

 

Loss  Aversion  

Loss  aversion  denotes  as  an  insight  where  humans  generally  find  losing  twice  as  much  more  painful   than   they   find   winning   joyful   (Kahneman   &   Tversky,   1979).   Loss   aversion   as   a   concept   is   closely   related   with   prospect   theory,   a   theory   formulated   by   Kahnmeman   and   Tversky   and   developed   through  extensive  testing  and  research  by  these  two  authors.  Fundamentally,  prospect  theory  is  the   finding   that   people   tend   to   prospect   a   certain   outcome   through   the   use   of   a   reference   point,   for   instance  current  wealth  or  health.  In  this  case  especially  situations  that  involve  risk  and  uncertainty   were  tested.

 

 

II.1.2.6.  

 

 Choice  and  information  Overload  

People   face   choices   daily,   thus   coping   with   many   choices   can   be   challenging.   Barry   Schwartz   elaborates   on   the   subject   of   choice   overload   and   its   effects   in   his   book   ‘The   Paradox   of   Choice’   (Schwartz,   2004).     Schwartz   points   out   a   crucial   dogma   that   free   or   democratic   societies   operate   under,  which  advocates  that  choice  or  information  overload  is  good.  The  more  elements  of  choice   one  has,  the  more  freedom,  where  the  more  freedom  equates  to  more  prosperity.  Schwartz  argues   that  this  is  not  natural  for  humans.  The  pace  of  technology  for  instance,  is  too  high  for  the  human   brain   to   contend   with.   For   example,   when   buying   a   cell   phone,   there   are   multiple   options   of   cell   phone   choices.   Once   acquiring   a   few   options,   humans   must   again   choose   between   the   different   applications  the  phones  have,  presenting  the  brain  with  greater  options.    

 

Choice  has  negative  effects  on  people  such  as  paralysis.  An  excess  of  choice  tends  to  paralyse  people   leading  to  the  inability  of  making  any  choice  at  all.  This  process  leads  to  procrastination  and  thus  no   choices  are  made  at  all  (Johnson  et  al.,  2012).    Furthermore,  if  we  do  succeed  at  making  a  choice   from   a   variety   of   options,   research   shows   that   we   are   inevitably   less   happy   with   the   choice   then  

(13)

when  we  would  choose  from  a  few  options.  Not  in  the  least  because  we  would  always  think  about   the  many  other  options  we  had  and  the  possibility  of  them  being  the  better  option  than  the  one  we   chose  now.  The  regret  that  choosing  the  option  you  chose  subtracts  from  the  happiness  you  received   when  making,  in  your  mind,  the  right  choice.  The  more  options  there  are,  the  easier  it  is  to  regret  any   option   you   chose,   because   more   options   generates   a   greater   sense   of   missing   out   on   a   more   beneficial  option.  This  second  phenomenon  is  called  opportunity  cost,  because  it  reflects  the  concept   of  the  cost  of  missing  out  on  a  certain  opportunity  with  many  attractive  features.    

 

When   an   excess   of   options   arises,   the   third   phenomenon   is   an   escalation   of   expectations.   When   someone  has  few  options,  it  can  mean  the  expectations  for  these  options  are  relatively  low.  This  is   because  people  compare  the  options,  but  only  have  a  few  aspects  of  the  options  to  compare,  if  the   options   are   in   the   same   category.   However,   if   you   have   many   options,   you   have   many   different   aspects  of  options  to  compare  and  your  expectations  might  escalate.  This  might  lead  to  you  feeling   worse  about  your  choice,  even  though  you  did  better  than  you  would  have  with  fewer  options.  In   that  case  the  amount  of  choices  increased  expectation  levels  so  high  that  one  of  the  choices  should   have  been  perfect.  When  the  choice  is  not  perfect,  the  regret  subtracts  from  the  choice  happiness   again.    

