• No results found

The relationship between competition and corporate social responsibility : an economic review

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "The relationship between competition and corporate social responsibility : an economic review"

Copied!
77
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

M

ASTER

T

HESIS

MS

C

B

USINESS

E

CONOMICS

: C

OMPETITION

L

AW

& E

CONOMICS

T

HE

R

ELATIONSHIP BETWEEN

C

OMPETITION AND

C

ORPORATE

S

OCIAL

R

ESPONSIBILITY

: A

N

E

CONOMIC

R

EVIEW

Thierry F. Wetzel

11834544

thierry.wetzel@student.uva.nl

Supervision:

Leonard Treuren

Professor dr. Maarten Pieter Schinkel

(2)

Statement of Originality

This document is written by Student Thierry F. Wetzel who declares to take full

responsibil-ity for the contents of this document. I declare that the text and the work presented in this

document are original and that no sources other than those mentioned in the text and its

ref-erences have been used in creating it. The Faculty of Economics and Business is responsible

(3)

Abstract

Rising public awareness of global phenomena such as climate change and the corresponding

influence of special interests and activist groups have made corporate social responsibility

(CSR) concerns increasingly pervasive. “Ethical” behaviour in business has often been

at-tributed to firms’ and managers’ individual actions as well as to pressures originating from

internal stakeholders. At present, however, it is clear that also external pressures such as

product market competition act as a determinant of socially responsible behaviour. This

thesis delineates what is currently known about the relationship between competition and

corporate social responsibility. Existing literature indicates that increased levels of

compe-tition are positively correlated to corporate social responsibility, yet much of the evidence

is based on ambiguous measures of competition and CSR. This thesis discusses issues and

implications of current research and gives an overview of recent results in this strain of

liter-ature.

(4)

Contents

Abstract ii 1 Introduction 1 2 Views on CSR 4 2.1 Selective CSR Background . . . 5 2.2 Definition of CSR . . . 8

2.3 Objective Function Firms Maximise . . . 10

2.4 Is CSR Profitable? . . . 11

3 Measures of Competition and CSR 15 3.1 Measures Used . . . 15

3.2 Measurement & Data Concerns . . . 22

4 Competition and CSR 30 4.1 Qualitative & Theoretical Work . . . 32

4.2 Empirical Work . . . 37

4.3 What do we Know? . . . 57

5 Discussion 59 5.1 Gaps & Future Research . . . 59

5.2 How to go About? . . . 60

(5)

1

Introduction

In 1999, the European Commission (EC) notably condoned an agreement on the basis of the

public interest defence in cartel offences1. The agreement in question had the objective to

cease the production of washing machines below a certain energy efficiency level. In this

way, the reduction in energy consumption of washing machines would not just result in large

benefits for the environment, but also allow consumers to recoup the higher initial costs of

more efficient washing machines through reduced costs of usage within a reasonable time

frame. The EC has acknowledged the environmental benefits and cost savings for potential

customers and correspondingly allowed the agreement to take place.2

The rationale behind the public interest defence in cartel offences is about shielding

com-panies from competition; this should enable them to deploy resources to corporate social

responsibility (CSR) causes, which are, arguably, most beneficial in industries where the

quality of services to the public may decrease in response to competitive pressures. As a

result there has been a social push towards less competitive industries in order to benefit

society. This view, however, strongly neglects the positive impacts competition can have

on innovation, pricing, development and product differentiation. Without a strong

justifica-tion, allowing green cartels could provide leeway to companies that seek to disguise socially

undesirable, if not malfeasant, behavior behind a fac¸ade of positive deeds.

For this reason, gaining a comprehensive understanding of the effects that competition

has on CSR in different industrial context stands as an indispensable condition to effectively

determine when a public interest defence is likely to achieve a welfare-enhancing outcome.

1Under the Treaty of the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU) Article 101(1) prohibits “all

agree-ments between undertakings, decisions by associations of undertakings and concerted practices which may affect trade between Member States and which have as their object or effect the prevention, restriction or dis-tortion of competition within the internal market. . .”. There is, however, the exception laid out in Art. 101(3), which states that agreements “which contributes to improving the production or distribution of goods or to promoting technical or economic progress, while allowing consumers a fair share of the resulting benefit” can be exempted. This exception is known as the public interest defence in cartel offences.

(6)

From an empirical standpoint, only few studies have focused on how competition

re-lates to CSR. The reasons for this relationship remaining underexplored may partially be

attributed to endemic problems of endogeneity that add to methodological and data issues3

that arise when testing the effect of competition on firms' CSR practices. The extant

liter-ature has primarily been focused on CSR and its effect on corporate financial performance

(Vishwanathan, 2017; Margolis et al., 2009; Orlitzky et al., 2008; Margolis and Walsh, 2003),

whilst others have investigated how CSR is affected due to pressures imposed by a wide

vari-ety of stakeholder groups such as, but not limited to, governments, consumers and employees

(Aguilera et al., 2007; Barnett, 2007; Schuler and Cording, 2006; McWilliams and Siegel,

2001; Donaldson and Preston, 1995). Nevertheless, the driving forces of firm’s engagement

in CSR are not just dependent on internal factors such as pressures from consumers and

em-ployees, which implies that external market conditions will, to some extent at least, influence

CSR conduct. Subsequently, one can only understand how CSR conduct is shaped once the

relationship between competition and CSR has been scrutinised. Yet, the question of how

competition relates to CSR remains underdeveloped (Flammer, 2015; Hawn and Kang, 2013;

Van de Ven and Jeurissen, 2005).

At present4, only a relatively small amount of empirical work has tested the impact

com-petition exhibits on CSR conduct. In most cases this growing body of research has employed

the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI), as a measure for competition, and the Kinder

Lyden-berg and Domini (KLD) database to quantify CSR conduct on multiple dimensions relating

to the firms' diverse stakeholders, e.g. employees, the environment or investors. As

elab-orated in section 3 these measures can produce misleading results: as the results can only

be as robust as the underlying data and most of this information is self-reported by firms,

inconsistencies in the inputs' accuracy may lead to systematic differences in outcome. The

3CSR is a relatively new concept and the reliability of quantifying it is questionable as elaborated in section

3.

4The first paper found to build an econometric model of competition and CSR was in 2010. This will be

(7)

differences between the studies' findings are in turn likely to be driven by the variety of

mea-sures and methodologies employed, thereby obfuscates the effect that competitive pressure

have on CSR conduct. Some works have used fitted HHI values that account for the firm

being active in multiple industries in addition to using a different CSR measure derived from

the Asset4 database. As discussed in section 3, many of the concerns that the HHI

val-ues raise are rarely addressed. Especially in high-tech industries and platform competition,

market power may originate from small technological advancements that are not accurately

proxied by using concentration measures such as the HHI based on market shares, number

of employees and/or size of a company.

In light of these shortcomings and their implications for research, this study sets out to

demystify the relationship between competition and CSR, by building on work from

man-agerial and economic literature that aimed at identifying what aspects of CSR are profitable,

shedding light on the relationship between competition and CSR. Accordingly, the research

addresses the following questions: What does existing literature say about the relationship?

