• No results found

Explaining the MENA paradox with returns to education : empirical evidence from Egypt

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Explaining the MENA paradox with returns to education : empirical evidence from Egypt"

Copied!
26
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

 

 

Explaining  the  MENA  paradox  with  returns  to  education

 

Empirical  evidence  from  Egypt

   

         

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

2013-­‐2014  

Master’s  thesis  economics  –  development  economics   Supervisor:  Noemi  Peter    

Student:  Amber  Leverne  Schothorst   Studentnumber:  5883695  

   

Disclaimer:  The  Economic  Research  Forum  and  the  Palestinian  Bureau  of  Statistics  granted  Amber  Leverne   Schothorst  access  to  relevant  data,  after  subjecting  data  to  processing  aiming  to  preserve  the  confidentiality  of   individual  data.  Amber  Leverne  Schothorst  is  solely  responsible  for  the  conclusions  and  inferences  drawn  upon  

(2)

Table  of  contents

 

1.  Introduction   3

 

2.  Literature  review   4

 

2.1  Human  capital  theory  and  returns  to  education   4  

2.2  Estimating  the  returns  to  education   5  

2.3  Hypothesis   6  

3.  Methodology   7

 

3.1  Heckman  two-­‐step  method   7  

3.2  Heckman’s  two-­‐step  model  applied   8  

4.  Data  and  descriptive  statistics   9

 

4.1  Data  and  sample   10  

4.2  Representativeness  of  Egypt  as  a  MENA  country   10  

4.3  Descriptive  statistics   11  

5.  Empirical  model   12

 

6.  Results   13

 

7.  Discussion  and  limitations   16

 

8.  Conclusion   18

 

Acknowledgements   19

 

References   19

 

Appendices   22

 

Appendix  1  –  Extended  information  on  Egypt   22  

Appendix  2  –  Data   24  

Appendix  3  –  Limitations  Heckman  procedure   25  

(3)

1.  Introduction  

 

According  to  a  report  by  the  World  Bank  (2012)  on  gender  equality  in  MENA  countries12,  the   MENA  countries  have  showed  a  lot  of  progress  in  human  development,  especially  in  gender   equality  within  education  and  health.  However,  the  same  report  shows  that  only  25.5%  of  the   women  in  MENA  countries  join  the  work  force  and  this  participation  rate  grows  slowly;  only   0.17  percentage  points  annually.  In  comparison  with  other  developing  countries  with  an  average   female  labor  force  participation  rate  of  50%,  a  rate  of  25.5%  is  low.  Moreover,  the  labor  force   gender  gap  in  the  MENA  region  has  doubled  over  the  last  25  years  and  women  face  high  rates  of   unemployment.  The  typical  MENA  country  experiences  the  low  labor  force  participation,  

although  the  gender  gap  within  education  and  health  care  has  been  reduced  and  the  number  of   educated  women  is  higher  than  ever.  In  most  MENA  countries  this  has  not  translated  (yet)  into   equal  roles  for  men  and  women  in  the  labor  markets  (World  Bank,  2013,  p.4).  So  why  has  the   increased  human  capital  not  yet  contributed  to  an  increase  in  female  labor  force  participation   like  in  the  rest  of  the  world?3    

  The  essence  of  the  MENA  paradox  is  the  question  why  the  great  achievements  in  human   capital  do  not  seem  to  have  contributed  to  increased  female  labor  force  participation  in  the   MENA  region.  Why  is  it  important  to  study  the  MENA  paradox?  Gender  equality  in  labor  force   participation  is  important,  for  both  intrinsic  and  instrumental  reasons.  The  intrinsic  reason  is   that  gender  equality  –  equal  rights  –  is  one  of  the  basic  human  rights.  The  instrumental  reason  is   that  gender  equality  is  a  contributor  to  economic  development  (World  Bank,  2013,  p.  3).  Ideally,   solving  the  MENA  paradox  -­‐  and  increasing  gender  equality  -­‐  would  address  basic  human  rights   and  stimulate  growth  in  the  MENA  Region.  Hopefully  explaining  the  MENA  paradox  will  help   identify  and  eliminate  possible  barriers  that  currently  prevent  women  from  participating  the   labor  market  to  the  same  extent  that  men  do.  Moreover,  explaining  the  MENA  paradox  will   provide  a  better  understanding  of  dynamics  around  gender  equality  and  female  labor  market   participation.  

  This  thesis  investigates  if,  and  to  what  extent  the  MENA  paradox  can  be  explained  with   the  returns  to  education.      

  In  the  empirical  research  data  will  be  used  from  the  Egypt  Labor  Market  Panel  Survey   (ELMPS,  2006)  conducted  by  the  Economic  Research  Forum  and  the  Palestinian  Bureau  of   Statistics.  This  is  the  second  round  of  the  longitudinal  survey,  containing  37,140  observations.                                                                                                                            

1

 ‘MENA  countries’  and  ‘MENA  region’  are  interchangeably  used.  

2

 The  MENA  region:  Algeria,  Djibouti,  Egypt,  Iran,  Iraq,  Jordan,  Lebanon,  Libya,  Morocco,  Syria,  Tunisia,  West  Bank  and  Gaza  and  

Yemen    

(4)

The  data  contains  questions  on  individual  characteristics,  education,  employment  and  income.   As  the  identification  strategy  the  Heckman  two-­‐step  approach  for  sample  selection  is  used  to   estimate  the  returns  to  education  for  women  and  men.    

  To  the  best  of  my  knowledge,  this  thesis  is  the  first  to  address  the  specific  link  between   female  labor  force  participation  and  returns  to  education  in  Egypt  in  light  of  the  MENA  paradox4.   This  thesis  contributes  by  excluding  the  returns  to  education  as  an  explanation  for  the  low   female  labor  force  participation  in  Egypt.  This  outcome  opens  the  door  for  further  research,   since  a  clear  consensus  about  the  explanation  of  the  MENA  paradox  has  not  been  reached.       This  thesis  is  structured  as  follows.  Section  2  reviews  literature  on  returns  to  education   and  provides  previous  empirical  evidence  on  the  relationship  between  schooling  and  education.   Section  3  covers  the  methodology  and  presents  the  Heckman  two-­‐step  method  as  the  

identification  strategy.  Section  4  discusses  the  data,  Egypt’s  representativeness  as  a  MENA   country  and  descriptive  statistics.  In  section  5,  presents  the  empirical  method  and  in  section  6   the  results  are  presented.  Section  7  discusses  the  results  and  limitations  while  section  8  will   conclude.      