 

Companies  often  claim  to  offer  the  best  service  whilst  claiming  that  everything  is  possible.  Moreover   companies   currently   offer   multiple   options   in   their   taylor-­‐made   products,   but   this   again   leads   customers   to   believing   they   will   receive   a   perfect   service.   Looking   at   this   problem   from   that   perspective,   every   customer   experience   is   potentially   and   eventually   disappointing,   because   no   company   can   maintain   a   constantly   perfect   service.   As   well   as   this   disappointment,   it   also   brings   forth   regret   and   subtracts   from   your   choice   happiness.   It   can   be   inferred   that   the   only   option   to   essentially  enjoying  a  service  is  to  have  lower  expectations.  

 

II.1.2.7.  

 

 Heuristics  

Another   crucial   part   of   the   decision-­‐making   process   is   the   science   of   heuristics.   Heuristics   as   a   concept  can  have  many  different  meanings,  but  in  the  psychological  context  have  been  referred  to  as   ‘rules   of   thumb’   or   ‘mental   shortcuts’   (Shah,   Oppenheimer,   2008,   p.   207).   Simon   referred   to   it   as   ‘methods  for  arriving  at  satisfactory  solutions  with  modest  amounts  of  computation’  (Simon,  1990,  p.   11).  This  science  comprehends  any  method  of  learning,  problem  solving  or  decision-­‐making  that  uses   a   practical   approach   which   isn’t   necessarily   the   ideal   approach,   but   sufficient   for   the   task   at   that  

(14)

moment.  In  other  words,  when  one  makes  a  choice  in  the  decision-­‐making  process,  it  tends  to  be  the   choice  that  reaches  the  immediate  goal  the  quickest,  but  isn’t  necessarily  the  most  efficient.  Tversky   and   Kahneman   discuss   the   different   aspects   of   heuristics   in   their   article   ‘Judgement   under   Uncertainty:   Heuristics   and   Biases’.   The   authors   discuss   the   different   forms   of   heuristics   under   uncertainty,  so  when  one  has  no  prior  knowledge  of  the  outcome  of  the  choices  that  are  presented.   Three   heuristics   findings   from   this   paper   form   the   basis   of   heuristics   theory   these   days.   These   findings  can  be  categorized  as  follows  :  Anchoring,  Availability,  Representativeness.    

II.1.2.7.a   Anchoring  

Anchoring   is   an   interesting   heuristic   as   it   shows   the   brain   essentially   using   a   first   impression   of   experience  as  an  anchor  for  coming  experiences,  which  can  be  familiar  products  or  experiences.  The   anchoring  gives  the  subject  the  idea  that  there  is  an  order  or  segmentation  in  the  range  of  products   or  set  of  experiences  that  are  being  compared.  Subsequently,  anchoring  gives  the  subject  the  feeling   that   they   are   making   a   thought-­‐out   and   measured   choice,   choosing   the   best   out   of   all   options   presented.   In   reality,   this   is   not   the   case,   as   proven   by   Kahneman   and   Tversky   in   their   anchoring   experiment.  In  this  experiment,  subjects  were  shown  a  wheel  of  fortune  that  would  have  an  outcome   of  either  10  or  65  with  every  spin.  After  the  outcome,  either  10  or  65,  the  subjects  were  asked  how   many   African   countries   were   in   the   United   Nations.   Results   showed   that   subjects   whose   wheel   of   fortune  outcome  was  10,  guessed  a  number  that  was  close  to  10.  Subjects  who  got  65  as  an  outcome   guessed   a   number   that   was   close   to   65   (Kahneman,   Tversky,   1974,   p.   1126).   The   outcome   of   this   experiment  shows  that  even  though  there  is  no  direct  connection  between  the  wheel  of  fortune  and   the  number  of  African  countries  in  the  United  Nations,  the  human  brain  makes  use  of  anchors.  Both   the  wheel  of  fortune  and  the  number  of  countries  are  expressed  in  numbers,  which  apparently  is  the   overpowering  and  connecting  factor  in  the  human  brain.    