What are the issues with existing empirical evidence, and if yes what are the implications?

What future steps have to be taken in order to improve our understanding of the relationship?

Widespread CSR concerns have become increasingly pervasive due to the mounting public

awareness of global phenomena such as climate change and the resulting influence of

spe-cial interest agencies and activist groups, which include the World Wildlife Fund (WWF),

Greenpeace and the Sierra Club. Understanding the antecedents of CSR stands as a

precon-dition for designing strategies and policies that ultimately improve total welfare. Among its

antecedents, competition is expected to play a crucial role in shaping firms' CSR behavior

and the use of CSR as a competitive strategy. The nexus between competition and CSR is

thus not only theoretically relevant for economists and policymakers, but also for managers

who seek to understand the implications of CSR as a strategy in response to external market

(8)

This thesis contributes to the existing literature body by identifying the concerns that arise

when addressing the question of how competition and CSR relate to one another. Moreover,

the study investigates how these concerns have been addressed in current empirical work

and what the consequences of neglecting these concerns are. The main contribution is

sum-marising (1) what we know about the relationship, based on current empirical work, (2) what

aspects remain underdeveloped, and (3) how future research should address the question of

how competition relates to CSR.

The next section provides a brief overview of what CSR is and the conflicting views.

It will also briefly touch upon what firms maximise and whether profit maximisation is

achieved by employing CSR strategies. The core contribution of this thesis is to critically

assess the current empirical work conducted on the subject and provide an overview of what

evidence exists on the relationship of competition and CSR, which will be addressed in

Sec-tion 4. For that to be possible, however, it is necessary to provide an overview of how the

two main variables are measured. This will be addressed in Section 3. The final sections are

devoted to suggest avenues for future research and address what is needed to understand and

improve our understanding of said relationship.

2

Views on CSR

Providing a history of how CSR has been perceived and defined is not within the interest

of this research, it is, however, useful to provide a brief overview. This will illustrate to the

reader how difficult it is to measure and quantify a concept for which there are several

un-derlying paradigms and dimensions. For a comprehensive review see Carroll (2008, 1999);

(9)

2.1 Selective CSR Background

Prior to 1900 corporate contributions were discredited by many and such contributions were

legally bound to bring about benefits to the corporation (Muirhead, 1999). From the 1930s

the view has shifted and corporations started feeling pressure to effectuate social

contri-butions (Eberstadt, 1973). In the period leading to the 1950s there was a shift towards a

philanthropic responsibility of corporations and donations became the major aspect of

cor-porate social responsibility (Murphy, 1978). In 1991 Carroll5proposed the pyramid of CSR,

suggesting that it has as its basis the economic responsibilities, followed by legal, ethical

and philanthropic responsibilities. “Carroll's CSR domains and pyramid framework remain

a leading paradigm of CSR in the social issues in [the] management field” (Schwartz, 2017,

p. 504). Thus, CSR, currently, is seen as some combination of these dimensions: economic,

legal, ethical and altruistic responsibilities (Schwartz, 2017; Lantos, 2001; Carroll, 2008;

Carroll et al., 1991).

There are several views on underlying paradigms, motives and effectiveness of CSR

practices. Friedman proposed the shareholder view. He ends his essay by quoting a sentence

from his book: “[Social Responsibility is a] fundamentally subversive doctrine in a free

society, . . . , there is one and only one social responsibility of business — to use it resources

and engage in activities designed to increase its profits so long as it stays within the rules of

the game, which is to say, engages in open and free competition without deception or fraud”

(Friedman, 2007, p. 178). Thus, he indicates that the sole responsibility of the agent is to

the principal, which usually seeks profits. In this view, there is no responsibility beyond the

one to the principal, or shareholders. He claims that obligations of managers is to maximise

5The concept of CSR has been taken one step further to corporate social performance (CSP). Carroll (1979)

defines corporate social performance as a broader version of CSR i.e. a model of corporate social performance must include (1) a definition of CSR, (2) the dimensions in which corporations have responsibilities and (3) are companies reactive or proactive? (Carroll, 1979, p. 499) For the purpose of this research it is sufficient to look at the concept of CSR as all empirical work on the relationship of competition and CSR has been conducted using the concept of CSR not CSP. In section 2.4, however, CSP will occur.

(10)

shareholder value, in line with classical economic agency theory. However, by explicitly

calling out CSR as a measure that redirects resources from profitable strategies he could not

have accounted for recent trends in consumer preferences. Research into the awareness and

willingness to pay for sustainability is showing that in modern times consumers care more

for companies that went green and/or are involved in social activities.6

Contemporary much focus is on a different paradigm, namely the stakeholder approach.

Freeman et al. (2004) puts forward that “certainly shareholders are an important constituent

and profits are a critical feature of this activity, but concern for profits is the result rather than

the driver in the process of value creation” (Freeman et al., 2004, p. 364). He claims that

economic value is created by the interactions of individuals that get together on a voluntary

basis to elevate “everyone's circumstances”. Economic value is never explicitly defined but

comes closest to what economists perceive as total welfare. Thus, the process of improving

“everyone's circumstances” i.e. stakeholders, profits will follow. Caring for employees and

communities can ease the ways for organisations to conduct their daily activities.

Corre-spondingly, this can result in cost savings, productivity gains as well as talent attraction and

retention (Greening and Turban, 2000; Turban and Greening, 1997).

Even though stakeholder theory and CSR are related, Vishwanathan (2017) stresses the

difference amongst the two. That is to say, CSR literature is concerned about

understand-ing the firms behaviour with regards to the social perspective, whereas stakeholder theory

concerns the managerial perspective to establish that the CSR decisions undertaken are also

profitable for the firm. This does not, however, exclude the responsibilities a firm has to

society and especially its stakeholders, leaving stakeholder theory an important aspect in

understanding into the effects of CSR strategies and possibly into CSR activities. As

com-6Research into the awareness and willingness to pay for sustainability is showing that consumers and

em-ployees find it difficult to know the full range of CSR conduct as data is difficult to access (Lyon and Maxwell, 2006). Vermeir and Verbeke (2006) and Manaktola and Jauhari (2007) show that as consumers become aware the willingness to pay increases and Schuler and Cording (2006) and Madsen and Rodgers (2015) on how awareness of stakeholders of substantive CSR practices can enhance productivity and reduce costs.

(11)

petitors can be seen as stakeholders, it is reasonable to build upon stakeholder theory to

understand how competition and CSR are related to one another.