2.  Literature  review  

 

This  section  discusses  theories  concerning  returns  to  education,  human  capital  theory  and  the   Mincerian  wage  equation.  Moreover,  this  section  provides  empirical  evidence  on  the  

relationship  between  wages  and  schooling  and  the  returns  to  education.    

2.1  Human  capital  theory  and  returns  to  education      

 

Human  capital  is  the  complete  set  of  abilities  and  skills,  a  combination  of  endowments  such  as  IQ   and  the  capital  acquired  through  investments.  Human  capital  is  often  described  as  the  economic   value  of  a  person,  where  human  capital  is  viewed  as  a  production  factor  that  creates  an  output   with  a  certain  value.  Human  capital  theory  seeks  to  explain  how  investments  in  human  capital   have  effects  on  productivity  -­‐  compared  to  investments  in  conventional  capital  –  and  what  the   magnitude  of  these  effects  is  (Schultz,  1961).  Blaug  (1976)  discusses  that  key  to  human  capital   theory  is  that  people  base  their  investment  decision  on  their  expected  earnings  and  wealth  that   will  follow  from  the  decision,  not  on  personal  short-­‐term  satisfactions.  Hereby  foregone  

earnings  should  be  taken  into  account  as  investment  costs.  Also,  human  capital  theory  assumes   that  human  capital  can  deteriorate  when  aging  or  being  unemployed  (Berndt,  1991,  p.  156).                                                                                                                            

4  Galal  (2001)  addresses  the  paradox  of  education  and  employment  from  the  angle  of  the  supply  side  of  education  and  it’s  quantity  

(5)

    Berndt  (1991,  p.  154)  speaks  about  schooling  as  an  investment  and  makes  the   comparison  between  demand  and  supply  on  the  labor  market,  whereas  a  worker  will  educate   himself  when  the  expectation  of  future  earnings  is  compensating.  The  earlier  one  starts  to  invest   in  its  human  capital,  the  longer  it  can  benefit  from  the  investment,  since  earnings  tend  to  grow   with  work  experience  (Berndt,  1991,  p.  154).  Weiss  (1995)  has  a  more  nuanced  view  and  argues   that  human  capital  theory  is  often  associated  with  the  idea  that  increasing  years  of  schooling   directly  affects  productivity  and  therefore  directly  increases  wages.  However,  it  is  likely  that   endogenous  factors  driving  the  schooling  decision  affect  productivity  rather  than  the  years  of   schooling  itself.  Card  (1999,  p.  1802)  extends  this  theory  by  arguing  that  although  literature   often  indicates  a  positive  relationship  between  schooling  and  wages,  one  must  be  careful  with   causal  inferences  on  the  effect  of  schooling  on  wages.  Moreover,  it  is  the  question  whether   individuals’  earnings  are  higher  because  of  higher  education  or  whether  they  are  better   educated  due  to  greater  abilities  (Card  (1999,  p.  1802).  

  The  endogenous  factors  driving  the  education  decision  can  cause  biases,  whereas  ability   bias  is  a  common  example  (Harmon  et  al.,  2003,  p.  119).  Ability  theory  describes  that  people   with  higher  initial  endowments  of  human  capital  tend  to  be  higher  educated  and  receive  higher   wages,  since  initially  their  productivity  is  higher.  However,  when  omitting    ability  variables,   schooling  will  be  endogenous  and  performing  an  OLS  regression  will  cause  the  results  to  be   biased  (Harmon  et  al.,  2003,  p.  119).  Moreover,  an  educational  degree  sends  out  a  signal  about  a   person’s  productivity.  For  high-­‐ability  people  it  is  easier  to  obtain  a  higher  educational  degree,   therefore  returns  to  education  for  high-­‐ability  people  tends  to  be  upward  biased5.  It  is  often   argued  that  studying  the  returns  to  education  for  identical  twins  rules  out  ability  bias  and  only   captures  the  effect  of  education  on  wages  (Harmon  et  al.,  2003,  p.  119).  However,  this  falls   outside  the  scope  of  this  thesis6.  

 

2.2  Estimating  the  returns  to  education    

 

Mincer  (1974,  p.  2)  argues  that  people  differ  in  the  amount  of  capital  they  accumulate  and  the   returns  they  receive  for  their  investment.  He  developed  the  core  model  for  estimating  the   returns  to  investment  in  human  capital.  Investments,  rate  of  returns  and  initial  endowments  in   human  capital  differ  among  humans  and  initial  endowments  are  not  easily  captured  (Mincer,   1974,  p.  3).  The  Mincer  equation  is  also  known  as  the  human  capital  earnings  function.  This  

                                                                                                                         

5

 

See  for  example  Arrow  (1973),  Spence  (1973A),  Spence  (1973B),  Becker  (1975),  Weiss  (1971)  and  Weiss  (1995).

 

6

 See  for  example  Angrist  and  Krueger  (1990),  Ashenfelter  and  Krueger  (1994),  

(6)

model  tries  to  capture  the  effects  of  investments  in  human  capital  on  earnings.  Lemieux  (2006)   explains  that  the  most  commonly  form  of  the  Mincer  equation  is  the  following:  

  Log  γ  =  log  γ0  +  rS  +  β1X  +  β2X2               (1)

   

Where  log  γ  is  the  natural  logarithm  of  earnings,  S  the  total  years  of  education  and  X  the  total   years  of  potential  market  experience.  Adding  work  experience  as  an  exogenous  variable  is   relevant  since  wages  tend  to  grow  with  age  (Berndt,  1991,  p.154).  The  quadratic  term  of  the   potential  market  experience  indicates  the  diminishing  returns  to  scales  of  work  experience.  The   Mincer  equation  forms  the  base  of  most  empirical  models  that  try  to  capture  the  effects  of   schooling  and  education  on  wages.  Psacharopoulos  and  Patrinos  (2004,  p.  116)  discuss  that  the   Mincerian  equation  estimates  the  wage-­‐effects  rather  than  the  returns  to  education.  Moreover,   Psacharopoulos  and  Patrinos  (2004,  p.  112)  find  that  the  average  returns  to  education  are  the   lowest  for  non-­‐OECD  countries  and  the  MENA  region  and  this  rate  is  approximately  7%,  below   the  world  average  of  10%.  According  to  Harmon  et  al.  (2004,  p.  150)  the  world  average  returns   to  education  are  6%  (OLS)  and  9%  (IV).  

