• No results found

Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure: Clashing Preferences Between Commission and Council

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure: Clashing Preferences Between Commission and Council"

Copied!
97
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

MSc Public Administration: International and European Governance

Master Thesis

Supervisor: Dr. Alexandre Afonso

Second reader: Prof.dr. Bernard Steunenberg

FINAL THESIS

Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure: Clashing Preferences

Between Commission and Council

Alessandro Gasparotti s1792229

Submitted on: 10/01/2018

Abstract: The introduction of the Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure, as part of the reformed EU economic governance, poses questions on which institution is in control of the process. When the Commission drafts country specific assessments and recommendations at the end of the monitoring cycle, how much and with what intensity do member states in Council modify these prescriptions? Using textual analysis on the official documents of both institution we try to explain the extent of changes and their direction, through the employment of institutional, political, and economic predictors. While changes decreased in comparison to similar procedures before the crisis, suggesting the empowerment of the Com-mission, changes are still partially explained by well known Council’s dynamics.

(2)

Foreword

The writing of this dissertation is the culmination of a journey started

at Leiden University and continued at SciencesPo in Paris. Embarking in

writing an original piece of research is a daunting but rewarding

activ-ity. I would like to thank my supervisor, who accepted my request and

agreed on supervising my progress from abroad, thus allowing me to

en-rich my economics’ knowledge in Paris. His patience and support have

been key in completing this thesis. My gratitude goes especially to my

for-mer colleagues at the Clingendael Institute, whose knowledge and

kind-ness guided me toward understanding what I really hope to obtain

pro-fessionally, this whole research was inspired by my time working there.

Gratitude also goes to friends and family, people met along the road

dur-ing this experience: people who inspired me and supported me all along.

A final thanks goes to Alvise, a long-time friend, who invested his time

(3)

List of Abbreviations

AMR: Alert Mechanism Report CAP: Correction Action Plan

COREPER: Permanent

Representa-tives Committee

CSR: Country Specific

Recommen-dation

ECB: European Central Bank

ECFIN (DG): Directorate-General

for Economic and Financial Affairs

EDP: Excessive Deficit Procedure EFC: Economic and Financial

Com-mittee

EIP: Excessive Imbalance Proce-dure

EMCO: Employment Committee EMU: Economic and Monetary Union

EU: European Union

EZ: Euro Zone

GDP: Gross Domestic Product IDR: In Depth Review

IMF: International Monetary Fund MIP: Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure

OMC: Open Method of Coordination PMR: Poisson Model Regression QMV: Qualified Majority Voting RQMV: Reverse Qualified Majority

Voting

SGP: Stability and Growth Pact SPC: Social Protection Committee TEU: Treaty on the European Union TFEU: Treaty on the Functioning of

the European Union

(4)

Country Abbreviations AT: Austria (e) BE: Belgium (e) BG: Bulgaria CY: Cyprus (e) CZ: Czech Republic DE: Germany (e) DK: Denmark EE: Estonia (e) EL: Greece (e) ES: Spain (e) FI: Finland (e) FR: France (e) HR: Croatia HU: Hungary IE: Ireland (e) IT: Italy (e) LT: Lithuania (e) LU: Luxembourg (e) LV: Latvia (e) MT: Malta (e) NL: Netherlands (e) PL: Poland PT: Portugal (e) RO: Romania SE: Sweden SI: Slovenia (e) SK: Slovakia (e) UK: United Kingdom

(5)

Contents

Introduction 7

Economic governance reform . . . 8

Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure: legalistic introduction . . . . 10

Reforms and critiques . . . 14

Research question . . . 18

Theory 20 International contracts and MIP . . . 20

European Commission: policy entrepreneur and watchdog . . . 23

Member states’ preferences determinants . . . 28

Logic of action in the Council . . . 30

Hypotheses . . . 31

Research Design 34 Member states’ behaviour . . . 36

Variables and Operationalization . . . 38

Population and case selections . . . 38

Dependent variables . . . 38

Explanatory variables . . . 43

Analysis 46 Descriptive Statistics . . . 46

Weakening Commission’s Assessments . . . 49

Editing Commission’s Assessments . . . 52

(6)

Discussion . . . 56

Academic Implications . . . 62

Practical Implications . . . 64

Study Limitations . . . 65

Future Research Directions . . . 67

Bibliography 70 Appendix 88 List of variables . . . 88 Correlation Table . . . 91 Further Tests . . . 92 List of Tables 1 Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure findings for EU mem-ber states . . . 38

2 Example of coding weakening variable . . . 42

3 Summary statistics . . . 48

4 Generalized logistic regression model for the probability of weakening Commission’s texts . . . 51

5 Negative binomial regression model for the probability of edit-ing Commission’s texts . . . 53

6 Pearson Correlation . . . 91

7 Weakening odd ratios . . . 92

8 Generalized logistic regression model for the probability of weakening Commission’s texts - euro membership . . . 93

(7)

9 Generalized logistic regression model for the probability of

weakening Commission’s texts - euro out . . . 94

10 Negative binomial regression model for the probability of

edit-ing Commission’s texts - euro membership . . . 95

11 Negative binomial regression model for the probability of

edit-ing Commission’s texts - euro out . . . 96

List of Figures

1 European Semester Timetable . . . 11

2 Longitudinal data on the dependent variable edit . . . 39

3 Longitudinal data on the dependent variable weakening . . . . 40

4 Determinants of weakening and editing Commission’s

recom-mendations . . . 56

5 Number of edits and textual changes leading to a weakening

(8)

Introduction

The financial, economic and sovereign debt crisis that hit the European

Union (EU) in 2008 had, among various consequences, the rethinking of its

economic governance architecture, which proved flawed and ill-prepared

to anticipate, avoid, and manage such turmoil (P. Lane, 2012). Among the

shortcomings of the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) exposed by the

crisis, the narrow focus on budgetary indicators such as public deficits

and debts did not prevented the piling up of dangerous imbalances (De

Grauwe, 2013), and the whole monitoring of these indicators, inscribed in

the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP), lacked compliance by member states

(Savage & Verdun, 2007). As a consequence, some countries respecting

the SGP criteria ended up caught in turbulent times, like Spain and

Ire-land, while others - notably Greece - not having sound finances when the

crisis hit, had no room of manoeuvre for countercyclical fiscal policies and

were forced to implement austerity measures that contracted its GDP by

25% (Constâncio, 2014).

To adjust the institutional architecture, a bold set of reforms was

intro-duced - leading to the most rapid deepening of integration in EU history

(Jones, Kelemen, & Meunier, 2016) - reinforcing existing mechanisms and

establishing new ones to overcome the limitations previously neglected.

Other than establishing ad hoc mechanisms for financial assistance to

dis-tressed member states, with the adoption of the six-pack1 and two-pack2

-1Entered into force December the 13th 2011. Consists of five regulations and one di-rective. Regulation No 1175/2011, Regulation No 1177/2011, Regulation No 1173/2011, Directive No 2011/85/EU refer to fiscal policy, while Regulation No 1176/2011 and Reg-ulation No 1174/2011 address macroeconomic imbalances.

2Entered into force May the 30th2013. Consists of two regulations ensuring additional coordination: Regulation No 472/2013 and Regulation No 473/2013.

