• No results found

The relationship between wages, productivity and unemployment through time in China

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "The relationship between wages, productivity and unemployment through time in China"

Copied!
48
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

 

 

 

 

The  relationship  between  wages,  productivity  and  

unemployment  through  time  in  China  

 

 

 

Romy  van  As  

(10186042)  

 

 

Bachelor  Thesis  Economics  and  Business  

Specialization:  Economics  and  Finance  

Faculty  of  Economics  and  Business  

 

Supervisor:  Stephanie  Chan  

Academic  year:  2014  –  2015    

 

(2)

Statement  of  Originality  

 

This  document  is  written  by  Romy  van  As  (student  number  10186042),  who  declares  to  take  full   responsibility  for  the  contents  of  this  document.  

I  declare  that  the  text  and  the  work  presented  in  this  document  is  original  and  that  no  sources  other   than  those  mentioned  in  the  text  and  its  references  have  been  used  in  creating  it.  

The  Faculty  of  Economics  and  Business  is  responsible  solely  for  the  supervision  of  completion  of  the   work,  not  for  the  contents.  

 

(3)

Abstract    

Since  the  economic  reforms  of  China,  the  Chinese  economy  shifted  from  a  planned  to  a  market-­‐ oriented  economy.  Real  wages,  labour  productivity  and  unemployment  represent  an  important   connection  within  labour  markets  and  the  economic  reforms  caused  big  changes  in  these  variables.   There  are  many  economic  theories  that  state  that  there  is  a  relationship  between  the  variables.  The   connection  between  these  variables  received  a  sizable  amount  of  attention  in  other  countries,  but   not  in  China.  This  study  examines  the  relationship  between  wages,  productivity  and  unemployment   in  China  through  time.  Time  series  econometric  methods  show  that  there  is  a  long-­‐run  equilibrium   relationship  between  real  wages  and  productivity,  and  that  productivity  positively  causes  real  wages   in  the  short-­‐run,  which  is  supported  by  the  marginal  productivity  theory.  

   

(4)

 

Content    

1.  Introduction                     5   2.  History                     8       2.1       The  Chinese  economic  reforms             8     2.1.1     Unemployment                 8     2.1.2     Wages                   10     2.1.3   Productivity                 11     3.  Literature  review                   13  

    3.1     Wage  equation                 13  

    3.2       Literature  review  about  the  wage-­‐productivity-­‐unemployment  nexus     13  

    3.3       Findings  of  other  studies             16   4.  Methodology                   18   5.  Data                       21       5.1       Defining  the  variables               21       5.2       Data  information               22   6.  Results                       24       6.1       Preliminary  data  analysis             24       6.2       Cointegration  test  for  1980  –  2009             27       6.3     Cointegration  between  wages  and  productivity,  1994  –  2009       31   7.  Conclusion                     34   8.  References                     36   9.  Appendix                     38  

(5)

1.  Introduction  

More  than  30  years  ago,  China  started  the  long  process  of  embracing  free-­‐market  principles.  China   achieved  a  gross  domestic  product  (GDP)  growth  from  226  dollar  per  capita  to  6091  dollar  per  capita   in  the  period  from  1978  until  2012.  China’s  export  has  grown  about  13.6%  per  year  from  1980  to   2000,  which  is  very  remarkable  since  the  world  average  export  growth  per  year  was  5.9%  over  the   same  period  (Yue  and  Hua,  2002).  The  export  growth  of  manufacturing  goods  was  even  higher,   namely  18.8%.  In  the  period  from  2000  to  2005,  manufacturing  accounted  for  89%  of  China’s   merchandise  exports  and  32%  of  its  GDP.  This  made  China  more  specialized  in  the  manufacturing   sector  than  other  large  developing  economies  (Hanson  and  Robertson,  2008)1.  China  has  become  a  

major  source  of  supply  in  labour-­‐intensive  manufacturing  goods  and  China  has  a  comparative  

advantage  in  producing  these  goods,  which  ensures  that  world  product  prices  are  pushed  down  (Goh   and  Wong,  2010).    

 

China  is  now  called  the  world  second  largest  economy  and  the  “Reform  and  Opening  Up”  policy,   which  started  in  1978,  was  a  significant  turning  point  that  contributed  to  this  current  position.  The   economic  reforms  of  China  during  this  period  contributed  to  the  fact  that  China’s  economy  moved   from  a  planned  to  a  market-­‐oriented  economy  (Lin,  Cai,  &  Li,  1996).  The  shift  to  this  economy   contributed  to  a  better  exploitation  of  the  comparative  advantage  of  China  in  labour-­‐intensive   manufacturing  (Lin,  Cai,  &  Li,  1996).    

 

The  increased  Chinese  trade  has  led  to  higher  labour  productivity  in  China  (Young,  2000).  Significant   changes  in  the  structure  of  wages  and  the  labour  market  have  occurred  in  the  last  twenty  years   because  of  the  economic  reforms  (Yueh,  2004).  These  changes  caused  that  wages,  labour   productivity  and  unemployment  changed  a  lot  through  time.  Labour  productivity  increased  a  lot   because  of  the  growth  of  the  manufacturing  GDP,  wages  increased  in  the  last  15  years  and   unemployment  also  made  a  lot  of  changes.  There  has  been  a  political  debate  about  the  impact  of   globalization  on  the  developed  world  economies.  Low  wages  and  rapid  increases  in  productivity  in   “emerging”  economies  like  China  are  putting  high  wage  countries  at  a  cost  disadvantage  (Krugman,   Melitz  &  Obstfeld,  2012).    

    Real  wages,  productivity  and  unemployment  represent  an  important  connection  within   labour  markets  and  it  received  a  sizable  amount  of  attention  in  the  literature.  There  have  been  put   forward  many  economic  theories  that  state  that  there  is  a  relationship  between  these  variables.  An   example  of  such  a  theory  is  the  efficiency  wage  hypothesis,  which  is  a  theory  about  the  relationship  

(6)

between  wages  and  productivity  (Gärtner,  2009).  Conventional  economic  theory  suggests  that  higher   productivity  in  firms  is  rewarded  with  higher  wages,  but  conversely  the  efficiency  wage  hypothesis   proposes  that  higher  wages  cause  greater  productivity  (Wakeford,  2004).  This  proofs  that  

theoretically  the  causal  relationship  between  wages  and  productivity  is  interpreted  in  different  ways.   This  makes  the  development  of  real  wages  and  unemployment  and  the  strong  surge  in  productivity   in  China  an  interesting  case  to  re-­‐examine  the  relationship  between  wages,  productivity  and   unemployment.  Because  China  is  highly  specialized  in  the  manufacturing  sector  and  this  made   China’s  emergence  potentially  disruptive  (Hanson  and  Robertson,  2008),  the  focus  in  this  thesis  will   be  on  the  manufacturing  sector.    

