• No results found

Outward foreign direct investment and domestic, regional innovation performance in China : the role of OFDI country destination diversity and region-specific institutions

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Outward foreign direct investment and domestic, regional innovation performance in China : the role of OFDI country destination diversity and region-specific institutions"

Copied!
90
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

Outward foreign direct investment and domestic, regional

innovation performance in China: the role of OFDI country

destination diversity and region-specific institutions

Han-Ying Lee 11371609

June 23, 2017, Final

MSc. in Business Administration - International Management Track

ABS, UvA

Supervisor: Dr. Mashiho Mihalache

(2)

Statement of originality

This document is written by Han-Ying Lee who declares to take full responsibility for

the contents of this document.

I declare that the text and the work presented in this document is original and that no

sources other than those mentioned in the text and its references have been used in creating it.

The Faculty of Economics and Business is responsible solely for the supervision of

(3)

Table of contents

Abstract ... 4

1. Introduction ... 5

2. Literature review ... 11

2.1. Outward foreign direct investment ... 11

2.2. FDI spillovers and OFDI reverse spillovers ... 14

2.3. The effects of institutions on foreign direct investment ... 18

2.4. Regional innovation system in emerging markets ... 21

3. Conceptual framework and hypotheses ... 26

3.1. OFDI country destination diversity and domestic, regional innovation ... 26

3.2. Moderating effect of intellectual property right protection ... 30

3.3. Moderating effect of market development ... 33

3.4. Moderating effect of international openness ... 36

4. Methodology ... 38

4.1. Sample and data collection ... 38

4.2. Model specification ... 40

4.3. Estimation methodology ... 42

4.4. Variables and measures ... 44

4.4.1. Dependent variable ... 44

4.4.2. Independent and moderating variables ... 44

4.4.3. Control variables ... 47

5. Findings ... 50

6. Discussion ... 59

6.1. Theoretical implications ... 61

6.2. Implications for practice ... 64

6.3. Limitations and future research ... 65

7. Conclusion ... 67

(4)

Abstract

Recent years outward foreign direct investment (OFDI) flows from emerging economies

have increased substantially, but do these overseas investments bring innovation benefits at

home? In this paper, we aim to shed new light on this phenomenon and contribute to

disentangling the innovation performance implications of OFDI reverse spillovers. We

advance prior foreign direct investment (FDI) spillovers literature by examining the effect of

the diversity of OFDI country destinations on domestic, regional innovation performance,

and how institutions at sub-national level moderate this relationship. Using panel data of

OFDI activities from 30 Chinese provinces during the period 2011-2014, we find that the

diversity of OFDI country destinations is positively related to domestic, regional innovation

performance. We also find that this positive relationship is stronger in regions with higher

levels of intellectual property right enforcement, while weaker in regions with higher levels

of international openness.

Keywords: OFDI reverse spillovers, the diversity of OFDI country destinations,

(5)

1. Introduction

According to 2016 World Investment Report conducted by UNCTAD, outward foreign

direct investment (OFDI) flows from emerging economies have increased considerably from

$91 billion to $400 billion from 2000 to 2015, and now account for one-third of global

foreign direct investment (FDI) flows. Among which, China invested more OFDI than any

other emerging economy and was the third largest source of FDI outflows in the world by the

end of 2015 (UNCTAD, 2016).

One major motivation of OFDI by emerging economy multinational enterprises

(EMNEs) is to access strategic assets such as superior technologies in developed countries

and transfer the technologies back to the home country (Luo & Tung, 2007). These positive

externalities that benefit domestic firms with the presence of FDI are defined as "spillovers"

(Blomström, 1986). EMNEs often expect a broader spillovers effect of OFDI on domestic

firms, that is, reverse spillover (Li, Li, Lyles, & Liu, 2016), which can result in productivity

increase among domestic firms (Xia, Ma, Lu, & Yiu, 2014). The impact of FDI on domestic

firms’ productivity has drawn increasing research interest over the past decade (e.g. Haskel,

(6)

However, Zhang, Li, Li, and Zhou (2010) suggest that future research should examine

the effect of FDI spillovers beyond domestic firms’ productivity; for instance, exploring how

FDI can influence domestic firms' innovation will be interesting. Some studies have started to

address this call; nevertheless, in contrast to the large amount of research on the effects of

inward FDI (IFDI) on the innovation performance of host economies (e.g. García, Jin, &

Salomon, 2013), very few studies have examined the impact of OFDI on the innovation

performance of home economies in the context of emerging economies (e.g. Deng, 2007).

What's more, despite the appealing argument that FDI generates spillovers that benefit

domestic firms, previous studies have produced mixed results on this topic in emerging

markets, including positive effects (Wang, Deng, Kafouros, & Chen, 2012), marginal effects

(Haskel et al., 2007), and even negative effects (Jordaan, 2008).

There are three limitations of existing studies that can help to explain the underlying

reasons for the mixed results. First, Görg and Strobl (2001) argue that most previous studies

on FDI spillovers mainly focus on the simpler issue of whether the presence of FDI has an

impact on firms’ productivity. These studies have considered FDI as homogenous flows of

capital and have mostly overlooked the heterogeneous nature of FDI, such as entry modes of

(7)

Second, existing research on China has overlooked the link between institutions and FDI

spillovers. Institutions, defined as “the rules of the game” (North, 1990: 3) shaping firm

behavior, interaction, and performance, consequently, are crucial factors that influence FDI

spillovers that benefit domestic firms. Since both foreign and local firms have to adapt to

institutional conditions that vary among countries, it is important to consider the role of

institutions when examining FDI spillovers in emerging economies, where institutions are

complicated and changing rapidly (Yi, Chen, Wang, & Kafouros, 2015). However, prior

research mainly focuses on aggregate institutions at country-level, assuming that institutions

are homogenous across subnational regions in a country. While for countries with

heterogeneous institutions across subnational regions, such as China, the subnational effects

are critical (Yi et al., 2015). Existing literature provides limited knowledge of how such

cross-regional institutional variations affect FDI spillovers on domestic firms.

Third, the extant literature on FDI spillovers effects on productivity mainly focuses on

multiple sectors or countries level. However, when examining innovation performance, there

is a considerable literature proposing that innovation performance varies not just between

countries, but also between subnational regions (e.g. Fritsch, 2002). The reasons underlying

(8)

Regional innovation system is a system in which firms are systematically engaged in

interactive learning through an embedded institutional environment (Cooke, Uranga, &

Etxebarria, 1998). RIS theory is particularly suitable when studying the determinants of

innovation performance in the context of countries that contain substantial regional

disparities. For example, China, which is diverse in geography, economy, and innovative

capabilities across provinces (Fu, 2008).