Moreover, the different concepts of CSR can be subdivided into three subgroups: ethical,

altruistic and strategic7 CSR (Lantos, 2001; Bansal and Roth, 2000). The former represents

that firms behave morally acceptable and e.g. do not injure employees; this form of CSR

is broadly accepted and does not require any future analyses as it is encompassed in the

economic and legal responsibilities (Lantos, 2001). In contrast, altruistic CSR, which comes

closest to the CSR Friedman opposes in his 1970 essay, has a voluntary aspect to it and is

conducted with no concern for profit. It is about solving social issues that are not caused

by the firm and should thus be handled through a taxation system rather than companies

direct contributions (Friedman, 2007). The last, strategic CSR refers to the win-win situation

in which a company can do good by generating revenue and is thus the most noteworthy

and economically rational (Lantos, 2001). Naturally, from profit alone it is not possible to

deduce whether firms engaged for altruistic or profit reasons. They could for example have

“accidentally” made profit out of a purely altruistic CSR strategy. This makes it near to

impossible to distinct between the two empirically based on profitability of such measures.

A final noteworthy distinction is the one between symbolic and substantive CSR.

Compa-nies that are engaging in “greenwashing” i.e. using CSR to deceive customers (Delmas and

Cuerel Burbano, 2011) are generally engaging in “symbolic” CSR, which does not translate

into any benefits for stakeholders or the environment. In very competitive environments it

is even found to decrease financial performance (Kim et al., 2018). Substantive CSR refers

to CSR conduct that is aimed at being effective and is found, if stakeholders are aware of it,

to reduce costs and increase productivity (Schuler and Cording, 2006). Thus, it seems that

CSR, if conducted on a substantive basis, is positively correlated to profitability (see Section

7Du et al. (2011) shows that consumers that are involved in CSR initiatives favour this company even if

they have built a trust relationship with an industry leader, being the first approach to provide evidence for the use of strategic CSR as a means to differentiate.

(12)

2.4) regardless whether it was conducted for strategic or altruistic reasons.

2.2 Definition of CSR

One of the most commonly used definitions is the one employed by McWilliams and Siegel

(2001) and McWilliams et al. (2006)8: “[CSR relates to] actions that appear to further some

social good, beyond the interests of the firm and that which is required by law”. Their paper

resulted in convergence of using the same definition and undoubtedly contributed to the

re-search since then by resolving the issue of authors relying on varying definitional constructs.

However, this definition limits the scope of CSR. If a firm aligns their business model with

social issues, then arguably, by this definition the firm is not engaging in CSR. Suppose an

entrepreneur decides to build a firm based on producing sustainable cloth, using little to no

child-labour9, small emissions in production and distribution, employing a disabled work

force and so on. If he does this, not because he is genuinely altruistic, but because he sees

a profitable business in doing so, then his actions are part of his economic responsibilities

towards his firm and stakeholders. His corporation would therefore, by definition, not be

considered as socially responsible. For the purpose of this thesis, which is to scrutinise what

we know about the link of competition and CSR, we would like to not limit the scope of

CSR to voluntary10 as CSR in response to competitive pressure is, arguably, not voluntary

8They attribute methodological issues as the driver for the varying effects found in whether CSR is profitable

or not. Namely: “[1] result of inconsistency in defining CSR, [2] inconsistency in defining firm performance, [3] inconsistency in samples, [4] imprecision and inconsistency in research design, [5] misspecification of models, [6] changes over time, [7] or some more fundamental variance in the samples that are being analysed.” (McWilliams et al., 2006, p. 12) For managers, they propose using hedonic ways (i.e. product characteristics) to estimate whether CSR can be beneficial. This is not the point of this research, but we wanted to stress that care should be taken when estimating such equations as proposed by McWilliams et al. (2006). It does not contain any demand factors and therefore does also not touch upon the difficulties of estimating a structural equation with both price and quantity involved.

9This point can be debated as many countries that are using child labour are engaging in it due to Ricardos

Trade theory. They have an abundance in (child) labour and are using this as their comparative advantage. Many families in third world countries rely on such child labour to feed their families. Thus, child labour could be argued to not be harmful, but this is not a debate for this research.

10What and what is not voluntary is again a concept that could be debated lengthy without an unanimous

(13)

and certainly not beyond the economic responsibilities if it leads to a better positioning of

the firm. Most aligned with the idea of this research are the following two definitions:

(1) “The social responsibility of business encompasses the economic, legal, ethical, and

dis-cretionary expectations that society has of organisations at a given point in time” (Carroll,

1979 p.500 as cited in Carroll (1999)).

This definition captures the dynamics of CSR and points towards why so much literature

has focused on defining the concept. Thus, Carroll's definition offers the possibility that the

concept of CSR changes through time. The definition that I would like to employ is a mix

between Caroll’s 1979 definition and the one used by Peter Drucker 1984:

(2) “The proper social responsibility of business is to tame the dragon, that is to turn a

social problem into economic opportunity and economic benefit, into productive capacity,

into human competence, into well-paid jobs, and into wealth” (Drucker, 1984, p. 62) as cited

in Carroll (1999).

This definition does not rely on the voluntary part as most definitions post 1984 do. By

incorporating a voluntary part into the definition of CSR, one cannot make the distinction of

strategic and altruistic CSR. This is because strategic CSR will be in response to something

such as competition, which, arguably, is not voluntary nor beyond economic requirements.

All definitions, also the modern ones, accept that the economic function of a firm is part of

its responsibility as society wishes firms to create jobs and wealth. Why would thus

philan-thropy and voluntarism be part of the definition of CSR, that would be the job of charities or

governments through a sound taxation system. If companies find a way to align their interests

something voluntary. However, as economic activity is voluntary to begin with, we do not see the reason to include a voluntary dimension, i.e. beyond economic and legal requirements, into the definition of CSR.

(14)

with CSR, naturally this is still voluntary, which in turn makes CSR the profit maximising

strategy, then this type of CSR would better be placed under economic responsibilities. As

society wants companies to generate wealth and jobs, which sometimes can certainly be

done precisely by donating or doing voluntary work, then the definition should not limit the

concept to a voluntary dimension. If companies find a way to conduct their business in a

sustainable and socially acceptable way, within the legal and economic realms, then why

would we classify them as not being involved in CSR conduct?

2.3 Objective Function Firms Maximise

Proposing a maximisation problem that can be generalised to all firms and managers will

not be possible unless we find a way to read owners' and managers' minds. Nevertheless, it

is a useful point of discussion. To figure out what firms actually maximise it is necessary

to look at two sides i.e. do principals seek profit maximisation and do agents perform such

maximisation if wanted? Suppose agents engage in CSR practices that hurts profits. Then

we have a typical agency theory problem and managers and firms maximise different

func-tions. If there is a consensus that CSR can increase financial performance then, even taking

Friedman's (1970) extreme perspective, CSR should be conducted by agents as it maximises

the principals profit. Naturally, if the principal is maximising utility or social aspects then,

even absent profitability, the agent should engage in such practices. Russo and Fouts (1997)

acknowledge that consumers may be willing to pay more in the recent future, or go for the

company that is going green. This, as aforementioned, has happened. Thus, stakeholders

interest can become “parallel one another” (Freeman et al., 2004; Russo and Fouts, 1997)

when it comes to investing in CSR conduct. According to the research conduct by the author

there is no research on what functions firms maximise.11

11Future research in that area could attempt at collecting value statements of corporations, codify them

and compare them to CSR effectiveness and profitability to see whether they are enforced. Combined with (anonymous) interviews of managers, one could give an indication of what precisely is maximised by managers. This would then also shed light on whether an agency problem prevails as companies engage in CSR conduct.

