• No results found

Political backlash in Latin America : a curse or blessing for the water supply and sanitation services? : a case study of Bolivia, Chile and Ecuador

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Political backlash in Latin America : a curse or blessing for the water supply and sanitation services? : a case study of Bolivia, Chile and Ecuador"

Copied!
62
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

 

Political  backlash  in  Latin  America:  a  curse  or  

blessing  for  the  water  supply  and  sanitation  

services?  

A  case  study  of  Bolivia,  Chile  and  Ecuador  

       

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Lisanne  Soffner  

10152792  

Graduate  School  of  Social  Sciences  

MA  International  Relations  

Supervisor:  F.  Boussaid  

Date:  June  2015  

University  of  Amsterdam  

 

(2)

 

Abstract  

In  the  mid-­‐2000s  a  political  backlash  occurred  in  Latin  America.  There  has  been  much   written  on  the  causes  of  the  backlash,  but  not  on  the  effects  of  the  backlash.  This  thesis   focuses  on  the  effects  of  the  political  backlash  on  the  water  sector  in  Latin  America.  The   aim  is  to  find  the  answers  to  the  following  questions:  Did  the  political  backlash  

accompany  in  Latin  America  policy  change  of  the  water  supply  and  sanitation  (WSS)   services?    What  explains  the  differences  between  countries?  And  how  did  the  political   backlash  in  Latin  America  affect  the  access  to  WSS  services?  The  expectation  is  that  the   institutional  context  of  a  country  determines  if  a  backlash  is  accompanied  by  change  and   that  it  also  determines  the  amount  of  access  to  WSS  services  before  and  after  the  

backlash.  Using  a  case  study  approach  this  thesis  discusses  the  cases  of  Bolivia,  Chile  and   Ecuador.  The  conclusions  drawn  from  these  case  studies  partially  support  the  proposed   theory.  However,  it  is  concluded  that  this  thesis  is  more  an  explorative  research  and  that  

(3)

Table  of  contents  

ABSTRACT  ...  2  

INTRODUCTION  ...  4  

BACKLASH  ...  5  

WSS  SERVICES  IN  LATIN  AMERICA  ...  7  

Sectoral  policy  ...  7  

Sector  structure  and  institutional  organization  ...  8  

THEORY  ...  9  

A  CASE-­‐STUDY  APPROACH  ...  13  

BACKGROUND  LATIN  AMERICA  ...  14  

BOLIVIAN  CASE  ...  15  

CONTEXT  ...  15  

STATE  RESTRUCTURING  AND  INSTITUTIONAL  CONTEXT  ...  17  

State  restructuring  in  the  1990s  ...  17  

State  restructuring  in  the  2000s  ...  18  

Institutional  context  ...  19  

WSS  SERVICES  IN  BOLIVIA:  FROM  THE  NEOLIBERAL  PARADIGM  TO  THE  WATER  WARS.  ...  19  

Water  management  in  the  1990s  ...  20  

Water  privatization  and  water  wars  ...  20  

WATER  MANAGEMENT  AFTER  THE  WATER  WARS  ...  22  

De-­‐regulation  under  Evo  Morales  ...  22  

Water  management  from  a  traditional  to  a  modern  institutional  model  ...  23  

ACCESS  TO  WATER  AND  SANITATION  IN  BOLIVIA  ...  23  

CONCLUSIONS  BOLIVIA  ...  27  

CHILEAN  CASE  ...  29  

CONTEXT  ...  29  

State  restructuring  in  the  1980s  and  1990s  ...  30  

State  restructuring  in  the  2000s  ...  31  

Institutional  context  ...  32  

WATER  SUPPLY  AND  SANITATION  SERVICES  (WSS)  IN  CHILE:  WATER  LAWS,  WATER  RIGHTS  AND  WATER   MARKETS.  ...  32  

Water  management  from  1990s  till  the  present  ...  34  

Water  management  institutional  model  ...  35  

ACCESS  TO  WATER  AND  SANITATION  IN  CHILE  ...  35  

CONCLUSIONS  CHILE  ...  40  

ECUADORIAN  CASE  ...  42  

CONTEXT  ...  42  

STATE  RESTRUCTURING  AND  INSTITUTIONAL  CONTEXT  ...  44  

State  restructuring  in  the  1980s  and  1990s  ...  44  

State  restructuring  in  the  2000s  ...  45  

Institutional  context  ...  46  

WSS  SERVICES  IN  ECUADOR:  POLYCENTRICITY  AND  WATER  RIGHTS.  ...  46  

The  neoliberalization  of  water  governance  ...  47  

WATER  REFORM  AFTER  THE  ‘LEFT  TURN’  ...  48  

Institutional  model  shift  ...  49  

ACCESS  TO  WSS  SERVICES  IN  ECUADOR  ...  50  

CONCLUSIONS  ECUADOR  ...  53  

CONCLUSIONS/DISCUSSION  ...  54  

REFERENCES  ...  56  

(4)

 

Introduction  

“Backlash  in  Latin  America”  was  on  the  cover  of  the  economist  on  December  6,  1996.   The  article  described  the  trend  of  Latin  American  leaders  cutting  their  budgets,  while  at   the  same  time  they  opened  their  countries  for  the  international  trade  market.  The   author  argued  that  the  pace  of  growth  was  lower  than  expected,  which  would  lead  to   frustrations  and  eventually  to  a  political  backlash  in  Latin  America  (Stokes,  2009:  1;  The   Economist,  1996).  According  to  the  Oxford  dictionary  a  backlash  is:  “a  strong  negative   reaction  by  a  large  number  of  people,  especially  to  social  or  political  development.  In   this  article  the  authors  suggest  a  backlash  against  the  neoliberal  reforms  in  Latin  

America.  This  argument  was  supported  by  the  struggles  of  political  leaders  at  that  time;   the  popularity  of  both  neoliberal  presidents  Fujimori  (Peru)  and  Menem  in  Argentina   decreased,  Mexico  faced  guerrilla  movements  and  president  Frei  of  Chile  had  to  deal   with  a  restive  public  (Stokes,  2009:  1;  The  Economist,  1996).  

                In  December  2006,  ten  years  after  the  publication  of  this  story,  leftist  candidates   won  the  presidential  elections  in  Brazil,  Ecuador,  Nicaragua,  Venezuela  and  Peru.   However,  these  were  not  the  first  leftist  leaders  winning  in  Latin  America.  The  trend   started  in  2003  when  Kirchner  won  in  Argentina,  Vázquez  in  2004  won  in  Uruguay  and   both  Bachelet  of  Chile  and  Morales  of  Bolivia  won  the  elections  in  2005.  In  July  of  2006   the  leftist  candidate  lost  in  Mexico  after  a  close  call  and  in  2007  was  Colom  elected  to   president  in  Guatemala  after  defeating  his  rightist  opponent.  Consequently,  in  2008,  11   out  of  the  18  major  countries  in  Latin  America  were  ruled  by  a  left-­‐centred  president.  In   other  words,  65%  of  the  countries  in  this  region  and  approximately  350  million  people   lived  under  a  left-­‐centred  president  (Stokes,  2009:  1).  