 

2.3  Hypothesis  

 

The  hypothesis  in  this  thesis  is  ‘women  have  low  labor  force  participation  due  to  low  returns  to   education’.  If  the  returns  to  education  are  much  lower  for  women  than  for  men  in  Egypt,  it  could   explain  the  low  female  labor  force  participation.  When  returns  to  education  are  low  for  women,   it  could  go  two  ways.  Either  the  costs  of  education  are  extremely  high  or  the  payoffs  in  terms  of   wages  are  low  or  a  combination  of  both..  This  thesis  will  focus  on  the  latter  and  will  investigate   whether  the  returns  to  education  are  low  enough  to  explain  the  low  labor  force  participation.       If  the  returns  to  education  turn  out  to  be  low,  this  could  explain  the  low  female  labor   force  participation  rate.  Low  returns  to  education  could  imply  that  schooling  does  not  increase   human  capital,  in  that  case  a  diploma  will  be  a  piece  of  paper  rather  than  a  reflection  of  

productivity.  In  that  case,  the  MENA  paradox  could  be  explained  with  the  returns  to  education   and  policymakers  and  researchers  should  focus  on  the  quality  of  education  and  the  value  of   degrees.  Highly  simplified,  if  low  returns  to  education  for  women  are  found  it  increases  the   solvability  of  the  MENA  paradox.  However,  the  question  why  women  do  not  use  their  acquired   human  capital  remains  in  case  of  high  returns  to  education.  Possibly  women  invest  in  education   to  promote  themselves  on  the  marriage  market.  Also,  exogenous  factors  could  cause  the  low   female  labor  force  participation,  such  as  discrimination  by  employers.  This  result  would  also  be   contributive  since  excluding  a  possible  explanation  of  the  MENA  paradox  is  also  informative.    

(7)

3.  Methodology  

 

This  section  will  elaborate  on  the  methodology  and  the  empirical  model  applied  in  this  thesis.   Sample  selection  bias  occurs  when  those  employed  differ  extremely  from  those  who  are  not   participating  in  the  labor  market.  This  is  to  be  solved  with  a  Heckman  two-­‐step  correction   model.  Since  the  major  challenge  in  this  thesis  is  to  estimate  the  returns  to  education  for  women   who  do  not  work  (counterfactual),  sample  selection  bias  will  be  accounted  for.  However,  

selection  bias  is  not  the  only  possible  threat  to  estimating  the  returns  to  education,  ability  bias   and  signaling  are  possible  threats  as  well.  People  with  higher  initial  endowments  of  human   capital  earn  more  on  average  (ability  bias).  For  people  with  higher  ability  it  is  easier  to  obtain  a   higher  degree,  by  doing  so  they  send  out  a  signal  of  their  high  productivity  (signaling).  Applying   an  instrumental  variables  approach  could  solve  these  possible  biases  if  a  credible  instrument   would  be  available.  Due  to  the  lack  of  a  good  instrument  and  the  scope  of  this  thesis,  these  biases   will  not  be  accounted  for.    

 

3.1  Heckman  two-­‐step  method  

 

Heckman’s  (1979)  two-­‐step  model  for  sampling  selection  is  applied.  This  model  acknowledges   possible  sample  selection,  data  truncation  and  provides  a  method  to  overcome  the  problems   through  Ordinary  Least  Squares  Method  (OLS).  The  Heckman  two-­‐step  method  was  originally   designed  to  overcome  the  problem  of  sample  selection,  specifically  when  data  is  truncated.  The   method  was  the  answer  to  sample  selection  problems  and  Heckman  (1979)  introduced  the  case   of  estimating  the  wages  of  women  who  are  not  employed.    

  If  one  were  to  estimate  the  wages  of  women  directly  then  it  would  only  estimate  the   wages  of  women  who  are  actually  in  the  labor  force.  However,  one  cannot  automatically  say  that   these  wages  are  representative  for  those  who  do  not  work.  Since  being  employed  could  be  the   result  of  an  endogenous,  not  observed  decision.  One  example  is  self-­‐selection:  women  who  have   a  higher  reservation  wage  are  less  willing  to  work  for  a  certain  wage  than  women  with  a  lower   reservation  wage.  Also  it  is  possible  that  women  not  participating  in  the  labor  market  have  a   lower  productivity  that  would  logically  correspond  to  a  lower  wage.  Solely  performing  an  OLS   regression  would  lead  to  inconsistent  estimates  of  the  coefficient  on  wages  (Greene,  2003,  p.   783).    

  Heckman  acknowledges  the  possible  problem  of  sample  selection  and  treats  the  

endogenous  driver  of  the  unemployment  decision  as  omitted  variables  bias.  In  short,  in  the  first   step  the  probability  of  a  woman  being  employed  is  estimated.  In  the  second  step  the  wages  of   women  are  estimated.    Since  the  wages  are  only  estimated  for  those  women  who  are  in  the  first  

(8)

step  considered  to  be  in  the  labor  force,  the  Heckman  correction  term  is  added  in  the  second   step.  Basically  the  Heckman  correction  term  is  no  more  than  an  ‘instrument’  for  the  omitted   variable(s):  the  endogenous  drivers  of  the  decision  to  be  unemployed.  Adding  the  Heckman   correction  term  overcomes  the  problem  of  sample  selection  and  allows  the  wage  equation  to  be   representative  for  all  women,  employed  and  unemployed.  Moreover,  treating  the  sample  

selection  as  omitted  variables  bias  is  that  it  enables  to  use  Least  Squares  Method  in  step  1  and  2.   Another  benefit  of  using  Heckman  two-­‐step  model  over  other  sample  selection  models  (e.g.  ML)   is  that  the  Heckman  two-­‐step  model  estimates  the  standard  errors  correctly.    

 

3.2  Heckman’s  two-­‐step  model  applied  

 

Heckman  (1979)  introduced  the  case  where  women’s  endogenous  employment  decision  is   depending  on  their  reservation  wage.7  When  the  actual  wage  exceeds  the  reservation  wage,   people  will  enter  the  labor  market.  But  when  the  actual  wage  is  lower  than  the  reservation  wage,   a  person  chooses  not  to  be  employed  leading  to  unemployment  and  a  wage  of  zero.  However,  the   reservation  wage  cannot  be  observed,  so  another  in  the  model  exogenous  variable  is  used  to   estimate  the  probability  of  working.    

