• No results found

The effect of social protection reforms on the incidence and extent of precarious employment : in Belgium, Germany, Sweden and the United Kingdom since 1990 up to recent years

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "The effect of social protection reforms on the incidence and extent of precarious employment : in Belgium, Germany, Sweden and the United Kingdom since 1990 up to recent years"

Copied!
70
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

The  effect  of  social  protection  

reforms  on  the  incidence  and  

extent  of  precarious  employment    

In  Belgium,  Germany,  Sweden  and  the  United  Kingdom  

since  1990  up  to  recent  years

 

                                         

 

 

 

Lijsje  Goosen    

10554742  

lijsje@gmail.com  

 

University  of  Amsterdam    

Master’s  thesis  in  Sociology:    

Comparative  Organisation  and  Labour  Studies  

 

15-­‐08-­‐2014  

 

1

st

 Supervisor:  Dr.  J.  J.  De  Deken  

2

nd

 Supervisor:  V.  Di  Stasio  MSc  

(2)

Summary  

The  thesis  aims  to  discuss  the  effect  of  social  protection  arrangements  on  the  extent  and   incidence  of  precarious  employment.  The  concept  precarious  employment  is  discussed  and   defined,  in  particular  in  the  ways  it  differs  from  the  Standard  Employment  Relationship  and   how  it  relates  to  social  protection.  Indicators  are  ascribed  to  the  various  aspects  of  the   multi-­‐faceted  concept  of  precarious  employment  and  to  social  protection  systems.  Data  on   these  indicators  is  presented  over  the  timeframe  of  1990  to  2012  for  Belgium,  Germany,   Sweden  and  the  United  Kingdom.  Through  scrutinising  the  meaning  of  the  indicators  and   using  the  numbers  in  a  descriptive  manner  the  extent  and  incidence  of  precarious  

employment,  and  its  development  over  time,  is  discussed.  The  social  protection  systems  and   their  reforms  during  the  1990s  and  2000s  are  further  described  in  a  qualitative  manner.  In   the  conclusion  two  hypotheses  are  mostly  confirmed;  the  social  protection  systems  in   Germany  and  the  United  Kingdom  have  contributed  to  the  increase  in  incidence  and  extent   of  precarious  employment,  whereas  the  social  protection  system  in  Sweden  has  done  so  to  a   lower  extent  and  in  Belgium  has  hardly  aggravated  precarious  employment.  And  secondly,   precarious  employment  should  not  be  seen  as  a  dualisation  phenomenon,  as  the  social   protection  reforms  increased  precariousness  for  all.  

 

 

(3)

Table  of  contents  

Summary  ...  2  

List  of  Tables  ...  5  

List  of  Figures  ...  6  

1.  Introduction  ...  7  

1.1  Outline  ...  7  

2.  Theoretical  framework  ...  8  

2.1  The  Standard  Employment  Relationship  ...  8  

2.2  Global  changes  affecting  the  employment  relationship  ...  9  

2.2.1  From  Fordism  to  finance-­‐led  capitalism  ...  9  

2.2.2  Employment  under  finance-­‐led  capitalism  ...  10  

2.2.3  A  new  definition  of  employment  standards  ...  11  

2.3  Precarious  employment  ...  12  

2.3.1  Precarious  employment  in  policy  discussions  ...  12  

2.3.2  Precarious  employment  defined  ...  15  

2.4  Related  academic  debates  on  precarious  employment  ...  16  

2.4.1  A  wider  perspective  than  merely  precarious  jobs  ...  16  

2.4.2  A  new  form  of  precariousness  ...  17  

2.4.3  Non-­‐standard  work  and  precariousness  ...  17  

2.4.4  The  quality  of  jobs:  flexicurity  and  Decent  Work  ...  18  

2.4.5  Precarious  employment  and  dualisation  ...  19  

2.5  Social  protection:  link  to  precariousness  and  reforms  since  the  1990s  ...  20  

2.5.1  Social  protection  and  precarious  employment  ...  20  

2.5.2  Reforms  in  social  protection  since  the  1990s  ...  22  

2.5.3  The  reforms  and  precarious  employment  ...  24  

2.6  Vobruba’s  squares  of  labour  law  and  social  protection  ...  24  

2.7  Hypotheses  following  the  theoretical  framework  ...  26  

3.  Method  and  research  design  ...  26  

3.1  Precarious  employment  ...  27  

3.1.1  Unemployment  and  employment  ...  28  

3.1.2  Employment  contract  and  security  ...  31  

3.1.3  In-­‐work  poverty  ...  37  

3.2  Social  protection  ...  39  

3.2.1.  Basic  characteristics  ...  40  

3.2.2  Generosity;  Replacement  rates  ...  41  

3.2.3  Caseloads  of  working-­‐age  benefit  schemes  ...  44  

4.  The  extent  and  incidence  of  precarious  employment  ...  46  

4.1  Precarious  employment  in  Belgium  ...  46  

4.2  Precarious  employment  in  Germany  ...  47  

4.3  Precarious  employment  in  Sweden  ...  48  

4.4  Precarious  employment  in  the  United  Kingdom  ...  49  

(4)

5.1.  Social  protection  in  Belgium  ...  51  

5.1.1  Belgium’s  enduring  system  of  social  protection  ...  51  

5.1.2  Marked  changes  to  Belgium’s  social  protection  ...  52  

5.2  Social  protection  in  Germany  ...  52  

5.2.1  The  German  situation  in  the  1990s  ...  53  

5.2.2  Germany’s  reforms  towards  a  structural  divide  ...  54  

5.3  Social  protection  in  Sweden  ...  55  

5.3.1  Conditions  of  Sweden’s  unemployment  protection  system  ...  56  

5.3.2  Important  effects  of  the  reforms  and  increased  activation  in  Sweden  ...  57  

5.4  Social  protection  in  the  United  Kingdom  ...  58  

5.4.1  The  United  Kingdom’s  Job  Seeker’s  Allowance  ...  59  

5.4.2  Activation,  conditionality  and  risk-­‐recategorisation  in  the  UK  ...  59  

6.  Discussion  and  conclusion  ...  60  

6.1  The  situation  in  Germany  and  the  UK  versus  Belgium  and  Sweden  ...  61  

6.1.1.  The  extent  and  incidence  of  precarious  employment  ...  61  

6.1.2  The  effect  of  social  protection  ...  62  

6.2  Dualisation  versus  increased  precariousness  for  all  ...  64  

 