                The  many  unpopular  policies  of  the  neoliberal  development  paradigm  have   contributed  to  this  backlash.  One  of  these  unpopular  policies  was  the  privatization  of  the   water  supply  and  sanitation  (WSS)  services  because  in  some  cases  it  led  to  rate  hikes,   lack  of  transparency,  cut  offs  to  the  poorest  customers  and  poor  water  quality.  Latin   America  was  one  of  the  regions,  along  with  Africa  and  Asia,  which  experienced  these   negative  effects.  Consequently,  in  Latin  America  a  lot  of  the  WSS  contracts  came  under   attack,  which  led  to  protests  to  early  cancelation  of  the  WSS,  contracts  in  Bolivia  and   Argentina  (Baer,  2014:  141).  There  is  much  written  about  the  backlash  and  its  causes,   but  not  about  the  consequences  of  the  backlash.  You  might  expect  that  in  the  countries   of  Latin  America  where  the  backlash  occurred,  the  unpopular  neoliberal  policies  would   immediately  be  reversed  like  water  privatization.  However,  reality  shows  that  this  is  no   indisputable  fact;  some  countries  have  indeed  completely  reversed  the  policies  of  their   water  provision,  some  have  kept  the  privatization  measures,  and  others  moved  on  to  a   mix  of  public  and  private  provision  (Baer,  2014:  144).  This  phenomenon  raises  the   following  questions:  Did  the  political  backlash  accompany  in  Latin  America  policy   change  of  the  water  supply  and  sanitation  (WSS)  services?    What  explains  the   differences  between  countries?  And  how  did  the  political  backlash  in  Latin  America   affect  the  access  to  WSS  services?  The  aim  of  this  thesis  is  to  find  answers  to  two  these   questions  using  a  comparative  case  study.  In  order  to  answer  the  questions  is  first  some   background  information  on  the  political  backlash  in  Latin  America  discussed.  

Thereafter,  there  is  a  general  chapter  on  the  WSS  services  in  Latin  America.  That  chapter   is  followed  by  my  theory  on  this  topic  and  subsequently  follows  a  justification  for  the   case-­‐study  approach,  which  includes  some  background  information  on  Latin  America.  

(5)

Then  the  three  cases  of  Bolivia,  Chile  and  Ecuador  are  discussed.  Finally  this  thesis  ends   with  a  discussion  and  some  conclusions.  

 

Backlash  

It  was  widely  assumed  that  the  backlash  that  started  in  2005  in  Latin  America  occurred   as  a  reaction  to  the  unpopular  neoliberal  policy  reforms  in  the  1980s  and  1990s.  

However,  this  common  narrative  oversimplifies  the  relationship  between  neoliberalism   and  populism  because  it  is  “based  on  static  conceptions  of  neoliberal  reforms”  and  sees   “these  phenomena  as  mutually  exclusive  and  antagonistic  forces.”  (Haarstad  &  

Andersson,  2009:  1).  It  is  stated  by  various  authors  that  the  relationship  between   neoliberalism  and  populism  is  more  complex  than  a  simple  binary  division  (Haarstad  &   Andersson,  2009:  1).  

                For  example  Weyland  (2003:  1112)  argues  that  neoliberalism  and  populism  can   coexist  in  one  system  and  calls  this  ‘neoliberal  populism’.  His  argument  is,  that  under   some  circumstances,  populist  politics  can  go  hand  in  hand  with  neoliberal  

socioeconomic  policy  approaches  because  they  have  various  affinities.  An  example  of   these  affinities  is  that  successful  market  reform  can  strengthen  the  position  of  a  populist   leader  (Weyland,  2003:  1100).  However,  he  acknowledged  that  the  definition  of  

populism  explains  the  differences  between  authors  who  argue  that  neoliberalism  and   populism  can  coexist  together  and  the  authors  who  argue  that  there  is  an  

incompatibility  between  neoliberalism  and  populism  (Weyland,  2003:  1096).  In  a  later   written  article  Weyland  (2009:  145)  adds  on  to  his  previous  argument  and  he  argues   that  the  leftist  wave  that  emerged  in  Latin  America  is  not  uniform;  “The  new  

governments  range  from  the  cautious  Concertación,  a  solid  coalition  of  centrist  and  left-­‐ wing  parties  in  Chile,  to  the  radical  populism  of  Hugo  Chávez  in  Venezuela.  Other   governments  align  between  these  extremes.”  (Weyland,  2009:  145).  He  bases  this   argument  on  the  rentier  theory  and  states  that  the  fundamental  cause  of  the  rise  of  the   radical  left  in  Latin  America  is  the  availability  of  natural  resource  wealth  (Weyland,   2009:  151).  

                Haarstad  and  Andersson  (2009:  22)  argue  that  the  historical  traditions  of  the   indigenous  community  have  contributed  to  the  backlash  in  Latin  America,  but  argue  that   there  probably  are  more  factors  influencing  the  backlash.  Doyle  (2011:  1467)  states  that   the  current  emergence  of  populism  in  Latin  America  is  due  to  the  lack  in  trust  of  political   institutions  of  liberal  democracy.  This  would  explain  the  varying  degrees  of  popularity   for  populism  within  Latin  America.  

                Another  view  on  the  Latin  American  backlash  comes  from  Burgess  (2003:  906).   She  argues  that  both  external  incentives  and  organizational  capacity  explain  the   adaptation  of  Populist  Parties  adaptation  in  Latin  America.  It  should  be  noted  that  the   research  found  that  not  both  the  external  incentives  and  organizational  capacities  need   to  be  strong  in  order  to  have  a  positive  effect  on  the  adaptation  of  Populist  Parties.  In   addition,  the  amount  of  adaptation  varies  per  country.  

                Roberts  (2007:  3)  finds  in  her  research  that  the  revival  of  populism  in  Latin   America  is  mainly  caused  by  the  institutional  weaknesses  and  the  market  insecurities.   She  argues  that  these  conditions  have  made  the  region  vulnerable  to  new  patterns  of   social  and  political  mobilization.  

                In  sum  it  can  be  said  that  there  is  little  consensus  on  the  causes  of  the  backlash  in   Latin  America.  However,  from  the  existing  literature  we  can  conclude  that  the  backlash  

(6)

was  not  uniform  and  that  it  varied  per  country.  This  might  explain  why  different  Latin   America  countries  pursued  different  policies  on  their  WSS.  

