• No results found

FDI spillovers and its impact on the innovation performance of Latin America

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "FDI spillovers and its impact on the innovation performance of Latin America"

Copied!
75
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

FDI spillovers and its impact on the innovation performance

of Latin America

Name: Lisette Meppelink

Student number: 11355999

Date: June 22, 2018

Qualification: MSc. in Business Administration – International Management

track

Institution: Amsterdam Business School, University of Amsterdam

(2)

Statement of originality

This document is written by Lisette Meppelink who declares to take full responsibility for the

contents of this document. I declare that the text and the work presented in this document is

original and that no sources other than those mentioned in the text and its references have

been used in creating it. The Faculty of Economics and Business is responsible solely for the

(3)

Table of contents

Abstract……….. 4

1. Introduction………...5

2. Literature review………...8

2.1 Inward FDI and spillover effects ... 8

2.2 Product and process innovation ...11

2.3 FDI, formal competition intensity and innovation outcomes ...13

2.4 Informal competition and innovation ...15

2.5 Institutions and imitation tolerance...17

3. Conceptual model and hypotheses……… 19

3.1 Inward FDI and product- and process innovation performance ...20

3.1.1 Inward FDI effect on product and process innovation... 22

3.2 Moderating effect of formal competition intensity ...23

3.3 Moderating effect of informal competition ...25

3.4 Moderating effect of imitation tolerance ...27

4. Methodology……… 29

4.1 Sample and data collection ...29

4.2 Estimation Methodology ...31

4.3 Variables and measures ...32

4.3.1 Dependent variable ... 32

4.3.2 Independent and moderating variables ... 34

4.3.3 Control variables ... 36

5. Findings……… 37

5.1 Negative binomial regression ...40

5.2 Binary logistic regression ...44

6. Discussion……….46

6.1 Scientific relevance...50

6.2 Practical relevance...51

6.3 Limitations and future research ...51

(4)

Abstract

Over the past years, Latin America has proven to be a world region with fast-growing flows

of both inward and outward Foreign Direct Investment (FDI). The area has shown great

economic growth and enhanced innovative capabilities. Several authors have pointed out the

high inflows of FDI as the source of economic growth, but does this also apply to the greater

innovation performance? Is the effect of knowledge spillovers apparent in Latin America?

This study aims to shed light on the phenomenon of positive externalities resulting from

inward FDI flows in the often-neglected area of Latin America. It thereby advances prior FDI

spillovers literature and does not only examine the effect of inward FDI on the innovation

performance of Latin America, but also explores how (in)formal competition and imitation

tolerance moderate this relationship. Moreover, the innovation performance outcome is

further analyzed and distinguished between product and process innovations. Secondary data

is collected for 22 Latin American countries for the year 2010. The findings reveal that the

FDI spillover effect is present in Latin America, as the innovation outcome improves when

FDI inflows are high. However, this positive relationship weakens when there are large levels

of informal competition present. The results resemble a first step towards the fulfillment of a

large gap in research concerning innovation activities in Latin America.

Keywords: FDI spillover effect, innovation performance, product innovations, process innovations, informal competition, competition intensity, imitation tolerance, Latin America.

(5)

1. Introduction

Multiple studies have acknowledged the growing potentials of emerging economies (e.g.

Brenes et al., 2016). These economies are developing quickly and have become interesting for

developed economy multinational enterprises (MNEs) to invest in (Martin et al., 2015). Latin

America is such an emerging economy and has only relatively recently been open to Foreign

Direct Investment (FDI). From mid 1970 onwards, many Latin American governments started

opening their markets (Trevino and Mixon Jr., 2004). Even though not all economies have

responded similarly to the opportunities and challenges of globalization, many countries

experienced a positive effect on the economic performance and managed to catch up to other

regions in the world (Castellacci and Natera, 2016). Accordingly, several countries in Latin

America have been regarded as new engines of economic growth and have proved to possess

innovative and entrepreneurial capabilities (Lederman et al. 2013). Brazil has been part of the

BRICS – the new emerging economic powers of the world – since 2010 (Stuenkel, 2014),

Mexico and Colombia have been acknowledged as fast growing emerging economies and are

included in the MIKTA and CIVETS groups (The Economist, 2013), and both Brazil and

Mexico are currently members of the OECD (Brenes et al., 2016).

Data provided by UNCTAD 2017 shows a growing interest of foreign investors in Latin

America: from 2010 to 2016 the inward FDI increased from respectively 70.869 stocks to

138.766. In particular South America, as opposed to Central America, is responsible for this

large increase. The Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC)

reported that in 2010, Latin America showed great resilience to the international financial

(6)

the high inflows of FDI has yielded new opportunities for Latin America as inward FDI can

stimulate economic growth and support infrastructure development. However, despite the

growing potentials and almost doubling amount of inward FDI in Latin America, relatively

little research has been done in this area.

MNEs are increasingly expanding operations to turbulent economies, requiring the

understanding of non-traditional markets. Traditional developed market research and theories

do not properly fit the unique social, institutional and economic contexts of emerging

economies (Wright et al., 2005). Much attention has primarily been given to China and India

in non-traditional market research, neglecting the importance of Latin America. An additional

gap in research is the lack of insights on the relationship between inward FDI and innovation

performance. The majority of FDI spillover research has focused on productivity outcomes

solely (e.g. Blomstrom and Kokko, 1998; Liang, 2017). Moreover, previous findings appear

to be inconsistent; some found a positive effect of FDI on productivity performance (e.g.

Buckley et al., 2007) others a negative effect (e.g. Furman et al., 2002; Wang and Kafouros,

2009). Since FDI is often viewed as the engine for economic development and countries

increasingly compete to attract FDI, it is essential for managers and policymakers to

understand the impact of inward FDI not solely on productivity outcomes but on innovation

as well (Garcia et al., 2013).

This paper aims to fill the gap in research by investigating the effect of inward FDI on the

innovative capabilities of Latin American economies. Hence, the following research question

is addressed: What is the impact of inward FDI on the innovation performance of Latin

American economies? Does this impact differ for product innovations and process innovations?

(7)

In order to answer this question, data has been obtained for the year 2010 for 22 Latin

American economies from six different databases. The large numbers in economic growth

and FDI flows make Latin America a relevant region for enhancing previous (emerging

economy) FDI spillover literature.