Hence, this study aims to address these three gaps. By going beyond the existing

literature, our research question is to explore how the portfolio of OFDI can affect domestic

innovation and how institutions can influence this relationship. Specifically, we investigate

the effect of the diversity of OFDI country destinations on domestic, regional innovation

performance, and how region-specific institutions affect this relationship. We define the

diversity of OFDI country destinations as the extent to which OFDI activities of a province

are formed in different host countries. The institutional constructs contain different

dimensions of region-specific economic institutions, including intellectual property right

protection, market development, and international openness. These different factor

(9)

subsidiaries to parent firms but also the absorptive capacity of parent firms and thus the OFDI

spillovers effects.

To test the impact of OFDI country destination diversity on domestic, regional

innovation performance and the institutional factors that moderate this relationship, we

conduct Generalized Estimating Equations (GEE) analysis on a panel data of OFDI activities

from 30 Chinese provinces from 2011 to 2014. China is a particularly appropriate context for

this study not only because the country is the third largest sources of OFDI in the world but

also because it has gone through significant political and economic reforms that have resulted

in varying provincial institutions (Hong, Wang, & Kafouros, 2014). Our results indicate that

the heterogeneous nature of OFDI can have a different impact on OFDI reverse spillovers

and that home region-specific institutions can affect the occurrence and magnitude of this

reverse knowledge spillovers.

This study has multiple contributions to the existing literature. First, we shift the focus

from IFDI to OFDI, from developed economies to emerging economies, given that the FDI

literature has yet to examine the potential reverse spillover benefits of OFDI on the EMNE parent firms (Globerman & Chen, 2010; Meyer & Sinani, 2009). The results provide

(10)

positive effects of the diversity of OFDI country destinations on domestic, regional

innovation performance. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first study that examines

the effects of the heterogeneous nature of OFDI concerning country diversity rather than the

simple presence of OFDI on domestic, regional innovation. Second, it is among the first

attempts to theorize the roles played by home region-specific institutions in OFDI reverse

spillover effects. We demonstrate the vital role of institutions in facilitating the absorption of

the knowledge derived from Chinese OFDI. In particular, our study examines how regional

specific institutions facilitate or constrain the extent to which domestic regions benefit from

OFDI. Third, by modeling spillovers in the province-level, we also illuminate how the effects

of OFDI vary across subnational regions. For practical implications, our findings suggest that

policymakers in emerging markets need to develop policies that promote not only a large

amount of OFDI but also OFDI in diverse countries to improve domestic innovation. At the

same time, it is also important for policymakers to consider institutional conditions to enlarge

the benefits of reverse spillovers from OFDI. Overall, this study complements existing

research on FDI spillovers and sheds new light on the innovation performance implications of

(11)

The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 reviews the relevant

literature on OFDI, FDI spillovers, the effects of institutions on FDI, and regional innovation

system in emerging economies, and poses the research question. Section 3 introduces a

conceptual framework of how the diversity of foreign investments interacts with

location-bound institutions to jointly shape the effects of OFDI reverse spillovers on

domestic, regional innovation performance. We then present our methodological approach

and estimating methodology in section 4. Section 5 presents the results of our analysis. In

section 6, we discuss the theoretical and managerial implications of our findings, and the

main limitations of our study with several suggestions for future research. Finally, section 6

forms a conclusion and highlights the contributions of this study.

2. Literature review

2.1. Outward foreign direct investment

Foreign direct investment (FDI) is defined as an investment made to acquire lasting

interest in enterprises operating outside of the economy of the investor (Moran, 2012). In

international business literature, it is customary to classify the motivation of OFDI as natural resource seeking, market seeking, efficiency seeking, or strategic asset seeking

(12)

of the most important motivations for EMNEs to overcome their latecomer disadvantages,

and this is more particularly for Chinese MNEs (Child & Rodrigues, 2005; Luo & Tung,

2007). Rui and Yip (2008) argue that Chinese firms often use cross-border acquisitions to

gain strategic assets to compensate for their competitive disadvantages, while simultaneously

leveraging their unique ownership advantages.

Past research has revealed that EMNEs acquire technology from developed countries to

enhance their competitiveness back in their home markets also in the international market (Li,

Li, & Shapiro, 2012; Peng, 2012). Since technological resources are concentrated in

developed countries (Keller, 2004), investing in these countries and locating proximate to

technology centers can increase the opportunities for exchange and learning of localized tacit

knowledge and technical (Fosfuri, Motta, & Rønde, 2001).

There is empirical evidence on the relationship between OFDI by developed market

MNEs and their home country productivity growth, while the results on productivity growth

are not consistent. For example, De la Potterie and Lichtenberg (2001) find that both imports

and OFDI contribute to productivity growth in the United States, Japan, and 11 European

countries over the period 1971-1990. Driffield, Love, and Taylor (2009) distinguish between

(13)

types of outward investments increase productivity growth back in the United Kingdom. In

contrast, by examining Swedish MNEs' OFDI both in a firm- and industry-level, Braconier,

Ekholm, and Knarvik (2001) find no correlation between OFDI and their domestic

productivity. Similarly, Bitzer and Görg (2009) study 17 OECD countries' OFDI reverse

spillovers by using industry-level data. They detect that OFDI has a negative effect on some

of the OECD countries productivity, such as Denmark, Italy, South Korea, Norway, and

Spain. The OFDI effects are widely different across countries.

While mixed findings on the relationship between OFDI and home country productivity

growth are revealed in the context of developed countries, few studies test such relationships

in emerging countries, with only a few exceptions. Zhao, Liu, and Zhao (2010) examine the

contribution of Chinese OFDI to domestic productivity changes. They confirm the beneficial

spillover effects of OFDI on home country productivity growth over the period from 1991 to

2007, and that gains in efficiency have been the chief reason for this. In a similar vein, Herzer

(2011) investigate the relationship between OFDI and home country productivity by using a

sample of 33 developing countries for the period 1980 to 2005. They find that OFDI had a

robust and positive long-term effect on domestic productivity and that different extent of

(14)

and Görg’s (2009) study, they find that in South Korea, OFDI has the largest negative effect

on its domestic productivity.

Given the mixed results of the effects of OFDI on domestic productivity, Görg and

Strobl (2001) explain the underlying reasons. They argue that most previous FDI spillovers

research mainly "focus on the simpler issue of whether the presence of FDI affects

productivity in domestic firms" (Görg & Strobl, 2001: 724). These studies have considered

FDI as homogenous flows of capital and have mostly overlooked the heterogeneous nature of

FDI, such as entry modes of firms and the origins of countries (Zhang et al., 2010). Therefore,

in this study, we go beyond the existing literature, which mainly focuses on the FDI presence

in the industry, and further examine how the portfolio of OFDI influences innovation at home

market.