(9)

respectively agreed in 2011 and 2013 - the Euro Zone (EZ) tightened fiscal

surveillance and established a new procedure, the Macroeconomic

Imbal-ance Procedure (MIP), for the prevention and correction of macroeconomic

imbalances, inscribed in the new streamlined annual cycle of policy

co-ordination for economic governance, the European Semester (Stylized in

Figure 1).

Since 2012 then, other than a reinforced SGP to which it is a complement,

the MIP assesses macroeconomic developments within member states, in

order to correct excessive imbalances before they can threat the smooth

functioning of the single market and the common currency (European

Commission, 2016c, p. 18).

Economic governance reform

The Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure is considered by some

au-thors as a true break-though to overcome the short-comings of EMU

archi-tecture if applied symmetrically (De Grauwe, 2012), it is at times presented

as a new layer in already existing mechanisms, expanding their reach but

reproducing flawed governance structure (Verdun, 2015).

Having recognised the inadequacy of the pre crisis institutional

architec-ture of the EMU, in September 2010 the Commission presented the

Six-Pack legislative package (European Commission, 2010a, 2010b), aimed at

reinforcing surveillance and discipline in the economic governance of the

EU. Other than strengthening the SGP, the novelty of the package was the

(10)

Macroeco-nomic Imbalance Procedure (MIP). After a quick discussion,3 the Six-Pack

was approved and entered into force in December 2011. It’s legalistic basis

is enshrined in the EU Regulation No 1176/2011 on the prevention and

corrections of macroeconomic imbalances, which applies to all member

states, and the EU Regulation No 1174/2011 on enforcement measures to

correct excessive macroeconomic imbalances, which only applies to Euro

Zone members and entails procedures that can lead to sanctions.

Before discussing the MIP and the framework in which it operates, a

definition of what is considered an imbalance is presented:4

‘Imbalances means any trend giving rise to macroeconomic developments

which are adversely affecting, or have the potential adversely to affect, the

proper functioning of the economy of a Member State or of the economic and

monetary union, or of the Union as a whole.’ Regulation No 1176/2011

(article 2(1))

And furthermore:

‘Excessive imbalances means severe imbalances, including imbalances

that jeopardise or risks jeopardising the proper functioning of the economic

and monetary union.’ Regulation No 1176/2011 (article 2(2))

While apparently the definition of imbalance is clear in the legislation,

when it comes to assessing when one imbalance has to be considered

ex-3Interestingly, as noted in an interview given by one ECB’s top official to Moschella (2014, p. 1274) “The lack of a debate on IMF (that has an analogous mechanism in place and decades of experience on such monitoring) was conspicuous by its absence”, hinting that the unusual urgency to respond to the issue might have induced policy-makers to focus on delivering quickly instead of the quality of the response.

4A more precise definition was given by Thomas Wieser, former President of the EU Economic and Financial Committee (EFC): ‘A macroeconomic imbalance is the (negative or

positive) position of a domestic, external or financial variable... [which] may - if uncorrected over time - make the national savings/investment balance so untenable that it self-corrects

(11)

cessive is a controversial topic. Political scientists noted that the

vague-ness of the definition can result in excessive discretionary powers to EU

authorities (Chalmers, 2012) and consequent illegitimate constraints to

national decision-making (Schmidt, 2015).

Moreover, from an economic perspective, an imbalance is not inherently

dangerous (Blanchard & Giavazzi, 2002). Imbalances, most notably in the

current account, depend on many factors, among which comparative

ad-vantages and country specialization (Hunt & Morgan, 1995), political and

institutional preferences described by the scholarship of varieties of

cap-italism (Hall & Soskice, 2001), the Balassa (1964) Samuelson (1964)

hy-pothesis in time of economic catching-up (Tressel et al., 2014), and many

more (Wyplosz, 2016). Notwithstanding their origin, the crisis has made

clear their impact on the stability of the EMU. As Buti and Carnot (2012)

-two officials at the Commission - highlighted, the crisis cannot be simply

explained by fiscal profligacy in some member states, but it is part of a

wide set of financial and macroeconomic developments that were

under-estimated and now are monitored in the MIP.

Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure: legalistic introduction

As Figure 1 shows, the starting point of the new surveillance

proce-dure is the Alert Mechanism Report (AMR), prepared by the Commission,

which on a country-by-country basis identifies issues that necessitate a

review. Although the Commission examines the economic indicators

pre-This subsection is mainly based on actual legislation, a Compendium produced by the Commission (European Commission, 2016c), and the Commission’s website: https: //ec.europa.eu/info/business-economy-euro/economic-and-fiscal-policy-coordination/ eu-economic-governance-monitoring-prevention-correction/european-semester/

(12)

Figure 1. European Semester Timetable6

6Retrieved from: (last access 09/01/2018)

(13)

sented in a scoreboard encompassing both external competitiveness and

internal imbalances - with upper and lower bounds - there is no automatic

interpretation of the results, meaning that qualitative analyses are

under-taken, giving the Commission discretion and flexibility in its assessments.

The conclusions AMR are discussed in the EU’s Council of Economic and

Finance Ministers and in the Eurogroup for matters related to EZ

mem-ber states,5 after which, taking into account the feedbacks from member

states, the Commission decides which countries needs further

investiga-tion and prepares country-specific in depth reviews (IDR), as stated in

article 5 of Regulation No 1176/2011.

IDRs are far-reaching and account for country peculiarities. Surveillance

missions are held in member states, opinion by the European Central

Bank (ECB) officials can be requested for EZ members, and country

spe-cific situation are assessed against spillover effects in the rest of the Union.

The conclusion of IDRs, depending on the result of the assessment, can

lead to three different outcomes.

1. If no imbalance is detected - or in the case the member states was not

subjected to IDR - the Commission will avoid further action, for the

rest of the cycle of surveillance.

2. If imbalances are detected - even in the case of excessive ones that do

not require enhanced surveillance - the Council agrees, by Qualified

Majority Voting (QMV), on preventive country specific

recommenda-tions (CSR) drafted by the Commission to correct imbalances (article

5As noted in Vanhercke, Zeitlin, and Zwinkels (2015) and Zeitlin (2014), the Committee of Permanent Representatives (COREPER) is more and more involved in mediating debates so to provide a broader discussion, with the aim of including experts of different policy-fields, due to the overreaching nature of macroeconomic surveillance.

(14)

6(4)).

MIP related CSRs are issued in the larger framework of the European

Semester, together with recommendations related to the SGP and the

integrated guidelines.

3. If imbalances are deemed excessive and requiring corrective action,

Chapter III of Regulation No 1176/2011 details the functioning of the

Excessive Imbalance Procedure (EIP). In case of non compliance, EZ

member states can receive pecuniary sanctions, as described in

Reg-ulation No 1174/2011.

In a nutshell, the Council can adopt by QMV a recommendation

drafted by the Commission in which it recognises the imbalances as

excessive, and specifies a set of policies to be followed with a deadline

upon which the concerned member state has to submit a Correction

Action Plan (CAP). The full execution of policy recommendations puts

the procedure in abeyance, but its conclusion is dependent on the

correction of the imbalance, meaning that not implementing the

poli-cies in the recommendation but achieving a satisfying result is the

key objective. 7

The Commission is tasked with monitoring implementation of the

CAP. If the Council considers that the member states has not taken

corrective measures, it can adopt a Commission recommendation

of non-compliance setting new deadlines. Such recommendation is

adopted within 10 days unless rejected by reversed qualified majority

voting (RQMV) (article 10(4)).