This study contributes to existing literature in multiple ways. First, by shifting the focus from

productivity outcomes to innovative outcomes. There is currently little research investigating

whether FDI poses a negative or positive externality on the production of new ideas in the

host country, even though innovation has been considered one of the driving forces behind

growth (Al Azzawi, 2012). Second, more insight is being gained into the often-neglected but

fast-growing area of Latin America. It thereby advances non-traditional market studies that

mainly concern larger emerging economies such as China (e.g. Lew and Liu, 2016; Liu et al.,

2010) and India (e.g. Feinberg and Majumdar, 2001). Third, this study extends existing FDI

spillover literature by aiming to understand the context where the local condition can alter the

main relationship. Comparatively little is known about the contingent local contextual factors

that influence how FDI spillovers can be captured (Li et al., 2016). Specific local factors for

Latin America are therefore included, such as informal competition and growing levels of

inward FDI. Additionally, a divergent approach towards intellectual property rights (IPR) is

practiced. Most studies regard to IPR protection as indicator of successful innovation

outcomes (e.g. Segerstrom et al., 1990). Yet, this study suggests that, especially for emerging

markets, the proposed positive IPR effects might not always apply. Lastly, this research

advances previous innovation literature by not only using the amount of patents as innovation

(8)

The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. First, the main concepts are elaborated

upon in the literature review. Based on the discussed literature, hypotheses are constructed

and visualized in the conceptual model. After, the research methodology is justified and the

results of the research are discussed. The paper ends with a discussion, including a summary

of the findings, the scientific and practical relevance and limitations of the research.

2. Literature review

2.1 Inward FDI and spillover effects

One of the reasons why emerging economies try to attract foreign investment is the

opportunity of acquiring new technologies such as product and process innovations

(Blomström and Kokko, 1998). FDI is seen as a main source for diffusing such technological

advances (De Bondt, 1997). Emerging economies often aim to obtain advanced technologies

from developed countries through spillovers in order to gain a base for establishing domestic

innovation capabilities (Cheung and Lin, 2003).

Four major spillover mechanisms have been identified by previous literature (Blomström and

Kokko, 1998; Spencer, 2008): demonstration effects, employee turnovers, domestic business

linkages, and competitive pressures. Demonstration effects occur because inward FDI enables

local firms to observe the technologies, organizational practices and strategies of the investing

MNE. Consequently, local firms can apply the observed techniques in their own operations

and develop innovative capabilities (Blomström and Kokko, 1998). Domestic business

linkages can cause both positive and negative spillovers. On the one hand, interactions

between local firms and MNEs through subcontracting, licensing and other types of

(9)

1998). Strong relationships between MNEs and local firms can lead to knowledge sharing.

The knowledge gained from MNEs can in return push local suppliers and distributors to raise

their quality and service standards (Brash, 1966). On the other hand, MNEs are able to lock in

the best local goods and service suppliers or distributors when fully utilizing their capacity

(Spencer, 2008). Additionally, an MNE’s entry can limit local firms’ access to scarce

resources and can raise prices of input goods. The employee turnover spillover mechanism

arises as MNEs often pay higher wages than local firms. MNEs are therefore able to hire

away the most qualified employees from the local firms. Yet, simultaneously, employees that

have worked at an MNE can switch jobs to a local firm and diffuse its knowledge gained at

the MNE (Meyer, 2004). The last spillover mechanism is related to competitive pressures.

Inward FDI increases competition as MNEs enter the local market. Since MNEs usually

possess a greater productivity rate than their local counterparts (Haddad and Harrison, 1993),

competition from an MNE will force local firms to increase their productivity in order to keep

up in the competitive challenge (Blomström and Kokko, 1998). Another important beneficial

externality when imitating an innovation is the cost and risk reduction for the imitator. Before

an innovation is widely adopted, potential adopters face great risks and costs since little is

known about the effectiveness of the innovation and much research needs to be done. These

risks and research costs are made by the first adopter but are spared to others who imitate the

first adopter. Spillover effects are argued to be more important for emerging economies as

these economies have a limited supply of technological skills and information (Blomström

and Kokko, 1998).

It must be recognized that spillover mechanisms do require a certain amount of time to effect

(10)

operationalizing the spillover benefits (Chen, 1996; Meyer and Sinani, 2009). However, this

effect is weakened for emerging economies facing a large technology gap compared to the

foreign investor. In such a scenario, local firms will be able to benefit even from standardized

knowledge that is easy to obtain. (Meyer and Sinani, 2009). The probability of knowledge

diffusion also relies on the type of knowledge. Polanyi (1966) made a distinction between

codified and tacit knowledge, also often referred to as tangible and intangible knowledge.

Whereas codified knowledge can be translated in formal, symbolic language, tacit knowledge

is hard to articulate and is acquired through experience. Thus, codified knowledge is more

easily transferable compared to tacit knowledge. Spencer (2008) developed five critical

principles regarding knowledge spillovers. First of all, knowledge – in particular more

codified forms of knowledge – can diffuse even to distant local firms with which the MNE

has had no direct contact. On the contrary, tacit knowledge diffuses far more slowly and

irresolute. Furthermore, knowledge tends to endure in complex systems and individual

components of knowledge decrease in value when separated from the complete system of knowledge and organizational practices. In addition, the local firm’s absorptive capacity does

not only depend on the volume of its existing internal knowledge, it also highly depends on

the amount of overlap in which the knowledge to be acquired resides, i.e. the level of

common knowledge. The final principle acknowledges that local firms are able to improve

their process by acquiring tacit knowledge or by adopting technologies or organizational

practices that manifest that knowledge.

Despite the fact that MNEs rarely aim to strengthen local competitors, many do tolerate

spillovers and avoid imposing strong barriers to prevent these spillovers from happening

(Spencer, 2008). In general, there are large differences in capabilities and market scope

(11)

MNE, even though spillovers may occur. Besides, overprotection of knowledge assets can be

as costly as underprotection (Liebeskind, 1999) and reversed spillover effects might occur

where MNEs and local firms learn from each other (Sartor and Beamish, 2014). Overall,

inward flows of FDI are suggested to increase the possibility of (technological) knowledge

diffusion needed for innovative activities.

2.2 Product and process innovation

Innovation is a highly researched topic in the International Business field as it is an important

asset for surviving todays’ highly competitive and globalized economy (Nieto and Rodriguez,

2011). It has been largely recognized as a crucial element of a competitive advantage

(Danneels, 2002; Porter, 1990) and essential for sustaining such competitive advantages.

Innovation has been defined by Damanpour and Gopalakrishnan (p.3, 2001) as ‘an organization’s means to adapt to the environment, or to preempt a change in the environment,

in order to increase or sustain its effectiveness and competiveness’. Two types of innovations

can be distinguished: product and process innovation (Abernathy & Utterback, 1978). Product innovation concerns the development of new products or services that meet markets’ needs.