In  order  to  answer  the  second  question  we  first  need  to  look  at  the  privatization   debate.  The  provision  of  water  services  to  poor  people  has  been  a  thorny  issue.  It  can  be   stated  that  both  the  private  and  public  sector  have  failed  in  the  provision  of  water  

services  to  poor  people  (Bakker,  2007:  441).  Bakker  (2007:  442)  points  out  that  water  is   an  “uncooperative  commodity”  and  states  that  the  privatization  of  water  services  will   always  be  full  of  difficulties.    Furthermore,  the  critics  of  privatization  argue  that  the   commercialization  of  public  goods  is  solely  based  on  profits  and  therefore  will  increase   the  inequality  gap  across  metropolitan  regions  (Warner  &  Hefetz,  2002:  446).  

                The  empirical  evidence  of  Bayliss  (2002:  603)  shows  that  privatization  negatively   affects  the  livelihood  of  the  poor.  Privatization  takes  away  employment  and  income  and   it  reduces,  and  sometimes  even  excludes,  poor  people  from  access  to  WSS.  In  theory   privatization  will  stimulate  economic  growth  and  reduce  poverty.  However,  in  practice   there  is  no  empirical  evidence  of  a  relation  between  privatization  and  economic  growth   (Bayliss,  2002:  607).  Another  reason  why  privatization  harms  the  poor  is  that  

governments  must  provide  some  incentives  to  attract  investors.  These  incentives  are   often  concessions  so  the  country  meets  the  requirements  of  donors  (Bayliss,  2002:  608).                     Mr  Talbot  is  the  Chief  Executive  Officer  (CEO)  of  SAUR  (one  of  the  largest  water   companies  in  the  world)  and  a  strong  proponent  of  private  sector  participation  (PSP)  in   the  WSS.  He  claims  that  the  public  sector  has  failed  in  the  provision  of  WSS  and  argues   that  there  is  an  “unrealistic  demand”  in  developing  countries.  He  stated  that  SAUR   “cannot  provide  services  to  the  poor  without  government  subsidies  and  guarantees  and  

public  sector  investment.”  (Hall  &  Lobina,  2002:  4).  Budds  and  McGranahan  (2003:  112)  

are  in  line  with  this  argument  claiming  that  neither  the  private  nor  public  sector  on  its   own  is  able  to  provide  sufficient  WSS  to  the  poor  because  both  economics  and  politics   need  to  be  included  in  order  to  provide  adequate  services.  Other  scholars  contend,  that   some  government  intervention  is  needed  to  ensure  that  the  externalities  of  uneven  fiscal   capacity  are  internalized  (Warner  &  Hefetz,  2002:  446;  Lowery,  2000).  

                Other  strong  proponents  of  privatization  in  the  WSS  are  Anderson  and  Hill   (1997).  They  argue  that  water  privatization  is  the  most  efficient  way  in  providing   WSS.    The  market  allocates  water  more  efficiently  and  is  flexible  with  regards  to  the   change  of  price  in  the  WSS  (Anderson  and  Hill,  1997:  88).  

                Galiani,  Gertler  and  Schargrodosky  (2005:  87)  argue  that  the  advantage  of  PSP  is   that  it  provides  a  strong  incentive  for  cost  reduction  and  effectiveness.  These  incentives   of  cost  reduction  and  innovation  are  weak  under  public  ownership  because  public   ownership  does  not  benefit  from  more  efficient  and  innovative  provision  of  WSS.   According  to  their  empirical  evidence  there  is  an  increasing  rise  in  profitability,  

productivity  and  quality  in  sectors  that  made  a  shift  towards  privatization  (Galiani  et  al.   1997:  87;  Megginson  et  al.  1994;  Barberis  et  al.  1996;  Frydman  et  al.  1999;  La  Porta  and   Lopez-­‐de-­‐Silanes  1999).  When  states  have  a  non-­‐benevolent  leader  arguments  

described  above  favour  the  PSP  even  more  because  there  is  a  great  chance  that  non-­‐ benevolent  leaders  will  use  their  political  power  to  benefit  themselves  and  their   supporters  (Giliani  et  al.,  2005:  88).  

                Besides  this  strong  debate  between  state  led  and  private  led  water  provision  is   there  is  also  an  approach,  which  is  an  in-­‐between  method:  public  private  partnerships   (PPP).  The  argument  is  that  both  the  public  and  private  sector  can  deliver  meaningful   contributions  when  establishing  water  regulatory  institutions.  Hence,  the  best  approach   is  the  PPP  (Akhmouch,  2012:  13).  

(7)

  The  next  paragraph  elaborates  more  on  the  structure  of  the  water  sector  in  Latin   America.  There  is  explained  what  the  general  trend  in  organization  of  the  water  sector   has  been  over  time.  In  addition,  it  will  be  clear  whether  the  water  sector  in  Latin   America  is  privatized,  regulated  by  the  state  or  organized  through  PPP.  

WSS  services  in  Latin  America  

In  the  beginning  of  the  1990s  there  was  a  major  reformist  wave  of  the  water  supply   industry  occurring  in  the  Latin  American  region.  The  reform  of  the  water  supply  

industry  started  in  1988  in  Chile  when  the  country  adapted  new  legislation  considering   the  water  sector.  Thereafter,  in  1991  both  Mexico  and  Argentina  started  experimenting   with  private  sector  participation  (PSP).  The  second  reformist  wave  started  in  the  mid-­‐ 1990s  and  led  to  the  implementation  of  new  legislation  in  Bolivia,  Colombia  and  Peru.   After  these  countries  Brazil  and  Central  America  followed  and  by  the  end  of  the  90s   nearly  all  Latin  American  countries  had  reformed  their  water  sector  or  were  in  the   process  of  reform  (Foster,  2005:  1).  

 

Sectoral  policy  

The  condition  of  the  WSS  services  in  a  region  is  reflected  in  the  implemented  public   policies.  Regarding  Latin  America,  two  different  types  of  sectoral  policies  can  be   distinguished  and  these  two  different  sectoral  policies  are  linked  to  different  

institutional  models  (Foster,  2005:  CAF,  2012:  18).  The  first  model  is  the  ‘traditional’   model,  also  called  the  “clientalist”  model  (figure  1),  and  is  characterised  by  the  strong   power  of  the  provider.  Both  the  provisional  services  and  the  sectoral  functions  are  in  the   hands  of  the  provider  companies,  which  act  based  on  political  interests  (CAF,  2012:  21).  

  Figure  1.  Traditional  model  (Foster,  2005:  2).  