7Member state ownership it thus encouraged. Even the CAP is drafted by the con-cerned member state and approved or rejected by the Council on a Commission report. It the CAP is rejected twice, fines can be imposed for EZ members.

(15)

For EZ member states, Regulation No 1174/2011 envisages an

an-nual fine when two consecutive CAPs are rejected (article 3(2)),

in-terest bearing deposit in case of non-compliance with the CAP

(ar-ticle 3(1)), and annual fine in case of two Council decision on

non-compliance (article 3(2)). The yearly amount of sanctions and deposit

recommended by the Commission are 0.1% of the country’s gross

do-mestic product (GDP) in the preceding year (article 5). Sanctions are

adopted by the newly introduced RQMV: only EZ member states vote,

minus the concerned one (article 5). If after 10 days the

recommen-dation is not rejected, it is automatically adopted.

Reforms and critiques

Since its inception, the MIP has been adjusted and modified several

times, suggesting that the Commission takes advantage of the vagueness

characterising Regulation No 1176/2011 to overcome rising shortfalls,

possibly due to the limited investment in time during the drafting phase.

Such changes involved (i) the set of indicators used to produce the AMR,

(ii) the categorisation of imbalances in the IDRs’ conclusions, and (iii) the

terminology and policy priorities set out in CSRs.

Indicators referring to social conditions were added in order to better grasp

what these imbalances mean for affected citizens (European Commission,

2015c); such a turn indicates both increased attention by the Commission

toward transparency (part of throughput according to Schmidt (2013)),

supporting output legitimacy, and the successful lobbying of the

Employ-ment Committee (EMCO) and Social Protection Committee (SPC) within

(16)

by the Directorate General for Economic and Financial Affairs (ECFIN) in

analysing social matters and producing CSRs (Zeitlin & Vanhercke, 2014;

Vanhercke et al., 2015).

The categorization of imbalance, and consequently their severity, was

mod-ified almost every year, giving importance either to gravity or the urgency

of policy response, until the process was streamlined in 2016 to enhance

transparency in the MIP implementation (European Commission, 2015f).

Policy priorities and the very terminology adopted in CSRs evolved during

the years, with a revitalised attention to flexicurity and poverty reduction

(Bekker, 2015, 2017), disproving the assumption of a Commission

inher-ently neoliberal, operating to undermine the welfare state (Joerges, 2014).

The Commission then, when empowered with new competencies, operated

in a rational and dynamic framework, through ideational change,

peer-pressure and learning (Lombardi & Woods, 2008), both within the

institu-tion and regarding its relainstitu-tions with member states.

While an EIP - where the Commission enjoys expanded power

vis-à-vis member states - has never been initiated, most countries experienced

imbalances of some sort, 8 leading the Council to adopt so far 296 MIP

related CSRs 9 within the European Semester, coupling these

recommen-dations with the ones related to the SGP, forming a coherent framework

for economic surveillance (European Commission, 2013a).

The MIP framework resembles the SGP’s one, at the point that in the

yearly cycle of the European Semester the two tools follow the same

time-line (Figure 1) and CSRs are released for both mechanisms, suggesting

8In 80 out of the 89 IDRs produced member states were found experiencing imbalances (58 times), or excessive imbalances (22 times)

(17)

that the flaws exposed in the fourteen year of SGP’s history before the

in-troduction of the Six-Pack - lot of research has been produced regarding

the shortcomings of the SGP, see for an introduction Baerg and Hallerberg

(2016), Heipertz and Verdun (2010) - might not have been properly

ad-dressed, with the risk of reproducing them, thus undermining the whole

rationale of enhanced surveillance.

The definition of excessive imbalances is broad and extremely vague,

giv-ing discretion to the Commission, and could imply overreach (Chalmers,

2012; Joerges & Weimer, 2012). CSRs - although not binding - are now

part of the MIP mechanism,10 meaning that sanctions could be triggered

in case of non compliance, expanding the power of the institution. For

that reason MIP has been seen as exemplary of the post-crisis

reasser-tion of the EU legal order’s harder edge (Dawson, 2015a, p. 1). Member

states on the other hand committed to rebalancing macroeconomic

indi-cators within the reinforced framework of economic governance. Hodson

(2017) considers however such framework as a limited source of binding

recommendations, describing it more as an instrument of peer-pressure,

where government face the precision of recommendations that they

ex-pected when signing it into law.

Others criticise the procedure as a move toward executive dominance

(Crum, 2013; Curtin, 2014), based on ‘governing by the rules and ruling by

the numbers’(Schmidt, 2015). On the other side of the debate we find some

10Previously recommendations were produced as an instrument of peer pressure within the Open Method of Coordination (OMC), based on article 121 TFEU, but they had no enforcement mechanism, being thus a mere suggestion. The difference is substantial, due to the fact the EU competences are not encompassing all the fields regarding which CSRs are published, posing questions of legitimacy once sanctions can be issued to non-complying countries.

(18)

think tanks arguing that peer pressure is failing, implementation rates of

CSRs are declining and there is little we can expect from the Semester or

the MIP (Gros & Alcidi, 2015). MIP is seen as a very weak mechanism

(Sapir & Wolff, 2015) or as ineffective (Darvas & Leandro, 2015).

Focusing on the legalistic perspective could however miss important

developments, for instance the desire of the Juncker’s Commission to

cre-ate political ownership and engaging in genuine dialogue with the

mem-ber states (European Commission, 2015d). Vagueness of the regulation

and consequent high level of discretion in the Commission’s assessments,

coupled with such renewed political turn pose questions on whether hard

compliance is indeed the reality of post-crisis EU, or if instead a new

bal-ance of power arose between the Commission and member states

regard-ing the Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure.

Some scholars consider these new oversight powers as an expansion

of the Commission’s prerogatives in the face of member states, describing

them as a new wave of supranationalism (Dehousse, 2015; Schmidt, 2016;

Bauer & Becker, 2014; Laffan & Schlosser, 2016), while others concluded

that the new framework empowered member states in the Council, where

actual decision are taken (Puetter, 2012; Bickerton, Hodson, & Puetter,

2015; da Conceição-Heldt, 2016; Chang, 2013). Even though Bauer and

Becker (2014), drawing from Börzel (2005), show a medium expansion in

the breadth, and a strong expansion in the depth of Commission’s role in

economic policy surveillance since the crisis, and the faith in a more active

Commission, whose oversight powers are enhanced vis-à-vis national veto

player through the introduction of RQMV (Dawson, 2015b) at the time of

(19)

mea-sures under the MIP,11 although some member states have been under

scrutiny since its inception, in some case even on a deteriorating path.12

The preference for not exercising its powers at full is somehow puzzling,

and could be explained by the fact that the Commission tries to avoid

open conflict with member states, preferring softer forms of steering, or

that member states still retain enough power throughout the process to

block - or discourage - Commission’s action. Given Dawson (2015b) praise

for RQMV, whose application is only activated after the triggering of an EIP,

the Commission’s inability - or unwillingness - to trigger such a procedure

hints that careful attention has to paid to the steps leading to it, where

Council (Commission) could battle over blocking (pushing for) it.