Process innovation, on the other hand, regards the production or service operations of these

products and services (Damanpour and Gopalakrishnan, 2001). Both innovations can stem from two major sources: internal R&D and imitation of other firms’ innovations (Lewin and

Massini, 2004). Simply imitating other firms will not directly result in certain (cost)

advantages or capabilities. The imitator needs to improve the innovation in order to gain

advantages over the first mover. As such, process innovations are said to be important for the

(12)

requires firms to be capable of developing both product- and process innovations, which are

continuously being optimized and refined.

There is a difference in adopting product innovations and process innovations; each demands

a different organizational skill. Product innovations require meeting customers’ needs and

manufacturing the product, while process innovations require the ability to apply technologies

that can improve the efficiency of product development (Ettlie et al., 1984). According to

Damanpour and Gopalakrishnan (2001) product innovations occur more early on than process

innovations. Additionally, the process of translating knowledge to business practices is

generally less complicated for product innovations since product innovations tend to consist

of more codified knowledge compared to process innovations, which require complex and

tacit knowledge (Nieto and Rodriguez, 2011). Cimoli (2002) explains the different knowledge

requirements per innovation type by distinguishing between technology and information.

Information can be spread across firms as it can be written down and be reproduced by

individuals. Technology, on the other hand, includes tacit and specific knowledge and cannot

be diffused as a whole. Technology is embodied in individuals, organizations and networks

and is therefore much more complicated to reproduce.

All in all, product- and process innovations demand different inputs and produce contrasting

outcomes. They should therefore be treated as different processes as well. Though, literature

has primarily dealt with overall innovative activity, i.e. the totality of both product- and

process innovations, or focused on one innovation type solely, i.e. either product or process

innovation (Bonannoa and Haworthb, 1998). This study acknowledges the different

innovation types and aims to separate the effect of inward FDI for product innovations and for

(13)

2.3 FDI, formal competition intensity and innovation outcomes

The competitive intensity of firms is described by Barnett (1997) as the magnitude of effect

that a firm has on its competitors’ survival chances. Being a weak competitor means that the firm has only limited capabilities to ‘harm’ its competitors’ life chances, whereas strong

competitors reduce these life chances to a much larger extent. Auh and Menguc (2005)

describe a competitive intense market as a market that has a large number of competitors and a lack of potential growth opportunities. When competition further intensifies, firms’ behavior

will be greatly affected by the actions and contingencies of competitors. As a result, the

predictability and certainty of a competitive intense market reduces. These high levels of

uncertainty lead to incentives for firms to innovate in both products and processes, explore

new markets, find new ways to compete and learn how to differentiate from its competitors

(Zahra, 1993). Delbono and Denicolo (1990) explain competition intensity based on the

division between Cournot competition and Bertrand competition. Cournot competition applies when firms’ decision variables are output levels and Bertrand competition when firms’

decision variables are prices. Cournot competition generally leads to lower output and higher

prices than Bertrand competition, hence the former is said to be a situation where competition

is less intense. Assuming the competition of a homogeneous product, the incentive to

introduce an efficiency- or cost-reducing innovation is greater in conditions of Bertrand

competition. Bester and Petrakis (1993) further developed this theory by assuming the case

for differentiated products instead of homogeneous products. They found that for products

with low differentiation, high competition intensity increases the incentive to innovate. While

for products with high differentiation, low competition intensity increases the incentive to

(14)

When the international openness of an economy increases and inward FDI is attracted, the

competition intensity of the economy will increase. The exposure to larger competition from

MNEs may force local firms to be more productive and to enhance their innovation

performance (Kokko, 1996). Early economist such as Arrow (1962) and Delbono and

Denicolo (1990) already agreed upon that the more competitive an environment is, the greater the firm’s incentive to innovate will be. In addition, competition intensity can lead to mimetic

isomorphism (McKinsey et al., 2005), where local firms imitate the strategic behavior of

MNEs. Besides, emerging economies often try to increase competitiveness by acquiring and

developing new technologies (Wang and Kafouros, 2009). On the contrary, increased

competition in local markets may also have negative consequences for domestic economies.

Foreign firms that possess greater capabilities than local firms may steal market from the local

players and thereby force local firms to reduce output and increase costs (Aitken and

Harrison, 1999; Konings, 2001). Furthermore, increased competition causes saturated

markets, which leads to downward pressures on prices and a lower profitability (Hanson,

2001).

The conflicting findings regarding the effect of competition intensity on innovation

performance could be explained by the theory of Aghion et al. (2005). Their research found

an inverted-U relationship between competitive pressure and innovation activities. Thus, for

low levels of competitive pressure, an increase in competition causes an increase in

innovative activities. This is referred to as the escape competition effect; where

neck-and-neck firms innovate in order to escape competition. However, when competition becomes too

intense, the incentives to innovate are diminished as the rent-dissipation effect comes into

play. The increased competition generates lower post entry rents, which discourages

(15)

Overall, earlier studies show that there is no consensus concerning the competitive pressures’

impact on innovation outcomes. The one thing that researchers do agree upon is that

innovation is an interactive process (Freeman, 1987) and the result of a social process that

develops best when there is an intensive interaction between the suppliers and buyers of

goods, services, knowledge and technology (Cimoli, 2002). Firms do not compete in

isolation. Especially not in todays’ globalized world where technological developments are

taking place at an ever-increase pace. These developments force firms to respond quickly and

it makes it challenging for firms to produce and covert knowledge into innovations all by

themselves.

2.4 Informal competition and innovation

In emerging markets, firms typically face competitive threats from three groups: formal

domestic firms, foreign MNEs and informal firms (Iriyama et al., 2016). The informal sector

is an economy circuit where the activities related to the production and trade of goods and

services are not registered or conducted by unregistered entities. Such activities operate

outside of government regulation and tax systems (Heredia et al., 2017). The informal

economy circuit is especially large in emerging economies. According to Schneider (2002),

more than 50% of the gross domestic product of emerging economies is connected to the

informal economy. In the 2010 World Bank Enterprise Survey of firms in 22 Latin American

and Caribbean countries, 63.3 percent competes against informal firms and 31.4 percent

ranked competition from informal firms as one of their top three obstacles of doing business.