(15)

Is it possible that firms have different motives than profits? From a stakeholder theory

point of view it is precisely these “different” motives that result in profitability. For now it

seems that by maximising stakeholder value one can achieve profit maximisation. If correct,

it would make it irrelevant whether firms maximise profits or total welfare as one cannot

be done without the other. There seems to be an agreement that CSR is correlated with

profitability and some evidence of that is provided in section 2.4. Thus the question arises of

whether firms engage in (profitable) CSR in order to maximise their profits or whether they

genuinely want to do good — probably a bit of both.

What precisely is maximised, however, is hard to assess even if there is an indication that

CSR may result in profitability. It is does important to ask, regardless what firms maximise,

whether they get better at it. Provided the evidence on CSR engagement it seems that CSR

that is conducted slowly and gradually is more profitable, suggesting that there is a learning

curve of engaging in CSR conduct to achieve profitability. As there is a higher effectiveness

from “substantive” CSR on its effect on productivity and reduction in costs (Graafland and

Smid, 2016; Perrini et al., 2011; Schuler and Cording, 2006). This indicates that CSR, which

is of “symbolic” nature, neither maximises profits nor total welfare. Thus, CSR that is of

“symbolic” nature cannot be in the objective function of a rational firm regardless the motives

i.e. strategic or altruistic. This leaves the question of whether “substantive” CSR (henceforth

CSR unless otherwise indicated) is within the objective function of a firm. CSR that is

conducted in response to competitive pressure, provided that it will increase the consumer

mass as well as boost productivity and reduce costs, should thus be part of firm's maximising

strategy. Whether it is, however, is beyond the scope of this research to answer.

2.4 Is CSR Profitable?

There is the notion that by conducting CSR a firm can develop inimitable capabilities

(16)

2003). These include “skills and competences, knowledge and innovation, values,

legiti-macy, trust, and reputation in the stakeholder network” (Perrini et al., 2011, p. XX). These

in turn, can be leveraged as a competitive advantage through its effects on efficiency,

in-creased consumer attraction, and differentiation (Perrini et al., 2011; Greening and Turban,

2000; Turban and Greening, 1997). If CSR is profitable it is necessary to understand the

channels through which it impacts profitability in order to gain understanding of the role

competition plays in this relationship. This section will shed light on recent developments in

the CSR and profitability linkage and through which channels profitability is affected.

Due the effect of CSR as an inimitable capability it has a complex relationship to financial

performance, which is likely not bidirectional. Studies that aim at measuring the relationship

in an aggregate manner ignore such complexity (Perrini et al., 2011). Orlitzky et al. (2008,

2003) points to the difficulty, while analysing 30 years of CSR and profitability literature

in a meta study, of conducting meta studies in this context and shows that measurement

errors, sampling errors and stakeholder mismatching, in primary studies, can explain 15 to

100% of variation in findings (Orlitzky et al., 2003). Even though findings vary substantially

in their magnitude (Orlitzky et al., 2008) both studies indicate a clear positive correlation.

They do indicate that the CSR and CSP have a bidirectional effect i.e. the relationship is a

self enforcing mechanism. Furthermore, when CSR is conducted “slowly and consistently”,

with a focus on CSR dimensions that are related to the business and with higher initial

investments into core dimensions i.e. employees, consumers and shareholders, that then

corporate financial performance (CFP) will be enhanced (Tang et al., 2012).

Zhao and Murrell (2016) indicate that prior CFP is correlated with subsequent CSP,

whereas vice versa there is no relation. Thus an indication that without initial financial

health there is no CSR conduct supporting the argument of reduced competition as a means

to increase CSR, or at least kick start responsible behaviour. They further indicate that the

(17)

study. Garcia-Castro and Francoeur (2016) analyses, through costliness, complementarities

and contingencies, the relationship of CSR and CFP. Their findings suggest that “any attempt

to find a simple monotonic relationship between investments in stakeholders and firm

perfor-mance seems to be futile” further indicating the difficulty of finding a causal interpretation.

Nevertheless, they suggest that stakeholder investments are more fruitful when done across

all stakeholder groups.

These studies indicate the difficulty of finding a causal effect on the relationship of CSR

and CFP, but agree on the positive correlation between the two. Wood and Jones (1995) stress

that most studies vary in the way stakeholders are mismatched and that CSR, depending on

which stakeholders employed, will affect profitability differently. Naturally, competition will

thus affect each dimension differently. Moreover, they stress that “the empirical rigor and

mathematics of CSP theory are not just underdeveloped; they are missing” (Wood and Jones,

1995, p. 261).

Vishwanathan (2017) points out that there is still a high level of ambiguity about they

key relationship of CSP and CFP, not about the positive relationship, but rather the causal

interpretation. Indicating that both McWilliams et al. (2006) and Wood and Jones (1995)

critique have not been fully addressed. For example institutional theory would suggest that

firms engage in CSR to obtain legitimacy and that this legitimacy translates into reduced

risk. Others would argue, based on a more microeconomic approach, that investing into

CSR builds positive relationships which then mitigates losses when negative events occur

and hence reduce risk. Both conclude that it reduces risk, but have a very different theoretical

explanation for the effect (Vishwanathan, 2017).

Her meta analysis indicates that there are four pathways through which CSP impacts

CFP: (1) stakeholder endorsement, (2) reputitional improvement, (3) innovation, and (4) risk

mitigation. It is noteworthy to stress the fragility of reputational improvement. B´enabou

(18)

their discount factor. That is to say, if individuals engage in activities that receive to much

attention, pro-social behaviour will reduce due to the image concern of engaging in such

behaviour for the wrong reasons. This is likely to translate to corporations as well: if

cor-porations would engage in CSR and ensure that this CSR receives publicity, it is likely that

the public will perceive such behaviour as “greenwashing”. Thus there is a fine line

be-tween creating awareness that increases effectiveness of CSR practices and awareness that

will be deemed as “desperate”. Correspondingly, such companies would be perceived as

greenwashers by the public.

Whereas investing into core stakeholders such as employees and consumers can reduce

costs and increase productivity, there seem to be little short term benefits resulting from

firms engaging in environmental friendly conduct. In the context of competition, this would

suggest that CSR, on an environmental dimension, is not an effective strategy to deal with

immediate threats. Nevertheless, investing into environmental performance has its long term

benefits. In the presence of unexpected shocks, stock price movements are significantly less

negative in firms that have strong environmental control ratings (Shane and Spicer, 1983).

Furthermore, companies with stronger environmental performance i.e. less pollution have

been associated with reduced risk on stock prices (Spicer, 1978). One explanation for this is

that firms that are environmentally friendly have a long term objective reducing the risk of

short term default. This makes the stock more attractive, especially to institutional investors,

which in turn drives up its value (Graves and Waddock, 1994).