 

This  leads  to  the  following  research  question:    

"How  did  the  relationship  between  wages,  productivity  and  unemployment  in  China  behave  through   time?"    

This  thesis  will  look  at  how  the  productivity-­‐wage-­‐unemployment  relationship  in  China  moves  over   time  and  how  this  relationship  reacts  to  the  economic  reforms.  To  do  this  macro-­‐economic  data  for   China  from  1980  to  2009  will  be  used.    

 

In  this  thesis,  the  relationship  between  productivity,  wages  and  unemployment  will  be  examined  by   applying  time-­‐series  econometric  methods.  There  will  be  a  focus  on  several  sub-­‐questions  in  order  to   assess  the  research  question.  First,  there  will  be  examined  if  there  is  evidence  of  structural  breaks   and  trends,  which  will  be  identified  by  plots  of  real  wages,  productivity  and  unemployment.  From   this  we  can  examine  if  the  variables  are  responsive  to  the  economic  reforms  mentioned  above.   Second,  there  will  be  looked  at  if  there  is  a  long-­‐term  equilibrium  (co-­‐integrating)  relationship   between  real  wages,  unemployment  and  productivity.  Thirdly,  there  will  be  examined  if  a  Granger   causality  test  enlightens  the  short-­‐term  directions  of  causality  between  the  variables.  Based  on  the   results  arising  from  the  analysis,  this  thesis  discloses  how  and  to  what  extent  the  real  wage,   productivity  and  unemployment  affect  each  other.    

 

Section  2  contains  the  history  of  the  Chinese  economic  reforms.  In  section  3,  the  literature  review,   attention  will  be  paid  to  a  couple  of  things.  The  section  will  begin  with  a  review  of  the  labour  market   theories  about  the  relationship  between  wages,  productivity  and  unemployment  together  with  a   discussion  of  the  possible  causal  relationships  between  wages,  unemployment  and  productivity.  A   selection  of  previous  empirical  research  about  the  relationship  between  these  variables  in  other   countries  will  follow.  Section  4,  the  methodology,  outlines  the  method  that  will  be  used  in  this  thesis.   Section  5,  the  data  section,  first  pays  attention  to  the  definitions  of  the  three  variables  and  then  

(7)

describes  the  data  that  will  be  used.  Section  6,  the  results,  analyses  the  data,  reports  the  empirical   results  of  the  tests  that  have  been  used  and  will  state  the  interpretations  that  became  apparent.  In   section  7,  the  thesis  will  be  concluded  with  an  answer  to  the  research  question.  

 

(8)

2.  History  

This  section  discusses  a  history  of  the  Chinese  economy  that  outlines  the  movements  of  the  wage,   productivity  and  unemployment  through  time  caused  by  the  economic  reforms  of  China  according  to   the  literature.  Figure  1  gives  an  overview  of  all  the  events  during  the  economic  reforms  that  are   relevant  for  the  discussion  of  the  wage,  productivity  and  unemployment  over  time.  

 

2.1  The  Chinese  economic  reforms  

In  the  period  between  1978  and  1998,  the  GDP  per  capita  in  China  grew  8%  per  year.  This  

performance  makes  that  China  is  the  most  rapidly  growing  economy  during  this  period  in  the  world   (Young,  2000).  These  rapid  economic  developments  were  caused  by  economic  reforms  to  a  great   extent.  In  December  1978,  at  the  third  plenum  of  the  eleventh  central  committee,  the  authorities  of   China  decided  to  make  the  development  of  the  economy  a  top  priority  (Yueh,  2004).  The  economic   reform  program  that  they  started  was  initiated  to  seek  welfare  gain  and  to  tackle  urgent  problems   such  as  the  inefficiency  of  the  planned  economy  (Cai  &  Wang,  2010).  It  led  to  a  transition  to  an   economy  that  is  market-­‐oriented  (Liu,  2012).  The  reform  program  was  characterized  by  the  four   modernizations  of  industry,  agriculture,  national  defence,  and  science  and  technology  (Yueh,  2004).           The  entry  of  China  into  the  World  Trade  Organization  (WTO)  in  2001  was  accompanied  by  an   increase  in  key  economic  indicators  such  as  the  GDP  (Lee  &  Warner,  2007).  

     

2.1.1  Unemployment  

The  high  growth  of  the  GDP  during  the  reforms  was  accompanied  by  increasing  unemployment  rates   (Liu,  2012),  as  will  become  clear  in  this  part.      

 

    Before  1978,  in  the  planned  economy  of  China,  three  key  components  characterized  the   employment  system.  First,  the  government  allocated  the  labour  force  by  intervention  in  the  overall   urban  employment  to  secure  that  urban  workers  had  stable  and  life-­‐long  employment  (Cai  &  Wang,   2010).  Enterprises  were  not  allowed  to  choose  their  own  employees  and  employees  were  not   allowed  to  choose  their  own  jobs  (Liu,  1998).  Once  a  worker  was  allocated  to  a  job,  he  did  not  have  a   chance  to  switch  jobs  and  he  also  could  not  be  dismissed,  so  there  was  no  fear  of  unemployment,   which  is  why  unemployment  rates  before  the  reforms  in  urban  areas  were  low  (Liu,  1998).           The  second  component  that  characterized  the  employment  system  before  1978  is  the   household  registration  (hukou)  system  (Cai  &  Wang,  2010).  This  system  separates  the  labour  and  the   population  of  China  between  urban  and  rural  areas.  This  harms  the  functioning  of  the  integrated   labour  market,  because  fewer  rural  surplus  workers  than  was  expected  were  absorbed  by  the  

(9)

(industry-­‐oriented)  economic  growth  because  of  the  restriction  between  urban  and  rural  areas  (Cai  &   Wang,  2010).    

    Third,  the  employment  system  of  China  before  the  reforms  was  characterized  by  a  host  of   welfare  policies  (such  as  urban  exclusive  social  security  policy),  which  deterred  the  labour  mobility   and  the  equal  treatment  of  the  population  between  urban  and  rural  areas  (Cai  &  Wang,  2010).     These  three  institutional  arrangements  had  a  negative  effect  on  the  efficiency  of  the  employment   allocation  (Cai  &  Wang,  2010).    

 

From  1978,  labour  mobility  increased  because  of  the  economic  reforms  (Liu,  1998).  This  was  

implemented  by:  1)  reducing  the  role  of  the  government  in  the  allocation  of  labour  and  2)  setting  up   a  new  employment  system  that  was  based  on  contracts  (Liu,  1998).    