(16)

government institutions, causing the growth of the informal sector (Loayza, 1999). The large

informal sector is fostered by the complicated procedures and burdensome regulations that are

present in Latin America. The region scores significantly low on Ease of Doing Business

indicators, as Latin American economies require the largest numbers of procedures (12) and

days (66) to start a new business (González and Lamanna, 2007). An increase in informal

competition negatively affects economic growth in two ways. First, it reduces the availability

of public services for everyone in the economy. Second, it increases the totality of activities

that use some of the existing public services less efficiently or not at all (Loayza, 1999).

Informal competitors enjoy relative cost advantages as they usually fail to comply with

economic regulations and tax obligations. These cost advantages allow informal competitors to undervalue their products and steal market share from formal firms (OECD, 2009). Therefore, even though competition is considered to be the engine of economic growth in

most markets as it induces higher rates of productivity growth, competition between formal

and informal firms is not necessarily productive (González and Lamanna, 2007).

Formal and informal firms differ on many aspects.First of all, the type of products offered by

informal firms is typically of lower quality than those produced by formal firms (Amaral and

Quintin, 2006). Secondly, informal firms are much smaller and much less productive than

formal firms (La Porta and Shleifer, 2008). Informal firms serve different customers, mostly

low-income consumers. They do not advertise, have less capital and rely to a smaller extent

on public goods. Furthermore, managers of informal firms are less educated and have less

human capital than managers of formal firms (La Porta and Shleifer, 2008). Additionally, the

average education level is considerably lower in the informal sector compared to the formal

sector (Funkhouser, 1996). Very few formal firms have been previously informal, inconsistent with the theory that formality is a later stage of a firm’s life cycle when the firm is growing.

(17)

The vast majority of informal firms begin and end their existence as unproductive informal

firms (La porta and Shleifer, 2014). Informal firms are argued to be so inefficient that taxing

them or forcing them to comply with government regulations would most likely put them out

of business (La Porta and Shleifer, 2008). There is no inducement from available evidence for

assuming that informal firms would increase their productivity if they register. Entrepreneurs

are thus not likely to use the informal sector as a method of acquiring knowledge at lower

costs.

Related research performed by Mendi and Costamagna (2017) showed that informal

competition has a negative effect on both product and process innovations. The informal sector typically disrupts formal firms’ innovation practices due to cost-cutting pressures. This

makes informal firms a great obstacle to formal firms’ performances and innovation

capabilities. Since excessive regulations are proposed to be the main reason for the existence

of a large informal sector, informal sectors and institutions are closely connected in the sense that the informal sector can be partly explained by a country it’s institutional efficiency and

vice versa (Mendi and Costamagna, 2017). Overall, the informal sector is proposed to play a

large role in emerging economies hence its influence cannot be overlooked.

2.5 Institutions and imitation tolerance

Institutions are defined by North (1991, p. 97) as ‘the humanly devised constraints that structure political, economic and social interaction.’ Three main institutional pillars are

identified by previous research (e.g. Scott, 1995; Kostova, 1997): regulative, cognitive and

(18)

systems. Castellacci and Natera (2016) highlighted the importance of combining imitation

policy and innovation policy for increasing the growth rate of emerging economies. These

institutional factors, both normative and regulatory, have had a strong influence in the

catching up process of emerging economies. Governments often protect local firms from

initial failures and encourage them to learn from MNEs (Li and Kozhikode, 2009).

Cerqueti et al. (2016) describe imitation as an inverse measure of Intellectual Property Rights

(IPR) protection. According to the authors, there must be a balance between innovation and

imitation as an unbalance between the two will be costly to society. Too many imitations will

hinder economic growth while too little imitations decrease the number of innovation

diffusions. Conversely, governments should seek to balance the ratio between innovations and

imitations and should intervene when needed. However, this is not always practiced, as the

innovation and imitation ratio is highly dynamic and uncertain. It is impossible to establish

beforehand whether the ratio will go up or down.

Multiple authors have agreed upon the fact that imitations can benefit the society on the

whole by leading to a larger number of innovations (e.g. Sohn, 2008; Bessen and Maskin,

2009).Although imitation can weaken the incentive to innovate as it reduces the current profit

of the innovator, it raises the probability of further innovation, which could lead to new

profitable discoveries (Bessen and Maskin, 2009). Furthermore, Cerqueti et al. (2016) state

that imitations can mitigate damages introduced by monopolies and hasten the innovation

diffusion process. Fershtman and Markovich (2010) argue that imitation may be particularly

beneficial when firms have different innovative capabilities and are able to combine these

different capabilities by imitating. According to the authors this could eventually lead to a higher consumers’ surplus and higher value for firms than a strong patent protection regime.

(19)

Imitation is said to be especially important in economies that are far from the technological

frontier, as imitation can help these economies grow quickly. Besides, the diffusion of already

existing technologies is relatively easy. Thus, when a country is on the technological frontier

it can grow quickly by only imitating innovations (Hikino and Amsden, 1994).

3. Conceptual model and hypotheses

Figure 1 visualizes the conceptual model of this study by showing the main concepts and its

proposed effects. The next section will further explain this conceptual model and the motives

behind the hypotheses.

Figure 1. Conceptual model

H1: Inward FDI LA Innovation performance

LA (+)

H1a: Product innovation over process innovation (+)

Competition LA H2: Formal competition intensity (+) H3: Informal competition (-) Institutions LA H4: Imitation tolerance (+)

(20)

3.1 Inward FDI and product- and process innovation performance

Emerging economy firms are in general not likely to possess greater innovative technology

advantages over their equivalents in developed economies (Peng et al., 2008), but the

presence of foreign investors can enhance the innovative performance of local emerging

economy firms operating in the same sector (Crescenzi et al., 2015). Due to the (often) long

histories of economic and political uncertainty, Latin America has traditionally suffered from

low levels of entrepreneurship and innovation (Aguilera et al., 2017). However, during the

end of the twentieth century several structural reforms were adopted in many Latin American

countries. This period of economic crisis and reforms induced firms to rethink their activities,

improve their competitiveness and seek for opportunities outside of the domestic market

(Dominguez and Brenes, 1997). The changes eventually led to a new period of stability and

economic growth (Cuervo-Cazurra, 2008). The structural reforms caused the adoption of

pro-market reforms and a greater international openness, which stabilized the economies and also

led to higher inflows of FDI. Economic growth resumed bringing Latin America to be part of

the emerging economies (Ciravegna, 2012). The increasing inflows of FDI provided a range

of new opportunities. Further economic growth was fueled, infrastructure development

supported and firms showed greater innovative capabilities (O’Neil, 2014).