These points suggest that CSR measures, if correctly and specifically used, should be

employed by rational firms and can be used as a strategy in response to competition.

More-over, the relationship of CSR and financial performance is found to be bidirectional. This

may indicate that certain industries are affected differently by competition as in some cases it

will reduce CSR through its reducing effect on profits and in others it will be high in order to

(19)

on more factors than just industry and country fixed effects, which is what is mainly used to

control for endogeneity issues in empirical work of competition and CSR as elaborated in

section 4.

3

Measures of Competition and CSR

3.1 Measures Used

CSR. CSR conduct is generally measured by and provided by environmental, social and

gov-ernance (ESG) research. The most widely used providers are the MSCI ESG KLD STATS

(henceforth, KLD) measure and Asset4.12 These are used as a proxy of CSR conduct both

for responsibility concerns and strengths.

The KLD data base comprises of five universes labelled A through E:

(A) MSCI KLD 400 Social Index (KLD400) plus the MSCI USA Index, covering a

time-span from 1991 to 2014 and encompasses 650 firms. The index experienced slight

ad-justments throughout these periods, so the index's coverage slightly adjusted and

com-prises the said data only since STATS-2013 data set.

(B) the largest 1000 U.S. companies (by market capitalisation), which however, has been

discontinued as of the STATS-2013 data base.

(C) is comprised of the KLD400 and the largest 1000 U.S. companies over a time-span from

2001 to 2013 covering 1100 firms.

(D) contains the MSCI USA IMI Index covering 2400 firms from 2003 to 2014.

12There is also Sustainalytics, which yields a neglectable difference in results (Van den Heuvel, 2012); as no

empirical work testing the relationship of competition and CSR used Sustainalytics and that it yields similar results to Asset4 we will only look at KLD and Asset4

(20)

(E) is the “non-US universe” and only covers 2013 and 2014. It includes emerging markets,

the investable market index, Nordic IMI, Australia IMI, South Africa and Canada, and

encompasses 2600 firms.

The index's measures span across three pillars: environment, social and governance

where each pillar is further subdivided into themes such as climate change and human

cap-ital. For each theme the database contains key issues such as carbon emissions for climate

change. For each key issue the index assesses components of the management capabilities

of a company i.e. strategy & governance, initiatives and performance. Generally, a

com-pany gets scored on only four to seven of the most “material” ESG key issues for the firm's

primary industry. In addition, there are a set of key issues that are applicable to all

compa-nies such as carbon emissions, labor management, and health & safety. Each key issue is

rated on a scale from zero to ten. Also, the ratings are then converted into a simple binary

scoring model. If the given threshold for an indicator is met the variable takes the value of

one and zero otherwise.13 The scores are constructed using (1) macro data (at segment or

geographic level) from academic, government, and NGO datasets, (2) company disclosure

data i.e. 10-K, sustainability reports etc.) and (3) government databases.

For a detailed overview of how these measures are constructed see the KLD data base

executive summary methodology clickhereand for a detailed overview of how measures are

constructed seehere.14 To understand that these measures are constructed as a combination

of self-reported data and assessed data it is however useful to provide a brief explanation of

how some variables are constructed.

One of the environmental dimensions is waste management. Companies that report

13If a company has not been researched on an indicator it will naturally be indicated with NR (not

re-searched).

14Alternatively see MSCI ESG KLD STATS: 1991-2014 DATA SETS accessible through:

https://www.wiso.uni-hamburg.de/bibliothek/recherche/datenbanken/unternehmensdaten/msci-methodology-2014.pdf and see MSCI ESG Ratings Methodology 2015 accessible through:

(21)

strong programs (such as addressing electronic waste, having recycling programs etc.) and

track records of reducing waste/emissions score higher compared to companies that do not.

Additionally, there is the environmental opportunities section, which is likely to be one of the

more subjective dimensions. Corporations that refurbish buildings with “green”

characteris-tics15score higher. More, if they have a “green” strategy in place they yield a higher score

and consequently are better ranked. For an employee dimension there is e.g. gay and lesbian

policies. Corporations that have notably progressive policies in place, towards its gay and

lesbian employees, score higher. Another example is the community engagement indicator,

which identifies corporations that have notable community engagement programs in place

(concerning the local communities in which a firm is active in) and metrics include

commu-nity impact assessments. This measure also exists as a concern where the indicator assesses

the gravity with which a firm's controversies impact the community. This includes, but not

limited to, widespread or egregious community impacts, criticism by NGO's and other third

party observers as well as a history of development related legal cases.

These examples illustrate that even though rankings do not solely rely on self-reported

policies or programs, most measures do include such programs. Further, strengths and

con-cerns, as shown by the community impact, are not derived from the same methodology where

concerns generally comprise scandals or concerns of third party observers and strengths

en-compass self reported policy programs but also an assessment of its effectiveness. This, as

elaborated in the proceeding concern sections, may result in a bias of ranking as the scores

are at least partially based on self-reported data and/or constructing a net index i.e. strengths

minus concerns. It is also important to note that the index puts forward, in its disclaimer,

that “the information should not be relied on and is not a substitute for the skill, judgment

and experience of the user, its management, employees, advisors and/or clients when making

investment and other business decisions. All information is impersonal and not tailored to

15With “green” characteristics it includes, but not limited to, lower embodied energy, used recycled materials,

(22)

the needs of any person, entity or group of persons.” As the literature shows that CSR

im-pacts profitability differently, depending on the dimension used, it is also expected that the

impact of competition on CSR (if any) varies across dimensions and is likely to be

depen-dent upon industry and country contexts. Therefore, it seems that using an all generalised

index to measure may drive a systematic bias into the results when running regressions on

the relationship of competition and CSR as elaborated later on.

The most noteworthy subsection is the KLD400 index, which contains data from 1991

to 2015 for US and 2013-2015 for non-US i.e. Canada AsiaPacific and European markets

(Source: KLD400 methodology). The research is conducted by the an independent unit of

MSCI and is the most widely used measure up to date. Moreover, it contains reference data

i.e. for example name of company. It includes observables such as emissions and scandals,

but also self-reported policy dummies such as employee benefit program and/or

environ-mental emission program. These scores are measured on a scale from AAA to C and are

normalised across industries and companies i.e. some industries may not contain a single

AAA rating. Apart from Standard & Poor (S&P) 500 the data base also contains the KLD

400 Social Index in which companies that are involved in alcohol, gambling, tobacco,

mili-tary weapons, civilian firearms, nuclear power, adult entertainment and genetically modified

organisms are excluded (Source: MSCI KLD 400 Social Index Methodology). Moreover,

companies need to receive a rating of above B in the MSCI ESG Rating to remain in the

KLD index. For a detailed explanation see KLD Methodology 2016 or clickhere.16

The Asset4 database, provided by Thomson Reuters (Reuters), is the predecessor of the

Reuters ESG Scores.17 The data base encompasses 7000 companies globally.18 Moreover,

16Or alternatively, visit the MSCI KLD 400 Social Index Methodology 2016 accessible here:

https://www.msci.com/eqb/methodologymeth docsMSCI KLD 400 Social Index Methodology May 2016.pdf

17Only one paper used the Asset4 and did not use the improved ESG Scores provided by Reuters, thus the

focus in the analysis lies on the implications of the Asset4 drawbacks albeit the ESG Score data base does correct for some issues. Most data, however, remains self reported by companies, thus, the improvement does not deal with the most apparent issue. As the KLD base is by far the most widely used, it would not add too much value of explaining the newer version of the Asset4.