Step  1  –  the  selection  equation:        

W*i  =  ziγ  +  ui           [Wi=1  if  W*I  >  0  and  Wi=0  otherwise]       (1)  

• W*I    =  [yI  -­‐  y*I]    

• Prob  (Wi  =  1|zi)  =  Φ(  ziγ)   • Prob  (Wi  =  0|zi)  =  1  -­‐  Φ(  ziγ)  

The  underlying  assumption  is  that  employment  (Wi)  is  determined  by  the  difference  (W*I)   between  the  actual  wage  (yi)  and  the  reservation  wage  (y*i).  Wi  is  a  binary  variable  whereas   value  1  indicates  person  I  is  employed  and  0  otherwise.  Ziγ    is  a  vector  of  exogenous  variables   determining  W*I  and  the  exogenous  variables  from  the  regression  equation  (2).  Ziγ  indicates   whether  the  actual  wage  exceeds  the  reservation  wage  and  thus  whether  someone  will  be   employed  (Wi=1).  The  selection  equation  estimates  the  difference  between  the  actual  wage  (Wi)   and  reservation  wage  (y*i),  whereas  a  female  is  considered  to  be  employed  (Wi=1)  if  the  

reservation  wage  W*i    >  0.  

The  selection  equation  basically  provides  an  estimate  of  the  probability  that  a  person  will  be   employed  (Wi=1).        

                                                                                                                         

(9)

Step  2  -­‐  regression  equation:    

  yi  =  xiβ  +  [Heckman  correction  term]  +  εI     [Only  observed  if  Wi=1]     (2)  

Xi  is  a  vector  of  individual  endogenous  variables  that  determine  the  wage  (yi).  The  regression  

equation  is  only  estimating  the  wages  for  those  who  are  in  the  sample,  i.e.  those  who  are   employed  (Wi=1).  Key  to  the  Heckman  procedure  is  that  the  latent  endogenous  variable  W*I  is   not  included  in  the  regression  equation.  Instead  the  sample  selection  that  occurs  in  step  1  is   considered  as  omitted  variables  bias  is  modeled  by  the  Inverse  Mill’s  Ratio.  It  is  possible  to  do   so,  since  the  Mill’s  ratio  follows  the  property  of  the  truncated  normal  distribution.  The  omitted   variables  problem  is  modeled  by  the  Heckman  correction,  whereas  the  Heckman  correction  is   ρεu  •  σε  •  λI  •(-­‐  ziγ).  An  implication  of  the  model  is  that  coefficients  are  consistent  and  

asymptotically  normal.  By  applying  the  Heckman  two-­‐step  method,  the  coefficients  on  xi  in  the   regression  equation  can  be  interpreted  for  both  employed  (Wi=1))  and  unemployed  (Wi=0)   women.  The  Heckman  two-­‐step  model  has  its  limitations  and  threats,  e.g.  the  estimator  can  be   inconsistent  (when  working  with  small  samples),  model  is  dependent  on  its  assumption  and   high  rate  of  censoring  causes  inefficiency.  See  appendix  3  for  more  information.  

  The  use  of  a  selection  variable  is  key  to  the  Heckman  two-­‐step  procedure.  The  selection   variable  allows  selecting  the  counterfactual  observations  and  therewith  taking  care  of  the   sample  selection  problem.  Without  the  selection  variable,  one  would  estimate  the  functional   form  in  the  selection  equation,  which  is  basically  an  OLS  regression.  Only  estimating  the   functional  form  and  omitting  the  Heckman  correction  would  lead  to  inconsistent  estimates  of   the  coefficient  on  wages  (Greene,  2003,  p.  783)  and  does  not  allow  to  take  care  of  the  sample   selection  problem.  However,  one  must  be  aware  that  in  the  end  the  representativeness  and   credibility  of  the  estimates  highly  depends  on  the  credibility  of  the  selection  variable.        

4.  Data  and  descriptive  statistics    

 

This  section  discusses  the  data  and  sample,  the  representativeness  of  Egypt  for  the  whole  MENA   region  and  the  descriptive  statistics.  

(10)

4.1  Data  and  sample

 

 

The  Egypt  Labor  Market  Panel  Survey  (ELMPS)  20068  contains  almost  40,000  cases  and  is  the   second  round  of  the  ELMPS  longitudinal  surveys  and  is  conducted  by  the  by  the  Economic   Research  Forum  and  the  Palestinian  Bureau  of  Statistics.  This  is  a  follow-­‐up  survey  on  the   households  that  were  interviewed  in  the  first  round  (1998).  This  longitudinal  survey  is  

considered  to  be  representative  for  the  Egyptian  population,  which  is  of  great  importance  to  the   credibility  of  the  estimates  on  the  returns  to  education  (Psacharopoulos  and  Patrinos,  2004).  To   ensure  the  representativeness  of  the  second  round,  a  refresher  sample  of  2,500  households  is   added9.  A  total  number  of  8,349  households  is  reached  in  the  2006  sample. The  dataset  contains   a  large  set  of  questions  on  individual  characteristics,  education,  income  and  employment,  which   allows  estimating  the  returns  to  education.  The  questionnaire  includes  household,  individual   and  community  level  questions.  All  household  and  community  level  observations  are  linked  to   the  individual  level  through  ID-­‐coding.  All  household  members  above  the  age  of  6  are  

interviewed,  however,  the  question  on  marital  status  is  asked  only  to  females  and  males  above   respectively  16  and  18  years  old  –  the  legal  marriage  ages.  Therefore,  the  ages  range  between   16-­‐82  (males)  and  18-­‐90  (females)  for  the  observations  in  the  empirical  research.  