                 

The  second  model  is  called  the  modern  model  (figure  2),  and  is  characterised  by  

dispersed  power.  The  provision,  regulation,  planning  and  policies  of  the  WSS  sector  are   the  responsibility  of  multiple  actors,  which  is  contrary  to  the  traditional  model.  The  idea   behind  this  model  is  that  all  the  actors  should  respect  the  rules,  and  not  following  the   rules  will  have  consequences  (CAF,  2012:  21).  

(8)

  Figure  2.  Modern  model  (Foster,  2005:  2).  

 

Currently  countries  are  moving  from  a  traditional  towards  a  modern  model.  

Nevertheless,  the  traditional  model  is  still  the  dominant  model  in  the  Latin  American   region  (CAF,  2012:  19).  

 

Sector  structure  and  institutional  organization  

Besides  the  division  between  the  traditional  and  modern  models,  we  can  distinguish   three  ways  in  which  the  water  sector  is  structured;  local  monopoly,  regional  monopoly   and  national  monopoly.  In  the  1990s  the  water  industries  of  most  Latin  American   countries  were  organized  in  national  monopolies  that  were  directly  controlled  by  the   government.  However,  the  performance  of  the  national  monopolies  was  often  

disappointing  and  combined  with  the  political  pressure  for  devolution  among  all   governmental  sectors,  this  led  to  decentralization  of  the  water  sector  in  various   countries.  It  should  be  noted  that  the  decentralization  of  the  water  sector  was  not   caused  solely  by  its  bad  performance,  but  that  is  was  part  of  a  wider  reform  of  the  state   (Foster,  2005:  3).  

                The  water  sector  providers  discussed  above  can  be  organized  in  different   organizational  forms.  Table  one  shows  the  various  models  of  institutional  organization   of  the  water  sector.  

 

  Ownership   Control  

Direct  provision   State    

Corporatization   State   Public  corporation  

PSP  contracts   State   Private  corporation  

Mixed  enterprise   State  and  private  investors   Private  corporation   Private  enterprise   Private  corporation    

Cooperative   Customers    

Table  1.  Different  models  of  institutional  organization  (Foster,  2005:  5).    

Before  the  1990s,  the  water  services  in  Latin  America  were  almost  completely  state-­‐ owned  with  different  degrees  of  corporatization  among  different  countries.  The   institutional  form  of  the  water  sector  influences  the  interests  of  the  managers  of  the  

(9)

sector;  public  sector  managers  are  most  likely  influenced  by  political  pressures,  while  an   increased  amount  of  corporation  strengthens  the  political  independence  of  a  publicly   owned  corporation  because  it  helps  to  become  financially  self-­‐sufficient.  Contrary,  the   motivation  of  private  sector  managers  is  profit  making.  Therefore,  their  interests  are  the   reduction  of  costs  and  the  expansion  of  sales  revenues.  Taking  this  into  account,  it  is   argued  that  it  is  easier  to  regulate  private  operators  than  public  ones,  because   regulatory  instruments  can  be  designed  and  implemented  to  make  it  attractive  for   private  enterprises  to  act  in  a  way  that  is  positive  for  the  consumers  (Foster,  2005:  5).   However,  the  practice  shows  that  a  lot  of  difficulties  are  involved  with  the  

implementation  of  private  sector  participation  (PSP).  In  rural  areas  there  is  the  problem   of  commercial  viability;  water  provision  is  not  profitable  in  these  areas.  In  the  larger   urban  areas  the  problem  is  often  public  opposition.  Privatization  in  some  cases  leads  till   a  significant  tariff  hike,  which  is  highly  undesirable  by  the  citizens  (Foster,  2005:  6).    

Theory  

It  is  hard  to  find  an  answer  to  the  question  why  the  backlash  in  Latin  America  emerged.   However,  it  might  be  possible  to  find  the  factors  that  influence  the  change  or  

preservation  of  water  policy  among  countries  in  Latin  America.  

In  this  thesis  I  want  to  build  further  on  the  institutional  weakness  argument.  This   argument  is  proposed  by  various  (most)  actors  and  is  both  mentioned  as  main  cause  or   as  one  of  the  causes  that  influenced  the  revival  of  populism  in  Latin  America.  I  want  to   use  this  theory  to  explain  the  different  policy  outcomes  of  the  WSS  in  various  countries   in  Latin  America.  When  a  countries  water  provision  is  poorly  institutionalized,  this  will   have  a  negative  effect  on  the  WSS  services  in  a  country.  Even  though  Latin  America  can   be  seen  as  a  water  abundant  continent,  there  are  large  water  asymmetries  within   countries  in  this  region.  Water  resources  are  mostly  located  in  the  inland  of  the   continent,  while  urbanization  and  land  development  are  concentrated  near  the  coast.   These  developments  stem  from  the  colonial  time  (Meija,  n.d.:  6).  Countries  with  poorly   institutionalized  WSS  services  will  not  be  able  to  overcome  these  water  asymmetries   and  will  therefore  be  affected  by  the  backlash  and  change  their  water  policies.  On  the   other  hand  are  countries  with  good  institutionalized  WSS,  which  are  able  to  overcome   the  water  asymmetries.  The  WSS  services  are  working  properly  and  therefore  these   countries  will  not  be  affected  by  the  backlash.  

                The  core  of  this  argument  is  that  the  water  sector  in  Latin  America  remains  stuck   in  traditional  forms  of  the  exercise  of  power  and  problematic  accumulation  models.  The   power  within  the  water  sector  is  often  highly  dispersed,  which  causes  deep  structural   problems  that  are  not  solved  by  a  political  shift  from  right  to  left  (Terhorst  et  al.,  2013:   66).  Institutions  in  the  water  sector  are  conceptualized  in  the  following  way:  institutions   that  are  responsible  for  the  policy  design  and  implementation  of  the  water  resource   management,  water  supply  (domestic,  agriculture,  industrial)  and  wastewater   treatment.  

  Based  on  previous  research  it  can  be  stated  that  there  are  two  factors  under   which  the  political  backlash  is  accompanied  by  policy  change  of  the  WSS  services.  The   first  factor  is  the  general  institutional  context  of  a  country.  The  operationalization  of  the   institutional  context  of  a  country  is  derived  from  a  publication  of  Rice  and  Patrick   (2008).  In  their  book  ‘Index  of  state  weakness  in  the  developing  world’  they  have  used   four  categories  with  several  indicators  to  measure  the  weakness  of  a  state.  One  of  these   categories  is  political  and  the  indicators  in  this  category  “assess  the  quality  of  a  state’s  

(10)

political  institutions  and  the  extent  to  which  its  citizens  accept  as  legitimate  their  system   of  governance.”  (Rice  &  Patrick,  2008:  8).    The  political  basket  consists  of  five  political   indicators:  

 

1. Government  effectiveness:  “this  indicator  is  among  the  most  direct  measures   available  of  the  strength  and  quality  of  state  institutions,  which  are  essential  for   the  provision  of  public  goods  and  the  formulation  and  implementation  of  sound   policies.”  (Rice  &  Patrick,  2008:  30).  