    First,  the  labour  reform  program  with  the  aim  of  increasing  labour  mobility  reduced  the   influence  of  the  state  regarding  labour  allocation  (Liu,  1998).  This  was  done  by  providing  general   guidelines  and  by  leaving  the  allocation  to  other  agencies  such  as  the  enterprises  themselves  or  to   labour  service  companies  (Liu,  1998).  From  the  mid  1980s,  enterprises  have  been  legitimated  to   select  and  dismiss  workers.  With  this  change  and  with  increasing  competition  pressure,  employment   has  become  more  market-­‐oriented  (Fang  &  Zhao,  2009).    

    Second,  the  new  system  that  was  based  on  contracts  was  implemented.  It  began  by   implementing  the  contract  responsibility  system.  During  the  economic  reforms,  this  system  was   implemented  into  the  rural  areas  at  the  end  of  the  1970s  (Cai  &  Wang,  2010).  Individual  households   and  local  managers  were  held  responsible  for  the  profits  and  losses  of  their  enterprise  by  contracting   the  former  collective-­‐owned  land  to  them  (Cai  &  Wang,  2010).  This  caused  improving  incentives  in   the  rural  sector,  which  was  accompanied  by  a  labour  surplus  in  this  area.  As  a  result,  many  labourers   migrated  from  rural  to  urban  areas.    

    In  1983,  the  contract  responsibility  system  was  implemented  in  the  state  enterprises.  This   was  the  most  significant  labour  reform  program  that  was  investigated  in  the  study  of  Liu  (1998).   Under  this  system,  the  contract  between  the  enterprise  and  the  employee  had  to  meet  all  kinds  of   conditions  such  as  the  duration  of  the  agreement  and  the  wages.  On  the  expiration  date  both  parties   could  decide  either  to  renew  the  contract  or  to  end  the  agreement.  This  has  strengthened  the   powers  of  managers  over  their  work  force  but  it  also  has  given  freedom  to  the  workers  to  quit  their   job  and  to  find  other  employment  opportunities.    

    In  1986,  the  Temporary  Regulations  on  Labour  Contract  System  of  State-­‐owned  Enterprises   was  issued  by  the  administration.  All  State  Owned  Enterprises  (SOEs)  were  required  to  recruit  new   workers  based  on  voluntary  contracts.  Under  this  new  system,  workers  were  to  be  contracted  and  

(10)

    During  the  reforms,  the  restrictive  regulations  and  welfare  policies  mentioned  before  were   removed,  which  increased  labour  mobility  since  the  1980s  (Cai  &  Wang,  2010).    

 

The  changes  in  the  policy  during  the  reforms  mentioned  above  have  had  impact  on  the  labour   market  and  unemployment  rates  in  the  last  three  decades  (Liu,  2012).    

    One  factor  that  contributed  to  the  high  unemployment  rates  in  the  beginning  of  the  

economic  reforms  is  the  inflow  of  people  from  rural  areas  who  were  seeking  jobs  in  urban  areas  (Liu,   2012).  The  inflow  of  people  was  caused  by  the  labour  surplus  and  thus  unemployment  in  the  rural   sector  because  of  the  contract  responsibility  system.  Liu  (2012)  confirmed  that  urban  unemployment   has  risen  strongly  between  1988  and  2002.      

    Unemployment  started  to  rise  from  the  mid  1980s  because  enterprises  were  legitimated  to   dismiss  workers  and  all  SOEs  were  required  to  recruit  new  workers  based  on  voluntary  contracts.   Under  this  new  system,  workers  were  to  be  contracted  and  re-­‐chosen  on  the  basis  of  their   performance  (Fang  &  Zhao,  2009).  This  caused  that  a  lot  of  workers  were  dismissed.    

    Another  factor  that  had  major  impact  on  the  labour  market  and  unemployment  is  the   massive  layoff  of  workers  in  the  urban  areas  due  to  the  retrenchment  reform  in  the  state-­‐owned   sector  (Liu,  2012).  The  restructuring  and  the  privatization  of  urban  collective-­‐owned  and  state-­‐owned   enterprises  caused  declining  numbers  of  manufacturing  workers  (because  of  the  layoffs)  (Banister,   2005).  In  this  sector  there  were  high  deficits,  which  caused  that  many  SOEs  went  bankrupt  in  the   1990s  (Liu,  2012).  This  was  a  reason  for  the  government  to  initiate  the  retrenchment  reform.  This   urban  radical  reform  was  intended  to  solve  the  inefficiency  problem  in  the  state  sector  and  this  was   done  by  the  layoff  of  approximately  a  quarter  of  the  workers  in  this  sector  in  the  period  between   1997  and  2000.  The  laying  off  of  workers  was  accompanied  by  unemployment  and  a  decline  in  urban   employment  (Cai  &  Wang,  2010).    

 

The  East  Asian  financial  crisis  in  the  end  of  1997  also  had  a  negative  impact  on  the  Chinese  economy,   which  was  experiencing  a  downturn,  in  turn  causing  managers  to  lay  off  a  lot  of  workers  (Cai  &   Wang,  2010),  which  contributed  to  the  rise  of  the  unemployment  rate.    

 

2.1.2  Wages  

An  important  part  of  the  reforms  was  the  reform  program  that  aimed  to  improve  the  linking  of  wage   levels  with  enterprise  and  individual  performance  (Liu,  1998).  Since  1978,  there  have  been  a  few  sets   of  reforms  regarding  wages,  specifically  in  1985,  1992,  1994  and  1996  (Yueh,  2004).    

 

(11)

redistributed  by  the  state  (Yueh,  2004).  Wages  and  bonuses  were  unrelated  to  the  individual  and   enterprise  performance  (Liu,  1998).  Because  of  this,  there  was  little  incentive  to  be  profitable,  so  it   reduced  the  motivation  and  initiative  of  employers,  which  in  turn  caused  low  productivity.    

    In  1985,  the  Ministry  of  Labour  determined  that  there  was  going  to  be  a  link  between  wages   and  the  economic  performance  of  collectively  owned  enterprises  and  state-­‐owned  enterprises.  The   economic  performance  of  these  enterprises  was  to  be  measured  by  enterprise  profitability  or  by  a   combined  indicator  of  economic  returns  (Yueh,  2004).  The  goal  of  linking  wages  to  the  economic   performance  was  to  provide  incentives  that  were  profit-­‐oriented  (Liu,  1998).    

    After  this,  in  1992,  the  State  Council  of  China  permitted  enterprises  to  set  their  own  wage   structure  if  these  structures  were  within  the  boundary  of  the  overall  wage  budget  that  the   government  had  established  (Yueh,  2004).  The  introduction  of  a  new  Labour  Law  in  1994  gave   management  more  discretion  over  wage  determination.  Because  of  these  reforms,  the  share  of   bonuses  in  total  wages  rose  for  all  enterprises  (Brooks  &  Tao,  2003).  Also  in  1994,  publicly  listed   companies  were  allowed  to  set  their  own  wages,  but  subject  to  standards  determined  by  the   government  (Yueh,  2004).    