 

4.2  Representativeness  of  Egypt  as  a  MENA  country  

 

Since  this  research  is  using  data  from  Egypt  only,  this  paragraph  will  briefly  discuss  whether   Egypt  is  a  representative  MENA  country10.  Comparing  Egypt  to  MENA  shows  that  female  labor   force  participation,  life  expectancy  at  birth  and  literacy  rates  are  similar.  However,  the  GNI  of   Egypt  is  approximately  15%  lower  than  the  average  of  MENA.  School  completion  rates  are   higher  in  Egypt  than  in  the  whole  MENA  region,  but  this  is  probably  due  to  the  fact  that  primary   school  is  compulsory  in  Egypt  and  attending  a  governmental  school  is  for  free  (Herrera  and   Badr,  2011).  So  there  is  a  large  incentive  to  attend  primary  education  in  Egypt.  The  percentage   of  females  holding  a  seat  in  parliament,  which  is  often  used  as  a  proxy  for  gender  equality,  is  8   times  smaller  in  Egypt  than  in  MENA.  However,  compared  to  previous  years,  this  rate  has   decreased  and  could  be  a  result  of  the  Arab  Spring  tensions.      

  For  the  MENA  region,  it  is  not  an  exception  when  both  higher  and  less  educated  people   compete  for  the  same  job,  which  makes  it  harder  for  those  with  middle  or  lower  education  to   find  a  job.  According  to  Bardak  et  al.  (2006)  the  number  of  higher  educated  women  in  the  MENA                                                                                                                            

8  A  third  round  from  2012  is  available  but  not  used  because  of  the  Arab  Spring  events.  

9

 

The  difference  comes  from  households  that  have  split  between  1998  and  2006,

 

10

 See  appendix  2  for  further  information,  statistics  and  tables  

(11)

region  that  are  willing  to  wait  for  a  challenging  job  is  increasing.  This  happens  mostly  in  the   public  sector,  since  women  in  the  MENA  region  hardly  enter  the  private  sector  (Bardak  et  al.   2006,  p.  16).    

  In  conclusion,  the  facts  indicate  that  Egypt  shows  the  pattern  that  is  typical  for  a  MENA   country;  the  female  labor  force  participation  is  low,  while  educational  and  health  measures   indicate  great  progress  over  the  last  decade.    

 

4.3  Descriptive  statistics    

 

Table  1  presents  the  descriptive  statistics.  The  average  age  in  this  sample  is  approximately  26.5   years  old,  which  is  quite  low.  However  it  is  not  uncommon  for  a  MENA  country  since  30%  of  the   population  in  the  MENA  region  is  below  14  years  old,  only  5%  is  older  than  6511.  On  average   42%  of  the  women  are  married  which  is  slightly  higher  than  42%  of  men.  A  possible  explanation   for  the  difference  is  that  polygamous  marriages  for  men  are  legal.  In  1981  Egypt  introduced  a   law  stating  that  education  is  compulsory  up  to  preparatory  education,  equal  to  9  years  of  

schooling.  The  mean  years  of  schooling  in  the  sample  concentrates  around  10-­‐11  years,  which  is     -­‐  as  expected  –  higher  than  9  years.  However,  regardless  of  the  compulsory  schooling  law,  only   70%  in  the  sample  has  at  least  attained  preparatory  education12.  This  implies  that  –  assuming   one  starts  school  at  age  6  –  schooling  is  compulsory  until  the  age  of  15.  The  rate  of  scholars   dropping  out  early  (before  age  15)  has  not  decreased  since  1981,  this  suggests  that  the   introduction  of  the  law  has  not  prevented  early  dropouts  ever  since.    

Variable   Female   Male  

Basic  variables   N=18,553   N=18,587   Mean  age     26.97   (19.61)   26.31   (19.22)   Married  (fraction)   0.42   (0.49)   0.40   (0.49)   Education  

Mean  years  of  schooling       N=7,477   10.43   (4.46)   N=9,222   10.88   (4.76)  

Highest  education  level  attained13    

Lower  education   Intermediate  education   Higher  education   Cumulative   0.373   0.771   1.000   Cumulative   0.375   0.747   0.999*                                                                                                                             11

 Source:  http://wdi.worldbank.org/table/2.1  

12

 

See  appendix  3.  

   

13

 Lower:  nothing,  primary,  preparatory,  Intermediate:  general  secondary,  technical  secondary  3-­‐years,  technical  secondary  5-­‐

years,  Higher:  Above  intermediate,  university,  post  graduate.  

(12)

Labor     LFP  (fraction)     N=3,544   0.57   (0.50)     N=10,465   0.81   (0.40)   Income  

Mean  hourly  wage  in  Egyptian  pound   (EGP)   N=1,501   3.36   (8.94)   N=5,171   3.76   (9.61)   Table  1  

*  Rounding  difference  **  see  appendix  3    

The  average  hourly  wage  for  women  in  Egypt  is  3.36  EGP;  the  hourly  wage  is  slightly  higher  for   men  (3.76  EGP).  This  could  also  be  a  result  of  the  low  female  labor  force  participation,  where   females  that  do  participate  on  the  labor  market  are  often  higher  educated  and  receive  a   relatively  higher  wage  (IMF,  2013,  p.  9).    

  The  labor  force  participation  for  women  in  this  sample  is  57%,  which  is  conflicting  with   the  rate  of  24%  reported  by  the  World  Bank  over  201214.  However,  the  gender  gap  in  labor  force   participation  is  large  (57%  against  81%)  while  the  gender  gap  in  total  years  of  schooling  is   small15.    

5.  Empirical  model  

 

This  thesis  follows  the  two-­‐step  model  for  sampling  selection  by  Heckman  (1979)  and  consists   of  the  following  two  equations  that  will  be  estimated  for  men  and  women  separately.  

LFP*i  =  γ0  +γ1Si  +γ2Agei  +  γ3Age2i  +  γ4  Marri  +  u1             (3)  

• LFPi=1  if  

γ

0

 +γ

1

S

i

 +γ

2

Age

i  

+  γ

3

Age2

i  

+  γ

4  

Marr

i  

+  u

1  >  0  and  LFPi=0  otherwise    

Equation  (3)  is  the  selection  equation  and  estimates  the  probability  of  a  person  being  employed   (LFPi=1).  Si  represents  the  total  years  of  schooling  of  individual  i  and  Expi  indicates  the  total  

potential  work  experience  in  years.16  Marri  is  a  binary  variable  whereas  value  1  indicates  that  

person  i  is  married  and  0  otherwise.  Marri  is  the  selection  variable,  all  other  variables  come  from  

the  regression  equation  (equation  (4)).    

  It  is  assumed  that  the  employment  decision  is  based  on  the  reservation  wage,  i.e.  the   minimum  wage  a  woman  is  willing  to  work  for,  which  cannot  be  observed  directly.  Marriage                                                                                                                            

14

 See  appendix  1;  table  A3.  