Moreover, apart from few notable contributions (Bekker, 2016; Savage &

Verdun, 2016), little attention has been given on how the Commission

fulfils its new mandate in monitoring post-crisis macroeconomic

develop-ment.

Research question

The goal of this research is thus to shed light on the relations between

member states and the Commission in the new MIP framework. The main

focus will be the its final phase, when the Council agrees on Commission’s

assessments and draft policy-recommendations, maintaining the right of

amending them.

11On a similar way, the Excessive Deficit Procedure (EDP) in the SGP framework has been opened several times - due to the stringent numeric criteria to respect - yet in the only case where sanctions were about to become a reality, the Commission proposed a symbolic 0% fine to both Spain and Portugal (European Commission, 2016b)

12Bulgaria, France, Sweden, and Italy presented imbalances since the first round of monitoring, with the latter being categorized as under excessive imbalances for the last four years (see Table 1 on page 38).

(20)

The crisis of trust toward EU institutions, the rising influence of national

movements campaigning for opting-out of the euro or the whole EU, and

the still ongoing consequences of the great recession, make a valid point

in favour of a better understanding of the current shortfall of a mechanism

aimed at averting future crisis. Perfecting it would enhance Commission’s

(and in general EU’s) output legitimacy, that in turn could facilitate

fur-ther integration where needed. Moreover, given the willingness of EU’s

institutions to make more incisive use of MIP’s corrective arm and

capabil-ity to steer structural reforms (J.-C. Juncker, Tusk, Dijsselbloem, Draghi,

& Schulz, 2015), a clear understanding of the mechanisms at play is of

paramount importance.

Our research question is thus as follow:

Why are some member states capable of modifying the assessments of

(21)

Theory

Regulation No 1176/2011, as previously detailed, involves an high

de-gree of vagueness, and empowers the Commission with discretion hardly

seen in other surveillance mechanisms13 (Chalmers, 2012). Such an

out-come can be explained by the uncertainty that faced the EU during the

adoption of the Six-Pack. At the time, even the European Council

Presi-dent Herman Van Rompuy considered the developments within the EMU

as an existential threat to single currency and possibly to the existence of

the EU as a whole (Rumpoy, 2012).

This chapter will provide the main arguments discussed in the

litera-ture, from which hypotheses and the research design framework will be

built.

International contracts and MIP

The decision of member states to agree on international forms of

co-operation can be analysed as a mechanism to guarantee commitments

against short-term opposing interests - time inconsistency - or political

in-stability (Kydland & Prescott, 1977). Delegation is thus a reinforcing tool

apt to depoliticize certain fields, guaranteeing compliance through an

over-sight system that is (at least partially) away from their control, enhancing

its credibility and time consistency (Gilardi, 2002, 2005; Majone, 2001).

Such form of restraint, based on delegation to an actor insulated from

both time inconsistency and political instability, is what Lijphart (1999,

p. 5) defines as divided power. Moreover, future politicians will hardly be

13For example, the SGP, while offering leeway to Commission’s assessments (Euro-pean Commission, 2015e), has a limited amount of numerical indicators, to which non-compliance will be evident.

(22)

able to reverse decisions on delegation, guaranteeing delegation’s

credibil-ity (Wallace, Pollack, & Young, 2015, p. 58).

Most evident in the case of EU, where deepening of integration is based

on cross-border-transactions that require supranational coordination

fol-lowed by further institutionalization (Sweet & Sandholtz, 1997),

coordi-nation often requires the establishment of hard mechanisms, based on

independent assessments of compliance and possible sanctioning

pow-ers against breaching parties (Thatcher & Sweet, 2004; Pollack, 1997;

Tallberg, 2000). Majone (1994, p. 94) has argued that the Commission,

because it is pan-European and not democratically elected, is more

insu-lated from political pressures and is therefore more likely to take difficult

decisions and less likely to be captured by vested interests than national

regulators.

Generally speaking, bounded rational governments are unable to

fore-see possible future developments during international negotiations (Cooley

& Spruyt, 2009, p. 29). As a consequence, recurring to incomplete

con-tracts, where the principal (in our framework, the Council) sets the main

goal and priorities, while the agent (the Commission) is tasked with sorting

out how to achieve them, can lower transaction costs during the agreeing

phase.14 Moreover, the dynamic development of the contract guarantees

its adaptability to changing environments, facilitating the agent’s task to

fulfil its mandate. Granting the agent the right to rewrite the contract when

new informations are available avoids the need for agreement between

nu-merous principals to renegotiate the contract, provided informations are

verifiable with the counterpart - the principal in this case - (Hart & Moore,

(23)

1988)

At the same time incomplete contracts, not having detailed rules grant the

agent a variable degree of flexibility. Flexibility in international agreements

allows member states to accept deeper commitments otherwise costly, due

to the constrains that they will be putting on an uncertain future (Johns,

2014; Mansfield, Milner, & Rosendorff, 2002; Kucik & Reinhardt, 2008).

If flexibility is exploited by one of the actors under surveillance, the

commitments of all signatory parties would lose enforceability,

undermin-ing the rationale and credibility of the surveillance mechanism as a whole

(Chapman, Fang, Li, & Stone, 2015; Copelovitch, 2010). Differently from

domestic law, where violations of the contract entails zero-sum payments

from breaching to breached-against party (as it is formal non-compliance

within the MIP), breaches in the process are not zero-sum (Guzman, 2005),

meaning that in case of a member’s violation, whose certification and

sanc-tioning is blocked at a certain step of the surveillance process, the

reputa-tional loss of the breaching party is not offset by benefit to the Commission.

In the case of MIP, member states agreed upon a new mechanism that

was layered on top of earlier legislation and Treaty provisions (Verdun,

2015). According to historical institutionalism’s theory (Pierson, 2000;

Capoccia & Kelemen, 2007; Mahoney, James y Schensul, 2006; DiMaggio

& Powell, 1983, for an introduction), setting up new institutions can

eas-ily lead to the recreation of existing frameworks, given the knowledge of

their functioning, vagueness on their goal, and technical uncertainty,

of-ten leading to isomorphic institutional change. Path dependency provides

incentives to recreate institutional choices inherited from the past, even if

(24)

why the MIP was created with characteristics already criticised in the SGP.

Yet, although MIP expanded existing surveillance over further policy-fields,

its architecture incorporated the contemporary novelties reinforcing the

SGP, thus augmenting uncertainties on member states’ commitment to

the new procedure. Reinforced mechanisms made sense in the case of SGP

because they were the result of a process of learning (Dunlop & Radaelli,

2015), so to resolve the criticality exposed during previous years. Their

reproduction in a new framework of surveillance, with different goals and

a broader focus, was not assured to be useful, and uncertainty was thus

even higher than on the SGP reform.

To overcome these issues, the agent has been tasked to come up with time

line, procedural rules, indicators to be analysed, and methodologies for the

assessment (Discussed in Section ‘Reforms and Critiques’). Such reliance

on the Commission suggests that member states recognized its authority

and importance in coordinating economic policies, other than committing

themselves credibly to international agreements and to benefit from the

policy-relevant expertise provided by supranational actors (Wallace et al.,

2015, p. 32).