(23)

the measures are constructed using only self reported company data. Only one study in the

linkage of competition and CSR used the Asset4, instead of KLD. As the data is based on self

reported company information only, it is not necessary to provide the same detailed overview

than for the KLD.

The index provides over 250 key indicators divided into ten main themes such as

emis-sions, environmental product innovation, human rights, shareholders and so on. These key

indicators are sub branches of the following five main pillars: (1) corporate governance, (2)

economic, (3) environmental and (5) social. The ratings work from A+ until D- and are made

up of a score from one to ten. It is important to note how Asset4 constructs the weights.

Cat-egories that contain several key issues such as management (it contains: composition,

diver-sity, independence, committees, compensation etc.) bear more weight than key issues such

as human rights that are made up of less or only one indicator. A very transparent illustration

of how it is calculated can be found in the Asset4 Reuters Methodology, or by clickinghere.19

Competition. How to measure industrial concentration has been debated lengthily over

the past decades, especially concerning what types of distribution should be used (for

ex-ample see Hart (1975) and Hart (1971)). A measure of industrial concentration should be

conducted using two observable, and thus measurable, phenomena i.e. the size and number

of firm distributions (Marfels, 1971). One measure that emerged is the entropy measure,

which allows e.g. concentration measured on a national level to be split into concentration

of several regions. This measure has rarely been employed in research and will thus receive

no further attention.

Furthermore, one can use characteristics of the size distribution of firms to draw

impli-cations on the level of concentration in a given industry (Curry and George, 1983). One

19Alternatively it can be found through Reuters ESG Asset4 methodology base accessible

here:

(24)

such measure is the use of the Lorenz Curve, intended to measure the distribution of wealth,

to measure the departure from a competitive industry in which each firm has the same size

(Gini, 1912; Lorenz, 1905). Indices that are based on the Lorenz Curve capture the

differ-ences in market shares fairly unambiguous but nevertheless ignore the number of firms (i.e.

the Lorenz Curve will be the same for 100 firms than for 5) (Davies, 1979).

The two most commonly used, by empirical literature on the relationship of competition

and CSR, and competition authorities, are the HHI, which is the sum of squared market

shares (Hirschman, 1964) and the ith-concentration ratio (CR

i) i.e. the sum of the ithlargest

firms (Marfels, 1971). See Belleflamme and Peitz (2015) and Tirole (1988) for a more

detailed description of the two. Using a linear Cournot model it is possible to relate the

Lerner index directly to the HHI (Belleflamme and Peitz, 2015), however, it is important

to note that most industries are not competing on quantities. The most useful property of

the HHI, which is not addressed using concentration ratios, is that larger firms receive more

weight. Different market structures, as elaborated in the concern section, can lead to the

same level of concentration when using concentration ratios. This problem is addressed in

the HHI by squaring market shares.

To overcome the concern of cross ownership20researchers have modified the HHI to

ac-count for such ownership structures. In merger cases it has been suggested that the modified

HHI (MHHI) captures cross ownership changes competition depending on how much of a

target is acquired (O’brien and Salop, 1999). Azar et al. (2016) have illustrated that this cross

ownership can be captured by a generalised HHI (GHHI). The GHHI does not change the

fact that the measure relies on the assumption of Cournot competition and that a manager

follows shareholders' interest. The only difference to the HHI is that the GHHI “allows for

20Suppose multiple companies have a vested interest in one another. E.g. Goldman Sachs will have a

(controlling) stake in multiple firms active in a given industry as well across industries. Much of the CSR conduct may then be attributed to spillover effects from one major firm that has a management in place that puts a heavy focus on CSR measures. Some firms' CSR conduct would then be driven by cross ownership, not competition per se. This will be elaborated further in the concern section.

(25)

simultaneous common ownership and cross ownership” (Azar et al., 2016, p. 12).

Another measure, which is found in any microeconomic or IO text book, is the Lerner

index. The general idea behind the index is that in perfect competition firms price at marginal

costs. This results in the index taking a value of zero. The index measures the markup

(i.e. price cost difference as a percentage of price) that can be charged by a given firm

and is therefore not dependent on size distributions and should be applicable to almost any

situation.21 Moreover, the index has a useful property: it can be expressed as the inverse

elasticity of demand. This is also known as the inverse elasticity rule according to which “the

markup is higher the less elastic is demand” (Belleflamme and Peitz, 2015, p. 27). If data is

available, which may proof to be a major issue in certain industries, then there are, broadly

speaking, two main ways to estimate price cost margins in the literature: (1) to estimate

each firm's price cost margin as something similar to revenues minus variable costs divided

by revenues (for example Scherer and Ross (1990)) and (2) the structural approaches such

as estimating elasticities (for examples see Graddy (1995) and Berry et al. (1995) (Boone,

2008).

Boone (2008) proposes a new measure of competition. The measure is constructed by

taking the difference of profits of the most efficient and least efficient firm relative to the

difference of the second most efficient firm's and the least efficient firm's profit; the ratio

of the two then represents the relative profit difference (RPD or Boone measure). In this

model an increase in competition can be modelled by either a fall in entry barriers or through

tougher competition of existing players. There are theoretical papers (Amir 2002, Bulow and

Klemperer 199 etc. as cited in Boone) that show how competition increases the price cost

margins instead of reducing them, which implies that, in traditional price cost estimations,

competition can in fact increase margins. The Boone measure's underpinning logic is that

21Certainly, there are several drawbacks to this as well. Most industries are not perfectly competitive to begin

with and in other industries mark ups are not indication of monopoly power as elaborated in the proceeding section.

(26)

when competition increases there is a larger shift of profits from less efficient firms to more

efficient firms: there is a punishment for being inefficient. Consequently, the measure is

monotone in competition under derived conditions (Boone, 2008). The measure has not

been used in any of the papers, but it may prove to be a useful tool for future research. It

is noteworthy to mention that the measure has been proposed as an additional tool, as it

requires the same data, not per se as a superior measure on all aspects. Albeit it is shown to

be theoretically more robust (see Boone (2008) for the derivations).

In the literature that aimed to analyse the link of competition the HHI index was the most

widely used. Some authors, as elaborated in section 4, used instruments such as a reduction

in trade barriers. These are good ways of measuring the impact additional competition has,

but cannot be summarised as a general measure. Also, variations using the fraction of

em-ployees (relative to all emem-ployees in an industry) and/or asset size (relative to all assets in an

industry) instead of market share and/or using the number of firms as an indication have been

employed. These are all variations of the HHI but are noteworthy as each of these proxies

has its own drawbacks as elaborated in the proceeding sections.