15

 

Independent  group  t-­‐test  indicates  difference  in  mean  years  of  schooling  is  significantly  different  from  zero.

   

16

 See  appendix  3  for  definitions  and  computations  of  variables  

(13)

does  not  affect  productivity  directly  thus  it  does  not  directly  affect  the  wage  one  receives.  

However,  marriage  does  affect  the  reservation  wage  of  women,  since  married  women  are  part  of   a  household  whereas  the  husband  often  provides  the  main  income.  When  the  total  household   income  is  higher  due  to  the  contribution  by  the  husband,  the  reservation  wage  of  a  woman   increases.  Therefore  Marri  is  included  as  the  selection  variable.    

Ln  Yi  =  β0  +β1Si  +β2Agei  +  β3Age2i  +  [Inverse  Mills  Ratioi]  +  ε1           (4)  

• [Only  observed  if  LFP=1]  

Equation  (4)  represents  the  regression  equation  and  β1  captures  the  effect  of  schooling  on  

wages.  Ln  Yi  represents  the  total  income  from  work,  including  bonuses  etc.,  excluding  subsidies   or  benefits  from  the  government  and  is  calculated  as  wage  on  an  hourly  basis.    

  Concluding,  the  sample  selection  is  treated  as  omitted  variable  bias,  which  is  on  its  turn   modeled  by  the  Inverse  Mill’s  Ratioi.  By  adding  the  Heckman  correction  term  Inverse  Mill’s  Ratio,   the  coefficient  on  schooling  represents  the  returns  to  education  for  all  women  regardless  of  their   labor  force  participation  status.      

6.  Results    

 

Table  2  shows  the  results  of  the  Heckman  two-­‐step  and  OLS  estimates.  The  Heckman  two-­‐step   model  strongly  depends  on  the  correct  specification  and  requires  the  correlation  between  the   selection  and  regression  equation  to  be  nonzero.  A  correlation  of  zero  will  cause  the  model  to  be   biased  (Guo  and  Fraser,  2010,  p.  124).  However,  this  is  considered  not  to  be  a  problem  since   both  Rho’s  are  nonzero.  Moreover,  the  significance  of  the  Inverse  Mill’s  Ratio’s  for  females  and   males  indicates  that  the  problem  should  be  modeled  with  the  Heckman  two-­‐step  method,  since   OLS  would  lead  to  biased  estimates17.  

  The  more  counterfactual  observations  are  sampled,  the  smaller  lambda  and  sample   selection  becomes  less  of  a  problem.  By  ‘counterfactual  observations’  the  part  of  the  population   is  meant  that  could  have  been  in  the  labor  force  –  selected  by  the  selection  variable.  Sigma  is  by   definition  larger  than  zero,  rho  lies  between  [-­‐1,1]  and  lambda  is  the  product  of  sigma  and  rho   (ρεu  •  σε  =λ).  A  positive  rho  means  that  omitted  factors  are  positively  correlated  with  the   selection  variable  and  the  dependent  variable  in  the  regression.  A  negative  rho  means  that   omitted  factors  are  negatively  correlated  with  the  selection  variable  and  positively  correlated   with  the  dependent  variable  –  or  vice  versa.  The  lower  the  value  of  lambda,  the  higher  the   probability  that  an  observation  contains  data  for  the  dependent  variable  (Heckman,  1976,  p.                                                                                                                            

(14)

479).          

Regression  equation   Female   Male  

  Heckman   OLS   Heckman   OLS  

(logmtotalreal)           Schooling  (years)     Age     Age^2     Constant     0.063**   (0.007)   0.094**   (0.013)   -­‐0.001**   (0.000)   -­‐2.500**   (0.304)   0.050**   (0.005)   0.076**   (0.011)   -­‐0.000**   (0.000)   -­‐1.915**   (0.194)   0.035**   (0.003)   -­‐0.058**   (0.017)   0.001**   (0.000)   1.354**   (0.351)   0.040**   (0.002)   0.051**   (0.006)   -­‐0.000**   (0.000)   -­‐0.866**   (0.101)  

Selection  equation   Female   Male  

  Heckman     Heckman     (LFP)           Schooling  (years)     Age     Age^2     Married     Constant       0.133**   (0.008)   0.234**   (0.016)   -­‐0.003**   (0.000)   -­‐0.908**   (0.078)   -­‐4.704**   (0.295)     0.021**   (0.005)   0.232**   (0.010)   -­‐0.003**   (0.000)   0.526**   (0.060)   -­‐3.392**   (0.170)       Mills   Lambda     0.249*   (0.098)       -­‐0.847**   (0.124)     Rho   sigma   0.37810   0.65776736     -­‐0.99934   0.84793435     N   2,294   1,441   6,167   4,709   Censored   Uncensored   853   1,441       1,456   4,702       Table  2  

**  significant  at  the  1%  level   *  Significant  at  the  5%  level  

+  Significant  at  the  10%  level  

 

  For  females  the  lambda  is  low  (0.249)  and  significant  and  rho  is  small  (0.378).  This   indicates  that  unobserved  factors  that  are  positively  correlated  with  LFP  tend  to  be  positively   correlated  with  the  dependent  variable,  resulting  in  higher  wages.  Heckman  two-­‐step  corrects  

(15)

for  this,  therefore  Heckman  two-­‐step  reports  a  higher  return  to  education  than  the  OLS  estimate.   Increasing  schooling  with  one  year  respectively  leads  to  a  6.3%  (Heckman  two-­‐step)  and  5.0%   (OLS)  increase  in  the  hourly  wage.  18      

  For  males  the  lambda  is  -­‐0.847,  which  is  significant,  negative  and  larger  than  the  lambda   for  females.  This  indicates  that  on  average  the  probability  that  an  observation  i  has  data  for  the   dependent  variable  is  lower  for  males  than  for  females.  The  negative  rho  indicates  that  

unobserved  factors  that  are  positively  (negatively)  correlated  with  LFP  tend  to  be  negatively   (positively)  correlated  with  wages.  Since  the  Heckman  procedure  corrects  for  these  unobserved   factors,  it  explains  why  Heckman  reports  a  lower  returns  to  education  than  the  OLS  estimation.   Increasing  schooling  with  one  year  respectively  leads  to  a  3.5%  (Heckman  two-­‐step)  and  4.0%   (OLS)  increase  in  the  hourly  wage.    