The enhanced innovative performance of Latin America could be explained by the recent

development in offshoring activities. Over the past few years MNEs have shifted from not

only offshoring manufacturing activities but also knowledge to emerging economies (Couto et

al., 2008). There are several reasons for offshoring R&D to emerging economies: strategic

asset seeking (Dunning and Narula, 1995); gaining knowledge and internalizing technical

spillovers (Feinberg and Gupta, 2004); diversifying knowledge and using the gained

(21)

and leveraging both the growing talent pool and growing technical competence in emerging

economies (Li and Kozhikode, 2009). Nieto and Rodriguez (2011) found a positive effect of

offshoring R&D on the innovation performance of MNEs. Positive results will stimulate

MNEs to continue the offshoring process and investigate in possible other emerging

economies. Subsequently, emerging economy firms have begun to catch up and develop their

own innovative capabilities. According to Mathews (2006) a good catching up strategy

contains three crucial elements: 1) linking with MNEs to access key resources; 2) leveraging

existing resources to gain a foothold in the target industry; and 3) learning from the linkages

and leverage. Thus, MNEs are said to play an important role in the catching up of emerging

economies and as such in the development of innovations.

Emerging economy governments have been aware of the beneficial externalities that come

with inward FDI. They have started to create a more favorable climate for MNEs and

encouraged domestic firms to collaborate with those MNEs in order to develop innovative

capabilities (Kim, 1997; Li and Kozhikode 2008; 2009). Despite the large risks for MNEs to

spillover knowledge, there is also the possibility of gaining reversed spillover effects as

argued by Sartor and Beamish (2014). The authors state that MNEs from developed

economies and emerging economy firms can learn from each other. As the technological- and

demand uncertainty for an MNE investing in an emerging economy increases, the MNE will

be willing to loosen its organizational control and learn from the local firms. When more

tacit/process innovation type of knowledge is desired, MNEs are likely to rely on socially

oriented mechanisms to enhance their learning (Makhija and Ganesh, 1997). Consequently,

local firms can teach MNEs about the local technological environment (Govindarajan and

(22)

technological knowledge of MNEs. FDI is therefore said to act as a technology transfer

vehicle between developed and emerging economies (Borensztein et al., 1998).

All in all, the reversed spillover effect and positive results from (knowledge) offshoring could

ensure that MNEs will continue to invest in Latin America. These investments are assumed to

generate knowledge spillovers, which are in turn expected to improve the innovative

capabilities of Latin American economies. Hence, the following hypothesis is formulated:

Hypothesis 1. Inward FDI has a positive effect on the innovation performance of Latin

American economies

3.1.1 Inward FDI effect on product and process innovation

Initial innovations of emerging economy firms tend to be production process related rather

than product development related (Hobday, 1995). This could be attributed to the fact that

emerging economies primarily serve as original equipment manufacturers (OEMs) for MNEs

(Li and Kozhikode, 2009). These OEM arrangements allow emerging economy firms to take

an active part in the value-added activities but not so much in the product development

technologies (Hobday, 1995). However, more recent literature highlights the growing activity

of outsourcing knowledge to emerging economies (e.g. Couto et al., 2008), where the

emerging economy does not just serve as an OEM but as an R&D developer. Another

important development is the fact that Latin America has become an interesting destination

for outsourcing services (Manning et al., 2010). The Global Services Report (2017) shows

that several Latin American cities are listed among the Top 20 offshoring/outsourcing

destinations for business services. These developments could lead to more tacit,

(23)

As previously mentioned, the process of translating knowledge to business practices is

generally less complicated for product innovations since product innovations tend to consist

of more codified knowledge compared to process innovations, which require complex and

tacit knowledge (Nieto and Rodriguez, 2011). The most codified knowledge may be diffused by simply carefully observing a practice, by examining a firm’s end products or other

processes that do not require extensive interaction among employees from the two firms

(Spencer, 2008). Though, the greater the tacitness, complexity and specificity of an MNEs

knowledge resources, the more difficult it will be for local firms to imitate the innovations or

practices that require these knowledge resources (Reed and DeFillippi, 1990).

Thus, product innovation type of knowledge is more easily accessible compared to process

innovation type of knowledge, as it is less tacit and more easily codified. This brings about

the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 1a. The positive effect of inward FDI on innovation performance is stronger for

product innovations over process innovations

3.2 Moderating effect of formal competition intensity

Firms in emerging markets typically face competitive threats from three groups: formal

domestic firms, foreign MNEs and informal firms (Iriyama et al., 2016). Formal firms are

likely to recognize other formal firms as closer competitors than informal firms, which are

perceived as more distant rivals. When formal competition is low, greater portions of formal firms’ attention capacity can be allocated to informal firms. On the contrary, when formal

(24)

informal firms, high levels of formal competition are proposed to increase the formal firms’

incentives to innovate.

Moreover, formal competition intensity is suggested to foster the positive relationship

between inward FDI and innovation for several reasons. First of all, FDI inflows bring

increased formal competition. The exposure to larger formal competition may force local

firms to be more productive and to enhance their innovation performance (Kokko, 1996).

Multiple studies have already acknowledged competition as enhancer of FDI spillovers (e.g. Sjöholm, 1999; Blomström et al., 1994; Kokko, 1996). One possible explanation is given by

Blomström and Sjöholm (1999). They argue thatMNEs possess a wide range of technologies

of which they can choose from when investing abroad. This technology transfer is adapted to

the competitive situation in the host economy. If MNEs face stronger competition in the local

market, they will be forced to use more advanced technology in order to assure their market

share (Wang and Blomström, 1992). Likewise, the increased competition as a consequence of

foreign entry forces domestic firms to become more efficient and innovative as well. Thus,

spillovers can be expected to increase with competition in the local market (Crespo and

Fontoura, 2007).

Second, when competition is intense, firms need to engage in risk-taking and proactive

activities (Cui et al., 2005). Due to the highly globalized market firms experience nowadays,

firms are becoming more dependent upon externalities outside of its own. It has become

almost impossible for an individual firm to produce all relevant knowledge itself. Let alone to

translate this knowledge into innovative products or production processes. Firms are

dependent upon external complementary knowledge and know-how (Cimoli, 2002). Hence,

(25)

multiple (spillover) externalities. As an increase in inward FDI is suggested to bring in more

of such knowledge externalities and competitive intense markets forces MNEs to bring in

more advanced technologies, competition intensity is proposed to aggravate the effect of

inward FDI on innovation performance.