2.2. FDI spillovers and OFDI reverse spillovers

The mechanism underlying the relationship between FDI and domestic productivity is

knowledge spillover effects (Zhang et al., 2010). FDI spillovers refer to positive externalities

that benefit domestic firms with the presence of FDI (Zhang et al., 2010). When MNCs enter

a host country, they deliver capital inflows, raise local employment and bring technological

(15)

The existing literature on IFDI recognizes four main channels for spillover effects to

occur. First, demonstration effect, through which domestic firms can improve their

productivity by observing and imitating the technology and management practices of foreign

firms (Kokko, 1994). Second, employment turnover, when employees from foreign affiliates

move to domestic firms, the technologies and management practices of foreign firms can

diffuse to domestic firms (Kokko, Tansini, & Zejan, 1996). Third, industry linkage, when

foreign affiliates build backward and forward linkages with domestic suppliers and

distributors, knowledge can be transmitted to domestic firms using the same suppliers and

distributors (Spencer, 2008). The fourth channel is through competition. The entry of foreign

affiliates can force domestic firms to increase their productivity by updating technologies and

adopting management practices to respond to competitive challenges (Blomström & Kokko,

1998). While the effects of competition can also be negative, as the entry of foreign may steal

the markets of final goods or raw materials away from their domestic competitors, this is

called a crowding out effect (Aitken & Harrison, 1999).

Most conventional research of knowledge spillovers focuses on the effects of IFDI on

host country in emerging economies (Li, Zhang, & Lyles, 2013). While the significance of

(16)

because this phenomenon is rather new and it is hard to obtain reliable empirical data (Lyles,

Li, & Yan, 2014).

Nevertheless, a group of studies starts to shift the light of spillover effects from IFDI to

OFDI (e.g. De la Potterie & Lichtenberg, 2001; Driffield et al., 2009; Herzer, 2011). Scholars

argue that the logic of spillover effects from inward and outward FDI is similar and that those

indicated channels in FDI spillovers above are also influential for OFDI (Chen, Li, & Shapiro,

2012). First, when EMNEs invest in developed markets, demonstration effects can be

realized through learning and imitating advanced technological know-how and management

techniques from local firms in developed economies (Herzer, 2011). Second, subsidiaries

abroad will employ local technical and managerial staffs, which will improve subsidiaries

technology and managerial practices, in turn, the parent firm (Singh & Agrawal, 2011).

Chinese MNEs for instance, they set up R&D centers in developed markets to enhance their

embeddedness in local innovation systems to learn (Di Minin, Zhang, & Gammeltoft, 2012).

Third, subsidiaries may acquire technical guidance and support through backward and

forward linkages with host country firms. For example, Harhoff, Mueller, and Reenen (2014)

show that German subsidiaries in the United States (US) benefit from R&D knowledge

(17)

downstream firms helps German firms to better tap into the R&D resource. Fourth,

competition will force EMNEs to update their technologies and practices to become more

productive because they face more competitive pressures in developed economies than in

their home economies (Li et al., 2016).

As a result, MNEs can transfer strategic assets accessed in oversea markets back to

home country, and so MNE parent firms can benefit from OFDI activities through these

channels, this is called reverse spillover (Li et al., 2016). Positive reverse spillover effects are

realized through knowledge spillovers to EMNE subsidiaries in a developed economy and

subsequently transferred from these subsidiaries back to their parent firms in emerging

economies (Chen et al., 2012).

However, past empirical results do not always confirm the existence of spillovers theory.

Discovering that FDI spillover effects are not consistent as many studies assume, more recent

research has examined the conditions under which spillovers might be strong, weak or

nonexistent. For example, Li et al. (2016) find that reverse knowledge spillovers will only

occur when the technological gap between a home province and MNEs' host countries is not

too large; otherwise, MNE parent firms are not able to capture the benefits of reverse

(18)

reverse spillovers are enhanced in home provinces with a greater presence of IFDI thanks to

the beneficial demonstration effects.

These findings from previous studies imply that location-bound factors could influence

the extent to which parent firms benefit from OFDI. Nevertheless, despite the concept that

differences in geography can explain variations in the effects of IFDI (Yi et al., 2015), prior

literature has not studied how such region-specific institutions affect OFDI reverse spillovers.

In this study, we investigate the effect of regional institutions on the occurrence and

magnitude of OFDI reverse spillovers across regions by exploring how they influence parent

firms as spillover receivers.

2.3. The effects of institutions on foreign direct investment

North (1990) defines institutions as the set of fundamental political, social, and legal

ground rules in the country, including both formal and informal constraints that shape human

interaction in society. The institution-based view assumes that firm-level actions are a

function of pressures in the firm's external environment. This view underlines the

complicated and changing relationships between organizations and their surrounding

(19)

institution-based view has become one of the leading viewpoints for theorizing international

strategy such as why and how firms conduct FDI (Peng, Wang, & Jiang, 2008).

The application of the institution-based view in studying FDI issues is dominated by two

groups of literature. The first group focuses on host-region institutions. As institutions create

both opportunities and barriers for IFDI, they constitute a critical portion of locational

advantages (Dunning, 1998). This literature suggests that more efficient institutions reduce

transaction costs and uncertainties of doing business in the host region, and thus providing

incentives for IFDI and entry by MNEs (e.g. Meyer, Estrin, Bhaumik, & Peng, 2009; Meyer

& Nguyen, 2005). The second group focuses on the relationship between institutional

differences between home and host regions and the legitimacy of an operation under these

various institutional pressures (e.g. Bénassy-Quéré, Coupet, & Mayer, 2007; Kostova &

Zaheer, 1999). This group of literature argues that larger differences in institutions between

two regions may discourage FDI between them because potential conflicts between local

adaption and internal consistency create greater liability of foreignness (e.g. Bénassy-Quéré

et al., 2007).

However, both groups of studies have neglected the influence of home-region

(20)

institutions also provide valuable insights into firm's global strategy. Firm's foreign expand

strategy may be influenced by the home country in both direct and indirect ways. A direct

influence, for example, the image of the home country perceived by government and

consumers in the host country can be served as an advantage or liability for firm's global

strategy Cuervo-Cazurra (2011). Besides, the institutional distance between home and host

regions related to economic freedom, political influence or FDI restriction also affects the

destination of OFDI (Kang & Jiang, 2012). Chen et al. (2012) find empirical evidence in

Chinese OFDI. They show that as the development of more efficient institutions at home

reduces the institutional differences, Chines MNEs are more encouraged to invest in

developed markets.