Bibliography  ...  65  

 

(5)

List  of  Tables  

 

Table  1  Definitions  of  precarious  work  ...  13  

Table  2  Unemployment  rates  (%)  ...  28  

Table  3  Duration  of  unemployment  (as  %  of  total  unemployment)  ...  29  

Table  4  Registered  unemployed  and  job  vacancies  (x1.000)  and  unemployed-­‐to-­‐

vacancy  ratio  ...  30  

Table  5  Employment-­‐to-­‐population,  15+  (%)  ...  31  

Table  6  Share  of  permanent  and  temporary  employment  (%)  ...  32  

Table  7  Employment  Protection  Legislation  –  Regular  contracts  ...  33  

Table  8  Employment  Protection  Legislation  –  Temporary  contracts  ...  33  

Table  9  Average  EPL  for  total  employment  ...  33  

Table  10  Main  reason  for  temporary  employment  (%  of  total  temporary  

employment)  ...  34  

Table  11  In  temporary  employment  because  of  inability  to  find  permanent  

employment  (%  of  total  employment)  ...  34  

Table  12  Temporary  employees  by  duration  of  contract  in  months  (Total  x1.000  and  

%  of  total)  ...  35  

Table  13  Share  of  involuntary  part-­‐time  employment  in  total  employment  and  as  a  

share  of  part-­‐time  employment  (%)  ...  36  

Table  14  Employment  by  job  tenure  interval  (%  of  total  employment)  ...  36  

Table  15  Average  job  tenure,  in  years  ...  37  

Table  16  In-­‐work  at-­‐risk-­‐of-­‐poverty  rate,  employed  persons  aged  16  and  over,  after  

social  transfers  (%)  ...  38  

Table  17  In-­‐work  at-­‐risk-­‐of-­‐poverty  rate,  employed  persons  aged  16-­‐64,  before  social  

transfers  (%)  ...  38  

Table  18  In-­‐work  at-­‐risk-­‐of-­‐poverty  rate,  age  18-­‐24  (%)  ...  39  

Table  19  In-­‐work  at-­‐risk-­‐of-­‐poverty  rate,  employees  with  a  permanent  job  (%)  ...  39  

Table  20  In-­‐work  at-­‐risk-­‐of-­‐poverty  rate,  employees  with  a  temporary  job  (%)  ...  39  

Table  21  Unemployment  insurance  coverage  rate  as  share  of  employed  (%)  ...  40  

Table  22  Duration  of  unemployment  insurance  benefit  and  waiting  days  ...  40  

Table  23  Net  replacement  rates  in  first  month  after  unemployment  for  single  60%  

Average  Wage,  no  children  –  and  with  2  children  (%)  ...  41  

Table  24  Net  replacement  rates  in  first  month  after  unemployment  for  single  100%  

Average  Wage,  no  children  -­‐  and  with  2  children  (%)  ...  42  

Table  25  Net  replacement  rates  in  first  month  after  unemployment  for  single,  120%  

Average  Wage,  no  children  –  and  with  2  children  (%)  ...  42  

Table  26  Net  replacement  rates  for  the  long-­‐term  unemployed,  without  and  with  

housing  and  social  assistance  benefits,  for  a  single  earning  67%  of  AW  with  no  

children  -­‐  and  with  2  children  (%)  ...  43  

Table  27  Net  replacement  rates  for  the  long-­‐term  unemployed,  without  and  with  

housing  and  social  assistance  benefits,  for  a  single  earning  100%  of  AW  with  no  

children  -­‐  and  with  2  children  (%)  ...  43  

(6)

Table  28  Net  replacement  rates  for  the  long-­‐term  unemployed,  without  and  with  

housing  and  social  assistance  benefits,  for  a  single  earning  150%  of  AW  with  no  

children  -­‐  and  with  2  children  (%)  ...  44  

Table  29  Caseload  unemployment  benefits,  includes  participants  in  ALMPs  except  for  

Sweden  (as  %  of  population  15-­‐64)  ...  45  

Table  30  Caseload  work  incapacity  benefits  (as  %  of  population  15-­‐64)  ...  45  

Table  31  Caseload  Early  retirement  benefits  (as  %  of  population  15-­‐64)  ...  45  

Table  32  Caseload  Social  assistance  benefits  (as  %  of  population  15-­‐64)  ...  45  

Table  33  Beneficiary  rates  ...  59  

 

List  of  Figures  

Figure  1  The  SER-­‐situation  according  to  Vobruba  ...  24  

Figure  2  Recent  developments  according  to  Vobruba  ...  25  

 

(7)

1.  Introduction  

There  has  been  extensive  research  on  the  effect  of  the  Europe-­‐wide  reforms  of  social   protection  systems  since  the  1990s,  which  in  general  included  less  generosity,  more   activation  measures  and  stricter  conditionalities,  and  has  led  to  a  decline  in  the  level  of   unemployment.  The  research  on  the  apparent  success  of  these  policies  however  hardly   takes  into  consideration  how  they  might  have  affected  the  nature  and  quality  of   employment.  Long  before  these  reforms,  at  least  since  the  1970s,  the  labour  market   structure  and  employment  relationships  underwent  changes  throughout  industrialised,   developed  countries.  Through  processes  of  globalisation,  financialisation  and  tertiarisation   as  well  as  policy  choices  promoting  flexibilisation  the  so-­‐called  standard  employment   relationship  deteriorated.  

Besides  global  trends  impacting  on  employment  relations,  national  policies  matter   for  the  situation  of  employees.  Flexibility  might  be  necessary  for  economic  growth;  the   uncertainty  it  brings  severely  affects  people.  Different  nations  have  chosen  different  forms   and  extents  of  providing  social  protection  for  the  increasing  insecurity  citizens  are  facing   (Crouch,  2014).  And  arguably,  this  variation  in  provision  has  led  to  different  outcomes  with   respect  to  precarious  employment  and  its  coverage  and  intensity  for  the  population.      