    In  1996,  the  floating  wage  system  was  introduced,  which  was  part  of  the  five-­‐year  plan  that   ran  from  1996  until  2000.  This  was  the  most  widely  reform  program  that  was  implemented  to  better   link  wages  and  performance  (Liu,  1998).  Wages  are  since  then  divided  in  two  components:  fixed  and   variable  wage.  The  variable  wage  includes  bonuses,  which  are  based  on  both  enterprise  profitability   and  individual  productivity  (Yueh,  2004).  

 

Furthermore,  the  non-­‐state  sector  has  grown  since  the  economic  reforms.  This  has  created  

employment  opportunities  in  this  sector  (Liu,  1998).  The  enterprises  in  this  sector  have  actively  tried   to  recruit  managerial  and  technical  workers  from  state-­‐owned  enterprises  that  are  highly  skilled.   They  did  this  by  offering  higher  wages  and  salaries  compared  to  the  state-­‐owned  enterprises.  This   caused  that  many  state-­‐owned  firms  lost  valuable  personnel  to  the  non-­‐state  sector.  This  is  why  the   state-­‐owned  enterprises  were  under  high  pressure  to  increase  their  wages  and  salaries  (Liu,  1998).         Liu  (1998)  found  positive  and  significant  relationships  between  the  reform  programs   mentioned  above  and  earnings,  which  indicates  that  the  programs  have  increased  earnings.      

2.1.3  Productivity    

While  in  the  past,  economic  growth  was  expressed  through  large  inputs  of  new  labour  and  capital   into  the  production  process,  during  the  economic  reforms  the  government  rather  wanted  to  achieve   growth  through  gains  in  productivity  (Kuan,  Hongchang  &  Yuxin,  1988).  Between  1978  and  1988,  

(12)

include  agriculture,  retail  commerce,  personal  services  and  small-­‐scale  manufacturing  operations   that  are  controlled  by  individuals  and  collectives  (Kuan  et  al.,  1988).    

    The  economic  reforms  in  the  late  1970s,  which  resulted  in  the  miraculous  growth,  have   attracted  the  attention  of  many  economists.  The  change  in  labour  productivity  caused  by  a  series  of   technological  and  institutional  changes  that  resulted  from  the  economic  reforms  has  been  crucial   and  controversial  (Wu,  1995).  Major  efforts  have  been  made  to  examine  what  the  role  of  

productivity  and  efficiency  was  in  this  economic  growth  to  investigate  whether  this  growth  is   sustainable  or  not  (Wu,  2000).    

    Productivity  growth  can  be  seen  as  the  sum  of  technological  progress  and  technical  efficiency   change  (Wu,  2000).  Technical  efficiency  change  refers  to  catching  up  on  the  frontier  (i.e.  

improvement  in  efficiency),  which  means  increasing  efficiency  with  the  existing  resources  that  are   utilised  in  production.  Technological  progress  refers  to  shifts  in  the  frontier  (i.e.  innovation).  The   economic  reforms  aimed  to  improve  the  technical  efficiency.  Centrally  planned  economies,  like  the   Chinese  economy  was  before  the  reforms,  often  produce  below  their  best  practice  outputs.  The  shift   to  a  market-­‐oriented  economy  aimed  to  raise  the  production  close  to  the  frontier,  so  it  increased   productivity  (Wu,  2000).  According  to  international  standards,  planned  economies  have  faced  low   levels  of  technological  progress,  so  again  the  shift  of  a  planned  to  a  market-­‐oriented  economy   contributed  to  the  stimulation  of  innovation  (Wu,  2000).  

    Empirical  studies  about  East  Asian  economies  have  been  paying  attention  to  the  contribution   of  labour  productivity  to  the  economic  growth  of  the  country.  According  to  Kuan,  Hongchang  and   Yuxin  (1998),  there  can  be  seen  a  mild  trend  in  productivity  through  time,  with  an  upward  break  that   coincides  with  the  efforts  of  the  economic  reforms  starting  in  1978.  Banister  (2005)  argues  that  sharp   increases  in  manufacturing  labour  productivity  ensued  from  the  restructuring  and  privatization  of   state-­‐owned  and  urban  collective-­‐owned  enterprises  because  those  reorganized  enterprises  are   competitive  in  the  domestic  and  global  economies.  

 

        Figure  1:  timeline  Chinese  economic  reforms   1978:  Start  

economic   reforms  

End  1970s:  contract   responsibility  system  

in  rural  areas  

Begin  1980s:   regulation  of   government  

1983:  contract   responsiblity   system  in  state  

enterprises   -­‐1985:  linking   wages  and   performance   -­‐1986:  SOEs   dismissed   workers   1992:   enterprises   set  own   wages   1994:  publicly   listed   companies  set   own  wages   1996:   Gloating   wage   system   1997:  East   Asian   Financial   crisis   2001:   entry   into   WTO  

(13)

3.  Literature  review  

This  section  gives  a  review  about  the  wage-­‐productivity-­‐unemployment  relationship.  It  first  discusses   the  wage  equation  and  then  the  possible  different  causal  relationships  between  labour  productivity,   real  wages  and  unemployment.  The  section  ends  with  a  part  that  pays  attention  to  the  findings  of   other  studies  about  the  wage-­‐productivity-­‐unemployment  nexus  in  other  countries.  

 

3.1  Wage  equation  

In  recent  literature  about  the  wage-­‐productivity-­‐unemployment  nexus,  wage  equations  have  been   derived.  According  to  these  different  wage  equations,  productivity  is  not  the  only  factor  that   influences  wages.  Wages  are  also  influenced  by  other  factors,  for  example  unemployment  (Goh  &   Wong,  2010).  The  following  specification  is  suggested  by  Blanchard  &  Katz  (1999):    

𝑙𝑛𝑤!− 𝑙𝑛𝑝!! = 𝛼 + 𝛽𝑙𝑛𝑝𝑟𝑜𝑑!+ 𝜆 𝑙𝑛𝑤!!!− 𝑙𝑛𝑝!!! + 𝛾𝑢!+ 𝜀!.  

In  this  formula,  𝑤!  is  the  nominal  wage  rate  in  time  t  and  𝑝!  is  the  price  level,  where  𝑝!!  is  the  

expected  price  level  in  time.  𝑝𝑟𝑜𝑑!  Is  the  level  of  productivity  and  𝑢!  is  the  unemployment  rate.  The  

lagged  term  of  real  wage  is  expressed  as  𝑤!!!− 𝑝!!!  and  proxies  for  the  expected  term  of  real  wage  

𝑤!− 𝑝!!  (Blanchard  &  Katz,  1999).  The  coefficient  on  𝑢

!  is  expected  to  be  negative  because  a  high  

unemployment  rate  will  cause  the  wages  to  decrease,  as  will  become  clear  from  the  literature  review   about  the  wage-­‐productivity-­‐unemployment  nexus.  The  coefficient  on  𝑝𝑟𝑜𝑑!  is  expected  to  be  

positive.    