3.2 Measurement & Data Concerns

CSR. One has to make a distinction between social performance and social action: social

im-pacts are not necessarily the same as social activity (Mitnick, 2000). This questions whether

self reported data allows researchers, investors, policy makers and managers to assess the

CSR behaviour of companies or at least its effectiveness. Companies have a moral hazard

when reporting such programs and are likely to overstate their CSR efforts, questioning the

legitimacy of variables based on self reported data in the use of CSR research. Studies that

are based on measures such as the Asset4 are thus inherently measuring what companies

re-port and thus they are measuring the relationship of competition and rere-ported CSR, not CSR

(27)

level data, and therefore, controls for some of these concerns.

Moreover, there are concerns regarding the endogeneity of CSR itself. Due to external

pressures resulting from, not limited to, competition, profitability or stakeholders, managers

may increase their CSR (reporting) to satisfy the party exhibiting the pressure. If stakeholder

pressure drives firms' decision to engage in CSR, for example, then this has to be controlled

for when assessing the relationship of competition (or any other measure) and CSR, which

may prove to be harder than said. Also, by only taking into account self reported data, there

is a sample selection bias. It is suggested that managers who are seeking acknowledgment,

from external observers such as investors and society, are more inclined to enhance their CSR

(reporting) efforts out of fear of not being reported (Shahzad and Sharfman, 2017; Doh et al.,

2010). Shahzad and Sharfman (2017) show that such a bias exists and can be controlled for

by implementing proxies to capture stakeholder pressure.

Furthermore, if measures do not clearly indicate the outcome of certain policies in place,

the distinction between substantive and symbolic CSR becomes blurry. By engaging in

greenwashing, a company will have to invest significantly less resources while having a

probability of not getting caught. A manager or company is thus, arguably, incentivised to

do so under certain conditions. Also, this likely means that managers have a rough estimation

of the consequences of CSR conduct and whether it is profitable to engage in greenwashing.

Naturally, this might backfire to managers as it has been shown that greenwashing can reduce

profitability, that is, if caught. The complexity of distinguishing between greenwashing and

CSR calls for a better reporting of the effects of CSR programs in order to understand the

forces that lead to companies acting in socially responsible ways not just for the sake of

it, but actually to elevate total welfare, regardless whether the motives were profitability,

gaining a competitive advantage or genuinely doing good.

The KLD measure is regarded as the superior measure of CSR (for example see

(28)

does it need to be to allow for useful insights. The KLD measure is largely based on other

research than only self reported company data, which already is a significant improvement

with regards to other measures. Nevertheless, self reported data such as sustainability reports

still feed into the ratings. Chatterji et al. (2009) tested how well the KLD data base does in

predicting historical and future environmental performance and find that KLD environmental

ratings do a “reasonable job of aggregating past environmental performance”(p. 50).

Also, they find that total environmental strengths score did not do well in predicting,

whereas net environmental concerns (i.e. strength minus weakness) can help at

predict-ing future performance. The methodology employed to measure strengths and weaknesses,

however, questions the construction of such a net index and whether it makes

methodologi-cal sense to subtract the two scores from one another. As strengths and concerns do not have

convergence validity, it is not possible to construct a grounded measure of net CSR by

sub-tracting concerns from strengths. (Flammer, 2015; Mattingly and Berman, 2006;

Johnson-Cramer, 2004)

There has thus to be a focus by modern researches into CSR into the core issue: how to

measure CSR? Without a clear consensus of of measurement that makes clear distinctions

between whether or not data was self reported, or whether a policy implemented was of

substantive or symbolic nature, it becomes near to impossible to comprehend under what

circumstances CSR conduct becomes a strategy and/or in what scenarios it is profitable. As

there is a different effect on profitability when engaging in substantive or symbolic CSR, it

is expected that this difference drive much of the results. This will also make it harder to

assess a causal relationship between competition and CSR.

In addition there is a problem with the aggregation of CSR scores i.e. each dimension has

a different linkage to profitability and is thus also expected to be differently affected by

com-petitive pressure. This leads to yet another concern with the measurement of CSR for

(29)

the same methodology in aggregation or tested the relationship of competition on the same

individual measures. Moreover, without a clear distinction of which measures are increasing

profitability or which measures are increased by profitability, aggregation of such data makes

a causal interperation even harder, especially when looking at the competition and CSR

re-lationship. Suppose for example environmental initiatives are less important to deal with

immediate competitive threats as they have little short term effects on core stakeholders and

productivity. Now imagine that at the same time focusing CSR on core stakeholders

trans-lates into increased productivity, motivation and quality of work that in turn reduces cost

and/or boosts profits. The two dimensions of CSR, if even affected by competition, work in

different directions. If one would now aggregate environmental scores and employee benefit

programs the effects of competition will likely cancel each other out. Thus aggregating may

cause large problems (that are not observed) by combining dimensions that have opposing

views one will underestimate the positive effect CSR can have, or overestimate the effect

less efficient CSR use can exhibit.

Proposing different types of CSR, such as altruistic, strategic, symbolic and substantive,

was a good advancement in understanding the concept. Which one of these actually prevail

under what contexts however, has not been unanimously agreed upon. As many dimensions

are differently affected, which is reasonable to believe at this point, then it is questionable

to aggregate a linkage of general CSR and competition. Needless to say the two data-bases,

i.e. KLD and Asset4, do allow for a coherent measurement across studies. However, most

authors are using their own ways of aggregating measures and selecting key indicators as

elaborated in section 4. Moreover, these data bases do not indicate the effectiveness of such

measures making it impossible to distinct between symbolic and substantive CSR by only

using these data bases.

Further, the time horizon for which these measures are available, especially for European

(30)

analyses, which may be an explanation for why most studies in the competition and CSR

relationship have used US data.

Lastly, there is a heavy selection bias of studies using the KLD 400 Index. Measuring

only corporations that receive a rating of “AA” or above, limited to the 400 highest rated

companies, does not give insights into corporations that are not socially responsible. In turn,

this magnifies the sample selection bias that already exists by only using corporations that

have CSR reporting in place. This limits the spectrum of CSR conduct that is measured and

will not give any insights into how competition is related to corporations that are not engage

in CSR. Understanding what drives CSR conduct in companies that are fairly engaged in

it, is a key piece in understanding the role competition plays especially when deciding on a

public interest defence in cartel offences. Moreover, ignoring some “dirty” industries such

as alcohol, tobacco, military weapons and genetically modified organisms does not allow to

gain insights into how CSR conduct relates to competition in industries with large

externali-ties on society now and future generations.