While  there  is  an  extensive  body  of  literature  on  developments  regarding  the  quality   of  jobs  and  the  reform  of  social  protection,  there  have  hardly  been  any  attempts  at  linking   the  reforms  of  social  protection  to  the  growth  of  precarious  employment.  With  this  thesis  I   hope  to  contribute  to  this  gap  in  the  literature  by  comparing  the  ways  in  which  changes  in   the  incidence  and  extent  of  precarious  employment  in  Belgium,  Germany,  Sweden  and  the   United  Kingdom  are  linked  to  reforms  of  social  protection  systems,  over  a  period  from  the   early  1990s  up  to  recent  years.  

To  illustrate;  it  can  be  expected  that  there  is  a  kind  of  trade-­‐off  between  on  the  one   hand  getting  the  unemployed  out  of  benefit  recipiency  and  into  a  market  remunerated  job,   regardless  of  the  quality  of  this  employment,  leading  to  a  declining  level  of  unemployment   and  on  the  other  hand  an  increase  of  precarious  employment  and  of  ‘revolving  door’   unemployment;  that  is  of  people  going  from  one  temporary  job  via  unemployment   assistance  to  another  temporary  or  otherwise  precarious  job.  The  United  Kingdom  and   Germany  are  expected  to  represent  examples  of  this  phenomenon;  the  UK  with  strong   activation  policies  and  in-­‐work  benefits  and  Germany  with  its  promotion  of  mini-­‐jobs.   Another  approach  for  a  nation  could  be  to  strive  for  proper  jobs  for  the  unemployed,   through  providing  them  with  useful  (re-­‐)training  as  well  as  time  and  an  income  to  look  for  a   suitable  job.  Perhaps  this  would  lead  to  higher  levels  of  unemployment,  but  also  to  less   precarious  employment.  Belgium  and  Sweden  have  been  chosen  as  possible  examples  of   this  scenario.    

1.1  Outline  

In  order  to  discuss  the  incidence  and  extent  of  precarious  employment  and  the  effect  of   social  protection  systems  on  precarious  employment  in  the  four  countries  selected,  the   remainder  of  this  thesis  is  structured  as  follows.  Chapter  2  provides  the  theoretical   framework,  through  first  discussing  the  “standard  employment  relationship”  as  well  as  its   decline  and  then  defining  precarious  employment.  The  social  protection  systems  relation  to   precarious  employment  is  discussed  and  an  insightful  visualisation  of  the  processes  

described  is  provided  after  which  the  hypotheses  are  formed.  The  method  and  research   design  is  outlined  in  chapter  3.  The  following  chapter  discusses  the  incidence  and  extent  of   precarious  employment  in  the  four  countries  over  the  period  from  1990  to  2012.  Chapter  5   deals  with  the  social  protection  reforms  and  characteristics  since  the  1990s,  also  for  each   country.  In  the  final  chapter  the  two  previous  chapters  are  combined  in  order  to  discuss  and  

(8)

conclude  on  the  effect  of  national  social  protection  systems  on  the  incidence  and  extent  of   precarious  employment.  

2.  Theoretical  framework  

Over  the  last  decades  much  attention  has  been  paid  to  the  changing  organisation  of  work,   including  the  rise  of  non-­‐standard  employment,  increasing  flexibility,  vulnerable  workers  and   the  growth  of  precariousness  (ex.  Fritz  and  Koch,  2013,  Barbier,  2010,  Standing,  2011).  The   most  often  cited  explanations  for  these  changes  in  the  de-­‐industrialised  parts  of  the  world   are  this  process  of  de-­‐industrialisation,  globalisation  and  intensified  global  competition,   flexibilisation  and  finally  corporate  restructuring  and  financialisation  (Clasen  and  Clegg,   2011,  Crouch  2011,  Cremers,  2010).  Whereas  in  traditional,  industrial  economies  there  is  (or   better;  was)  a  high  need  for  stable  employment  relationships,  in  the  service  economies  of   recent  decades  flexible  labour  relations  are  deemed  to  be  key  in  enhancing  economic   growth.  Many  policies  have  changed  accordingly,  in  order  to  enforce  flexible  labour   relations.  These  changes  in  the  labour  market  affect  people  in  such  a  way  that  a  different   mode  of  social  protection  is  required.  National  governments  need  to  adjust  in  order  to   provide  such  suitable  social  protection,  including  unemployment  protection,  to  the  changed   risks  accompanying  current  employment  relationships  (Clasen  and  Clegg,  2011,  p.7).  All   these  developments  have  impacted  on  employment  quality;  arguably  leading  to  an  increase   in  precariousness.  

In  this  chapter  the  developments  in  the  organisation  of  work  and  in  social  protection   and  their  relation  to  the  core  concept  of  ‘precarious  employment’  are  discussed.  

Furthermore,  the  first  step  in  contributing  to  the  gap  in  the  existing  literature  is  made;  in   discussing  the  relation  between  social  protection  and  the  extent  of  precariousness.  The   remainder  of  this  chapter  is  structured  as  follows.  Section  2.1  discusses  the  standard  

employment  relationship  (SER)  and  the  following  section  the  global  developments  that  have   impacted  on  the  employment  relationship  over  the  last  decades,  with  a  focus  on  those   changes  contributing  to  precarious  employment.  This  is  followed  by  section  2.3  in  which  the   concept  precarious  employment  and  its  characteristics  are  discussed  extensively.  Section  2.4   provides  an  overview  of  relevant  academic  discussions  on  precarious  employment,  including   the  relation  to  the  non-­‐standard  contract,  the  concepts  ‘decent  work’  and  flexicurity  and   dualisation.    Section  2.5  outlines  the  connection  between  the  two  core  concepts  of  this   thesis;  employment  precariousness  and  social  protection  systems  and  discusses  the  broad   changes  in  social  protection  since  the  1990s  in  European  countries  in  general.  In  the   following  section  an  insightful  description  and  visualisation  of  the  developments  in  labour   law  and  social  protection  is  provided.  In  the  chapter’s  final  section  the  main  hypothesis  on   the  relation  between  social  protection  and  precarious  employment  is  formulated,  as  is  an   additional  hypothesis  regarding  precariousness  and  the  dualisation  concept.  