Anchors  can  be  used  both  from  a  commercial  and  policy  point  of  view.  From  a  commercial  point  of   view,  anchors  are  interesting,  where  setting  up  a  large  anchor  can  make  a  consumer  pay  more  for  a   good  product  then  one  would  normally  do.  For  instance,  if  a  shop  owner  would  put  two  bottles  of   wine  on  display,  one  for  10  euros  and  one  for  15  euros,  then  the  10  euro  wine  sets  an  anchor  for   both  wines,  whilst  the  wine  might  actually  only  be  worth  3  and  5  euros,  or  might  even  be  worth  the   same.   Consumers   are   influenced   by   this   anchoring   and   will   see   the   10-­‐euro   bottle   as   the   ‘cheap’   bottle,  compared  to  the  15  euro  bottle  and  will  not  consider  the  price  or  actual  product  anymore.   This   shows   that   what   we   think   is   a   reasonable   price   to   pay   for   a   product,   often   comes   from   an   arbitrary  anchor.  In  the  document  Mindspace  the  following  is  brought  forth:  ‘It  has  been  shown  that   the  minimum  payment  amount  on  credit  card  statements  attracts  our  attention  and  “anchors”  our  

(15)

decisions.  When  a  credit  card  statement  had  a  2%  minimum  payment  on  it,  people  repaid  £99  of  a   £435  bill  on  average.  When  there  was  no  minimum  payment,  the  average  repayment  was  £175.  In   other  words,  presenting  a  minimum  payment  dragged  repayments  down.  Insights  such  as  this  may   offer  more  sophisticated  means  of  regulation’  (Dolan  et  al.,  2010,  p.  24).  One  of  the  writers  of  this   document,   David   Halpern,   later   formed   the   Behavioural   Insights   Team   and   advised   Prime   Minister   David  Cameron  on  policy  making,  with  the  use  of  insights  such  as  the  insight  described  above.  

II.1.2.7  b   Availability  

The  availability  heuristic  is  somewhat  interesting,  as  it  focuses  on  the  mind’s  view  on  the  probability   of   an   event   or   occurrence   happening.   More   specifically,   this   theory   focuses   on   the   mind’s   imagination  of  an  event  or  occurrence  presenting  itself.  It  is  inferred  that  people’s  estimation  of  a   specific  event  occurring  is  often  incorrect.  The  mind  takes  on  and  projects  certain  patterns  that  seem   to  be  correct,  but  are  often  false.    

II.1.2.7  c   Representativeness    

Representativeness   is   a   heuristic   that   mainly   has   to   do   with   the   human   ability   to   categorize.   This   ability   helps   us   to   make   sense   out   of   an   otherwise   chaotic   situation   and   the   ability   to   understand   things  better.  We  look  for  aspects  in  a  person,  object  or  situation  that  match  or  partly  match  a  pre-­‐ set  model  of  a  person,  object  or  situation  in  our  brain.  By  doing  that,  we  enable  ourselves  to  relate   the  unknown  to  something  we’ve  experienced  before,  thereby  making  us  understand  the  unknown   better.  This  can  also  be  seen  as  a  survival  tactic  as  instinctively  we  use  representativeness  to  make  us   understand  dangerous  situations  better.  Representativeness  is  thereby  closely  related  to  experience   as  well,  because  the  pre-­‐set  models  we  use  are  formed  partially  by  experience  (Tversky,  Kahneman,   1974).    

Subsequently,  by  classifying  certain  situations,  we  are  able  to  save  time  and  energy.  This  is  because   we  don’t  spend  time  thinking  about  the  right  way  to  act  in  a  certain  situation;  instead  using  a  sense   of  unwritten  rules,  to  make  a  quick  and  often  un-­‐thought  through  decision  to  tackle  a  given  problem.   Experience  hereby  makes  us  fall  into  the  mental  shortcut  of  representativeness,  because  we  create   patterns  in  our  brain  that  make  it  easy  for  us  to  link  experiences  to  patterns.  These  patterns  lead  us   to  pre-­‐set  models  that  we  then  use  to  identify  a  certain  unknown  person,  object  or  situation.  