3.2  Literature  review  about  the  wage-­‐productivity-­‐unemployment  nexus  

In  recent  international  macroeconomic  literature  there  are  several  economic  theories  that  justify  a   relationship  between  wages,  unemployment  and  productivity.  The  efficiency  wage  theory,  the   marginal  productivity  theory  and  the  wage  bargaining  theory  argue  that  there  is  a  causal  relationship   between  the  variables.  On  the  other  hand,  the  insider-­‐outsider  approach  casts  doubt  on  a  direct   relationship  between  wages  and  unemployment.  Table  1  summarizes  the  hypothesized  causal   relations  between  the  variables.    

 

3.2.1  Relationship  between  wages  and  productivity     Efficiency  wage  theory    

The  efficiency  wage  theory  states  that  real  wages  positively  affect  productivity  (Alexander,  1993).   The  theory  rests  on  the  assumption  that  workers  are  more  efficient  (i.e.  productive)  when  they   receive  higher  wages  (Gärtner,  2009).  There  are  various  arguments  that  explain  why  the  efficiency   and  hence  labour  productivity  may  increase  when  real  wages  rise,  such  as  shirking,  and  turnover   (Gärtner,  2009).    

(14)

    When  employees  are  getting  caught  shirking  and  are  getting  fired  because  of  this,  this  is  not   really  a  punishment  as  long  as  the  firm  pays  the  market  clearing  wage,  because  the  employee  can   find  a  job  with  the  same  wage  elsewhere  (Gärtner,  2009).  The  rise  of  the  firm’s  wage  rate  above  the   market  wage  will  provide  an  incentive  to  reduce  shirking  and  in  turn  to  increase  productivity.         Labour  turnover,  which  is  the  exchange  of  incumbent  workers  for  unemployed  outsiders,  is   costly  to  firms.  Those  costs  include  for  example  hiring  and  firing  activities  and  on-­‐the-­‐job  training  for   new  workers.  If  the  probability  that  a  worker  quits  is  negatively  related  to  the  real  wage,  than  firms   may  profit  from  paying  a  higher  wage  than  other  firms  because  they  face  lower  turnover  costs   (Gärtner,  2009).      

    If  real  wages  rise,  higher  productivity  will  be  established  because  higher  wages  raise  the  costs   of  job  loss  (Wakeford,  2004).  So  according  to  the  efficiency  wage  theory,  by  paying  their  employees  a   higher  wage,  firms  can  increase  the  efficiency  or  productivity  of  their  employees.    

    Because  the  cost  of  labour  (i.e.  the  sum  of  all  wages  paid  to  employees,  including  the  cost  of   employee  benefits  and  payroll  taxes  paid  by  the  employer)  will  rise  when  wages  increase,  the  threat   of  increasing  unemployment  (as  a  result  of  factor  substitution  from  labour  to  capital)  and  in  turn  the   threat  of  being  fired  will  also  stimulate  workers  to  be  more  efficient  (Alexander,  1993).  Goh  and   Wong  (2010)  argue  that  high  wages  will  strengthen  the  employment  relationship  in  the  long-­‐term,   which  leads  to  loyalty  from  employees  to  employers  and  hence  to  higher  effort.    

 

Insider-­‐outsider  approach  

In  contrast  to  the  efficiency  wage  theory,  the  insider-­‐outsider  approach  does  not  assume  that  wages   directly  affect  productivity  and  unemployment  (Goh  &  Wong,  2010).  The  insider-­‐outsider  approach   rests  on  the  assumption  that  insiders  are  incumbent  workers  who  have  more  advantageous   employment  opportunities  than  the  outsiders  (Dobbie,  2005).  Outsiders  are  those  currently  out  of   employment  but  who  are  seeking  employment  (Gärtner,  2009).  The  idea  is  that  insiders  resist   competition  with  outsiders  (i.e.  potential  new  employees)  in  wage  setting,  because  they  refuse  to   cooperate  with  outsiders  if  they  try  to  underbid  the  wages  of  the  insiders.  The  theory  argues  that,   because  of  turnover  costs  and  specific  knowhow  that  can  only  be  acquired  within  the  firm,  insiders   are  able  to  extract  a  higher  wage  than  the  wage  for  which  outsiders  are  willing  to  work  (Gärtner,   2009).  The  impact  on  the  employment  is  that  this  behaviour  will  ensure  that  there  is  absence  of   wage  underbidding  while  there  are  outsiders  who  are  unemployed  and  are  willing  to  work  for  a   lower  wage.  Because  insides  have  the  power  to  ensure  that  there  is  absence  of  wage  underbidding,   this  theory  does  not  assume  a  direct  effect  of  wages  on  productivity  and  unemployment.    

(15)

Marginal  productivity  theory  

The  marginal  productivity  theory  states  that  the  higher  the  labour  productivity  of  the  worker,  the   higher  the  worker  is  paid  (Goh  &  Wong,  2010).  When  individuals’  pay  is  performance  related,  wages   will  rise  if  productivity  increases,  so  this  will  result  in  a  positive  causality  from  productivity  to  wages   (Alexander,  1993).    

 

Besides  these  theories,  if  labour  unions  are  bargaining  for  increases  in  the  real  wage  on  the  basis  of   improvements  in  productivity  in  the  past,  wages  will  also  rise  if  the  past  changes  in  productivity  were   positive.    

 

3.2.2  Relationship  between  productivity  and  unemployment  

Changes  in  labour  productivity  may  cause  increases  but  also  reductions  in  the  unemployment  rate,   i.e.  the  effect  is  ambiguous  (Wakeford,  2004).  If  productivity  rises,  the  demand  for  labour  could   reduce  because  greater  efficiency  in  the  workforce  will  ensure  that  less  labour  is  needed  to  produce   the  same  output.  Assuming  that  other  factors  that  affect  unemployment  remain  constant,  this  will   cause  an  increase  in  the  unemployment  rate.  On  the  other  hand,  when  productivity  rises,  the  impact   on  the  employment  can  be  positive  because  of  the  output  effect  (Alexander,  1993).  This  means  that   the  unemployment  rate  will  decrease  because  workers  create  more  output  which  in  turn  creates   more  employment  (Wakeford,  2004).    

    The  impact  of  unemployment  on  productivity  is  hypothesized  to  be  positive,  because  a   higher  unemployment  rate  may  be  associated  with  higher  effort  and  hence  higher  average   productivity  among  the  workers  that  will  remain  (Wakeford,  2004).  