2.1  The  Standard  Employment  Relationship  

The  SER  should  be  seen  as  an  ideal  type,  though  there  have  certainly  been  times  when  it  was   reality  for  a  large  share  of  (male)  employees  in  Western  Europe  and  the  United  States.  Bosch   has  defined  the  SER  as  a  “stable,  socially  protected,  dependent,  full-­‐time  job  (…)  the  basic   conditions  of  which  (working  time,  pay,  social  transfers)  are  regulated  to  a  minimum  level  by   collective  agreement  or  by  labour  and/or  social  security  law”  (Bosch,  2004,  p.618-­‐619).  It  is   the  exceptional  combination  of  “fulltime  and  stable  employment  with  attached  collective   bargaining  procedures,  social  rights  and  protections”  (Van  Aerden  et  al,  2014,  p.772)  that  is   key  in  the  SER.  Another  aspect  of  the  SER  is  that  work  is  “exercised  during  a  lifelong  career”   (García  and  de  Schampheleire,  2002,  p.75).  To  summarise,  the  SER  has  several  key  aspects;   it’s  fulltime  and  stable  and  the  social  standards  are  linked  to  such  permanent,  fulltime  work.       These  key  aspects  relate  to  the  social  function  the  SER  fulfilled  for  employers  and  

(9)

employees  as  well  as  society  as  a  whole.    “The  focus  of  the  contract  is  not  only  on  today  but   also  on  tomorrow,  with  many  mutual  obligations  enshrined  therein”  (Bosch,  2004,  p.619).   Thus,  employers  provide  for  their  employees  not  only  for  the  hours  worked,  but  also  when   they  are  not  working  or  training,  for  example  during  sickness  or  vacation.  Employers  and   employees  share  mutual  obligations,  such  as  to  adhere  to  a  minimum  period  of  employment   as  well  as  to  the  rules  for  termination  of  the  contract.  The  welfare  state  plays  a  role  in   decommodifying  the  employees,  through  providing  social  protection  in  the  form  of  

employment  protection  as  well  as  linking  entitlements,  such  as  unemployment  and  sickness   benefits,  to  the  SER.  Another  facet  of  the  SER  is  the  adherence  to  certain  standards,  with   regards  to  working  times,  overtime  premiums  and  holiday  entitlements,  among  other  things.   Through  these  SER  arrangements  employees  can  count  on  either  a  permanent  contract  or   an  income  provided  by  the  welfare  state  in  case  of  a  transition  period  between  jobs  or  in   periods  of  illness  or  accidents.  As  employees  stand  stronger  against  corporate  decision-­‐ making,  through  mutual  obligations  and  employment  protection,  their  bargaining  position  is   quite  strong.  The  SER  enables  labour  to  plan  for  both  the  short  and  long  term  (p.620).     The  SER  came  into  existence  over  the  1950s  and  1960s,  a  period  of  economic  growth   and  low  unemployment  rates.  It  intended  to  protect  employees  against  economic  and  social   risks,  increase  economic  efficiency  through  stability  and  reduce  inequality  (p.632).  When   economic  growth  slowed  down,  the  services  industry  became  more  important  and   unemployment  grew  these  goals  were  no  longer  compatible.  The  regulation  of  the   employment  relationship  became  to  be  resisted  by  employers,  and  as  they  were  in  a   stronger  bargaining  position  deregulation  followed.    

2.2  Global  changes  affecting  the  employment  relationship  

It  is  commonly  assumed  that  the  protection  of  living  standards  and  social  status  is  anchored   in  western  European  societies,  through  culture,  politics  as  well  as  institutions.  Paid  

employment  forms  the  basis  of  this  European  model  of  society,  including  the  welfare  state   arrangements.  The  model  furthermore  depends  on  the  settlement  of  social  and  political   conflicts  between  organised  capital  and  labour.  Welfare  states  can  function  as  mechanisms   for  redistribution  as  well  as  providing  a  social  structure  and  social  mobility  based  on  equality   and  justice.  As  such  the  state  is  expected  to  provide  the  conditions  that  enable  a  certain   degree  of  social  and  employment  security,  in  order  for  individuals  to  plan  and  carry  out  their   lives.    

 

Consequently,  the  regulation  of  good  working  conditions  and  the  provision  of   decent  social  security  benefits  and  services  form  the  legitimate  basis  of  a  democratic   welfare  state,  providing  people  with  risk  protection  and  positive  social  rights  

(Bothfeld  &Leschke,  2012,  p.339).    

However,  the  actual  situation  in  Western  Europe  is  markedly  different  in  several  regards,   most  importantly  the  deterioration  of  employment,  both  in  quantitative  and  qualitative   sense,  and  the  related  welfare  benefits  and  services.    There  seems  to  be  a  trade-­‐off  between   employers’  interest  in  profits  and  employees’  interest  in  employment  security  and  decent   wages,  and  under  different  pressures  it  has  again  tilted  towards  the  employers’  side,   facilitated  to  different  extents  by  national  governments.  

2.2.1  From  Fordism  to  finance-­‐led  capitalism  

During  the  few  decades  of  roughly  the  1930s  to  1970s  there  was  an  exceptional  situation  of   not  only  economic  growth,  but  also  shared  prosperity  through  the  class  compromise  in   which  capital  shared  productivity  increases  with  labour,  and  labour  in  return  accepted  the   scientific  forms  of  work  organization  (Baccaro,  2010,  p.342).  The  regulated  national  banking   systems  and  Bretton  Woods  institutions  ensured  stability  both  domestically  and  

(10)

internationally  (Boyer,  2010,  p.349).  The  demand  for  workers  was  high  and  opportunities  for   advancement  were  good  for  most  workers.  Trade  unions  experienced  a  good  bargaining   position,  and  the  expansion  and  extension  of  labour  laws  ensured  favourable  conditions,   regarding  wage  increases,  limiting  working  hours,  strengthening  employment  protection  as   well  as  improvements  in  old-­‐age  and  unemployment  insurance.  As  most  basic  material   necessities  were  attained  workers  became  concerned  with  more  intrinsic  aspects  of   employment;  such  as  meaning,  autonomy  and  challenge  (Kalleberg,  2009,  Vobruba,  1999).   Vobruba  has  defined  this  situation  as  the  ‘full  employment  society’,  an  era  in  which  the   labour  market  had  fulltime,  regular  jobs  available  for  all  who  needed  it.  And  for  those   temporarily  without  a  job,  there  were  expanding  social  security  services  and  benefits   available,  at  least  for  those  willing  to  work  (1999,  p.5).  