Conjointly, Bester and Petrakis (1993) proposed that a competitor in a situation of intense

competition will favor product innovations over process innovations. This can be clarified by

the fact that a competitive intensive market forces firms to innovate on a continuous and fast

pace. Product innovations require less complicated knowledge and are therefore in general

more easily converted into practice than process innovations. Thus, competitive pressures are

proposed to increase a firms’ preference to improve and invent products over processes.

In conjunction with above findings, competition intensity is suggested to strengthen the

positive effect of inward FDI on innovation performance. Henceforth, the following

hypothesis is formulated:

Hypothesis 2. The positive effect of inward FDI on innovation performance is stronger when

the competition intensity in Latin American economies is higher

3.3 Moderating effect of informal competition

McCann and Bahl (2017) define informal firms as firms that produce and sell legal products

and services but remain unregistered, allowing them to avoid legal requirements such as taxes

and regulations. The informal sector often targets low-income consumers who cannot afford

(26)

effectuates the unemployed from the formal sector but rather as a sector whose products

overlap and compete with those from the formal sector, despite the quality gap (Banerji and

Jain, 2007). Formal firms might thus be forced to compete directly against informal firms for

the same resources, possibly leading to an inefficient allocation of resources in the economy

and hence an efficiency loss (Mendi and Mudida, 2017). As mentioned earlier, formal

competition is considered to be positively affecting the relationship between inward FDI and

innovation. Competition between formal and informal firms on the other hand, is not

necessarily productive (González and Lamanna, 2007). Informal competition can be

damaging to the overall economic performance, as the cost advantage informal firms enjoy is

the outcome of neglecting business regulations.

Informal competition is found to have a negative effect on both product and process

innovations (Mendi and Costamagna, 2017). Informal firms may affect formal firms’

innovation decisions in a number of ways. First, the informal sector generally disruptsformal firms’ innovation practices when formal and informal firms compete for similar customers

and resources (McGahan, 2012). As a consequence, input resources such as high skilled

human capital can become more scarce to formal firms. The informal sector generally offers

readily available jobs that require low skills, distorting the process of skills accumulation by

formal firms (Mendi and Costamagna, 2017). Second, informal firms have a large impact on

the competition in product markets. By their very nature, informal firms face lower entry

costs than formal firms since they are not being taxed (Djankov et al., 2002; McKenzie and

Sakho, 2010). Due to the low entry barrier, informality can quickly raise the number of competitors for a firm’s product (Mendi and Costamagna, 2017). The increasing informal

competition will lead to lower prices for the customer, as informal firms will compete on

(27)

Mudida, 2017). This event can pressurize formal firms to cut costs as well, making it

unattractive to be spending on R&D practices. Third, informal firms cause competitive

pressure on product quality, as they typically produce lower-quality versions of the products

produced by formal firms (Banerji and Jain, 2007). In emerging economies like Latin

America the incomes of consumers are generally low hence consumers might be unable to

afford the higher-quality product and opt for the lower-quality one.

All in all, there are many arguments prompting that informal firms form a great obstacle to formal firms’ performances and innovation capabilities (Mendi and Costamagna, 2017).

Based on these disruptive characteristics of informal firms, the third hypothesis is formulated

as follows:

Hypothesis 3. The positive effect of inward FDI on innovation performance is weakened by

the size of the informal economy in Latin American countries

3.4 Moderating effect of imitation tolerance

According to Cerqueti et al. (2016) imitation is an inverse measure of IPR protection. As IPR

refers to the legal protection provided for innovative firms, it indicates the extent to which a

firm is able to protect and capture the economic value of its innovations (Kafouros, 2012).

The adverse would thus be a condition where the firm is not able to protect its innovations

and where imitation is stimulated. Whereas IPR protection has previously been regarded to as

an essential for attracting inward FDI. More authors have started recognizing the drawbacks

of strong IPR protection and the benefits of imitation (e.g. Sohn, 2008; Bessen and Maskin,

(28)

incentive to innovate than before, despite its lowering rents, as it finds itself in a

neck-and-neck competition with a technologically equal rival and will remain so until it innovates again

(Aghion et al., 2001).

Imitation is said to be beneficial for the entire society as it alleviates the damage caused by

monopolies and thus increases consumers’ surplus (Cerqueti et al., 2016). Fershtman and

Markovich (2010) argue that a weak patent protection regime will eventually lead to higher

value for firms as opposed to a strong patent protection regime. According to Kafouros et al.

(2012), MNEs can profit more easily in economies where IPR protection is less effective

since knowledge spillovers tend to be higher in these economies. Imitation is also argued to

be one of the most evident spillover channels (Crespo and Fontoura, 2007). Introducing a new

technology may be too expensive and risky for local firms to undertake hence a technology

that has already been used successfully by an MNE is more encouraging for local firms to

adopt. Imitation engenders more external discoveries and leads to reversal knowledge

spillovers, in which the MNE and the local firm can learn from each other. Pisano (2006)

states that other mechanisms such as technological complexity, careful assignment of

responsibilities and possession of complementary co-specialized resources that are

unavailable to other firms, generates more effective protection of innovations.

All in all, economies where imitation is more readily practiced are proposed to provide an

attractive environment for MNEs. Knowledge spillovers are more easily realized, enhancing

the conditions for new innovation developments. A tolerant policy towards imitation is

therefore expected to have a positive moderating role on hypothesis 1, forming the fourth and

(29)

Hypothesis 4. The positive effect of inward FDI on innovation performance is strengthened

when an economy has a high imitation tolerance

4. Methodology

4.1 Sample and data collection

The underlying population of this study is the totality of emerging economies as these

economies have proven to develop quickly (Brenes et al., 2016). The final empirical setting

choice is Latin America based on three main reasons. First of all, several countries in Latin

America have been regarded as new engines of economic growth and have shown to possess

innovative and entrepreneurial capabilities (Lederman et al. 2013). Secondly, data provided

by UNCTAD 2017 illustrates a growing interest in Latin America; from 2010 to 2016 the

inward FDI increased from respectively 70.869 stocks to 138.766. Lastly, relatively little

research has been done in this area despite the growing potentials and almost doubling

amount of inward FDI. Most studies concerning the effect of inward FDI on the innovation

performance of emerging economies focus on larger emerging economies such as China and

India (e.g Lew and Liu, 2016; Feinberg and Majumdar, 2001)

Based on a similar looking study of Godinez and Liu (2015) a country-level unit of analysis is

used. Data is obtained for 22 Latin American countries for the year 2010. Unfortunately,

multiple challenges when conducting research in Latin America have been acknowledged.