2. Rule  of  law:  “The  state’s  ability  to  govern  on  the  basis  of  legitimate  public  norms   and  institutions  is  a  strong  indicator  of  the  likelihood  of  long-­‐term  political   stability.”  (Rice  &  Patrick,  2008:  30).  

3. Control  of  corruption:  “Responsibly  governed  states  are  able  to  prevent  the   diversion  of  public  resources  from  core  state  functions.  Extensive  corruption   erodes  state  institutions  and  curtails  investments  in  public  goods.”  (Rice  &   Patrick,  2008:  30).  

4. Voice  and  accountability:  “states  that  have  mechanisms  in  place  for  peaceful   dissent,  transfer  of  power  and  policy  reform,  and  are  less  prone  to  political   instability  in  the  long  term.”(Rice  &  Patrick,  2008:  30).  

5. Freedom:  “states  with  fewer  civil  liberties  and  political  rights  tend  to  be  more   susceptible  to  destabilizing  events.”  (Rice  &  Patrick,  2008:  30).  

 

Rice  and  Patrick  (2008:  9)  have  standardized  these  indicators  ranging  from  0.0  (worst)   to  10.0  (best).  It  is  expected  that  when  a  country  has  a  weak  institutional  context,  it  is   more  likely  that  the  backlash  in  this  country  is  accompanied  by  policy  change.  More   information  on  the  political  indicators  of  Rice  and  Patrick  (2008:  30)  used  in  this  thesis   can  be  found  in  the  appendix.    

  The  other  factor  under  which  the  political  backlash  accompanied  by  policy   change  of  the  WSS  services  is  the  structure  of  the  WSS  services.  The  WSS  services  in   Latin  America  are  structured  according  to  the  traditional  or  modern  model.  The  trend  in   Latin  America  is  that  countries  are  moving  from  a  traditional  towards  a  modern  model   (CAF,  2012:  19).  Hence,  when  countries  followed  the  traditional  model  prior  to  the   backlash  it  is  likely  that  after  the  backlash  a  transition  towards  the  modern  model  takes   place.  Nonetheless,  it  should  be  noted  that  the  water  sector  structure  is  interrelated  with   the  institutional  context.  A  strong  institutional  context  leads  to  a  proper  organized  water   sector,  no  matter  which  kind  of  model  the  country  is  using.  However,  when  the  

institutional  context  of  a  country  is  weak  has  this  has  negative  effect  on  the  water  sector.   In  this  case  the  water  sector  is  often  poorly  organized  because  the  institutional  context   is  weak  and  not  able  to  support  the  water  sector.  

  The  last  question  that  this  research  tries  to  answer  is:  how  did  the  political   backlash  in  Latin  America  affect  the  access  to  WSS  services?  In  order  to  answer  this   question  two  indicators  are  taken  into  account:  

 

1. Access  to  water  and  sanitation.   2. Water  tariffs    

 

The  first  point  will  be  measured  based  on  the  data  from  the  World  Bank  (2014)  on   access  to  water  and  sanitation.  Besides  looking  at  the  hard  data  on  access  to  water  and   sanitation,  I  will  look  at  the  improvement  in  access.  The  amount  of  improvement  during  

(11)

the  neoliberal  period  and  the  improvement  after  the  backlash  are  compared.  It  is  likely   that  a  countries  institutional  context  has  an  effect  on  the  access  to  water  and  sanitation.     In  addition  the  place  of  the  case  countries  is  examined  in  the  ranking  of  the  

Environmental  Performance  Index  (Environmental  Performance  Index,  2014)  on  the   issue  of  water  and  sanitation.  This  is  a  database  that  has  ranked  all  countries  from  1-­‐ 178.  With  this  information  it  can  be  determined  whether  a  country  has  an  adequate   access  to  water  and  sanitation  or  not.  Based  on  the  institutional  weakness  theory  the   expectation  is  that  countries  with  a  weak  institutional  context  have  a  lower  access  to   water  and  sanitation  than  countries  with  a  strong  institutional  context.  However,  it   should  be  noted  that  from  the  data  of  the  World  Bank  (2014)  on  access  to  water  and   sanitation  we  cannot  draw  firm  conclusions.  There  are  several  reasons  why  this  is  not   possible.  The  first  is  that  the  data  used  are  from  1990  (beginning  of  the  neoliberal   period)  until  2012.  The  neoliberal  period  lasted  until  2005,  which  is  16  years,  while  the   period  after  the  backlash  is  still  in  process.  Of  the  period  after  the  backlash  is  only  the   data  of  the  following  seven  years  available.  It  is  impossible  to  compare  16  years  with   seven  years,  because  you  cannot  predict  with  certainty  what  is  going  to  happen  the   upcoming  nine  years.  In  addition,  it  can  also  be  the  case  that  the  effects  of  the  changes   made  after  the  backlash  are  only  visible  in  the  long  term.  Besides  that  it  can  also  be  the   case  that  during  the  neoliberal  period  the  access  increased  rapidly  because  it  was   relatively  easy  to  provide  a  large  part  of  the  population  with  access.  While  it  are  the  last   few  percentages  of  the  population  without  access  that  are  the  hardest  to  reach.  For   example,  it  is  harder  to  provide  access  to  people  that  live  a  few  hundred  kilometres  from   urban  areas  than  to  reach  the  millions  of  people  living  in  the  urban  areas.  To  obtain  a   more  nuanced  view  on  the  data  on  access  if  water  and  sanitation  I  also  look  at  the  water   tariffs.  The  tariffs  of  water  over  the  years  give  us  valuable  information  in  the  

affordability  of  clean  water  and  sanitation  over  the  years.                                              

(12)

  Fig ur e  3 .  A rg um en t  f lo w  

(13)

A  case-­‐study  approach  

In  this  thesis  I  use  a  qualitative  case  method  approach.  This  approach  is  commonly  used   in  the  field  of  comparative  politics  because  scholars  in  this  field  apply  rational  actor   assumptions  in  a  nonmathematical  approach.  This  is  done  to  develop  hypotheses  and   theories  that  are  applicable  to  a  small  number  of  cases  (Mahony,  2007:  123;  e.g.,  Bates,   1981;  Geddes,  2003;  Laitin,  1999;  Munck,  2001).  