Competition. Whereas the Lerner Index ignores the number of firms (Davies, 1979), the

CRi22and the HHI use both differences in market shares and number of firms. Nevertheless,

these two measures place a too high value on the number of firms, leading to a certain

de-cline in competition as long as the market share of one additional firm exceeds 0.05 (Hart,

1975). Thus, they overemphasise the impact additional entry of a small firm may have on

concentration (Davies, 1979).

All studies that tested the relationship of competition and CSR do use the HHI or some

22The CR

ihas not been used by researchers in the empirical literature testing the relationship of competition

and CSR. The concerns arising with this measure are enormous and if authors used only a certain amount of firms to construct a measure of concentration, they still used the HHI approach, but only on a certain number of firms, not all. To illustrate why: suppose we are measuring the CR4. An industry that has one firm with 65%

with the remaining share divided amongst seven firms equally leaving 5% each. Now, suppose that there are

four firms with 20% market share and four firms with 5%. Both of these industries would yield the same CR4

(31)

form of it, as a proxy for concentration. Few works such as Flammer have used an instrument

such as a reduction in trade barriers.23

The first issue with the HHI is that slight measurement errors can change concentration

proxies drastically. Suppose that the largest players in the market have 35, 25 and 15%

market share and the remaining market shares are divided into five companies with a share of

5% each. This yields an HHI of 2175. If the market share is measured as 40% and 20% i.e. a

5% difference in the largest two companies the HHI jumps to 2325, and with 10% to 2575. If

measurement errors in the larger shares of companies vary across years and industries, then

concentration ratios may mask the effect competition exhibits on CSR as some industries

may in fact be more competitive than others albeit otherwise indicated. Also, by squaring

market shares the HHI may understate the value of small firms and overstate the value of

large firms (Roberts, 2014). This concern carries through to proxies such as using ratios of

employee numbers or ratio of asset size of corporations.

The next issue is cross-ownership of firms active in multiple industries, which in turn may

mask the level of competition. Suppose several firms have a stake in one another. According

to the basic HHI this would not be accounted for as it is simply the sum of squared market

shares. Suppose that four firms are active each having a share of 25% (HHI of 2500). If

now, however, each of the four owns a 50% in one of the others, for the sake of the argument

suppose that this cross ownership is between two firms each thus creating two groups of two

cross-owned firms, then concentration would be a lot higher than suggested by the HHI. Due

to the cross-ownership they do not just have the means to coordinate easier, they also have

a vested interest in keeping competition at a minimum. The standard HHI measures would

fail to capture such effects, whereas the MHHI does indeed account for such ownership

structures. For this reason has the GHHI and MHHI been proposed.

23Naturally, such instruments are also questionable in their exogeneity. But Flammer, for example, also

only looked at multilateral agreements, as they are harder to be influenced by a large corporation, to reduce endogeneity concerns of her measure of concentration. This will be elaborated later on.

(32)

More importantly, measuring concentration, which the HHI does, does not necessarily

imply competition even if it has been accurately measured. Market concentration does not

have to lead to competition in any situation. If for example capacity constraints are present,

and large initial investments into plants are required, then this creates entry barriers for new

entrants. Suppose that the capacity constraint firms can still operate profitable and have no

incentive to leave the market. In this scenario, a large number of firm does not necessarily

imply competition. The number of capacity constraint firms would provide the good at their

maximising production level, while other firms can start increasing prices as the other firms

will not have the ability to capture this. Moreover, in this situation barriers would be high

and potential entrants would have to conduct significant investments.

This brings the next critique on the HHI: entry barriers. An industry that is very

concen-trated by a two to three large firms, but faces zero entry barriers does not allow its players

to exhibit market power. Thus, the HHI would suggest that there is low competition, when

in fact their is extremely high potential competition, which in turn exhibits pressure on to

firms to not raise prices for example as this would attract immediate entry of potential

com-petitors. Further, the degree of concentration is impacted by many other factors apart market

shares and entry barriers such as locational distribution, psychology of corporate officers

and/or product substitutability (Roberts, 2014; Herfindahl, 1950). Such indices, relying on

size distributions, also fail at capturing firm specific demand elasticities which in turn

deter-mine the level of output and prices (Elzinga and Mills, 2011). For illustration purposes one

more example is provided: suppose there is an industry with two dominant players of each

40% market share. If one of the remaining firms, let us say for simplicity two more firms

with each 10% share, is developing a new platform, algorithm and/or patent, then it is likely

that this industry will be highly competitive in the near future. However, it will take time for

this firm to reach a large enough market share. Due to capacity constraints it may choose

(33)

seem to be dominated by two firms, based on market shares, whereas in reality the smallest

firm has significant power in the market, which in turn makes it a competitive industry. The

two large firms have significant buying power and the small firm has capacity constraints

resulting in all three firms preventing each other from abusing its dominance (that is, absent

collusion of course). In this scenario, competition is working perfectly fine and consumers

can benefit from the small firm licensing out its technology to others. Nevertheless, the HHI

would be 3400 indicating a high level of concentration.

Also assume that proxies are used measuring the number of employees and asset sizes

instead of market shares. By measuring the number of employees one will underestimate

the effect capital intense firms have on concentration. Suppose Amazon continues its

atom-isation of factories and carries such practices to all levels. Once Amazon would be fully

automised, it would in fact not be taken into account when measuring the number of

em-ployees. Needless to say, if Amazon manages to fully atomise itself it should be seen as

more dominant opposed to being neglected in such measures. The same argument goes for

relying on asset size as it would understate the impact labor intense corporations have on

competition.

Apart the criticism on the HHI, there are several concerns when using price cost margins

as a proxy of the level of competition. The Lerner index itself has been said to measures

market imperfection not the degree of monopoly power as it solely measures the departure

from a perfectly competitive environment in which no profits can be earned (Scitovsky 1995

(CITE)). The index is a static measure and therefore fails at capturing the dynamics of

com-petition such as “technological advancement, innovation, and learning by doing” (Elzinga

and Mills, 2011, p. 559). If firms exhibit a significant strengths in learning by doing, the

in-dex fails at capturing potential competition and possibly overstates the level of competition

based on market shares, when it is in fact driven by innovation and companies getting better

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

In other words, as the value of (independent) variable X changes, response in the (dependent) variable Y is expected. When more than one X has influence on the

H1: Positive (negative) media exposure on corporate social responsibility of an organization has a significant positive (negative) effect on the corporate financial performance

In order to examine the intervening effects of exploitation efforts on the relationship between corporate social responsibility and a firm’s financial performance,

Keywords: Corporate social responsibility, corporate social irresponsibility, country-level, industry-level, firm-level, environmental score, social score, corporate governance score,

In line with earlier research I also find evidence for a positive correlation between female representation in a board and CSR pillar scores at a 5% level for Environmental

As the results show mixed results with different environmental performance measurements, it implies that only some aspects (underlying variables) of the environmental

Table 2 reports the descriptive statistics for all the variables used in the full sample, which are the Tobin’s Q-ratio, return on assets (ROA), ES (environmental and

Additionally, regarding nationality, previous research showed an evident link between the CSR and managers’ national culture and how it plays a significant role in