 

3.2.3  Relationship  between  wages  and  unemployment   Wage  bargaining  theory  

The  effect  of  unemployment  on  the  real  wage  can  be  explained  by  the  wage  bargaining  theory.  The   unemployment  rate  affects  wages  because  of  changes  in  bargaining  power  (Alexander,  1993).  When   the  unemployment  rate  rises  because  of  other  factors  than  wage  and  productivity,  union  bargaining   power  is  expected  to  weaken  (Wakeford,  2004).  This  in  turn  will  cause  real  wages  to  decrease.      

Marginal  productivity  theory  

The  unemployment  rate  will  also  affect  wages  by  incentivise  workers  to  increase  effort  to  secure   their  jobs  if  the  unemployment  rate  rises  (Wakeford,  2004).  If  the  workers’  effort  and  hence   productivity  rises  (according  to  this  theory),  wages  are  expected  to  increase.    

(16)

Efficiency  wage  theory  

The  efficiency  wage  theory  states  that  when  real  wages  rise,  factor  substitution  will  occur  from   labour  to  capital,  which  in  turn  will  cause  a  higher  unemployment  rate  (Goh  &  Wong,  2010).  

Involuntary  unemployment  is  also  explained  by  the  efficiency  wage  theory.  Involuntary  unemployed   workers  are  willing  to  work  at  a  lower  wage  than  the  market-­‐clearing  wage  (Yellen,  1984).  But  when   lower  wages  are  paid,  the  productivity  of  the  employees  who  are  already  working  will  become  lower   (according  to  this  theory),  which  is  why  firms  will  not  lower  the  wages  (Yellen,  1984).  

Causal  relation                                                                            Effect                                                                            Reason  

Real  wages  à  productivity   Positive   Efficiency  wage  theory  

Real  wages  à  unemployment   Positive   Higher  labour  costs  will  cause  substitution  from   labour  to  capital  

Productivity  à  real  wages   Positive   (1)  Marginal  productivity  theory:  payment  based  on   performance  

(2)  Bargaining  

Productivity  à  unemployment   Positive  

Negative  

Less  labour  is  needed  to  produce  the  same  output   Output  effect  

Unemployment  à  productivity   Positive   Increase  effort  to  secure  jobs  

Unemployment  à  real  wages   Negative   Wage  bargaining  theory:  rise  in  unemployment  will   weaken  bargaining  power  

Table  1:  Hypothesized  causal  relations  between  the  variables  

 

3.3  Findings  of  other  studies  

Goh  and  Wong  (2010)  examined  whether  there  exists  a  relationship  between  productivity,  wages   and  unemployment  in  Malaysia.  Their  main  findings  show  that  unemployment  is  separated  from  the   equilibrium  relationship  in  the  long  run  between  real  wages  and  labour  productivity,  so  there  exists  a   long-­‐run  equilibrium  (cointegrating)  relationship  between  real  wages  and  labour  productivity  in  the   period  from  1970  to  2005.  They  found  that  labour  productivity  is  a  meaningful  long-­‐run  factor  in   determining  wages,  while  the  effect  of  unemployment  on  the  real  wage  rates  in  negligible.  Real   wages  are  very  responsive  to  a  change  in  productivity  in  Malaysia  (the  productivity  elasticity  of  real   wages  is  greater  than  1).  They  found  that  in  the  long  run,  for  every  1  per  cent  rise  in  labour  

productivity,  real  wages  rise  by  1,223  per  cent.    

    Goh  and  Wong  (2010)  also  found  that  productivity  Granger  causes  real  wages  (in  the  short   run),  which  supports  the  marginal  productivity  theory.  In  their  study,  changes  in  productivity  are  not   immediately  reflected  in  the  real  wages,  which  can  be  seen  by  the  relatively  long  lags  that  they  used.       Conversely,  the  real  wage  has  no  impact  on  productivity  in  the  short  run.    

(17)

Jeremy  Wakeford  (2004)  investigated  the  relationship  between  real  wages,  labour  productivity  and   the  unemployment  rate  in  South  Africa  between  1983  and  2002.  He  found  strong  evidence  of  a  break   in  1990.  After  this  year,  all  the  variables  increased  rapidly.  He  found  a  long-­‐term  equilibrium  

(cointegrating)  relationship  between  real  wages  and  labour  productivity  for  the  period  1983-­‐2002,   but  unemployment  was  not  connected  to  the  system.  There  is  also  strong  evidence  found  by   Wakeford  that  productivity  and  real  wages  are  cointegrated  in  the  period  between  1990  and  2002.         The  long-­‐term  wage-­‐productivity  elasticity  that  is  found  in  this  study  is  0,58,  so  a  1  per  cent   rise  in  productivity  is  accompanied  with  a  0,58  per  cent  rise  in  real  wages.  This  indicates  that   productivity  has  grown  faster  than  wages  in  South  Africa.  

Wakeford  found  the  following  dynamic  (short-­‐term)  causal  relationships:  real  wages  Granger-­‐cause   productivity  negatively.  Productivity  does  not  Granger-­‐cause  real  wages,  so  productivity  has  no  effect     on  real  wages  in  the  short  term.    

 

Alexander  (1993)  used  time  series  methods  to  analyse  the  relationship  between  unemployment,  real   wages  and  productivity  in  the  United  Kingdom  for  the  period  between  1955-­‐1991.    

The  results  of  this  study  show  evidence  of  a  structural  break  in  the  late  1970’s.  Before  1979,  the   central  variable  was  unemployment,  which  was  caused  by  both  productivity  and  real  wages.   Unemployment  was  cointegrated  with  wages  and  (separately)  with  productivity.  There  was  a   negative  causality  from  wages  to  unemployment  but  conversely  there  was  no  causal  relationship   from  unemployment  to  wages.  Alexander  found  no  evidence  of  dynamic  (short-­‐term)  causality  from   wages  to  productivity  or  vice  versa  in  this  period.    

    In  the  period  from  1979  to  1991,  there  was  a  bivariate  causal  relationship  between  wages   and  productivity  and  unemployment  was  almost  divorced  from  the  system.  The  long-­‐run  wage   elasticity  of  productivity  was  about  0,50  in  this  period.  There  was  a  negative  causality  from  wages  to   productivity  (which  contradicts  the  efficiency  wage  theory).  Alexander  found  no  direct  relationship   between  wages  and  unemployment  for  the  period  1979-­‐1991.    

(18)

4.  Methodology  

In  this  thesis,  time  series  data  are  used.  Time  series  data  are  data  for  a  single  entity,  such  as  a  person,   a  firm  or  a  country  and  the  data  are  collected  at  multiple  time  periods  (Stock  &  Watson,  2012).  Time   series  data  can  be  used  to  examine  the  changes  of  variables  over  time  and  to  make  a  forecast  about   the  future  values  of  those  variables.  With  time  series  data  the  dynamic  causal  effects  between   variables  can  be  studied.    