This  situation  is  generally  referred  to  as  the  Fordist-­‐era,  of  full  male  employment,   and  lasted  until  it  turned  out  that  the  domestic  markets  were  saturated  and  could  no  longer   provide  the  necessary  growing  demand,  which  meant  a  rapid  decline  of  economic  growth   and  profits.  Also,  Taylorists  methods  to  increase  productivity  were  exhausted  (Koch,  2013,   p.32).  Firms,  enabled  by  technological  changes,  started  to  look  for  cheap  labour  as  well  as   markets  abroad,  and  they  became  ever  more  inserted  into  the  global  market.  Governments   at  their  turn  acted,  to  varying  extents,  by  diminishing  the  restrictions  on  capital  mobility,  and   the  deregulation  of  banking  and  financial  sectors,  all  in  order  to  improve  competitiveness   and  boost  profitability,  to  sustain  the  necessary  economic  growth.  Furthermore,  also  in   response  to  employers’  pressures,  governments  restricted  or  removed  regulatory  barriers  to   the  use  of  temporary  and  part-­‐time  hiring  and  eased  regulations  on  working  time  patterns   as  well  as  employment  protection  legislation  (Gray,  2004,  p.3).  By  making  labour  cheaper  it   was  believed  employers  would  start  hiring  more  labour  and  the  levels  of  unemployment   would  come  down.  Tertiarisation,  the  shift  from  manufacturing  to  services,  also  affected  the   position  of  labour,  mainly  because  of  the  fact  that  many  jobs  in  services  tend  to  be  less   skilled  and  as  such  lower  paid.  All  in  all,  with  the  regime  shift  from  Fordism  to  post-­‐Fordism,   or  finance-­‐led  capitalism,  soaring  profits  returned.  However,  the  extreme  mobility  of  capital   has  had  a  negative  influence  on  workers  through  increased  flexibility,  wage  moderation  and   a  decline  in  trade  unions  bargaining  position  (Tridico,  2012).    

2.2.2  Employment  under  finance-­‐led  capitalism  

The  deteriorated  conditions  for  employment,  low  skilled  labour  in  particular,  are  not   contingent  but  in  fact  key  in  this  finance-­‐led  stage  of  capitalism.  Not  because  globalisation   would  inevitably  have  led  to  precarious  employment,  in  fact  policies  were  deliberately   pursued  in  order  to  create  an  economic  environment  more  conducive  to  capital  and   companies.  Global  open  markets  would  in  the  end  benefit  everyone,  because  of  efficient   production  and  innovation  through  fierce  competition,  which  required  flexible  labour.   Despite  failing  to  deliver  these  benefits,  this  is  now  the  reality  in  which  labour  exists.   Whereas  employers  used  to  share  some  of  the  responsibility  and  reduce  individual  risk  by   offering  job  security  despite  market  volatility,  the  current  situation  is  such  that  the  individual   employee  bears  most  of  the  risk  (ILO,  2012,  p.40-­‐44).  Capital’s  search  for  flexible  labour  is   crucially  linked  to  the  choices  made  by  governments  that  favour  a  deregulated  monetary   regime  and  foster  wage  competition  (Barbier,  2013,  p.17).    

There  are  four  main  ways  in  which  the  finance-­‐led  capitalism  stage  is  deteriorating   employment.  First  of  all,  with  globalisation  the  rationale  for  collectively  keeping  wages  up  in   order  to  stimulate  consumer  demand  is  gone,  as  domestic  spending  power  of  wage-­‐earners   is  less  important  than  in  the  Fordism  age.  Profits  can  be  made  outside  of  the  domestic   market.  Also,  the  decrease  in  real  wages  can  be  compensated  by  consumer  loans,  as  such   maintaining  the  spending  power  companies  are  interested  in.  “Financialisation,  hence,  is   likely  to  be  accompanied  by  a  redistribution  of  primary  income  from  the  wage-­‐earning  to  the   capital-­‐owning  class”  (Koch,  2013,  p.34).    

(11)

Secondly,  under  finance-­‐led  capitalism  “Creating  shareholder  value  became  the   mantra  of  modern  corporations  and  shifted  the  management  focus  from  ‘empire’  building   and  job  creation  to  short-­‐term  economic  indicators”  (Dünhaupt,  2013,  p.8).  From  the   perspective  of  analysts  and  fund  managers  personnel  is  not  a  resource,  but  is  perceived  as   an  expense  factor.  And  whereas  labour  costs  can  be  quantified  precisely,  the  amount  of   value  created  by  labour  becomes  an  indistinguishable  part  of  the  overall  result.  (Kädtler,   2011,  p.183)  This  also  relates  to  the  increased  outsourcing  and  transnationalisation  of  chains   of  production,  as  such  moves  are  aimed  at  improving  shareholder  value  at  the  expense  of   (former)  employees.  Under  the  heading  of  ‘remaining  competitive’,  the  original  employees   might  be  forced  to  accept  unfavourable  conditions  because  of  a  threat  in  outsourcing,  or  in   fact  lose  their  jobs  due  to  international  low  wage  competition.    

Furthermore,  under  Fordism  conditions  were  in  place  through  which  low  skilled   workers  could  earn  decent  wages,  through  trade  unions  bargaining  for  decent  wages,   training  and  internal  promotion  opportunities  and  the  strong  welfare  state,  the  finance-­‐led   stage  of  capitalism  broke  down  these  conditions  because  of  globalisation  and  tertiarisation.   Its  dominant  logic  is  to  subject  workers  to  market  forces,  through  employment  

externalization,  a  broad  term  that  includes  the  breakdown  of  training  and  promotion   ladders,  the  declining  job  security  and  the  rise  of  nonstandard  work.  All  this  has  a  negative   effect  on  conditions  of  employment  including  wages,  training,  job  security  as  well  as  work   intensification  (Vidal,  2013,  p.589-­‐591).    

Finally,  globalisation  has  led  to  a  highly  competitive  environment,  in  which  

consumer  demands  are  increasingly  flexible  and  diversified.  As  such  production  and  service   provision  is  said  to  require  more  flexible  employment,  meaning  employers  strive  towards   more  temporary,  casual  and  part-­‐time  contracts,  in  order  to  circumvent  costs  associated   with  fulltime,  permanent  employees  (Koch,  2013,  p.38).  As  regular  contracts  tend  to  come   with  more  job  security,  in  general  higher  wages  and  more  social  protection.  