  By  assessing  the  model  specific  parameters  rho  and  lambda,  it  is  concluded  that  the   selection  equation  is  likely  to  be  specified  correctly  for  females.  However  rho  for  males  is  almost   equal  to  [-­‐1].  Since  rho  is  the  correlation  between  the  error  terms  of  the  regression  and  selection   equations,  there  is  not  much  information  in  the  selection  variable  marriage,  that  distinguishes   between  those  two  equations.  Therefore  one  must  be  careful  when  interpreting  the  Heckman   two-­‐step  estimate  for  males.      

Variable   Female   Male  

    Age     Schooling  (years)     Married  (fraction)     Uncensored   N=1,441.   36.13   (10.75)   13.78   (3.55)   0.66   (0.47)   Censored   N=853   38.07   (15.90)   10.21   (4.86)   0.75   (0.43)   Uncensored   N=  4,702   35.46   (11.23)   11.77   (4.62)   0.71   (0.45)   Censored   N=1,465   41.91   (21.78)   10.07   (5.12)   0.51   (0.50)   Table  3    

  Table  3  shows  descriptive  statistics  on  the  observations  in  the  Heckman  two-­‐step  

estimates.  For  females,  the  fraction  of  people  married  is  higher  under  the  censored  observations   (75%  against  66%).  This  is  consistent  with  the  hypothesis  that  marriage  raises  the  reservation   wage  and  therefore  plays  a  role  in  the  decision  to  be  employed  or  not.  The  results  suggest  that  it   is  likely  that  these  women  would  have  worked,  if  they  had  not  been  married.    

  The  censored  males  in  the  Heckman  two-­‐step  estimate  have  a  lower  percentage  of   marriage  (51%  censored  against  71%  uncensored).  Possibly  marriage  plays  less  of  a  role  in  the   decision  to  be  employed.  It  is  not  expected  that  being  married  increases  a  man’s  reservation   wage.  For  both  females  and  males  the  monthly  household  benefits  are  higher  for  the  censored                                                                                                                            

(16)

observations,  which  raises  the  reservation  wage  for  both  (and  is  not  gender  specific).  It  should   be  noted  that  the  monthly  household  benefits  include  illness  support  and  pension  benefits;  it  is   possible  that  the  ‘censored’  people  are  not  unemployed  because  of  reservation  wage  

considerations  but  because  of  the  inability  to  work.    

7.  Discussion  and  limitations  

 

 

The  hypothesis  in  this  thesis  is  ‘women  have  low  labor  force  participation  due  to  low  returns  to   education’.  The  female  labor  force  participation  is  57%  whereas  the  male  labor  force  

participation  is  81%.  This  large  difference  is  noteworthy  since  the  gender  gap  in  education  is   very  small,  men  have  on  average  0.41  more  years  of  education  compared  to  women.  The  

Heckman  two-­‐step  estimates  for  the  returns  to  education  show  that  women  have  higher  returns   to  education  than  men  –  6.3%  and  3.5%  respectively.  This  rules  out  the  possibility  that  a  degree   is  a  piece  of  paper  rather  than  a  reflection  of  productivity;  according  to  the  rate  of  return  these   women  do  not  lack  productivity  according  to  the  rate  of  return.  

  However,  the  question  remains  why  women  do  not  put  their  acquired  human  capital  into   practice.  There  is  more  than  one  possible  explanation.  One  is  that  women  invest  in  education  to   promote  themselves  on  the  marriage  market.  Pencavel  (1998,  p.  326)  argues  that  it  is  well   known  that  there  is  a  positive  correlation  between  the  education  of  men  and  women.  Moreover   he  argues  that  the  importance  of  educational  degrees  in  assortative  mating  has  increased  since   the  1950’s.  Assortative  mating  is  the  theory  that  describes  how  individuals  like  to  marry  spouses   that  are  similar  to  themselves  in  many  aspects,  such  as  education,  ethnic  background,  religion   etc.  (Lefgren  and  McIntyre,  2006,  p.  789).  Furthermore,  Anderson  and  Hamori  (2000,  p.  230)   argue  that  the  potential  of  an  individual  translates  to  a  social  price  that  reflects  the  attraction   and  future  prospects  of  the  individual  as  a  spouse.  Lefgren  and  McIntyre  (2006,  p.  788)  found   that  half  or  more  of  the  correlation  between  women’s  education  and  consumption  runs  through   the  marriage  market.  For  women,  education  is  thus  an  efficient  way  to  increase  future  prospects.   Furthermore,  Lefgren  and  McIntyre  (2006)  discuss  that  men  with  higher  income  tend  to  marry   women  who  have  the  potential  of  earning  a  good  salary  when  entering  the  labor  market.  The   data  from  ELMPS  2006  shows  a  significant  negative  effect  of  marriage  on  being  in  the  labor   force19.  This  suggests  that  being  married  reduces  the  probability  of  joining  the  labor  market.   This  is  in  line  with  the  hypothesis  that  women  educate  themselves  to  find  an  appropriate  spouse   on  the  marriage  market  rather  than  having  the  intention  of  being  employed.    

                                                                                                                         

(17)

  According  to  the  International  Monetary  Fund  (2013,  p.9)  women  in  MENA  countries   that  participate  on  the  labor  market,  are  often  higher  educated  and  receive  a  relatively  higher   wage  than  women  all  over  the  world.  It  is  possible  that  the  returns  to  education  are,  despite  the   Heckman  correction,  upwards  biased  since  the  females  who  are  employed  have  a  higher  

educational  attainment.  The  World  Bank  (2012,  p.11)  suggests  that  the  low  female  labor  force   participation  in  the  MENA  region  could  be  a  result  of  culture  in  which  marriage  is  an  invisible   hand  that  alters  women’s  opportunities  to  enter  the  labor  market.  To  illustrate;  the  third  round   of  the  Egypt  Labor  Market  Panel  Survey  in  2012  contains  a  question  why  women  do  not  work  –   for  those  who  do  not  work.  7.8%  of  the  women  that  do  not  work  indicate  that  it  is  refused  by   their  husband/fiancé,  32.8%  indicates  that  they  would  rather  stay  at  home  to  take  care  of  their   children.  Moreover,  13.6%  of  the  women  argue  there  are  no  suitable  jobs  and  17.5%  argue  that   the  wages  of  the  available  jobs  are  not  suitable.  Another  15.9%  answered  that  they  did  not  want   to  work.  