Experiences  are  not  the  same  as  memories.  Experiences  happen  in  the  now,  memories  happen  in  the   now   and   in   the   past   and   are   more   comprehensive   than   experiences.   Experiences   form   memories,   and   all   experiences   together   form   a   memory   about   a   certain   situation,   object   or   thing.   Memory   strongly  plays  into  representativeness  because  memory  affects  experience  and  thereby  also  affects  

(16)

the  way  in  which  the  unknown  is  classified.  In  describing  how  this  works  precisely,  Daniel  Kahneman   discusses  a  typical  example  of  two  patients  that  undergo  a  colonoscopy  (Kahneman,  Ted  Talk,  2010).   Two  aspects  are  measured  in  the  experiment,  experience  and  memory.    

During   the   test,   the   two   patients   were   asked   to   describe   the   level   of   pain   they   suffer,   every   60   seconds.   Afterwards,   the   patients   were   required   to   describe   how   they   felt   during   the   test.   Interestingly  enough,  the  patient  they  found  who  recorded  higher  pain  levels,  did  not  have  the  worst   memory   of   the   test,   in   fact   the   other   patient   did.   This   means   that   there   is   a   correlation   between   memory  and  experience,  and  memory  being  the  accumulation  of  all  those  experiences.  It  might  be   that   the   patient   who   had   the   worst   experience   has   had   many   painful   experiences   in   the   past   and   now  goes  into  these  medical  tests  with  a  biased  feeling  about  how  that  whole  experience  is  going  to   be.  

It  is  the  same  as  going  to  the  dentist,  because  we  have  been  submitted  to  these  dentist  visits  from  an   early  age  on,  our  minds  have  formed  a  pre-­‐set  model  around  dentists,  namely  that  it  is  unenjoyable   to  visit  the  dentist.  One  might  ask  if  this  would  be  the  same  if  a  person  has  never  gone  to  the  dentist   before  and  now  goes  for  the  first  time  at  the  age  of  30.  Probably  this  person  will  feel  bad  whilst  he  is   having  his  teeth  checked,  but  will  not  feel  so  bad  about  the  whole  experience  of  going  to  the  dentist,   because  of  a  lack  of  memory  on  dentists,  which  could  have  made  him  feel  significantly  worse.  

Research  also  shows  that  the  ending  of  an  experience  is  the  most  important  factor  of  the  memory   that  is  revolved  around  it.  It  is  like  making  a  very  hard  test  that  you’ve  worked  on  for  a  few  hours,  if   the  last  few  questions  went  well,  it  is  likely  someone  will  feel  more  confident  about  a  good  result   than   if   the   last   few   questions   of   the   test   were   miserable.   Similar   results   were   found   in   the   experiment  where  Kahneman  found  out  that  if  the  experiment  continued  for  a  few  more  minutes,   the  overall  memory  of  the  experiment  was  better.  This  had  to  do  with  the  fact  that  the  patients  were   familiar  with  to  the  colonoscopy  and  the  idea  of  it,  and  the  memory  was  now  more  peaceful.  

Kahneman   and   Tversky   underwrite   all   above   stated   characteristics   in   their   paper   “Probability   and   Representativeness”,   and   they   conclude   the   major   insight   that   comes   from   research   on   representativeness.   First,   the   insight   that   we   try   to   estimate   probability   on   questions   we   have   no   answer  to  or  no  bearing  of  when  it  comes  to  knowledge.  Even  in  these  situations,  we  try  to  classify   and  categorize  to  come  to  a  certain  estimation  of  an  outcome,  based  on  nothing  in  the  end,  as  the   situation  or  problem  described  cannot  be  classified  or  categorized.  Additionally,  there  is  another  way   to  classify  something,  through  availability  (see  &  I.  1.7).  According  to  Kahneman  and  Tversky  it  relates   to  mental  effort  in  these  types  of  heuristics,  as  they  are  seen  as  mental  shortcuts.  They  are  seen  as   mental  shortcuts  because  they  assess  a  certain  situation.  More  specifically,  the  question  should  be  

(17)

how   well   heuristics   can   assess   a   certain   situation,   and   arguably   not   efficiently,   as   heuristics   are   intended  to  save  time  and  effort.  Heuristics,  and  especially  representativeness  can  therefore  mislead   people  easily.  