There is a lack of research networks for data collection and problems regarding data gathering

(30)

generalizations derived from data gathered in developed countries are not necessarily

applicable to emerging economies (Burgess and Steenkamp, 2006). For validity reasons the

quality of the research could have been improved by creating a longitudinal panel dataset that

includes multiple years. However, the majority of the data is dependent upon the availability

of the World Bank Enterprise Survey data. As this survey is not conducted on a yearly basis

and the only fully complete year for all 22 Latin American countries is the survey conducted

in 2010, only one year can be analyzed correctly. A similar method was practiced by Mendi

and Costamagna (2017); their research uses the 2006 World Bank Enterprise Survey and is

hence solely focused on one year (2006) as well.

The quantitative analysis is thus performed by use of secondary data and, consistent with

many previous studies, mainly gathered from the World Bank Enterprise Surveys (e.g. Meyer

and Sinani, 2009; Gorodnichenko et al., 2014; Kayalvizhi and Thenmozhi, 2017). The World

Bank Enterprise Surveys database consists of firm survey responses of over 19,000 firms in

47 developing countries. The survey employs standardized survey instruments and a uniform

sampling methodology to minimize measurement error and to yield data that are comparable

across economies (González and Lamanna, 2007). Mostly developing countries are

administered (Mendi and Costamagna, 2017). However, not only data from the World Bank

has been used. To prevent triangulation of data and to assure data credibility, four other

sources have been consulted: WIPO, UNCTAD, the World Economic Forum’s Global

(31)

4.2 Estimation Methodology

Hypotheses 1, 2, 3 and 4 are being analyzed by use of a Generalized Linear Model (GLM).

The dependent variable for these hypotheses is the number of patent applications. Thus, the

outcome variable contains data in the form of counts and is not normally distributed. Using an

Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression is considered a problematic strategy for analyzing

count data for two main reasons. First of all, an OLS regression is likely to produce

non-sensical, negative predicted values for the expected count. Secondly, the validity of an OLS

regression depends on variance assumptions that are unlikely to be met in count data

(Gardner, Mulvey and Shaw, 1995). There are alternative regression models based on

non-linear models for the expected counts that respect the characteristic of a non-negative

variable. The most practical one is considered to be the Poisson regression (Gardner, Mulvey

and Shaw, 1995), which requires the dependent variable to follow a Poission distribution and

the mean and variance of this variable to be close. However, the goodness-of-fit test rejects

the Poisson distribution assumption of our dependent variable. The one-sample

Kolmogorov-Smirnov is highly significant (p<0.01) indicating overdispersion. The mean of the total patent

applications is 127.18 while the variance is 66504.0129. As such, a Poisson regression would

not be appropriate. To correct for overdispersion the negative binomial regression is

recommended by multiple sources (e.g. Gardner et al., 1995; Allison and Waterman, 2002).

The negative binomial model was originally practiced by Greenwood and Yule (1920) to

represent accident proneness. The estimation is particularly useful in accounting for the

overdispersion issue as it rationalizes overdispersion. In comparison to Poisson distribution,

the negative binomial assumes that accidents of the dependent variable are Poisson

distributed, but the values of the variable do not have the same mean rate (Land, McCall and

(32)

coefficients for large numbers of dummy variables (Allison and Waterman, 2002). Since this

study does not contain a large sample size and no large numbers of dummy variables, no

problems regarding the estimate coefficients are foreseen.

The number of patent applicants is not the only dependent variable to be tested as the interest

of this study also lies in the difference between product- and process innovations. The binary

logistic regression is the estimated efficient measure for testing this hypothesis (1a) as the

dependent variable is a dichotomous variable that takes value 0 for product innovations and 1

for process innovations. Similar to OLS, the independent variables can either be continuous or

categorical. The logistic regression model makes no distributional assumptions. Only the

assumptions of linearity and additivity need to be verified in addition to the usual assumptions

about independence of observations and inclusion of important control variables (Harrell,

2015). Unlike OLS whose goal is to predict a score on some outcome measure, the goal of

logistic regression is to assess the likelihood of falling into one of the outcome categories

based on a set of independent variables (Maroof, 2012).

4.3 Variables and measures

4.3.1 Dependent variable

Innovation performance Latin America. Following a myriad of previous studies (e.g. Garcia

et al., 2013; Funk, 2014; MacGarvie, 2006; Aghion et al., 2015; Guler and Nerkar, 2012;

Lahiri, 2010), innovation performance is measured by the use of number of patent

applications. Patents are unique and proposed to visualize the method of technology transfer

(e.g. Henderson et al., 1998). The measure of patent filings provides a fairly good, although

(33)

researches have operationalized patent citations as an indicator of knowledge spillovers (e.g.

Jaffe et al., 1993; Branstetter, 2006; Salomon and Shaver, 2005). In accordance with the

research ofWoo et al. (2015),this study draws on the patent data from the World Intellectual

Property Organization (WIPO). The WIPO distinguishes patent applications between

domestic and foreign applicants. Hence, the WIPO data is considered to be a good proxy of

the actual patent filings done by Latin American firms and cannot be biased by influences of

(large) foreign firms.

Product- and process innovations. Consistent with the 2011 paper of Nieto and Rodriguez,

the innovation performance outcome is further divided into product and process innovations.

This division provides a more accurate and detailed image of the innovation performance of

Latin America than the number of patent applications solely, as the patent counts capture both

product and process innovations (Fu et al., 2011). Hence, using product and/or process

innovations alongside patent application counts provides a valuable complement (Salomon

and Shaver, 2005; Garcia et al., 2013). The World Bank Enterprise Survey data provides two

proxies for distinguishing between product and process innovations; one being the amount of

firms that introduced a new product or service and the other being the amount of firms that

introduced a process innovation. As this study is performed on a country-level unit of

analysis, the totality of firms introducing a product- and/or process innovation has been

computed. This results in a total percentage of firms per country introducing a product

innovation and a total percentage of firms per country introducing a process innovation.

Thereafter, one variable has been created in order for the dependent variable to be appropriate

for binary logistic regression. This variable, labeled as Type of Innovation, is dichotomous

(34)

process innovations in that country and value 1 if the percentage of process innovations over

products innovations is higher.

4.3.2 Independent and moderating variables

Inward FDI Latin America. Consistent with related studies such as those of Trevino et al.