  It  should  be  noted  that  this  thesis  has  some  limitations.  The  outcomes  of  this  empirical   research  are  dependent  on  the  underlying  assumptions.  One  could  debate  about  the  reflection  of   productivity  in  wages,  the  relevance  and  credibility  of  marriage  as  a  selection  variable  and  the   definitions  of  the  variables  used  in  the  specifications.  Becker  (1985)  argues  that  the  more  time   women  dedicate  to  tasks  within  the  household,  the  less  energy  they  invest  in  their  job  compared   to  men,  possibly  resulting  in  lower  productivity  and  salaries.  The  underlying  assumption  for   using  marriage  as  a  selection  variable  is  that  marriage  does  only  affect  the  reservation  wage  of  a   woman,  not  the  productivity.  So  if  Becker’s  (1985)  argument  is  true,  this  could  be  a  threat  to  the   use  of  marriage  as  the  selection  variable.  However,  the  wage,  that  is  assumed  to  reflect  

productivity,  is  calculated  on  an  hourly  basis  and  is  therefore  not  expected  to  cause  biases.       By  applying  the  Heckman  two-­‐step  method  the  estimator  can  be  inconsistent  (when   working  with  small  samples)20.  The  model  is  highly  dependent  on  its  assumptions  and  a  high   rate  of  censoring  causes  inefficiency.  The  dataset  that  is  explored  in  this  thesis  is  large,  the   assumptions  are  verified  (nonzero  correlation  between  the  error  terms  of  the  two  equations)   and  the  rate  of  censoring  is  relatively  low  (between  23%-­‐37%).  These  threats  are  therefore  not   considered  to  cause  large  problems.    

  In  conclusion,  the  returns  to  education  do  not  seem  to  provide  an  explanation  for  the   MENA  paradox.  However,  it  is  debatable  how  low  the  returns  to  education  must  be  to  conclude   that  the  returns  to  education  cause  the  low  female  labor  force  participation.  Nonetheless,  female   labor  force  participation  is  much  lower  than  male  labor  force  participation  even  though  the   returns  to  education  are  much  higher  for  females,  which  is  somewhat  contradictory.  However,  it   is  possible  that  there  are  unobserved  (endogenous)  factors  driving  the  female  labor  force                                                                                                                            

(18)

participation  decision  that  are  not  included  in  this  research,  but  that  does  explain  the  

controversy  in  the  proportions  between  men  and  women;  the  returns  to  education  and  labor   force  participation.  

8.  Conclusion  

 

This  thesis  investigated  whether  the  returns  to  education  could  explain  the  MENA  paradox.  The   MENA  paradox  addresses  the  question  why  female  labor  force  participation  in  the  Middle  East   and  North  Africa  is  so  low,  while  it  should  be  higher  given  development  indicators  in  

comparison  to  similar  development  regions.  As  indicated  by  economic  literature,  one  can   estimate  the  returns  to  education  by  applying  the  Heckman  two-­‐step  model.  This  model   estimates  the  returns  to  education  as  the  effect  of  schooling  on  wages.  This  is  estimated  with   data  from  the  Egypt  Labor  Market  Panel  Survey  2006,  which  contains  almost  40,000  

observations  and  includes  questions  on  individual  characteristics,  education  and  schooling.  To   account  for  the  possible  selection  bias  that  could  come  from  the  fact  that  only  wages  of  women   in  the  labor  force  are  observed,  the  Heckman  two-­‐step  model  corrects  for  this  by  estimating  who   are  considered  eligible  for  being  in  the  labor  force  based  on  the  selection  variable  marriage.  The   results  show  that  the  returns  to  education  are  higher  for  women  than  for  men  (6.3%  and  3.5%),   whereas  the  labor  force  participation  rate  is  of  women  is  lower  compared  to  men  (57%  and   81%).  In  consideration  of  similar  total  years  of  schooling  for  both  men  and  women  (0.41  years   difference)  the  result  is  puzzling.  Under  the  assumption  that  wages  reflect  productivity,  the   theory  that  education  is  a  piece  of  paper  rather  than  a  reflection  of  skills  and  abilities  is  excluded   –  which  could  be  the  case  when  the  returns  to  education  for  women  turns  out  to  be  low.  

However,  the  returns  to  education  for  women  are  high,  so  why  would  women  still  invest  in  their   education  while  most  of  them  do  not  end  up  in  the  labor  force?  One  possible  explanation  runs   through  the  marriage  channel;  being  educated  gives  females  a  higher  probability  of  marrying  an   educated  spouse.  Also,  it  could  be  possible  that  women  are  discriminated  on  the  labor  market  or   that  it  is  embedded  in  culture.    

  For  further  research  I  would  recommend  to  investigate  the  marriage  market  theory  and   discrimination  on  the  labor  market.  Also  I  would  recommend  investigating  whether  the  women   that  do  participate  on  the  labor  market  are  higher-­‐educated  and  therefore  earn  more,  as  the  IMF   indicates  However,  it  should  not  be  ignored  that  the  MENA  paradox  addresses  a  wide-­‐spread   multi-­‐dimensional  paradox,  that  can  probably  not  be  captured  within  the  field  of  economics   alone.    

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

Therefore, in this paper, our starting point is that performance defined as (a) the level of scientific and technological achievements, (b) the degree to which

This effect relies on the matching of the standing wave field within the multilayer stack with the structure: the minima of the wave field intensity are placed in the center

Since corporations mainly operate in environments associated with causation and, in contrast, startups emerge in contexts related to effectuation, it is interesting to examine how

Wat Spaanschen Brabander uniek maakt is niet zozeer het commentaar op de eigen tijd, maar hoe Bredero een wereld tot leven laat komen waarin de menselijke natuur, met al

Surface ozone over the Tibetan Plateau is sensitive to ozone perturbation in the upper layers [27], suggesting that ozone above the planetary boundary layer may strongly

projekte kan aangepak word en ons glo werklik dat veel meer studente betrek kan word deur behoorlike propagering en wer· wing vir soortgelyke take. Verder moet die

To answer the question if the health of emerging markets can be linked to excess returns, we examined the relation and correlation between investment grade index and the

tional for the L.B.E. with boundary conditions and the functional for the integral equation, that can be derived from the L.B.E. with its boundary conditions. The