 

Prior  in  performing  a  cointegration  test,  it  is  a  common  practice  to  determine  the  stationarity  of  the   time  series.  Stationarity  means  that  a  time  series  𝑌!  has  a  probability  distribution  that  does  not  

change  over  time  (Stock  &  Watson,  2012).  A  stationary  time  series  has  the  property  that  the  mean,   the  autocorrelation  and  the  variance  structure  do  not  change  over  time.  The  most  important  types  of   non-­‐stationarity  are  breaks  and  trends  (Stock  &  Watson,  2012).  A  trend  is  a  long-­‐term  persistent   movement  of  a  variable  through  time.  In  time  series,  there  can  be  seen  two  types  of  trends:  a   deterministic  and  a  stochastic  trend.  A  deterministic  trend  is  a  non-­‐random  function  of  time,   whether  a  stochastic  trend  varies  over  time  and  is  random.  A  deterministic  trend  can  be  a  linear   function  and  a  stochastic  trend  is  for  example  a  trend  that  exhibits  a  long-­‐lasting  period  of  increase   followed  by  a  long-­‐lasting  period  of  decrease  (Stock  &  Watson,  2012).  If  the  root  of  an  AR(p)  model   equals  1,  then  the  time  series  is  said  to  have  a  unit  root.  A  time  series  contains  a  stochastic  trend  if  it   has  a  unit  root.  A  break  is  another  type  of  non-­‐stationarity  and  it  arises  when  the  regression  function   changes  over  time.  If  the  variables  in  a  time  series  are  non-­‐stationary,  then  the  statistical  tests  can  be   unreliable.  

    A  series  that  is  stationary  and  does  not  have  a  stochastic  trend  is  integrated  of  order  zero:   I(0).  If  a  series  has  a  random  walk  trend,  then  the  series  is  integrated  of  order  one:  I(1).  It  means  that   the  series  has  a  unit  autoregressive  root  (i.e.  is  stationary  in  levels),  and  because  a  non-­‐stationary   series  needs  to  difference  for  it  to  be  stationary,  then  the  first  difference  of  the  variable  is  stationary.   If  the  first  difference  of  series  has  a  trend,  then  the  series  is  integrated  of  order  two:  I(2).  This  means   that  the  first  difference  of  the  variable  has  an  autoregressive  unit  root  and  the  second  difference  is   stationary.  So  in  general,  if  𝑌!  is  I(d),  then  𝑌!  is  integrated  of  order  d  and  𝑌!  must  be  differenced  d  

times  to  be  stationary  and  to  eliminate  the  stochastic  trend.  This  means  that  Δ!𝑌

!  is  stationary.  

    To  detect  trends  in  time  series,  several  methods  can  be  used.  An  informal  method  is  for   example  inspecting  a  plot  of  a  time  series  (Stock  &  Watson,  2012).  If  doubt  remains  from  this   method,  then  a  formal  method  can  be  used  to  test  the  hypothesis  that  there  is  a  stochastic  trend   against  the  alternative  hypothesis  that  there  is  no  stochastic  trend.  An  example  of  such  a  method  is   the  Augmented  Dickey-­‐Fuller  (ADF)  test.  This  test  is  an  augmented  version  of  the  Dickey-­‐Fuller  test   for  a  larger  set  of  time  series.  

 

(19)

 

If  two  or  more  time  series  variables  have  the  same  stochastic  trend  (i.e.  they  appear  to  have  a   common  trend),  this  is  referred  to  as  cointegration  (Stock  &  Watson,  2012).  If  this  is  the  case,   regression  analysis  can  reveal  long-­‐run  relationships  between  the  variables.  The  definition  of   cointegration  is  as  follows:  When  𝑋!  and  𝑌!  are  both  integrated  of  order  one,  then  if  for  the  

coefficient  𝜃,  𝑌!− 𝜃𝑋!  is  integrated  of  order  zero  (i.e.  is  stationary),  then  𝑋!  and  𝑌!  are  cointegrated  

and  𝜃  is  the  cointegrating  coefficient.    

    When  there  are  three  time  series  variables,  𝑤𝑎𝑔𝑒!,  𝑝𝑟𝑜𝑑!,  and  𝑢𝑛𝑒𝑚𝑝!,  then  they  are  

cointegrated  if  𝑤𝑎𝑔𝑒!− 𝜃!𝑝𝑟𝑜𝑑!− 𝜃!𝑢𝑛𝑒𝑚𝑝!  is  stationary.  When  there  are  three  time  series  

variables,  there  can  be  more  than  one  cointegrating  relationship.  A  test  for  multiple  cointegrating   relationships  is  the  Johansen  cointegration  test  (1988).  For  the  Johansen  test,  variables  must  be  non-­‐ stationary  at  level  but  stationary  in  first  differences  (Johansen,  1988).  This  test  determines  the   number  of  cointegrating  relations  of  a  Vector  Error  Correction  Model  (VECM).  For  this  test,  the  null   hypothesis  and  the  alternative  hypothesis  are  the  following:  

𝐻!: 𝑡ℎ𝑒𝑟𝑒  𝑎𝑟𝑒  𝑛𝑜  𝑚𝑜𝑟𝑒  𝑡ℎ𝑎𝑛  𝑟  𝑐𝑜𝑖𝑛𝑡𝑒𝑔𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑛𝑔  𝑟𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠     𝑣𝑠. 𝐻!: 𝑡ℎ𝑒𝑟𝑒  𝑎𝑟𝑒  𝑚𝑜𝑟𝑒  𝑡ℎ𝑎𝑛  𝑟  𝑐𝑜𝑖𝑛𝑡𝑒𝑔𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑛𝑔  𝑟𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠.  

If  a  cointegrating  relation  is  found,  then  a  VECM  can  be  estimated  to  account  for  the  long-­‐term   equilibrium  and  short-­‐term  dynamics  in  the  system  (Stock  &  Watson,  2012).  