2.2.3  A  new  definition  of  employment  standards  

A  new  definition  of  social  standards,  in  this  case  relating  to  employment  standards,  has   come  about.  As  what  is  accepted  as  employment  standards  differs  across  space  and  time.   Whereas  the  Fordist  employment  standard  of  the  SER  was  fulltime,  permanent,  on-­‐site,   wage  employment,  as  described  in  section  2.1  above,  the  employment  standard  in  finance-­‐ led  capitalism  is  clearly  different  (Koch,  2013,  p.30).  According  to  Vobruba  there  is  a  twofold   crisis  in  paid  work;  there  are  too  few  paid  jobs  in  relation  to  the  number  of  people  who  rely   on  paid  work,  and  at  the  same  time  there  are  quality  issues  with  a  lot  of  jobs  (1999,  p.27).   He  considers  a  return  to  the  full  employment  society  under  capitalism  improbable,  mainly   because  there  is  no  such  thing  as  a  ‘clearing  of  the  market’  or  ‘economic  equalisation’   through  which  a  balance  of  jobseekers  and  vacancies  will  come  around.  The  labour  market   has  inherent  peculiar  features,  including  institutional  and  cultural  aspects  influencing  the   supply  of  labour,  in  particular  certain  groups  such  as  women  and  migrants.    

Furthermore,  the  feasibility  of  a  return  is  diminished  because  of  the  deteriorated   preconditions,  as  they  existed  under  Fordism  as  described  above.  Despite  all  this,  Vobruba   highlights  the  fact  that  the  welfare  state  arrangements  and  social  inclusion  remain  based  on   full  employment  in  many  regards.  And  many  policies  are  still  aimed  at  a  return  to  full   employment,  albeit  with  a  different  understanding  of  full  employment,  as  it  has  come  to   also  include  non-­‐standard  employment  (p.28-­‐31).  Thus,  the  current  situation  is  one  in  which   people  depend  on  cash,  however  there  are  not  enough  jobs  available.  Plus,  for  the  

unemployed  and  insecurely  employed  there  is  an  additional  problem:    

The  basic  problem  facing  people  who  enter  the  labour  market  as  an  additional   labour  supply  lies  in  the  fact  that  they  have  to  work  first  in  order  then  to  get  an   income  (p.42)  

(12)

 

Section  2.5  will  elaborate  on  this  additional  problem.  

  For  now,  what  remains  to  be  said  about  global  changes  impacting  on  the   employment  relationship  is  the  following:  

 

“(…)  the  postfordist  regime  still  systematically  generates  a  job  structure  with  a  large   percentage  of  low-­‐autonomy  jobs  and  increasingly  produces  a  stratum  of  long-­‐term   working  poor,  whose  wages  are  kept  low  by  the  existence  of  various  strata  of  a   reserve  army  of  under-­‐  and  unemployed.  (…)  The  wage  form  continues  to  present   interdependent  relations  –  the  banker  and  his  or  her  maid,  software  developers  and   their  janitors,  creatives  and  their  cheap  goods  and  services  –  as  independent  market   transactions.  Some  things,  indeed,  do  not  change.”  (Vidal,  2013,  p.605-­‐606)  

 

Now,  the  concept  of  precarious  employment,  to  which  the  global  developments  over  the   last  decades  that  were  just  outlined  have  contributed  in  terms  of  expansion  and  

progression,  is  discussed.  

2.3  Precarious  employment  

Precarious  work  is  a  concept  that  is  used  to  describe  an  employment  situation.  Precarious   literally  means  insecure  or  uncertain,  but  also  perilous,  critical  and  unstable.  In  sociology  the   concept  ‘precariousness’  originated  in  France  in  the  late  1970s,  referring  to  general  poverty   and  insecurity,  and  became  further  defined  by  the  distinction  between  precariousness  in   general  and  employment  precariousness  (Barbier,  2004).  Without  denying  the  existence  of   precariousness  unconnected  to  employment,  throughout  this  thesis  precariousness  always   refers  to  employment  precariousness.  The  terms  precarious  employment,  precarious  work   and  precariousness  will  be  used  interchangeably.    

Up  to  date  it  remains  difficult  to  define  the  term  exactly,  however  not  so  much   because  of  a  fundamental  lack  of  clarity.  It  is  mostly  due  to  the  fact  that  employment   precariousness  is  multi-­‐faceted  and  depends  upon  contexts.  Precariousness  could  also  be   said  to  be  relative,  briefly  put;  in  developing  and  transitional  countries  precarious  work  is   often  the  norm  and  mostly  relates  to  poverty  wages  and  the  informal  economy.  In  the   developed,  prosperous  world  precarious  work  revolves  around  earnings  inequality,  

insecurity,  vulnerability  to  dismissals  and  non-­‐standard  contracts  (Kalleberg,  2009,  p.14-­‐15).   Despite  this  relativity  and  context-­‐dependence,  precariousness  is  a  concept  that  expresses   an  experience  widely  shared  and  recognised  as  a  society-­‐wide  issue  in  contemporary   societies.  

  Following  Kalleberg,  it  is  important  to  emphasise  that  what  is  discussed  in  this  thesis   is  employment;  work  that  produces  earnings,  or  profit  for  the  self-­‐employed.  This  definition   leaves  out  other  forms  of  work  that  ‘merely’  produce  value;  such  as  household,  community   and  care  work  (2009,  p.2).    

2.3.1  Precarious  employment  in  policy  discussions  

In  order  to  explain  the  concept  table  1  below  provides  an  overview  of  descriptions  of   precarious  work  by  different  organisations  involved  with  (improving  conditions  of)  labour,   including  trade  union  federations,  non-­‐governmental  institutions  and  research  institutes.     This  is  not  an  exclusive  list  of  organisations  in  the  field  of  labour  conditions,  however  the  key   players  at  the  European  level  are  included.  The  main  words  used  to  define  precarious  work   are  in  bold,  to  enable  easier  comparison.  