  The  countries  chosen  for  exploration  in  this  study  are  most  different  pathway   cases  (Gerring  &  Cojocaru,  2015:  8).  A  pathway  design  is  used  to  identify  the  causal   mechanisms.  This  is  possible  because  both  X  and  Y,  in  this  research  the  political   backlash  and  water  sector  policy,  are  known  (Gerring  &  Cojacaru,  2015:  8).  Pathway   cases  contain  both  treatment  and  outcome  of  interest  while  confounding  factors  are   excluded  (Gerring,  Kingstone,  Lange  &  Sinha,  2011:  1736).  

  The  region  this  research  is  interested  in  is  Latin  America;  hence  all  the  case   studies  are  located  there.  I  have  chosen  three  different  countries  in  the  region  of  Latin   America  to  discuss  in  this  thesis:  Bolivia,  Chile  and  Ecuador.  These  countries  do  not   share  all  the  same  characteristics  like  country  size,  population  size,  available  water,   population  or  type  of  government.  However,  the  expectation  is  that  the  institutional   context  of  a  country  determines  whether  or  not  the  political  backlash  leads  to  policy   change.  Both  Bolivia  and  Chile  elected  a  leftist  president  in  the  mid-­‐2000s  but  

completely  but  Bolivia  changed  its  water  policy  drastically  and  Chile  did  not.  In  order  to   diversify  the  sample  I  have  added  Ecuador.  Qua  characteristics  is  Ecuador  situated  in  the   middle  of  the  extremes  Bolivia  and  Chile  but  has  changed  its  water  policy  after  the   backlash.  I  want  to  use  this  case  to  confirm  or  reject  the  hypothesis  that  the  effects  of  the   backlash  are  dependent  on  the  institutional  context.  In  addition  the  cases  are  used  to   identify  other  factors  that  influence  policy  change  after  a  backlash.  

    A  case  study  method  with  a  small  N  is  the  most  appropriate  approach  to  address   the  questions  of  this  thesis  within  the  timeframe.    

  Each  case  study  begins  with  a  paragraph  on  the  general  context  of  the  country.   Thereafter  is  the  restructuring  of  the  state  and  institutional  context  in  the  neoliberal   period  and  period  after  the  backlash  discussed.  Thirdly,  the  management  of  the  WSS   services  is  discussed  in  depth  and  the  situations  before  and  after  the  backlash  are   compared.  Subsequently,  the  access  to  WSS  services  is  discussed  and  this  narrative  is   supported  with  data  of  the  World  Bank  (2014),  Environmental  Performance  Index   (2014)  and  data  on  the  water  tariffs  in  each  country.  Finally,  each  case  ends  with  a  short   sub-­‐conclusion.                          

(14)

Background  Latin  America  

Before  the  reformist  wave  in  Latin  America  can  be  discussed,  it  is  necessary  to  look  at   the  context  in  which  the  wave  took  place.  In  the  post-­‐war  period  the  Latin  American   region  followed  the  import  substituting  industrialization  (ISI)  model.  This  model   changed  the  entire  Latin  American  economy  and  therefore  also  the  institutions  and   society  (Forteza  &  Tommasi,  2005:  5).  In  short,  this  model  implies  state  regulation  to   control  the  impact  of  the  global  market  by  encouraging  the  domestic  industry  to  

enhance  domestic  innovation,  enhance  competitive  capacities  and  limit/prevent  import   of  manufactured  goods  (Greig  et  al.,  2007:  87).  However,  in  the  1960s  this  inward-­‐

oriented  development  strategy  started  to  show  the  first  cracks;  the  performance  of  Latin   America  was  disappointing  compared  to  the  performance  of  South-­‐East  Asia,  which   adopted  an  opposite  economic  model  (Forteza  &  Tommasi,  2005:  5).  The  production  in   Latin  America  was  inefficient;  there  were  high  unemployment  rates,  balance  of  payment   deficits,  inflation  and  sectoral  imbalances  (Greig  et  al.,  2007:  103;  Kiely  1998;  Norberg   2003).  These  negative  effects  led  to  the  gradual  erosion  of  support  for  the  ISI  model  and   the  debt  crisis  starting  in  1982  was  a  tipping  point  and  strengthened  the  view  that  the   ISI  model  was  not  working  and  unsustainable.  At  this  point  the  policy  reform  in  Latin   America  started  and  this  reform  was  revolving  around  the  ideas,  wich  later  became   known  as  the  Washington  Consensus  (Forteza  &  Tommasi,  2005:  5).  

                The  Washington  Consensus  is  a  concept  that  was  first  used  by  John  Williamson  in   1989.  It  was  a  new  development  model  for  developing  countries  that  were  affected  by   the  crisis  (Forteza  &  Tommasi,  2005:  5).  The  Washington  Consensus  consisted  of  a  list  of   neoliberal  policy  descriptions  that  would  ‘help’  developing  countries.  The  policies  are:   fiscal  discipline,  public  expenditure  priorities,  tax  reform,  interest  rates,  unified  

exchange  rates,  trade  liberalization,  foreign  direct  investment,  privatization,  

deregulation  and  property  rights  (Greig  et  al.,  2007:  120).  The  idea  behind  these  policies   was,  as  described  by  Sachs  (2005:  81):  “Be  like  us  (or  what  we  imagine  ourselves  to  be  –   free  market  oriented,  entrepreneurial,  fiscally  responsible)  and  you,  too,  can  enjoy  the   riches  of  private  sector-­‐led  economic  development.”  In  the  end  of  the  80s  and  the   beginning  of  the  90s  a  second  reformist  wave  took  place  towards  this  neoliberal   development  model  (Forteza  &  Tommasi,  2005:  5).  However,  after  implementation  of   the  pro-­‐market  reform  policies  it  became  clear  that  this  reform  brought  both  positive   and  negative  effects.  The  economic  outcomes  were  ambiguous;  while  the  inflation  in  the   Latin  American  region  significantly  declined,  the  policies  could  not  insolate  the  region   from  macroeconomic  shocks  (Forteza  &  Tommasi,  2005:  8).  Also  the  two  main  goals  of   the  Washington  Consensus,  economic  growth  and  increased  productivity,  were  not   fulfilled  as  expected.  Economic  growth  was  higher  than  during  the  lost  decade  in  the   80s,  but  far  below  the  economic  growth  the  country  experienced  in  the  60s  and  70s  and   still  way  below  the  growth  of  the  South-­‐East  Asian  region  (Forteza  &  Tommasi,  2005:  9;   Lora  and  Panizza,  2002;  Loayza  et  al.  2005).  Likewise,  the  Washington  Consesus  policies   did  not  raise  productivity  as  expected  and  can  be  neglected  as  a  factor  that  contributed   to  the  economic  growth  during  the  nineties  (Forteza  &  Tommasi,  2005:  9).  The  social   outcomes  of  the  economic  reform  were  also  not  as  expected.  While  some  scholars   argued  that  the  reform  had  a  positive  effect  on  poverty  and  income  distribution,  most   scholars  state  that  this  is  not  the  case  and  that  it  had  little  effect  on  inequality  and   poverty  reduction  (Forteza  &  Tommasi,  2005:  10).        