II.1.2.7  d   Intertemporal  and  Present  Bias  

Intertemporal   biases   concern   the   different   values   that   humans   give   to   a   time   slot   in   a   process   in   different  stages  of  that  process.  It  is  linked  with  the  Present  Bias,  which  indicates  that  humans  are   more  inclined  to  value  payoffs  that  are  in  the  near  future  more  than  payoffs  that  are  in  the  distant   future.   This   indicated   that   humans   find   it   difficult   to   postpone   payoffs,   even   if   the   payoff   in   the   distant  future  is  of  higher  value  (O’Donoghue,  &,  Rabin,  1999,  p.  115).  This  human  behaviour  can  be   explained   through   the   tendency   of   humans   to   be   impulsive   in   and   instinctive   to   find   gratification,   which   is   for   instance   the   case   with   addiction   to   nicotine,   as   Bickel   et.   al   suggest   (Bickel,   Odum,   &   Madden,  1999,  p.  450).  

 

Summary    

 

In  this  chapter  the  paper  has  shown  that  people  tend  to  make  choices  based  on  influences  through  a   multiplicity   of   complex   thoughts,   persuasions   and   incentives.   Behavioural   economics   is   a   scientific   discipline   that   applies   psychological   insights   into   human   behaviour   to   explain   economic   decision-­‐ making  (Almeida  et  al.,  2016,  p.  10).  This  will  also  be  the  definition  of  BE  that  this  paper  will  refer  to   and   use   hereafter.   Since   the   beginning   of   BE   in   the   early   fifties,   many   experiments   on   the   human   psyche  in  relation  to  choice  have  been  conducted  and  they  form  the  basis  for  BE  theory.  Behavioural   economics  have  gradually  gained  an  important  status  within  the  field  of  economics.  As  nudging  can   be  seen  as  an  application  of  BE  basics  with  the  goal  of  influencing  people´s  behaviour,  this  chapter   examined  the  most  important  behavioural  insights.  The  different  insights  of  behavioural  economics   that  were  discussed  in  this  chapter  thus  provide  a  clear  overview  of  the  complexity  of  the  consumers’   choice   patterns,   but   also   in   the   way   choices   can   be   influenced.   The   way   choices   are   presented   matters,   but   also   factors   like   peer   pressure,   the   consumers’   own   choice-­‐history,   expectations,   memories  about  certain  situations  and  motivation  plays  an  important  role.  In  the  next  section  the   research  delves  into  nudging  as  a  method  to  influence  humans.  As  presented  through  this  chapter,   the   BE   theory   has   provided   helpful   explanations   to   why   people   are   continuously   influenced   when   making  choices.  It  is  therefore  now  both  interesting  and  necessary  to  discover  what  the  theoretical   fundaments  of  nudging  are.    

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

As Robert Noggle (2018) puts it, “the assumption that manipulation undermines autonomy is so common in discussions of manipulation and consent that it would be difficult

Verder pleiten ze voor een meer integrale benadering, waarbij interventies niet geïsoleerd worden toegepast op één aspect van gedrag, zoals roken, maar op de

‘Het gaat om mensen die zich vergissen, mensen die niet kunnen bewijzen dat de uitvoeringsorganisatie een fout heeft gemaakt, mensen die iets verkeerd begrepen hebben, mensen

Aan de hand van het enquêteonderzoek dat in deze studie wordt uitgevoerd in Tussen Beide Markten in Groningen, wordt vastgesteld wat het fietsparkeergedrag is van de respondenten

Concluderend vormt de lijn nudge een goedkoop en efficiënt alternatief voor traditionele interventiemethoden voor planologen in het bestrijden van overlast

Er zijn in totaal elf experts op het gebied van ruimtelijke planning geïnterviewd, waarbij er gevraagd werd naar het gebruik van nudging, de ervaringen hiermee en de

Gekeken zal worden hoe de planoloog lokale partijen zoals de supermarkt een stadsbeheer kan betrekken om zo nudging tegen zwerfafval effectiever te implementeren.. Het probleem

Verder pleiten ze voor een meer integrale benadering, waarbij interventies niet geïsoleerd worden toegepast op één aspect van gedrag, zoals roken, maar op de leefstijl waar roken een