In order to better understand Commission’s powers, preferences, and

subsequently its relation with member states (the principal), it is useful to

dive into the role of such an institution.

European Commission: policy entrepreneur and watchdog

The building block of the Commission’s role is inscribed in the Treaty on

European Union (TEU), whose article 17 describes the two main functions

(25)

The Commission ‘promote the general interest of the Union and take

appropriate initiative to that end’. EU integration scholarship describes

such role as policy entrepreneurship (Copeland & James, 2014). It is an

agent whose interest lays in expanding its role though more delegation of

competencies. Important in such context is also the ability to take

advan-tage of windows of opportunity to propose and push in favour of its own

solution to policy-makers (Kingdon, 1984).

This behaviour by the Commission can be specifically seen in its signalling

of the shortcoming of surveillance regarding macroeconomic imbalance

when member states were in many cases still profiting from emerging

im-balances (European Commission, 2008). When - soon after - the economic

and financial crisis hit the EU, in May 2010 the Commission produced a

Communication proposing - among others - the surveillance of

macroeco-nomic developments through a new mechanism (European Commission,

2010c), it was eventually agreed by European Parliament and Council in

November 2011. This decisive result scored by the Commission was also

politically useful to demonstrate its ability to remain relevant and act

de-cisively throughout the economic crisis (Armstrong, 2012, p. 214).

Such an example, however, represents more an exception than the rule,

especially on major reforms. In fact, as pointed out by Marks and Hooghe

(2009), with the end of the ‘permissive consensus’ that characterised

Eu-ropean’s ambitions toward integration, and member states’ ideational

con-vergence toward the so called ‘Maastricht orthodoxy’ (Andor, 2013), which

implies a more pronounced turn toward intergovernmental decision-making,

Commission’s entrepreneurship is constrained by member states’

(26)

2013), having renounced aiming at an ‘ever closer Union’, as the White

pa-per on the future of Europe suggests, proposing for the first time a scenario

with EU’s retrenchment (European Commission, 2017c).

Even though Commission’s role in setting the economic agenda is

re-duced, article 17 TUE also gives it ‘coordinating, executive and

manage-ment functions’. Such tasks are of paramount importance in the

frame-work of MIP, given the nature of incomplete contract on which the

mecha-nism is established.

Due to the broad definition of imbalances, the unsettled question on when

an imbalance should be considered excessive, and the sensitivity of policy

recommendations to curb them - reforms can be required in a range of

fields encompassing labour market protection, pension reforms, taxation,

banking and housing sectors’ developments (to name a few) - the

Commis-sion has an high level of responsibility and discretion at its hands. This

is even more evident in relation to members of the euro zone, for which

non-compliance can lead to financial sanctions.

In order to ensure this task the Commission has to be perceived as

le-gitimate. Lacking input legitimacy, and being throughput legitimacy

ques-tioned due to the opaqueness of its assessments, attention to be as

trans-parent as possible, inclusive in producing assessments with all engaged

actors, and to deliver tangible and indisputable results (output legitimacy)

is among the main priorities of the Commission (Schmidt, 2013), otherwise

member states could have incentives to disregard its prescriptions, and in

the worse case to roll back the delegated powers.

Regarding throughput legitimacy, the Commission pays lot of attention to

(27)

see for example). Other than involving national actors more deeply in the

process, through periodically revamped frameworks such as the 2015 one

by the Juncker Commission, from which member states now have more

time for national discussion (Figure 1 on page 11 presents the revamped

Semester) and reinforced dialogue with the institutions (European

Com-mission, 2015b; Stuchlik, 2016), the Commission needs to establish itself

as a credible, authoritative and prepared actor. Even though an internal

reorganization took place to provide for better analytical skills (Savage &

Verdun, 2016), it still faces an asymmetry of informations against each

member state,15 hence it focuses on collaborating with them to achieve

its goals (European Commission, 2015d). An interesting insight in this

matter, exposed by Schout (2017), is that in many cases national voters

trust EU institutions more than their own government, thus enhancing

Commission’s legitimacy vis-à-vis its counterparts in the Council.

While not being the main focus of this research, it is interesting to note

that even if the Commission had the best knowledge of each member state

situation and was able to craft policies capable of solving every issue under

the MIP, as pointed out in Jones (2016): ‘then reform [would be] more a

process of politicians imposing the best solution policy advisers can offer

on powerful groups while at the same time selling the necessity for

sac-rifice to the electorate’. On a similar vein, Scharpf (2011) highlights that

under the scope of MIP recommendations governments’ capacity to

exer-15Moschella (2014) compares MIP surveillance with well established IMF’s one. She concludes that although asymmetry of information is a characteristic of each and every international surveillance body, the reiterated relations between officials from the Com-mission and member states provide a better solution to this problem than the IMF instru-ments. The MIP offers the tools to produce tailored recommendations, instead of generic ones normally produced by the IMF’s staff.

(28)

cise indirect influences over variables such as nominal wages or private

savings vary greatly between countries (in some cases being deemed ‘non

existing’), making compliance potentially impossible, or politically

suici-dal.

As a consequence, while the Commission has to aim at the highest

an-alytical level possible, contestation by member states is inherent in the

process, due to both the residual uncertainty of the proposed measures,

and the political implication such recommendations have over national

decision-making.

Even before the reform of economic governance in the EU, the power

of the Commission appeared to be ample and uncomfortable for member

states. Already within the Lisbon Strategy, where the Open Method of

Coordination (OMC) guaranteed only soft surveillance powers to the

Com-mission, according to Zeitlin and Heidenreich (2009, p. 236) it was

com-mon that bilateral meeting between Commission and member state took

the form of a negotiation over the modification or withdrawal of an

‘embar-rassing’ recommendation.

If such a situation occurs within the MIP framework a few considerations

are in order. First, Commission’s power can be counterbalanced by the

actions of some member states, especially if in the Council they are able to

create a coalition to suppress or water down certain inconvenient

recom-mendations. Second, we can deduce that not all member state have equal

capabilities and power to act that way, meaning that Commission’s

discre-tionary power would end up being stronger with weaker member states,

and weak with stronger ones. Finally, if some member states manage to

(29)

other member states would have an incentive to build coalitions to obtain

the same treatment, being a qualified majority needed to approve changes.

Member states’ preferences determinants

While assumed as strategic actors maximising their utility, member

states’ rationality is constrained by a number of factors over which they

have little control. this is most evident analysing their behaviour over time

(Moravcsik, 1993; Kydland & Prescott, 1977).

Member states do not have fixed preferences, meaning that even parties

favouring integration in specific domains might in the future oppose the

very contract they pushed for in the first place, due to changing (economic)

environment, unforeseen developments (both internally and

internation-ally), ideational change in their elite or electorate, or strategic opposition

for bargaining/electoral reasons (Börzel, 2002; Börzel & Risse, 2000).

An example of it can be the lobbying from Germany and France for the

cre-ation of the SGP, their breaching the pact soon after, subsequent reform on

a more flexible way, followed by Germany’s opposition against SGP’s

flexi-bility in the midst of the crisis (Heipertz & Verdun, 2010; Valero, 2015).