(15)

Bolivian  case  

Context  

 

Bolivia  is  a  lower  middle-­‐income   country  in  Latin  America  and  has  a   population  of  10.67  million  people   (World  Bank,  2013).  It  is  a  resource  rich   country  and  the  Bolivian  export  is   highly  dependent  on  the  raw  materials   that  are  produced  by  a  small  part  of  the   workforce.  Therefore,  the  export  of  raw   materials  is  not  able  to  support  the   entire  population  (Kohl&  Farthing,   2006:  62).  The  country  is  characterised   by  inequality  and  the  poorest  part  of  the   population  is  the  most  deprived  from   goods  and  services  (Nickson&Vargas,   2001:  Bustamante,  2004:  38).  

Like  most  Latin  American   countries  Bolivia  followed  the  import   substitution  industrialization  growth   model  (ISI)  in  the  post-­‐war  period.  This   model  dominated  the  region  until  the  

‘80s.  However,  following  the  ISI  model  did  not  help  Bolivia  to  become  more  independent   of  the  developed  countries  for  capital  and  manufactured  goods.  Besides  that  the  model   was  far  more  inefficient  than  in  that  it  was  in  South  East  Asia.  The  ISI  policies  were  more   restricted  and  therefore  led  to  inflation  and  generated  frequent  balance  of  payment   crisis  (Kohl&Farthing,  2006:  61).  By  the  1970s  it  became  clear  that  the  ISI  model  had   failed  in  Latin  America  and  the  critics  started  to  develop  a  new  economic  model  that  was   in  line  with  the  logic  of  trade  liberalization  and  globalization.  This  alternative  economic   model  was  later  known  as  the  Washington  Consensus  or  as  the  New  Economic  Policy   (NEP).  Following  this  NEP  had  various  consequences  for  Bolivia.  With  regards  to  the   political  and  economic  sphere  there  was  an  attempt  in  the  end  of  the  80s  to  establish  the   foundations  for  a  market  democracy  by  opening  the  market  and  introducing  municipal   elections  and  other  electoral  reform.  However,  due  to  the  long  Bolivian  history  of   resistance,  confrontational  politics  and  multiple  parties  made  this  very  hard.  After  the   attempt  to  political  reform  the  process  of  redefining  the  tasks  of  both  the  state  and  the   market  started.  This  led  to  the  withdrawal  of  the  state  from  the  economy.  Consequently,   the  economic  sector  got  privileged  in  the  policy-­‐making  process  (Kohl&Farthing,  2006:   82).  Secondly,  the  NEP  led  to  the  closing  of  the  state  mines,  which  were  the  most  

powerful  symbol  of  the  State  of  52’  (the  name  for  the  society  created  by  the  ISI  model).   State-­‐owned  enterprises  were  privatized  and  these  put  an  end  to  the  protectionist   policies  that  Bolivia  had  followed  under  the  ISI  model.  Bolivia  was  also  one  of  the  first   countries  where  these  neoliberal  policies  were  implemented  under  the  name  of   structural  adjustment  programs  (SAPs).  The  SAPs  soon  became  one  of  the  most  

favourite  tools  of  the  international  financial  institutions  (IFIs),  like  the  World  Bank  and   Figure  4.  Map  of  Bolivia.  (The  World   Factbook,  2015)  

(16)

the  IMF,  to  use  in  developing  countries  (Kohl  &  Farthin,  2006:  61).  It  is  important  to   notice  that  the  NEP  laid  the  foundation  for  more  economic  reform  and  for  the  political   decentralization  that  happened  in  Bolivia  

At  first,  the  impact  of  following  the  NEP  had  better  results  than  Bolivia  could  have   hoped  for;  within  a  couple  of  months  inflation  in  the  country  dropped  from  the  annual   rate  of  20,000%  to  9%.  Bolivia  soon  became  known  as  one  of  the  success  stories  of   neoliberalism’s  ability  to  stabilize  the  macroeconomics  of  a  country.  However,  the   implementation  of  the  NEP  also  had  some  negative  effects:  due  to  the  closing  of  the   mines  over  20.000  people  lost  their  jobs  within  the  first  year  and  in  addition  another   35.000  workers  lost  their  manufacturing  job  over  the  next  five  years  (Crabtree  et  al.   1987;  Farthing,  1991;  Kohl&Farthing,  2006:  61).  The  achievement  of  attaining  economic   stability  was  the  greatest  accomplishment  of  the  NEP  in  Bolivia  because  macro  economic   stability  is  a  necessary  condition  to  obtain  sustainable  growth.  It  should  also  be  noticed   that  the  main  reason  of  the  NEPs  fast  stabilizing  ability  was  the  tacit  legalization  of   cocaine  profits,  which  allowed  US  dollar  accounts  at  the  central  bank  (Kohl&Farthing,   2006:  73).  Nevertheless,  the  greatest  disadvantage  of  the  NEP  was  that  it  widened  the   gap  between  rich  and  poor  and  Bolivia  was  already  a  country  with  a  tiny  middle-­‐class.   The  new  neoliberal  policies  favoured  the  few  rich  at  the  top  and  exploited  the  poor.  To   minimalize  this  negative  effect  of  the  NEP  the  government  followed  their  long  tradition   of  dividing  popular  forces  and  made  different  deals  with  the  indigenous  campesinos  and   the  people  living  in  the  cities.  Hence  the  NEPs  new  property  tax  was  only  applied  on  the   city  and  not  the  rural  areas  (Kohl&Farthing,  2006:  81).  

                 In  1985  it  could  be  concluded  that  the  Paz  Estenssorro  government  was  the  first   government  since  1952  that,  more  or  less  successful,  created  a  new  paradigm  for  the   Bolivian  society.  By  balancing  coercion  with  consent  they  were  able  to,  as  we  currently   know  temporarily,  establish  a  neoliberal  paradigm  that  was  accepted  by  heterogeneous   society.  Dunkerley  argues  that  the  main  reason  for  the  failure  of  this  hegemonic  

neoliberal  consensus  lies  in  the  inability  of  the  government  to  institutionalize  and   control  the  new  neoliberal  regime  (Dunkerley,  1990;  Kohl&Farthing,  2006:  82).  