As for the indirect influence of home country institutions on firm's global strategy are

mainly related to the firm capability that induced by home country conditions. For example,

the development of market-supporting institutions create the conditions for EMNEs to build

skills and capabilities in technology, branding, and management, which in turn enables the

firm to invest in developed markets (Chen et al., 2012). Moreover, Stoian (2013) finds that

the overall progress in home country’s institutional reforms, such as privatization, trade and

(21)

competitiveness of the home country and enhance the ownership advantages of EMNEs, thus

enabling firms to invest abroad.

Despite the growing interest in studying the role of institutional differences between

home and host countries in the context of OFDI (Peng et al., 2008), most existing research

has viewed institutions as one of the determinants of OFDI decisions rather than factors that

influence the extent to which MNE parent firms benefit from OFDI. Furthermore, most

studies have not examined institutions at the sub-national levels but consider within-country

institutions as a homogeneous entity, with rare exceptions (Chan, Markino, & Isobe, 2010;

Meyer & Nguyen, 2005). However, large-scale emerging economies with multiple

administrative regions, such as China and India, are characterized by diverse institutions

across sub-national regions (Liu, Lu, & Chizema, 2014). As a result, regional institutional

environments create conditions that form firm-specific resources and capabilities (Meyer &

Nguyen, 2005). Hence, it is important to consider institutional environment at sub-national

levels when investigating its impact on MNEs’ OFDI strategies in emerging markets (Chen et

al., 2012). This study aims to fill these gaps by explaining the role of home-region

institutions in EMNE parent firms as OFDI reverse spillovers receivers.

(22)

In innovation literature, comparisons of innovation performance across countries focus

on the structures and dynamics of national innovation systems (Lundvall, 1992; Nelson,

1993). However, as noted in Liu and White (2001), an aggregate level of analysis at the national level is associated with plenty of questions and criticism owning to the regional

disparities within a nation, especially in transitional and emerging economies. There is a

considerable literature proposing that innovation performance varies not just between

countries but also between sub-national regions (e.g. Acs, Anselin, & Varga, 2002; Fritsch,

2002). This is because knowledge generation and new technology production have a

tendency to cluster spatially (Li, 2009). Given the uncertainty, complexity and tacit form of

new knowledge, it cannot be fully articulated and may only be transferred through

face-to-face interaction and trust-based relations (Fu, 2008; Morgan & Cooke, 1998). Thus,

the knowledge and technical capabilities also tend to be geographically-bounded, and that

knowledge spillovers tend to be localized (Cooke, Gomez Uranga, & Etxebarria, 1997;

Cooke, Heidenreich, & Braczyk, 1998). That is to say, the sensitivity of the transfer of new

knowledge to distance provides an essential reason for the development of regional

innovation clusters (Cantwell & Iammarino, 2000). Therefore, spatial proximity could be

(23)

(Howells, 1999). This has inspired researchers to extend the innovation system framework to

the regional dimension, which gives rise to the concept of regional innovation system (RIS).

RIS theory is based on the assumption that location and spatial proximity matter for

innovation activities (Cooke et al., 1997). Cooke et al. (1998: 1564) define regional

innovation system as "systems in which firms and other organizations are systematically

engaged in interactive learning through an institutional milieu characterized by

embeddedness." Iammarino (2005: 499) adds that RIS is composed of "the localized network

of various actors and institutions in different sectors whose activities and interactions

generate, absorb, and diffuse new technologies within and outside the region." As a network

provides opportunities for exploiting new knowledge combination and creation, it triggers a

positive innovation cycle(Nightingale, 1998). The main groups of actors in a region that may influence the innovation activities are agents (e.g. inventors and entrepreneurs), public

research institutions, supportive services, and the regional workforce. It is the interaction, the

density, and the quality of the network between these actors that determine how innovation is

generated in a certain area (Fritsch, 2002). The recognition of the centrality of relationships

and the mutual influences among the actors in the system is indeed the key insight of the

(24)

constitutes an adequate approach to analyze the determinants of innovation performance in

the context of countries that cover huge geographical areas and feature substantial regional

disparities regarding economic and innovative capabilities (Fu, 2008; Yang & Lin, 2012).

Extant literature has investigated several determinants of regional innovation

performance. For example, Jaffe, Trajtenberg, and Henderson (1993) show that R&D

expenditures contribute the most to regional innovation output, which is measured by the

number of patents or new products launched at the regional level. Besides the increase in

R&D expenditures, Sleuwaegen and Boiardi (2014) find that an increase in high-quality

R&D staff that is regional intelligence is also a strong driver of patent growth. What's more,

noted by Cornett (2009), the organizational and functional aspects of knowledge-based

regional development policies are important factors that stimulate innovative activities since

they can foster knowledge dissemination, innovation, and entrepreneurship in local industrial

sectors.

In the past two decades, innovation performance in China has increased dramatically.

According to World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO), the number of patent

applications per capital in China grew almost 13 times between 1995 and 2007 (Li, 2012).

(25)

third-ranked nation in patenting in the world. Hu and Jefferson (2009) find that in addition to

R&D intensification, foreign direct investment, a more patent-friendly legal environment, and ownership reform with more entry of non-state enterprises all significantly contribute to the patenting boom in China during 1995-2001.

However, there has been an increasing disparity in innovation performance across

Chinese regions (Li, 2009). Chung (2002) argues that the high degree of “coherence” and

“inward orientation” at the provincial level justifies that each Chinese region constitutes an

innovation system. Despite the increasing emphasis on RIS in China, several scholars have

stressed the need for more research into exploring the underlying determinants of innovation

disparity at the regional level (Furman, Porter, & Stern, 2002). Some studies have started to

address this call. For example, Li (2011) points out that an institutional change at the

provincial level, the implementation of patent subsidies programs, is one important facilitator

for regional patenting growth. Li (2009) also finds that inefficiency in the innovation process,

which determined by government support and the constitution of the R&D performers (firms,

universities, and research institutions), has a significant impact on the regional disparity in

innovation performance. Nevertheless, few studies have considered the effects of Chinese

(26)

how OFDI interacts with region-specific institutions. Hence, this study complements RIS

literature by illuminating how OFDI concerning country diversity and region-specific

institutions affect domestic, regional innovation performance in emerging economies.

3. Conceptual framework and hypotheses

In this section, we develop our hypotheses on how the diversity of OFDI country

destinations affects domestic, regional innovation performance, and how and what

region-specific institutions influence this relationship. Fig.1 shows our conceptual model.

Fig.1. Conceptual model.

3.1. OFDI country destination diversity and domestic, regional innovation

EMNE’s major motivation of OFDI is to access strategic assets such as superior

technologies and managerial practices from their counterparts from developed markets and

(27)

factors that can influence this reverse spillover effects is the extent to which EMNEs have the

opportunity to learn from foreign firms, while OFDI potentially brings up this opportunity

(Zhang et al., 2010). We further argue that the diversity of OFDI country destinations can

additionally contribute to the reverse knowledge spillover effects.