     

(13)

Table  1  Definitions  of  precarious  work    

Organisation  and  source   of  description  

Definition  or  description   ILO  ACTRAV  –  

International  Labour   Organisation,  Bureau  for   Worker’s  Activities  

http://www.ilo.org/actr av/what/events/WCMS_ 153972/lang-­‐-­‐

en/index.htm    

The  precariousness  of  work  arrangements  is  heterogeneous  and   multifaceted  depending  on  the  country,  region,  and  the  economic  and   social  structure  of  the  political  systems  and  labour  markets.  The  scope   and  different  forms  are  ever  expanding,  as  unscrupulous  employers  are   always  trying  to  circumvent  regulations  or  to  find  loopholes  in  regulations   in  order  to  increase  the  profitability  of  their  business  at  the  expense  of   their  employees.  Nonetheless,  common  characteristics  of  precariousness   are  the  absence  or  the  insufficient  level  of  rights  and  protection  at  the   workplace.  While  informal  employment  is  obviously  precarious,  this  is   also  increasingly  true  for  many  forms  of  formal  employment  including   sub-­‐contracting,  temporary  contracts,  agency  work,  fake  self  employment   and  involuntary  part-­‐time.  

ITUC  –  International   Trade  Union   Confederation     http://www.ituc-­‐ csi.org/IMG/pdf/8GC_E_ 16_b_-­‐ _FINAL_Resolution_on_ Precarious_and_Informa l_Work-­‐2.pdf    

Precarious,  atypical  and  unprotected  forms  of  employment  deprive   millions  of  workers  of  the  coverage  of  labour  legislation  and  social   security  and  undermine  the  union  capacity  to  organise  and  bargain   collectively.  Such  workers  are  effectively  denied  these  rights  because  of   the  inadequacy  of  law  or  its  application,  which  often  does  not  cover  the   full  range  of  relationships  under  which  work  is  performed.    

ETUC    -­‐  European  Trade   Union  Confederation  

http://www.etuc.org/de cent-­‐work    

The  ETUC  has  defined  an  end  to  precarious  jobs  as  a  principle  for  decent  

work.  Precarious  jobs  undermine  working  conditions  and  health  and  

safety,  generate  poverty  wages  and  damage  social  cohesion.  As  such,  

precarious  work  can  be  seen  as  a  lack  in  decent  work.  Basic  principles  for   decent  work  are;  better  work  organisation  (including  work-­‐life  balance   and  lifelong  learning  for  skill  and  qualification  enhancement),  strong  

employment  protection  legislation  (to  foster  investment  in  human  capital  

and  innovation),  social  welfare  system  to  provide  security  for  those   changing  jobs  and  finally  social  dialogue  and  collective  bargaining.  The   ETUC  emphasis  the  importance  of  job  security,  training  as  well  as  health  

and  safety  conditions  including  stress.   ILRF  -­‐  International  

Labour  Rights  Forum  

http://www.laborrights. org/issues/precarious-­‐ work    

Companies  worldwide  are  shirking  their  legal  obligations  to  workers  by   replacing  permanent  jobs  with  contract  and  temporary  work.  Precarious   workers  are  those  who  fill  permanent  job  needs  but  are  denied  

permanent  employee  rights.    Globally,  these  workers  are  subject  to   unstable  employment,  lower  wages  and  more  dangerous  working   conditions.  They  rarely  receive  social  benefits  and  are  often  denied  the   right  to  join  a  union.  Even  when  they  have  the  right  to  unionize,  workers   are  scared  to  organize  if  they  know  they  are  easily  replaceable.    Women,   minorities  and  migrant  workers  are  much  more  likely  to  fill  these  kinds   of  jobs.  Permanent  employment  across  a  number  of  sectors  has  shifted  to   precarious  jobs  through  outsourcing,  use  of  employment  agencies,  and   inappropriate  classification  of  workers  as  “short-­‐term”  or  “independent   contractors.”    

GURN  –  The  Global   Union  Research   Network  

http://www.gurn.info/e n/topics/precarious-­‐ work    

Worldwide,  billions  of  workers  suffer  from  precarious  working  conditions.   They  work,  but  lack  decent  jobs,  security,  protection  and  rights.  

The  precariousness  of  work  arrangements  is  heterogeneous  and   multifaceted  depending  on  the  country,  region,  and  the  economic  and   social  structure  of  the  political  systems  and  labour  markets.    

Precariousness  in  the  world  of  work  mainly  arises  from  contractual   arrangements  under  which  work  is  performed.  This  includes:  stand-­‐by,   temporary,  employment-­‐agency,  casual,  part-­‐time,  seasonal  contracts,  

(14)

pseudo  self-­‐employment,  no  direct  or  an  unclear  employer/employee   relationship,  poor  protection  against  dismissal,  and  lack  of  –  or  limited   access  of  workers  –  to  exercise  their  rights  at  work.  

EFFAT  -­‐  European   Federation  of  Food,   Agriculture  and  Tourism   Trade  Unions  

http://www.effat.org/en /precarious-­‐work    

Precarious  workers  are  mostly  deprived  of  common  workers’  rights,  such   as  continued  wage  payment  in  case  of  sickness  or  holidays,  rights  of   employees  to  participate  in  company  decision-­‐making  and  collective  pay   agreements.  As  a  result,  the  affected  workers  have  major  gaps  in  their   social  security  protection.    

Work  can  be  described  as  precarious  if  the  level  of  income,  protection   and  social  integration  of  workers  sinks  far  below  the  level  defined  and   recognised  as  standard  in  contemporary  society.  Work  is  also  precarious  if   it  is  subjectively  associated  with  a  loss  of  meaning,  a  deficit  of  recognition   or  uncertainties  regarding  planning,  and  if  social  standards  are  

significantly  changed  to  the  disadvantage  of  the  workers.     Precarious  work  covers  a  broad  and  multifaceted  spectrum.   IndustriALL  Global   Union   http://www.industriall-­‐ union.org/issues/social-­‐ justice-­‐and-­‐ globalization/stop-­‐ precarious-­‐work    

Global  capital  is  driving  fundamental  changes  to  the  way  that  people  are   employed.  Secure  jobs  are  becoming  more  and  more  rare,  while  agency   work,  contract  work  and  temporary  work  are  taking  over.  For  young   people,  there  is  practically  no  other  option  –  the  only  jobs  on  offer  are   insecure.  

Workers  in  precarious  jobs  have  little  chance  to  join  a  union  or  to  bargain   collectively.  Pay  and  conditions  are  being  driven  ever  lower  by  

companies  that  rely  on  precarious  work  to  reduce  their  labour  costs  and   pass  all  the  risks  of  employment  onto  workers.  

In  order  to  combat  precarious  work  IndustriALL  Global  Union  demands:   Legislation  that  protects  workers  and  their  rights  from  being  undermined,   collective  agreements  that  ban  the  use  of  precarious  work  or  put  defined   limits  on  it  and  respect  for  and  enforcement  of  labour  rights  –  for  all   workers.  