Respecting international agreements can be a sword of Damocles for

member states: the two level game existing in the EU (Putnam, 1988) can

be exploited to retain consensus while taking unpopular measures,16 or it

can encourage internal opposition to government incapable of standing up

against EU institutions leading to government change.17

16As in the recently analysed case of Latvia (Eihmanis, 2017), where national govern-ment implegovern-mented stricter austerity measures than the ones asked by the Commission and yet was able to be re-elected.

17Walter (2015) models why some countries implemented austerity measures quite smoothly while others faced problem. In the first two years of the economic and financial crisis in Europe Bosco and Verney (2012) defined electoral results as ‘incumbent epidemic’.

(30)

Drawing from multilateral lending and conditionality theories,

histori-cally developed for understanding behaviour inside International Monetary

Fund (IMF) and World Bank (WB), a powerful state is an influential one in

decision-making and rule bending (Thacker, 1999). Moreover, a

power-ful state is capable of shaping the size of conditionality and the strings

attached to financial lending (Copelovitch, 2010). We assume that

simi-lar mechanisms will be generally in place even inside EMU’s architecture.

Member states thus are not created equals, and their power determines

their ability to oppose Commission’s actions throughout the process of

oversight, instead of just fighting back once a problem is brought up.

In the EU, power can be categorized according to the voting rights of each

member states, or considering which tends to be the main actors around

whose positions coalitions are built (Kauppi & Widgrén, 2004; J. E. Lane

& Mæland, 2000; Aksoy, 2010), being the two often overlapping.

Different factors appears to impact on the influence of member states

in international negotiations.

Public support for instance can both favour or hinder member state power.

As researched by Chaudoin (2014b) regarding international trade

agree-ments, voters favour honouring the commitments only if they have no

preference over the issue. This can also be reversed as theorising thus

that where public opinion support European institutions, member state’s

power vis-à-vis the Commission will decrees. Moreover, in another paper

Chaudoin (2014a) found that voters are sensitive toward respect or

disre-spect for international agreements mainly during election periods.

Consequently, elections are sensitive periods for member states (Hibbs,

(31)

1991) to avoid antagonizing particular and powerful interests groups, other

than temporarily approve some policies to increment voters’ support

(Fernández-Villaverde, Garicano, & Santos, 2013; Efthyvoulou, 2012).

The outcome of elections can also influence member state power in

differ-ent ways: weak governmdiffer-ents have lower negotiating power internationally

due to the constraints under which each minister is kept accountable for

in national parliaments (Martin & Vanberg, 2004; Pahre, 1997; Goetz &

Meyer-Sahling, 2009). Moving toward the left side of the political

spec-trum for a government tends to mean that complying with financial

com-mitments will be harder (Grieco, Gelpi, & Warren, 2009). Moreover, in

the Council, the partisanship of a minister could have an impact on the

outcome notwithstanding the party affiliation of the prime minister: the

opaqueness of voting in the Council may provide incentives for a minister

to promote his agenda instead of the government agreed upon one.

Logic of action in the Council

Given the way surveillance is conceived in the MIP - if automatism was

in place - member states at risk would be pinpointed by the AMR and

sub-sequent IDRs would expose critical policy fields to be addressed through

CSRs. Targeted countries then would take actions to correct imbalances in

order to avoid be put under the corrective arm of MIP, where enforceability

will be stricter and non-compliance punished with financial sanctions.

However Commission’s discretion plays a role in assessing member states,

hinting that similar situations could be treated differently for reasons still

uncovered in the literature. Moreover, member states still retain power in

(32)

have in incentive to ‘correct’ Commission’s prescriptions before they are

endorsed. This move would simplify their task internally and avoid giving

ground to the Commission to step up its monitoring powers.

Member states’ behaviour is thus an important, yet not systematically

analysed, aspect of multilateral macroeconomic surveillance.

Bargaining strategies are particularly interesting in case of member

states facing imbalances that join forces to collectively suppress unfavourable

assessment by the Commission. Literature here affirms that lax

enforce-ment of international rules leads to bad behaviour by other member states

(Finance, 2004).

Hypotheses

The incomplete nature of the contract regulating the MIP is the

subopti-mal result of member state unwillingness to delegate further competencies

to an independent body that could force them to adopt policies that might

undermine national interests and traditional models of policy (Hall, 2014;

Hall & Soskice, 2001), forcing institutional convergence as a way to reach

the economic one.

On the other hand, coordination was deemed necessary due to the

inter-dependence of member states’ economies, as demonstrated by the harm

caused by rising imbalances and diverging trends prior to the economic

and financial crisis. The Commission thus was enabled with oversight and

steering competences over member states economic policies, empowered

by a mechanism of enforceability that in the case of euro zone members

can lead to financial sanctions, underpinning its hard power.

(33)

ca-pable of watering down Commission’s recommendations, and what

deter-mines these outcomes.

We can then hypothesise member states to exploit their own power to avoid

harsh assessment, which could lead to uncomfortable recommendations.

Recommendations that might on the one hand impact national

govern-ments’ re-election chances in case of implementation, and their loss of

credibility in the face of other member states and financial markets on the

other (notwithstanding be fact that they could face sanctions if members

of the euro zone).

H1.1 Member states’ power determines the final outcome of

Commis-sion’s assessments, followed by

H1.2 Bigger member states have more success in modifying

recommen-dations.

Given the nature of enhanced surveillance in the corrective arm, we can

theorise that

H1.3 Member of the euro zone - ceteris paribus - will be more invested

in watering down Commission’s assessment than non euro zone member

states.

Given the two-level political game in the EU we can expect that:

H2.1 The higher Euroscepticism, the higher the chances for member states

of modifying Commission’s assessments

That can also be reversed into:

H2.2 The higher support for the Commission, the lower the chances for

member states of modifying Commission’s assessments.

Considering the internal dimension of member states part of international

(34)

sit-ting governments regarding their strategic behaviour, thus we expect:

H3.1 In the run-up to elections, member states will increase changes to

Commission’s assessment due to more attention toward their achievements

and failures. Moreover:

H3.2 After elections resistance by member states against Commission

in-terference will increase , so to establish themselves as authoritative actors

in EU’s negotiation at the eyes of their voters.

H3.3 Fragmented governments, whose cabinet positions are split

be-tween competing parties, will have more chances of modifying Commission’s

assessments, due to the higher criticism and difficulty of implementing

sug-gested policies they will face internally

H4.1 The more worrisome the imbalance (and the higher the number and

precision of prescriptions to comply with), the more the chances for member

states of modifying Commission’s assessments.

H4.2 Non-compliance with the other pillar of surveillance - the SGP - will

increase the chances for member states of modifying Commission’s

assess-ments. So to avoid having a too large set of recommendations and a way

too harsh assessment to be presented to national parliaments.

H4.3 Member states experiencing a recession will have more chances of

modifying Commission’s assessments. This is due to the fact that they’ll

receive more recommendations and national voters will be already

com-plaining about incumbent government, hence the need to water down bad

(35)

Research Design

In order to test the aforementioned hypotheses, both qualitative and

quantitative designs could be employed.