With greater diversity of OFDI country destinations, EMNEs are exposed to new and

diverse knowledge from multiple markets and cultural perspectives (Hitt, Hoskisson, & Kim,

1997; Li, Wu, & Zhang, 2012). As Zahra and George (2002) argue, exposure to an

environment with diverse technologies and management practices can facilitate firms’

innovation and openness. Moreover, knowledge diversity in the environment “provides a

more robust basis for learning because it increases the prospect that incoming information

will relate to what is already known” (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990: 131). Wijk, Bosch, and

Volberda (2001) show empirical evidence that the breadth of knowledge exposure has a

positive impact on a firm’s propensity to explore new and related knowledge. Therefore,

international diversification can facilitate innovation because it is considered as a channel for

EMNEs to approach a greater variety of innovative ideas, technologies and complementary

assets brought by their foreign counterparts through OFDI in global markets (Wu, Chen, &

(28)

Besides, knowledge diversity can also provide more opportunities for EMNEs to

recombine these technologies and practices to create new competitive advantages. Noted by

the innovation and knowledge management literature, recombining existing elements of

knowledge into new syntheses often brings about new knowledge creation (Katila & Ahuja,

2002; Kogut & Zander, 1992). As foreign counterparts in different countries bring various

technologies and management practices, the knowledge pool enhances regarding scale and

scope. This improves the possibility for EMNE parent firms to find new useful recombination

of these elements, hence facilitating new knowledge creation (Zhang & Li, 2010). From this

point of view, the greater the diversity of technologies and management practices brought by

foreign counterparts through OFDI, the greater the knowledge combination potentials, and

thus greater innovation potentials for EMNE parent firms.

More specifically, drawing insights from the literature on OFDI reverse knowledge

spillovers, we argue that a greater diversity of OFDI country destinations can enhance the

reverse spillover effects through the four channels discussed earlier.

First, given that EMNEs can observe and imitate a wider variety of technological

know-how and management practices brought by foreign counterparts from a greater

(29)

through the merger and acquisition of foreign firms, EMNEs can have face-to-face

communication with various foreign firms which is essential for transferring sophisticated

and tacit technologies or know-hows (Wu et al., 2016).

Second, as EMNEs build extensive business linkages with host upstream or downstream

firms in diverse countries, a greater variety of knowledge and technological know-how can

be transmitted back to EMNE parent firms (Li et al., 2016), which can further facilitate new

knowledge creation. For instance, EMNEs can directly interact with global competitors and

suppliers through the establishment of R&D or manufacturing bases in diverse foreign

countries, and thus timely obtaining technologies and market information which is helpful for

innovation (Wu et al., 2016).

Third, when employees of EMNE foreign subsidiaries from a greater variety of country

origins, they bring a wider variety of technological know-how and management practices to

the subsidiaries, in turn, EMNE parent firms (Li et al., 2016). EMNE parent firms in order to

benefit from the knowledge, they may conduct personnel exchanges by transferring

subsidiaries researchers to parent firms or sending researchers from parent firms to the

(30)

Fourth, EMNEs investing in diverse countries are exposed to more competitive

international markets than firms operating only in a domestic market. The competitiveness

will force these firms to innovate rapidly and update their technologies and techniques to

remain viable in competitive international markets (Hitt et al., 1997; Li et al., 2012). While

firms operating in domestic market may be isolated from such competition due to trade and

geographical barriers, diversified international firms are compelled to adopt best-practice

technologies to survive (Blalock & Gertler, 2004). From this perspective, a greater diversity

of OFDI country destinations enhances the competitive pressure faced by EMNEs, in order to

stay viable in highly competitive global markets, these internationally diversified firms will

invest more in innovation to achieve competitive advantages (Wu et al., 2016). Based on the

arguments above, our first hypothesis is thus:

Hypothesis 1. All else being equal, the diversity of OFDI country destinations is positively

related to domestic, regional innovation performance.

3.2. Moderating effect of intellectual property right protection

In previous hypothesis we argue that the diversity of OFDI country destinations can

(31)

intellectual property right (IPR) protection can be beneficial for EMNEs to transfer and

utilize the diverse knowledge acquired through OFDI.

It is often assumed that strong IPR protection limits the risk of expropriation and

opportunities of technological learning by local firms (Maskus, 2000). That is to say,

increased protection of IPR makes imitation for other domestic firms more

difficult (Branstetter, Fisman, & Foley, 2006). According to Chen and Puttitanun (2005), less

imitation means more incentive for the domestic innovating firm to invest more in innovation

because the technological advantages can be well protected. As we argued above, EMNEs

with a greater diversity of technical know-how acquired through OFDI have greater

innovation potentials. These EMNE parent firms are those that have the ability to develop a

patentable new technology. In a stronger IPR environment, technology appropriation can be

curbed by well-established contract enforcement and intellectual rights protection

mechanisms (Zhou & Poppo, 2010). Hence, local innovators are more encouraged to

innovate because in these regions the cost of knowledge expropriation is significantly

reduced and minimized (Shi, Sun, & Peng, 2012). Chen and Puttitanun (2005) also show

empirical evidence that strong IPR enforcement improves local firms' innovation in

(32)

In developed economies, firms can readily enforce IPR law because strong institutions

shield against illegitimate imitation (Coriat & Weinstein, 2002). While in emerging

economies, there is often a weak legal infrastructure and poor enforcement of property rights

and contracts (Siebeck, Evenson, Lesser, & Braga, 1990). What's more, unlike the typical

view that IPR protection within a given nation is similar across its regions, emerging

countries show wide cross-regional variations in the effectiveness of IPR enforcement. In

regions with strong IPR protection and implementation, firms are encouraged to invest more

in R&D and advanced technologies. By contrast, in regions with weak IPR enforcement,

firms face the risk of value expropriation and cannot use patents to appropriate returns from

innovation (Yi et al., 2015). In countries, like China, which have a short history of enforcing

IPR laws to protect innovation and that feature different regional institution and market

development, these cross-regional variations are particularly significant. In China, as a result

of administrative decentralization, provincial governments and regional authorities have

substantial judicial independence, and they frequently affect courts' judgments (Peck &

Zhang, 2013). Overall, we expect that EMNE parent firms in a strong IPR protection

(33)

OFDI, thus increasing their domestic, regional innovation performance. We formulate the

following hypotheses:

Hypothesis 2. The positive relationship between the diversity of OFDI country destinations

and domestic, regional innovation performance is positively moderated by IPR protection.