SOLIDAR  –  European   network  of  NGOs   working  to  advance   social  justice  in  Europe   and  worldwide  

http://www.solidar.org/ IMG/pdf/23_solidar_no nstandard_empl_relatio ns.pdf    

The  result  [of  increases  in  ‘working  poor’  and  ‘a-­‐typical  employment   contracts]  is  precarious  employment  that  encompasses  forms  of  work   involving  job  insecurity,  low  income,  limited  (or  no)  social  benefits  or   statutory  entitlements  and  low  societal  participation.  

BARSORI  /  AIAS  -­‐   “Bargaining  for  Social   Rights”  financed  by  the   European  Commission   carried  out  by  

Amsterdams  Instituut   voor  ArbeidsStudies   http://www.uva-­‐ aias.net/uploaded_files/ regular/BARSORIOvervie wReport-­‐1.pdf    

Precarious  employment  refers  to  employment  that  combines  some  of  the   following  characteristics:  low  levels  of  income  and  income  security,  low   job  and  employment  security,  bad  working  conditions,  limited  access  to   training,  limited  social  security  rights  and/or  limited  voice.  Precarious   employment  affects  the  working  situation  of  the  person  in  such  

employment  but  also  his  or  her  private  life  and  the  household  he  or  she  is   part  of  through,  for  example,  low  income,  problems  in  accessing  loans  or   high  levels  of  insecurity.  

 

Several  conclusions  come  forward  out  of  this  table  of  definitions.  First  of  all,  precarious  work   is  not  easy  to  delineate.  Secondly,  the  concept  is  multi-­‐faceted;  not  one  organisation  defines   it  through  a  single  aspect  of  employment  or  work.  However,  the  following  aspects  are  part   of  practically  all  descriptions:  

(15)

• The  instability  or  insecurity  of  jobs   • Low  wages  

• Limited  social  security  rights    

Other,  less  often  returning,  aspects  of  precarious  work  are:  

• Bad  working  conditions,  including  a  lack  of  health  and  safety   • Loss  of  meaning  of  work  

• Denial  or  discouragement  to  join  a  trade  union  and  participate  in  collective   bargaining  and  other  forms  of  democratic  workplace  representation   • Lack  of  participation  in  company  decision  making  

• Limited  access  to  training  

• Intrusion  into  private  and  family  life  (through  disabling  planning,  causing   insecurity,  low  income  and  difficulties  in  accessing  loans)  

 

Some  organisations  also  emphasise  the  importance  of  context;  of  economic  as  well  as  social   structure.  Furthermore,  several  also  hint  towards  the  expanding  trend  in  precariousness,   notably  the  International  Labour  Organisation,  as  employers  are  actively  looking  for  ways  to   push  precarious  work  as  a  means  of  increasing  their  profits.    

The  definitions  and  shared  characteristics  provided  by  these  organisations  overlap   with,  and  at  the  same  time  are  often  derived  from,  the  definitions  of  precarious  

employment  used  in  academic  debates.  

2.3.2  Precarious  employment  defined  

Common  characteristics  ascribed  to  employment  precariousness  clearly  come  forward   throughout  academic  literature;  they  revolve  around  objective  (legal)  and  subjective   (perceived)  uncertainty  and  insecurity,  or  a  state  of  threatening  risk.    

The  uncertainty  or  insecurity  relates  most  importantly  to  the  ability  to  secure  a  sufficient   income  and  the  status  of  employment  and  related  chances  of  dismissal  (Olsthoorn,  2013).   These  two  elements  return  in  an  often  cited  early  definition:  precarious  employment  occurs   when  employment  fails  to  provide  employees  with  a  minimum  standard  of  living  (Rodgers   and  Rodgers,  1989),  because  both  income  and  continuation  of  employment  matter  in  the   ability  to  ensure  a  minimum  standard  of  living.  However,  the  context  in  which  the  

employment  relation  takes  place  also  matters.  This  mainly  refers  to  the  rights  employees   derive  from  their  employment  relation  (Olsthoorn,  2013).    Other  aspects,  such  as  working   conditions,  power  and  voice,  task  autonomy,  career  and  salary  growth  opportunities  and   employment  tenure  are  also  returning  aspects  related  to  precariousness.  

 

The  concept  of  precarious  work  goes  beyond  the  form  of  employment  to  look  at  the   range  of  factors  that  contribute  to  whether  a  particular  form  of  employment  

exposes  the  worker  to  employment  instability,  a  lack  of  legal  and  union  protection,   and  social  and  economic  vulnerability  (Rodgers  and  Rodgers,  1989,  p.1).  

 

This  also  relates  to  rights  against  arbitrary  discretionary  power  of  employers,  either  through   labour  law,  trade  unions  and  collective  bargaining  or  the  right  of  appeal  at  court.  This  range   of  factors  exists  in  different  dimensions.  Thus  while  threatening  insecurity  due  to  

employment  relation  characteristics  is  key,  the  concept  precariousness  is  multidimensional,   it:  

 

(…)  not  only  results  from  a  limited  contract  duration  (the  temporal  dimension),  but   also  from  insufficient  pay  and  salary  progression  (the  economic  dimension),  lack  of,   or  reduced,  access  to  legal  and  social  protection  (the  social  dimension),  or  the  

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

Job security has also been shown to major role as a mediator between flexible employment and well- being in a similar study conducted using the ESS database.(Van den

Based on a search in the Scopus digital library, we report from an analysis of peer-reviewed systematic literature reviews and mapping studies to showcase major areas of RE

ABSTRACT: Though 1,4-disubstituted 1,2,3-triazole rings have been utilized as electronic bridges in the solution phase, the use of a triazole ring to serve as an electronic bridge

consistency in brand advertisements and customer-based brand equity, brand attitude and brand image and whether this relationship is moderated by brand familiarity, a 3 (level

The energy market is transitioning from a supply driven market to a demand driven market, from a central to decentral production and from fossil/nuclear fueled to renewable

My name is Delilah Takawira and I am a Master of Nutrition Student at Stellenbosch University I would like to invite you to participate in a research intervention that aims to

The following keywords were used for search purposes: brand, brand awareness, brand loyalty, destination image, brand personality, tourism marketing, tourism promotion,