A small-n in-depth comparative case study, assessing a few member states

over specific cycles of the European Semester, could offer a detailed

ac-count of the logic underlying the outcome we observe in these cases,

pro-viding a thorough explanation for formal rules and informal behaviours

of the actors involved. Still, deeply interpreting only a few cases makes

generalization difficult, and more often that not, entails using too many

variables to explain an outcome (Schneider, 2008, p. 278). Moreover, the

connection between the specific cases and existing theories needs to be

really strong (Toshkov, 2016, p. 285), and external validity is not ensured

(Toshkov, 2016, p. 304). If we wish to analyse a weak or rare effect, we will

then most surely conduct research on deviant cases, where such an effect

would be most evident, for which very specific conditions could mislead

us to consider the causal mechanism that explains an outlier a common

feature of all cases in which such effect occurs. The abundance of

vari-ables makes even harder weighting their impact, discouraging

generaliza-tion even more.

Given the exploratory nature of this thesis, on a path - to our knowledge

- still untouched, uncovering general trends and possible causal

mecha-nisms would pave the way for more specific analyses, establishing a new

venue of research. Thus, hoping to contribute to member states’ and

Com-mission’s bargaining power literature, we rely on a large-n design, due to

(36)

relationship (Toshkov, 2016, p. 200).

One of the main shortcomings of applying quantitative approaches to

decision-making in the Council and its relations with the Commission is that only

revealed behaviours will emerge (Heisenberg, 2008, p. 270), whereas

strate-gic behaviours and informal norms are a strong component of Council

decision-making (Puetter, 2012).

Notwithstanding such pitfall, already providing a general set of variables

that influence the outcome of bargaining in the MIP framework would ease

the process of uncovering more subtle and informal independent variables

in single case or small-n comparative studies.

Finally, since the MIP is a new procedure, we are interested in testing

established theories of international political economy to it, so to uncover

similarities and differences due to specific governance arrangements. We

thus follow a deductive structure of theory testing: abstract propositions

are tested empirically and can either be confirmed or disproved (Toshkov,

2016, p. 39).

We will try to confirm our four hypotheses. However, due to the reduced

time-span of the analysis, the presence of an economic and political shock

at the beginning of our analysis that could bias behaviours, and the

pres-ence of unobserved variables that could shape outcome, the prospect of

theory confirmation is reduced. Still, following Popper’s falsifiability

crite-rion, our goal in pursuing scientific discovery should be falsification

(37)

Member states’ behaviour

Since the establishment of the Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure

a total of 296 MIP-related country specific recommendations have been

adopted by the Council throughout six European Semester’s cycles.

First of all, using text-analysis techniques, we will conduct an analysis of

both editing and weakening of the texts assessing National Reform

Pro-grams, at whose end CSRs are detailed, considering whether the wording

or the meaning was changed from the Commission recommendation to the

final one adopted by the Council. Moreover, in case some prescriptions

were deleted through the process, it will be noted. The creation of such

dataset would also provide new information for Council’s behaviour,

be-ing useful for different research questions, thus possibly contributbe-ing at

expanding our knowledge on decision-making in the reformed economic

governance framework.

Such an assessment will provide a first count of whether member states

are actually capable of watering down Commission’s suggestions, with

what frequency they are able to do it, and whether the successful text

modification is equally distributed among member states.

On a second moment we will then test if these results correlate with

different set of variables, relating to Member state power, their economic

situation, the composition of national governments and the proximity of

elections, the attitudes of national voters toward the EU, or euro

mem-bership. In case of positive results we would then try to better uncover

plausible causal mechanisms. Obtaining negative results will still provide

(38)

(Bauer & Becker, 2014) and opening a venue of research on how the

Com-mission is capable to constrain member states’ prerogatives.

Another interesting venue of research, partially explored by Gros and

Alcidi (2015), relates to implementation of CSRs. It is considered low by

different accounts - similar at the rate of implementation of OECD’s ‘Going

for Growth’ recommendations. What seems overlooked is the relation

be-tween implementation, results of subsequently monitored indicators, and

following further recommendations. Process tracing analysis regarding the

Netherlands and MIP18 suggests that member states can forcefully reject

Commission’s intrusion in national politics, making the institution

with-draw non complied recommendation, although no change in

macroeco-nomic indicators would suggest an improvement of the national situation.

Thus, combining an analysis on non-implemented recommendations and

later developments in the scoreboards could uncover other cases in which

such phenomenon took place, offering a precise target for further in-depth

analyses. Moreover, comparing analyses of weakening with the follow-up

National Reform Programme could help understand how member states

exploits these changes in dealing with future cycles of macroeconomic

surveillance. For reasons of time constraints and the effort required such

cases - if uncovered - will not be analysed in this paper. This research

still contributes to the scarce strand of literature targeting the MIP, thus

proposing a frame in which the proposed and other researches could be

conducted.

18An unpublished manuscript by Bokhorst (2016) presents the case of the Netherlands and its mortgage interest tax deductibility (MID), addressed by the Commission and re-moved by the Dutch delegation after having demonstrated that no political party would have tackled it.

(39)

Variables and Operationalization

Population and case selections.

Table 1

Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure findings for EU member states

Year no In-depth review no Imbalance Imbalance Excessive EIP Program Country 2012 AT, CZ, EE, DE, LT, LV, LU, MT, NL, PO, SK BE, BG, CY, DK, FI, FR, HU, IT, SI, ES, SE, UK EL, IE, PT, RO 2013 AT, CZ, EE, DE, LT, LV, LU, PO, SK BE, BG, DK, FI, FR, HU, IT, MT, NL, SE, UK SI, ES CY, EL, IE, PT, RO 2014 AT, CZ, EE, LT, LV, PO, SK DK, LU, MT BE, BG, FI, FR, DE, HU, IE, NL, ES, SE, UK HR, IT, SI CY, EL, PT, RO 2015 AT, CZ, DK, EE, LT, LV, LU, MT, PO, SK BE, FI, DE, HU, IE, NL, RO, SI, ES, SE, UK BG, HR, FR, IT, PT CY, EL 2016 CZ, DK, LT, LV, LU, MT, PO, SK AT, BE, EE, HU, RO, UK FI, DE, IE, NL, SI, ES, SE BG, HR, CY, FR, IT, PT EL 2017 AT, BE, CZ, DK, EE, HU, LT, LV, LU, MT, PO, RO, SK, UK FI DE, IE, NL, SI, ES, SE BG, HR, CY, FR, IT, PT EL

Sources: European Central Bank (2012), European Commission (2013b, 2014, 2015a, 2016a, 2017a)

Since the establishment of MIP, six rounds of surveillance were

con-cluded at the time of writing (winter 2017). Our unit of analysis is

country-by-year. Given a population of currently 28 member states, minus

coun-tries that joined the EU after the establishment of the procedure, and

member states under specific programs of surveillance for which the MIP

does not apply, we obtain a population of n=149 cases. For details see

Table 1. Data availability reduces the sample to n=148: recommendations

for Estonia in 2013 are unfortunately not available in English from any

official source.19

Dependent variables.

The main dependent variable is member states’ success in watering

down Commission’s assessment. To capture this effect we consider the

level of variation between Commission’s assessments of National Reform

Programs and Council’s approved country specific recommendations.