3.3. Moderating effect of market development

Marketization is defined as the degree of market-oriented mechanism development and

institutions in order to achieve more efficient market functioning (Fan, Wang, & Zhu, 2007;

Henisz, Zelner, & Guillen, 2005). Given that sub-national regions in large emerging countries

differ in the degree of marketization (Khanna & Palepu, 1997), we argue that the level of

market development in a region moderates the effects of the diversity of OFDI country

destinations on domestic, regional innovation performance.

First, a high degree of marketization implies a high level of market monitoring

mechanisms and legal systems (Shi et al., 2012). In regions with strong market development,

there are well-developed markets and technology transfer institutions so that institutional

uncertainty and transaction costs are reduced. Hence, EMNEs are more willing to transfer

various technologies and entrepreneurial experimentation back home (Yi et al., 2015). In

(34)

technology transfer, poorly developed markets and institutions pose challenges for EMNEs

and reduce their willingness to transfer diverse technologies back home (Tihanyi & Roth,

2002). Therefore, as well-established markets and institutions facilitate technology transfer

by EMNEs, there is greater availability of various knowledge resources that creates greater

potentials for innovation (Kafouros & Forsans, 2012).

Second, Zhang et al. (2010) propose that the extent to which firms can benefit from

diverse knowledge brought from foreign firms is contingent upon their capacity to learn from

foreign firms. That is a firm's absorptive capacity, "the ability to recognize the value of new

information, assimilate it, and apply it to commercial ends" (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990: 128).

Here we argue the level of market development in a region influences firms' ability to learn

from foreign firms (Meyer & Nguyen, 2005), and thus facilitates the absorptive capacity of

EMNEs.

Regions within emerging market with a high degree of marketization usually indicate

that the commodity and factor markets have achieved significant improvement (Peng, 2003).

Moreover, that certain market intermediaries and legal frameworks are similar to those in

developed economies (Peng, Sun, Pinkham, & Chen, 2009). This similarity means that

(35)

developed economies to achieve a competitive edge. Relying on absorptive capacity literature,

a firm's ability to use new knowledge elements depends largely on the firm's existing

knowledge stock (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990). Hence a certain level of knowledge overlap is

necessary for a focal firm to employ the knowledge stock of another firm (Tallman, Jenkins,

Henry, & Pinch, 2004). Therefore, EMNE parent firms from regions with high market

development are more capable of recognizing the value and contents of different knowledge

brought by foreign firms from various country origins.

Furthermore, the well-established institutions in a region also facilitate the exchange of

factors for value creation, which in turn helps firms to develop their absorptive capacity

(McEvily & Zaheer 1999). For example, a well-functioning labor market facilitates labor

mobility and accumulation of human capital so that domestic firms can recruit employees

from foreign firms, which in turn helps domestic firms acquire new and extend existing

innovative capabilities, thus facilitating their absorptive capacity. Based on the arguments

above, we hypothesize:

Hypothesis 3. The positive relationship between the diversity of OFDI country destinations

and domestic innovation performance is positively moderated by the degree of market

(36)

3.4. Moderating effect of international openness

International openness refers to an institutional context with a bunch of policy incentives

facilitating MNEs to enter or go outward in a focal country (Ortega & Peri, 2014). However,

although policies are set at a country level, they are implemented at a regional level (Meyer

& Nguyen, 2005), resulting in cross-regional variations in international openness within a

given country. In China, for example, although the government has actively supported OFDI,

the implementation of these policies varies across provinces. Some provinces opened earlier

than others for foreign investment. This makes international openness in China spatially and

structurally uneven (He, Wei, & Xie, 2008).

Again, drawing from the perspective of Zhang et al. (2010) that the extent to which

firms can benefit from diverse knowledge brought from foreign firms depends on their

absorptive capacity. We propose that variations in international openness across regions

moderate the effects of the diversity of OFDI country destinations on domestic, regional

innovation because the degree of international openness influences EMNE parent firms'

ability to utilize knowledge acquired through foreign markets.

Building on knowledge spillovers literature, many scholars have suggested that the

(37)

2013). These effects may be realized through various channels. First, through exposure to an

open trade regime, local firms can observe or learn through the imitation of foreign firms'

products and technologies and adapted by their R&D efforts (Blomström & Kokko, 1998).

Second, local firms may benefit from employee turnover whereby skilled employees from

foreign affiliates take a job in local firms carrying with them valuable knowledge. Third,

knowledge spillovers may be transmitted through upstream or downstream value-chain

linkages from foreign firms to local suppliers/distributors (Spencer, 2008). Fourth, great

international openness raises the level of competition in a region, forcing local firms to

become more efficient. To meet this competitive challenge, local firms in these regions are

likely to develop flexible strategies, learning practices and advanced technologies

(Blomström & Kokko, 1998).

Overall, international openness assists the integration of emerging countries into the

global economy (Lou & Tung, 2007). Indigenous firms in such environment are forced to

observe, learn from, and imitate the superior competencies of their foreign competitors

(Durán & Ubeda, 2005). As the existing stock and quality of knowledge of EMNE parent

firms will influence the extent to which knowledge reverse transfers from overseas markets

(38)

also be able to adapt and exploit those assets subsequently to be beneficial to their home

economies (Li et al., 2016). Thus these four effects will also strengthen EMNE parent firms

ability to learn and transfer knowledge from foreign markets, which enable them to make the

most of the resources they have accessed through their outward direct investment (Li et al.,

2016). Therefore, EMNE parent firms from a higher degree of international openness regions

are more capable of taking advantage of various technologies and management practices that

acquired through their OFDI from different country origins. We thus hypothesize:

Hypothesis 4. The positive relationship between the diversity of OFDI country destinations

and domestic, regional innovation performance is positively moderated by the degree of

international openness.

4. Methodology

4.1. Sample and data collection

We choose China as the empirical setting for this study of the effect of OFDI country

destination diversity on domestic, regional innovation for three main reasons. First, China is

an example of a large emerging economy and was the third largest source of FDI outflows in

the world by the end of 2015 (UNCTAD, 2016). Second, China is a country with significant

(39)

regions (provinces & municipalities) (Peck & Zhang, 2013), this makes it more appropriate to

conduct a regional level analysis instead of an aggregate national level. Third, the Chinese

Government has actively supported OFDI through its Go Global policy (Luo, Xue, & Han,

2010), suggesting that China can receive benefits from it.

In line with a large number of previous literature that study Chinese regional innovation

system, we choose the administrative provincial-level regions as the unit of analysis (Fu,

2008; Li, 2009; Yang & Lin, 2012). We use a balanced panel dataset for 30 provinces and

municipalities over the period 2011–2014. Tibet is excluded from the analysis because of the

limited availability of data.