However,  it  is  important  to  notice  that  the  neoliberal  reforms  in  Bolivia  seldom  had  an   outcome  that  corresponded  with  the  policy  objectives.  And  this  mismatch  between   outcomes  and  political  objectives  led  to  frequent  resistance  of  the  population.   (Perreault,  2005:  266).  The  transition  period  towards  a  neoliberal  paradigm  reveals   some  major  weaknesses  of  the  Bolivian  government  and  their  policies.  Firstly,  for  the   political  system  to  work  political  patronage  needs  to  be  divided  among  the  ruling   parties.  This  is  not  in  line  with  the  neoliberal  wish  to  diminish  government  power   Secondly,  the  NEP  did  not  spread  the  benefits  of  neoliberal  market  development  equally   over  the  population.  The  rural  and  indigenous  people  have  a  long  and  perpetuating   history  of  exclusion.  When  the  NEP  was  implemented  the  policy  makers  did  not  include   these  people.  These  weaknesses  mainly  contributed  to  the  fragility  of  the  neoliberal   system  and  this  fragility  started  to  become  visible  in  the  second  half  of  the  1990s   (Kohl&Farthing,  2006:  83).  Subsequently,  in  2005  Evo  Morales  used  these  weaknesses   to  his  advantage  and  was  elected  president  with  the  promise  to  end  the  past  two  

decades  of  neoliberalism  (Spronk,  2014:  2).  The  next  paragraphs  elaborate  more  on  the   state  restructuring  taking  place  in  Bolivia  from  the  1990s  until  the  years  after  the   political  backlash.  

(17)

State  restructuring  and  institutional  context  

State  restructuring  in  the  1990s  

In  1993  Gonzalo  Sánchez  de  Lozada  became  president  of  Bolivia.  Before  his  election   Sánchez  de  Lozada  had  already  been  Minister  of  Planning.  During  his  time  as  minister  he   had  both  designed  and  implemented  some  of  the  more  radical  policies  of  the  NEP.  

Besides  that  he  had  also  thoughts  about  further  political  and  economic  reforms  for   Bolivia.  Sánchez  de  Lozada  felt  structural  economic  and  political  reform  were  necessary   to  reassert  authority  of  the  weakened  state  because  it  would  reduce  the  corruption,   renew  legitimacy  of  the  government  and  attract  foreign  investors.  When  Sánchez  de   Lozada  became  president  these  ideas  were  clearly  reflected  in  his  policy.  First  he  

implemented  his  Plan  de  Todos  (Plan  for  everyone),  which  was  a  radical  reformist  policy   package  in  order  to  drastically  change  both  the  economy  and  the  state  (Perreault,  2005:   272).  The  Plan  de  Todos  consisted  of  seven  mechanisms:  

 

1. “Constitutional  reform”  (Perreault,  2005:  272;  Kohl,  1999;  MNR-­‐MRTKL,  1993).   2. “Administrative  decentralization  through  the  Law  of  Popular  Participation  and    

the  Law  of  Decentralization”  (Perreault,  2005:  272;  Kohl,  1999;  MNR-­‐MRTKL,   1993)  

3. “Privatization  of  state  industries”  (Perreault,  2005:  272;  Kohl,  1999;  MNR-­‐ MRTKL,  1993).  

4. “A  second  agrarian  reform  through  the  Law  of  the  National  Institute  of  Agrarian   Reform”  (Perreault,  2005:  272;  Kohl,  1999;  MNR-­‐MRTKL,  1993).  

5. “Education  reform”  (Perreault,  2005:  272;  Kohl,  1999;  MNR-­‐MRTKL,  1993).   6. “Restructuring  of  the  pension  system  and  introduction  of  social  insurance  

payments  for  citizens  over  65  years  of  age”  (Perreault,  2005:  272;  Kohl,  1999;   MNR-­‐MRTKL,  1993).  

7. “Reforms  of  the  judicial  system.”  (Perreault,  2005:  272;  Kohl,  1999;  MNR-­‐ MRTKL,  1993)  

 

The  first  point,  constitutional  reform,  was  to  clear  the  way  for  the  other  reforms.  The   new  constitution  of  1994  stated  that  Bolivia  was  a  multi-­‐ethnic  and  pluri-­‐cultural   country.  In  addition  the  constitution  acknowledged  the  rights  for  campesino  and   indigenous  people  (Perreault,  2005:  272;  Healy  and  Paukson,  2000;  Van  Cott,  2000;   Zimmerer,  2000b).  

                Not  all  the  reform  measures  were  drastic;  the  majority  of  the  measures  were   implemented  more  gradually.  These  measures  included  the  reduction  of  social  spending   and  the  freezing  of  wages.  However,  these  piecemeal  measures  fueled  an  almost  

continuous  political  unrest  during  the  90s.  Plan  de  Todos  was  not  only  implemented  to   reform  the  economy,  it  had  a  much  bigger  purpose.  It  was  designed  to  restructure  the   state  by  reforming  social  service,  fiscal  and  administrative  structures,  industry,   agriculture  and  land  markets.  Plan  de  Todos  gained  its  legitimacy  because  of  the   rewritten  constitution  of  1994  (Perreault,  2005:  272;  Van  Cott,  2000).  The  main  

innovation  of  the  Plan  the  Todos  compared  to  former  reforms  was  that  it  simultaneously   tried  to  address  the  autonomy  that  the  subnational  regions  asked  for  with  the  opening  of   their  markets,  which  the  international  institutions  like  the  IMF  demanded.  So  the  Plan   de  Todos  transferred  the  authority  over  decision-­‐making  and  state  revenues  from  the   central  government  towards  the  local  level,  while  it  at  the  same  time  supported  foreign   investments  in  their  economy.  Two  of  the  seven  mechanisms  of  the  Plan  de  Todos  had  

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

Er is veel geschreven over integriteit van bestuurders op de verschillende eilanden in Caribisch Nederland, maar niet erg veel over Saba en Sint Eustatius4. Om deze

The calculation thus confirms our hypothesis: at zero voltage, the surface roughness is smoothed out by the dynamically entrained thick oil film; for finite voltage, the

In addition to these well-known roles of aneuploidy, chromosome copy number changes have also been reported in some studies to occur in neurons in healthy human brain and

municipalities have trouble cancelling these plans. Protest groups see them as avoidable, and try to influence councils. Category three are the other plans and projects. These

Dit onderzoek is opgedeeld in zeven hoofdstukken. Na de inleiding komen in hoofdstuk 2 de methoden van dit onderzoek aan bod. Gehanteerde methoden worden verantwoord, alsmede de

In the study it has been found that lack of proper communication is one of the factors that is a challenge to effective parental involvement in schools. Parents do not receive

According to Ross, there are four main pathways through which natural resources could lead to violent conflicts: their effects on the economy, on governance, on communities living in

This means that interface resistance in the gas phase can generally be neglected and therefore the biolayer concentration at the interface may be assumed to be in