19All documents were automatically retrieved from: http://eur-lex.europa.eu/homepage.html

Documents regarding Denmark (2017), Czech Republic (2017), and Slovenia (2015) were retrieved from the website of European Commission or Council. Documents regarding Estonia (2013) are not available at all.

(40)

Such variation is represented by two different variables, defined edit and

weakening, following the example of Baerg and Hallerberg (2016). They are

both coded by the author using two different methods: edits is the result

of automated text analysis, while weakening takes advantage of the

swift-ness of semi-automated data gathering to perform human coded textual

comparison.

Figure 2. Longitudinal data on the dependent variable edit

(a) Average edit by year (b) Average edit by Country

Edit is a count variable that represents the number of changes that

oc-curred between the two versions of the document (i.e. the Commission’s

draft and Council’s approved one). It is produced through an automated

procedure based on a script compiled using the coding language Python.

After having compared the two versions of the same text, we calculated

the Levenshtein (1966) scale of distance,20 a measure of the required

dele-tions, insertions or substitutions needed to match the two texts (Sörensen,

2007). Once we have the raw data, we can check the distribution of

changes across countries and across year. As Figure 2 show, there is

in-20Distance can be calculated at different levels. Micro changes would consider a letter as the unit of analysis, thus accounting for all textual modifications. Meso changes would focus on words, whereas macro changes focus on sentences as unit of analysis. We opted for micro analysis, in order to have the highest level of information.

(41)

deed quite some level of variation, suggesting that certain circumstances

favour or hinder the chances of editing Commission’s text.

The main problem with the variable edit is that it does not measure

content similarity. Two versions of the texts could have a Levenshtein

dis-tance of zero, while having different meanings due to textual substitutions.

To overcome this effect of automated text analysis, we produced a second

dependent variable, called weakening. Using human coding, we assessed

the changes and their meaning between the two versions of the texts,

cod-ing a binary outcome for weakencod-ing (1, effect is present), and no change

(0, effect not present). In order to be considered an instance of weakening,

the Council text needs to be less critical toward a member state, or have

prescribed less stringent - or precise - outcomes. Few examples of

weaken-ing are presented for clarification in Table 2 in 42. There is no distinction

between the level magnitude of watering-down: as soon as weakening is

found the case is coded as such, without accounting for multiple

weaken-ing in the same text or different degrees of changes. Results are presented

in Figure 3.

Figure 3. Longitudinal data on the dependent variable weakening

(42)

Analysing both variables offers the opportunity to check whether

mem-ber states change texts with the only result of weakening the

recommenda-tions received, or whether also minor changes are important to them, due

for instance to the follow-up discussions inside national parliaments, or

the possibility for journalists to extrapolate part of the recommendations

to comment on the government’s results or unsuccessfulness. Data

pre-sented in Figures 5 on page 62 show that the instances of weakening are

quite scarce between countries and across years, while editing is a more

widespread practice.

As observed by Grimmer and Stewart (2013, p. 267) automated

meth-ods are no substitute for thinking about the problem and validating

gath-ered informations, thus the weakening variable provides a qualitative

as-sessment based on human judgement and benchmarking. That way,

al-though the two variables assess different outcomes, we are capable of

test related effect using different methodologies, reducing possible biases

(43)

G PREFEREN CES BET WEEN INS TITUTIONS 42 Table 2

Example of coding weakening variable

Country and year Commission assessment Council assessment

Netherlands 2014 Even though the 2013 recommendations called for

a focus on support for households most in need, this redirection has not taken place. Therefore, while the proposed measures are steps in the right direction, the overall pace of reforms is slow in ad-dressing underlying problems and thus needs to be stepped up, while continuing to ensure that so-cial housing is available to disadvantaged citizens unable to obtain housing at market conditions, in-cluding in high demand locations. The 2013 rec-ommendations suggested that the stepping-up of the housing market measures should be subject to overall economic developments. As the economy and the housing market are expected to continue recovering, consideration should be given to speed-ing up the pace of reforms.

The 2013 recommendations called for a focus on support for households most in need, this redirec-tion is work in progress. Therefore, while the pro-posed measures are steps in the right direction, the overall pace of reforms is slow in addressing un-derlying problems and thus needs to be stepped up when the economy allows for it, while continuing to ensure that social housing is available to disadvan-taged citizens unable to obtain housing at market conditions, including in high demand locations.

Germany 2016 Achieve a sustained upward trend in public

invest-ment, especially in infrastructure, education, re-search and innovation, by using the available fis-cal space and prioritising expenditure. Improve the design of federal fiscal relations with a view to ad-dressing the persistent public under-investment, especially at municipal level.

Achieve a sustained upward trend in public in-vestment, especially in infrastructure, education, research and innovation, while respecting the medium term objective. Improve the design of fed-eral fiscal relations, with a view to increasing public investment.

Cyprus 2017 Cyprus also continues to face critical challenges for

the functioning of the judicial system.

Cyprus has been taking measures to reinforce its judicial system but continues to face serious chal-lenges as regards the efficiency thereof.

(44)

Explanatory variables.

In order to test the hypotheses outlined in the previous chapter, a set of

independent variables deduced from the theory will be employed to

evalu-ate possible con-causal relations, other than providing answers expanding

our understanding of what factors impact MIP’s decision making.

Explanatory variables used in this research can be divided into four

cat-egories: institutional, European, political, and macroeconomic predictors.

They are as follow:

Institutional variables are included in matrix I={euro, large state, shared

behaviour}

Euro: Takes the form of a dummy variable describing whether the country

is part of the euro zone (1) or outside (0), so to assess if ceteris paribus

EZ member states are more invested in avoiding unfavourable

recom-mendations that, if disregarded, might lead to the opening of an EIP,

where RQVM would make it harder to avoid financial sanctions in

case of repeated non-compliance.

Large State: Takes the form of a dummy variable with the value (1) if

the country is among the four biggest EU member states (France,

Germany, Italy, or the United Kingdom).

Shared Behaviour: Takes the form of a spline smoother of the

year-by-year trend of both measures of the dependent variables, as discussed

in Baerg and Hallerberg (2016), to hint the likelihood of changing

textual outputs when other member states are doing it. A positive

coefficient indicate a positive correlation between changing the text

when others are doing it, a negative coefficient indicates no common

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

T h e partnership also directed the attention of all p a rt­ ners, m anagers and employees to the considered opinions of the C om ­ mittee on A ccounting

This research aims to validate the macroeconomic risk-return trade-off between output growth and output volatility, whether country-specific exposure to the Global Financial Cycle

It accordingly recommended, inter alia, that member States should provide constitutional guarantees by: (i) recognising children as rights-holders and not merely

Pursuant to the Protocol on the application of the prin- ciples of subsidiarity and proportionality, the Commission will take due account in its legislative proposals of their

To conduct an interdisciplinary research study, the following research question has been formulated: ‘To what extent is food security affected by foreign direct investment in the

Seine Argumentation geht bereits, wie der Titel Versuch eines Beweises, daß die erste Sprache ihren Ursprung nicht vom Menschen, sondern allein vom Schöpfer erhalten habe

shown that while there is a low level of treatment demand from specialist substance abuse treatment centres related to misuse of or dependence on products containing codeine compared

The standard assumption that member states vote independently and affirmatively with a probability of 0.5 leads to a more pessimistic view of the Council’s decision- making