 

An  application  of  the  F-­‐statistic  that  is  very  useful  is  to  test  if  the  lags  of  one  of  the  variables  have   predictive  content  that  is  useful,  above  and  beyond  the  other  variables  that  are  included  in  the  VAR   (Stock  &  Watson,  2012).  If  one  argues  that  a  variable  does  not  have  predictive  content,  then  this   corresponds  to  the  null  hypothesis  that  the  coefficients  on  all  of  the  values  (lags)  of  that  variable  are   zero.  The  Granger  causality  statistic  is  the  F-­‐statistic  testing  this  null  hypothesis  and  the  test  of  this   null  hypothesis  is  called  the  Granger  causality  test  (Stock  &  Watson,  2012).  Alexander  (1993,  p.  87):   “If  X  and  Y  are  two  jointly  covariance  stationary  processes,  then  X  is  said  to  ‘Granger  cause’  Y  if  past  Y   and  past  X  better  predicts  current  Y  than  past  Y  alone”.  So  if  X  granger  causes  Y,  then  X  is  said  to  be  a   useful  predictor  of  Y  (given  the  other  variables  in  the  regression).  However,  this  does  not  necessarily   mean  that  a  change  in  X  will  cause  a  subsequent  change  in  Y,  but  it  does  mean  that  the  past  values  of   X  are  useful  for  forecasting  the  changes  of  X  (beyond  that  contained  in  the  past  values  of  Y).  For  this   test,  the  null  hypothesis  and  the  alternative  hypothesis  are  the  following:    

𝐻!: 𝑛𝑜  𝐺𝑟𝑎𝑛𝑔𝑒𝑟  𝑐𝑎𝑢𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦   𝑙𝑎𝑔𝑠  𝑎𝑟𝑒  𝑗𝑜𝑖𝑛𝑡𝑙𝑦  𝑧𝑒𝑟𝑜  𝑣𝑠. 𝐻!: 𝐺𝑟𝑎𝑛𝑔𝑒𝑟  𝑐𝑎𝑢𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦  

 

The  productivity-­‐wage-­‐unemployment  nexus  will  be  investigated  as  follows.  First,  a  preliminary  data   analysis  will  present  some  graphs,  growth  rates  and  correlation  coefficients.  The  variables  are  plotted  

(20)

to  see  the  behaviour  of  the  wages,  unemployment  and  productivity  over  time.  When  the  variables   are  presented  graphically,  there  can  be  found  evidence  for  trends  and  breaks.    

    To  determine  the  stationarity  of  the  time  series  or  the  order  of  integration,  Augmented   Dickey-­‐Fuller  tests  are  applied  to  the  three  series  to  detect  trends  in  the  series.  

    After  a  preliminary  data  analysis,  assuming  that  the  variables  are  found  to  be  non-­‐stationary,   the  Johansen’s  multivariate  cointegration  test  will  be  applied.  This  procedure  starts  with  selecting  an   appropriate  lag  order  for  the  VAR  and  then  applies  trace  and  maximal  eigenvalue  tests  to  determine   the  number  of  cointegrating  vectors.    

    Finally,  to  determine  the  direction  of  dynamic  short-­‐term  causal  relationships  among  the   variables,  Granger  causality  tests  will  be  performed.    

    Tests  and  estimations  in  this  thesis  are  performed  using  STATA.      

(21)

5.  Data  

This  section  starts  with  defining  the  definitions  of  the  variables  and  then  discusses  information  about   the  data  that  are  used.  

 

5.1  Defining  the  variables   5.1.1  Defining  real  wages  

Real  wages  are  in  the  literature  defined  either  as  real  product  wages,  or  as  real  consumption  wages   (Wakeford,  2004).  We  speak  of  real  consumption  wages  when  nominal  wages  are  deflated  by  the   consumer  price  index  (CPI).  Wages  are  then  measured  in  terms  of  consumption  goods  (which  means   the  workers’  real  purchasing  power).  The  real  product  wage  is  the  wage  rate  in  terms  of  the  labour   cost  of  production  (Wakeford,  2004).  For  this  definition,  the  nominal  wage  is  deflated  by  the   producer  price  index  to  provide  a  measure  in  terms  of  output.      

    The  choice  between  real  consumption  wages  and  real  product  wages  depends  on  the   relationship  that  is  being  investigated.  If  the  concern  is  about  real  purchasing  power  of  the  workers,   it  is  the  most  appropriate  to  use  real  consumption  wages  as  wage  measure.  Following  the  study  by   Goh  and  Wong  (2010)  and  Alexander  (1993),  the  real  consumption  wage  is  used  in  this  thesis.   Because  the  focus  will  be  on  the  manufacturing  sector,  the  nominal  manufacturing  wage  is  deflated   by  the  consumer  price  index.  In  this  analysis,  the  average  real  wages  (i.e.  per  worker)  are  under   consideration,  which  involves  a  ratio  between  the  sum  of  wages  of  all  employed  persons  and  total   employment.  

 

5.1.2  Defining  labour  productivity  

In  general,  the  definition  of  labour  productivity  is  the  extent  to  which  a  firm’s  labour  force  is  creating   output  in  an  efficient  way  (Datta,  Guthrie  &  Wright,  2005).  To  measure  productivity,  it  is  the  most   appropriate  to  use  marginal  productivity,  which  is  the  value  added  (i.e.  the  contribution  to  the   output)  of  the  last  worker  hired;  only  such  a  measure  is  not  easy  to  obtain.  The  second  best  concept   of  productivity  in  economics  would  be  a  measure  of  output  per  hour  of  labour  input  (Wakeford,   2004).  However,  this  is  also  not  easily  obtainable.  The  use  of  average  labour  productivity  is  more   common  in  practice  (Wakeford,  2004).  This  measure  can  be  calculated  in  several  ways,  for  example   by  dividing  total  output  by  total  employment  (i.e.  total  labour  inputs)  (Datta  et  al.,  2005).    

    Following  the  study  by  Alexander  (1993),  Wakeford  (2004)  and  Goh  and  Wong  (2010),  the   measure  for  productivity  is  GDP  divided  by  total  employment.  Again,  because  the  focus  lies  on  the   manufacturing  sector,  the  data  for  GDP  and  employment  are  from  the  manufacturing  sector.      

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

Model 2 represents the relationship between the dependent variable of absenteeism and the independent variables of well-being and job satisfaction taking into account

H2a: A static descriptive normative message will be equally effective in changing one’s intentions to reduce meat consumption whether framed as a loss or a gain.. •

In deze rubriek komen artikelen over onderwijs- en examenbeleid, komt nieuws van het Ontwikkel- team Wiskunde 12-16, komt de inhoud van circu- laires van het Ministerie van

As Company X wants to optimize their production process overall, we investigate every process on its own on optimization possibilities. Currently, the cycle times within the

Wat Nederland betreft: als ik kijk naar de 100 grootste Nederlandse ondernemingen dan lijkt het mij uiterst onwaarschijnlijk dat de helft o f meer daarvan meer waarde voor

Gegeven de bevinding dat met name relatief hoogopgeleide mensen zelfstandige zonder personeel worden en dat opleidingen juist voor deze groep het best renderen, is het zorgelijk

The original data is used, since predicting the trend data for different smoothing factors is misleading; an over smoothed output variable can be perfectly

In Drenthe werken de verschillende betrokken partijen samen in de 'Alliantie Drentse zorg voor ouderen' om deze opgaven aan te pakken, waaronder huisartsen, thuiszorg,