We obtain OFDI data of each 30 Chinese regions from the Statistical Bulletin of China’s

Outward Foreign Direct Investment, compiled by the National Bureau of Statistics (NBS),

the Ministry of Commerce, and the State Administration of Foreign Exchange of China (Li et

al., 2016). The data for innovation and R&D are drawn from The China Statistical Yearbook

on Science and Technology and The Database of China Main Since & Technology Index

collected by the Ministry of Science and Technology of China (Li et al., 2016). The

region-specific institutional data are assembled from various issues of The China Statistical

(40)

and internally consistent because all firms in China are required to cooperate with the NBS

and submit their corporate information to the NBS (Chang & Xu, 2008). Hence, the statistics

published by NBS have been largely used by previous studies focus on Chinese strategy and

international business (e.g., Buckley, Clegg, & Wang, 2007; Chang & Xu, 2008).

4.2. Model specification

In line with prior studies of regional innovation performance, we base our model on the

knowledge production function proposed by Griliches (1979). This knowledge function

assumes that the outcome of successful R&D expenditure represents innovation and that

innovation is a function of the inputs to the R&D process (Cohen & Levinthal, 1989):

𝐼𝑁𝑁 = 𝑎×(𝑅𝐷𝐼𝑖)!

where

INNi = Innovation performance in region i

RDIi = R&D inputs in region i

Here we expand this basic model by including our explanatory and other control

(41)

𝐼𝑁𝑁𝑖, 𝑡 = 𝑎 + 𝛽1  ×𝑅𝐷𝐼𝑖, 𝑡   + 𝛽2  ×𝐷𝐼𝑉𝑖, 𝑡 + 𝛽3  ×𝐼𝑃𝑅𝑖, 𝑡 + 𝛽4  ×𝑀𝐴𝑅𝑖, 𝑡 + 𝛽5  ×𝐼𝑁𝑇𝑖, 𝑡

+ 𝛽6  ×𝐷𝐼𝑉𝑖, 𝑡  ×  𝐼𝑃𝑅𝑖, 𝑡 + 𝛽6  ×𝐷𝐼𝑉𝑖, 𝑡  ×  𝑀𝐴𝑅𝑖, 𝑡 + 𝛽6  ×𝐷𝐼𝑉𝑖, 𝑡  ×  𝐼𝑁𝑇𝑖, 𝑡

+ 𝛽4  ×𝑍𝑖, 𝑡 + 𝜀𝑖, 𝑡

where

DIVi,t = OFDI country destination diversity in region i in period t

IPRi,t = Intellectual property right protection in region i in period t

MARi,t = Market development in region i in period t

INTi,t = International openness in region i in period t

Zi,t = Vector of control variables for region i in period t

εi,t is an independent and identically distributed error term

In studies of innovation performance, it is worth noting that there may exist reverse

causation that generates estimation problems (Zhang et al., 2010). This means that the

explanatory variables may affect innovation, but innovation may also influence some of the

explanatory variables. For example, OFDI may result in better domestic innovation

performance, but more innovative firms are also more likely to have OFDI (Li et al., 2016).

Therefore, the number of OFDI (relatedly, the diversity of OFDI country destinations) from a

(42)

to rule out this possible simultaneity and endogeneity issues, we lag the dependent variable

by one year to account for the fact that spillover effects take times to materialize and to avoid

possible endogeneity with the independent variables (Yi et al., 2015; Li et al., 2016).

4.3. Estimation methodology

We analyze the 4-year panel data by utilizing negative binomial models in generalized

estimating equations (GEE). GEE are an extension of generalized linear models applied to

longitudinal data (Liang & Zeger, 1986). We choose this estimation technique to estimate

more efficient and unbiased regression parameters relative to ordinary least squares

regression because of three reasons.

First, our dependent variable takes the form of count data. Consequently, ordinary least

squares regression is inappropriate since our dependent variable is not normally distributed

(McCullagh, 1984). Our dependent variable is in negative binomial distribution as a

goodness-of-fit test rejects the Poisson distribution assumption due to over-dispersion

(Gardner, Mulvey, & Shaw, 1995). Given that GEE approach facilitate regression analyses

on dependent variables that are not normally distributed (Nelder & Baker, 1972), we run

(43)

appropriate link function involves modeling the logarithm of the mean, this will be auto

specified by the model (Gardner et al., 1995).

Second, GEE accounts for autocorrelation by estimating parameters and standard errors

based on an estimation correlation derived from within-cluster residuals (Liang & Zeger,

1986). When data consist of repeated measures, there may be correlation within a subject

over repeated measures. Thus, researchers must account for the correlation within responses

when estimating regression parameters (Ballinger, 2004), in our case that would be the

unobserved factors influencing patterns in particular provinces over time. With the use of

GEE for time series data, the standard errors are likely to be autocorrelated over time (Greene,

1990).

Third, GEE is more robust than other panel data methods since it offers multiple

correlation matrix structures to best match the data (Liang & Zeger, 1986). As suggested by

Ballinger (2004), for data that are correlated within a subject over time with equal time

interval repeated measures, an autoregressive correlation structure (AR1) is an appropriate

correlation matrix because it sets the within-subject correlations as an exponential function of

this lag period. Hence, we specified our working correlation matrix as autoregressive

(44)

4.4. Variables and measures

4.4.1. Dependent variable

Domestic, regional innovation performance

Domestic, regional innovation performance is measured by the number of granted

patents in each province in each year (Fu, 2008; Paci & Usai, 1999). Patent counts are mostly

used measure in previous research since they identify innovation performance more

accurately than alternative measures such as "new product" sales (Wang & Lin, 2013). This is

because patents capture both product and process innovation (Fu, 2008), while "new

products" are often roughly defined, and in many countries like China they can be potentially

over-recorded by firms to receive subsidies (Li, 2009). Furthermore, the process of patent

registration guarantees the quality and public availability of data (Griliches, 1979). Overall,

patent counts provide a homogeneous and meaningful indicator of innovation performance

across countries (Malerba, Orsenigo, & Peretto, 1997).

4.4.2. Independent and moderating variables

OFDI country destination diversity

(45)

create the entropy of the diversity of OFDI country destinations at province level:

𝐷𝑖𝑣𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑖𝑡𝑦 = − 𝑆𝑖 ln(𝑆𝑖) !

!!!

where Si is the proportion of the number of countryi over the total number of OFDI countries

invested by each region in a year. N is the total number of different countries that invested by

each region in that year. Entropy equals zero if all OFDI from a province in a year have the

same country destination and it rises with the extent of the diversity of OFDI country

destinations in a province. This variable was calculated for each of the 30 provinces and

municipalities and was updated yearly.