(2008) and Castellacci and Natera (2016), the inward FDI is operationalized by the amount of

inflows in US dollar (adjusted for inflation). This data is subtracted from the United Nations

Conference on Trade And Development (UNCTAD). The Kolomogorov-Smirnov test was

run in order to check the normality of variables. The results were significant for the

independent variable (p<0.05), implying that the distribution of the sample is significantly

different from a normal distribution (Field, 2009). Inward FDI is non-normal and positively

skewed. To correct for positive skewness a log transformation was performed (Field, 2009).

Formal competition intensity. This variable is constructed using the World Economic Forum’s

Global Competitiveness Index. The index ranks countries according to 12 pillars of

competitiveness (Schwab, 2010) and has been widely used by scholars studying competition

intensity (e.g. La Porta and Shleifer, 2008). The 12 pillars of competitiveness are: institutions,

infrastructure, macroeconomic environment, innovation, health and primary education,

business sophistication, higher education and training, market size, goods market efficiency,

technological readiness, financial market development and lastly labor market efficiency

(Schwab, 2010). The index ranges from 1 to 7, where 1 indicates a country with very low

levels of global competitiveness and 7 a country with very high levels of global

competitiveness. For reference, the index of 2010-2011 ranged from 2.73 (Chad) to 5.63

(Switzerland). Within Latin America, Chile achieved the highest score with a ranking of 4.69

(35)

Informal competition. In order to operationalize the moderating effect of informal

competition, data from the World Bank Enterprise Survey is used (Mendi and Costamagna,

2017). This survey captures the amount of firms competing against unregistered or informal

firms. More specifically, the survey measures the amount of perceived competitive pressure

from informal producers; formal firms are requested to rank on a 0 to 4 scale how much of an obstacle the informal sector competitors are to the firm’s operations (Mendi and Costamagna,

2017; McCann and Bahl, 2017). This paper captures the amount of firms competing against

unregistered or informal firms. The total percentage of firms dealing with informality is

computed per country and used as a representation of the size of the informal competition of

that country.

Imitation tolerance. Cerqueti et al. (2016) state that imitation is an inverse measure of IPR

protection. The country specific Intellectual Property Index (IPI) developed by Park (2008) is

mainly used to obtain the IPR measurement (e.g. Klein, 2018; Kafouros et al., 2012; Zhao,

2006). However, this index is not given for the year 2010. Another reliable option that has

been used by previous studies is the Property Rights score of the Index of Economic Freedom

(IEF) dataset. This index scales from 10 to 100 and combines various aspects of the degree to

which private property is protected in a given country, intellectual property rights are

respected, and citizens are protected against extralegal seizure of property (Autio and Acs,

2010). In accordance with the paper of Kafourus et al. (2012), this study measures IPR

ineffectiveness rather than IPR effectiveness. Thus, the measures need to be recoded by

(36)

4.3.3 Control variables

As there are other factors that could affect the innovation performance of Latin America,

control variables are included. Previous research has acknowledged the influence of R&D

expenditures on innovation productivity (e.g. Cohen and Levin, 1989), hence this factor is

controlled for. The Enterprise Survey of the World Bank captures the amount of firms that

spend on R&D. These amounts have been computed into a percentage value per country,

leading to the total percentage of firms that spend on R&D per Latin American economy.

Secondly, it is essential to account for disparities in economic development across Latin

American economies hence real GDP per capita is controlled for. The real GDP per capita

also controls for being a proxy for the attractiveness of foreign investors (Klein, 2018). The

GDP per capita variable is log transformed in order to correct for the positive skewness of the

variable (Field, 2013).

Lastly, in order to account for differing country size, the log of each country’s population is

included as a proxy for the size of the economy (Klein, 2018). The GDP per capita and total

country population data is collected from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators.

(37)

5. Findings

The countries that received the highest amount of inward FDI are the Bahamas and Barbados,

of which the inward FDI per capita in 2010 was respectively 3180.45 and 1596.54. One might

expect these high inflows to be surprising for such small countries, though, these economies

are known as tax havens (Hines and Rice, 1994). Consequently, the main objective of MNEs

investing in the Bahamas and Barbados is likely to be the pursuit of tax minimization rather

than taking an active role in the economy. As this might bias our results, the Bahamas and

Barbados have been excluded. Besides the two large tax havens, the country that received the

highest amount of FDI in 2010 is Chile (1012.44). The lowest ratio of FDI inflows is found

for Suriname, as its value is highly negative (-478.06). The most patents were filed in Mexico,

not in Chile. Though, Chile is the third runner-up after Mexico (951) and Argentina (552)

with 328 patent applications in 2010. The least amount of patents was applied for in Honduras

(38)

The mean, standard deviation and correlation matrix for each variable are presented in table 2.

A positive correlation between patent applications and inward FDI is shown, though this

correlation is not significant. The most concerning correlations close to or above the threshold

of 0,8 are between imitation tolerance and inward FDI (-.773**), imitation tolerance and

formal competition (-.822**), formal competition and inward FDI (.812**) and total country

population and patent application (.886**). The latter correlation is justified since the total

country population is a control variable and hence expected to (highly) correlate to the

dependent variable (Pallant, 2010). To diagnose any multicollinearity issues, the VIF scores

and collinearity tolerances have been computed. In order for the assumption to be met, the

VIF should be well below 10 with tolerance levels above 0.2 (Field, 2009). As the VIF of all

variables ranges from 1.307 to 4.132 and the tolerances all exceed 0.2 ranging from 0.242 to

0.765, multicollinearity between the variables is rejected. The majority of the correlations

between the explanatory variables have small correlation values. Moreover, data is gathered

from six different sources and none of the highly correlated variables are obtained from a

similar source. As such, multicollinearity is not expected to be a serious hassle for the

(39)

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

If you take on the point of view that third parties are necessary to make relationships work, then you are likely to become obsessed by determining whether courts are

In contrast, output in more applied disciplines (biomedical research and engineering) and social sciences is less important, and scientific impact and visibility

Business and economic aging research should focus on individual and group level, the effect of leisure activities on retirement, the effect of prior experiences

Financialization is an important aspect of both globalization and economic development in general. While mainstream literature describes the financial system and

In the case of foreign competition it is expected the inverted U shape has a short but steep positive effect, meaning for relatively low levels of competition innovation

IP (invention patents) Log of number of invention patents National Bureau of Statistics of China UP (utility model patents) Log of number of utility model patents National

By adapting the empirical framework of national innovative capacity and employing panel data analysis under fixed effect model, I find that inward FDI itself does not

It seeks not only to contribute knowledge about the main effects of lean on the performance construct but also to evaluate the impact of two contextual factors on any