We collect OFDI destination country data by each province over 2011 to 2014 from

“Cross-border Investment Firm List” provided by Department of Outward Investment and

Economic Cooperation, Ministry of Commerce, China (Marukawa, Ito, & Zhang, 2014). This

dataset contains 19,526 overseas affiliates and branches of Chinese firms (including

Foreign-invested or Joint-Venture firms) throughout 31 provinces and municipalities

approved by the Chinese government during 2011-2014. We categorize these data by the

regional origin of the investor and the approval date of OFDI. We then remove those

(46)

population of 17,720 firms that conduct OFDI over the period 2011-2014.

Intellectual property right protection

IPR efficiency is measured as the proportion of granted IP lawsuits over the total

application number of IP lawsuits in a region (Yi et al., 2015). We obtain IP lawsuits from

the website of the State Intellectual Property Office of China. A higher ratio of the IPR

enforcement implies a stronger regime of IPR protection in the region.

Market development

Following Yi et al. (2013) and Hong et al. (2014), we use a marketization measure

developed by the National Economic Research Institution (Fan et al., 2007). This is a

comprehensive composite index that provides an overall assessment of marketization in each

Chinese province (Shi et al., 2012). The overall index is accessed via five key areas:

government and market roles; development of non-state-owned enterprises; development of

commodity markets; development of factor markets; and development of free market

institutions and a legal environment. A higher score indicates a higher level of market

development.

(47)

International openness is an institutional arrangement with a set of policy incentives

facilitating MNE to enter or go outward in a focal country. In line with numerous studies (e.g.

Ortega & Peri, 2014; Yi et al., 2015), international openness is measured by the ratio of

imports and exports to GDP in a province. A higher ratio shows a greater degree of

international openness.

4.4.3. Control variables

We include five control variables. First, building on the knowledge production function

proposed by Griliches (1979), we include R&D inputs as one of the control variables. In line

with previous studies of innovation process at the sector (e.g. Li, 2011) and regional levels

(e.g. Fu, 2008), we use R&D intensity to measure the R&D inputs. The R&D intensity is

calculated by dividing the R&D expenditure by the GDP of the region in a particular year,

thus taking into account the relative sizes of the regional economies.

Second, to control the development potential and regional demand for innovation, we

include the regional GDP growth rate as one of the control variables (Ouyang & Fu, 2012).

This is because we expect regions with faster economic growth have stronger innovation

(48)

that firms will also have the desire and the expertise to produce those products (Li et al.,

2016).

Third, given that foreign technology has been a critical source of advanced knowledge

for many developing countries to increase their innovation capabilities (Yang & Lin, 2012), it

is important to control for this potential determinant of innovation performance. Moreover,

over the period covered by this study, China was a major buyer of foreign technology (Li,

2011). We thus expect those regions where foreign technology purchase account for high

proportions of technology transaction to exhibit higher levels of innovation (Li et al., 2016).

Fourth, drawing insights from previous studies that state-owned enterprises (SOEs) may

be less interested in innovation than private enterprises because they generally operate in

protected industries like energy and national defense (Lin, Cai, & Li, 1998). We thus employ

the proportion of SOEs capital investment over the total value of capital investments in each

region to control its negative impact on innovation performance (Li et al., 2016).

Last but not least, as argued in our conceptual framework, regional absorptive capacity

is important to facilitate the realization of the benefits of OFDI for domestic innovation. In a

similar vein, scholars suggest that regions with a certain scientific base and amount of R&D

(49)

reverse transferred from overseas markets (Deng, 2007; Durán & Ubeda, 2005). Thus,

spillovers to domestic economies are more likely to take place in such regions. Hence,

assuming that highly educated people are typically the ones to undertake the innovation

process, we measure the absorptive capacity of each region by calculating the ratio of R&D

staff to the total employees of a region in a given year (Li et al., 2016). Table 1 provides

detailed definitions of each of the variables. Table 1

Description of variables.

Variable name Acronym Operationalization

Innovation performance INNit Granted patents of region i in year t

Diversity of OFDI country DIVit Formula (3) of region i in year t

Intellectual property right IPRit Granted IP lawsuits over the total application number of IP lawsuits of region i in year t

Market development MARit Marketization index (Fan et al., 2007) of region i in year t

International openness INTit The ratio of imports and exports to GDP of region i in year t Research intensity RDIit R&D expenditure/GDP (percent) of region i in year t

GDP growth rate GDPit GDP growth rate (percent) of region i in year t

Foreign technology purchase FTECHit Foreign technology purchase value over the total value of technology transaction in region i in year t

State sector’s share of output SOEit The share of capital investment of local SOEs' over the total of region i in year t

(50)

5. Findings

The number of granted patents nationally in China has risen over the 2012-2015 period,

from 1,163,226 in 2012 to over 1,596,977 in 2015. However, this national increase has not

been reflected uniformly across the Chinese regions, better innovation performance regions

have been concentrated in several coastal provinces (e.g. Jiangsu, Zhejiang, Guangdong).

Similarly, there has been a marked increase in OFDI flows from China over the period,

rising radically from US$ 74.65 billion in 2011 to US$ 123.12 billion by 2014. The most

active regions are the coastal provinces and municipalities (e.g. Guangdong, Jiangsu,

Zhejiang, Beijing, and Shanghai). Moreover, coastal provinces have invested in more diverse

foreign countries over the period (e.g. Shandong, Jiangsu, Zhejiang).

Table 2 exhibits mean, standard deviation, and the correlation matrix for all the variables.

The positive and significant correlation between dependent and independent variable

supports our hypothesis that regions with higher innovation performance have higher OFDI

countries diversity. Most of the correlations between the explanatory variables are small,

indicating that multicollinearity is not a serious concern in the estimation. Although the

correlations between market development and international openness (0.69), research

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

[…] exophones Schreiben kann man die Diversität und Pluralität einer Sprache und Kultur bewusst machen, und dies kann die Vielstimmigkeit innerhalb einer Sprache, eines

■ Patients with inherited arrhythmia syndromes (like congenital Long QT syndrome (LQTS) and Brugada syn- drome) are potentially at increased risk of ventricular arrhythmias and

In general, my research supports Dunning’s theory of the four motivation types. It contradicts the criticism that his framework might not be suitable for Chinese FDI, as it

The inclusion of the independent variable shows that there is a positive relation of .005 at a 1% significance level between the number of M&As and the host country

From table 1, I find that Chinese culture is characterized by low assertiveness, high institutional collectivism, high in-group collectivism, low future orientation, low

Policy makers in not just the developing nations themselves but in developed nations with economic ties to such countries, or stakeholders in organisations such

Besides intra-industry effect investigated by previous literatures on similar topic, we also investigate inter-industry spillover effects of two opposite direction, and a

I propose a model that connects environmental conditions such as risk and uncertainties, external stakeholders and government incentives of host- countries with