• No results found

Quality signals and personal subsidies : how cultural foundations in the Netherlands select artists

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Quality signals and personal subsidies : how cultural foundations in the Netherlands select artists"

Copied!
51
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

         University  of  Amsterdam  –  Faculty  of  Economics  and  Business                                  

 

 

Quality  signals  and  personal  subsidies  

                 How  cultural  foundations  in  the  Netherlands  select  artists  

                                       

Koen  de  Boer   5799864   27-­‐11-­‐2013  

Supervisor:  Monika  Kackovic    

(2)

Abstract    

With  funding  decreasing  and  competition  increasing,  the  pressure  on  subsidy  allocators  and  subsidy   applicants  is  higher  than  ever.  For  many  cultural  foundations,  the  quality  of  an  artist’s  work  is  one  of   the  most  important  criteria  for  personal  subsidies.  The  problem  is  that  the  quality  of  cultural  

products  is  often  difficult  to  determine  prior  to  ‘consumption’.  It  was  expected  that  cultural   foundations  use  alternative  measures  such  as  quality  signals  to  determine  the  quality  of  an  artist’s   work.  This  research  provides  evidence  that  quality  signals  are  able  to  influence  cultural  foundations’   appraisal  of  artists  applying  for  personal  subsidies.  Data  showed  that  the  more  quality  signals  an   artist’s  CV  contained,  the  more  personal  subsidies  the  artists  received.  Participation  in  biennales   turned  out  to  be  the  strongest  quality  signal  and  public  foundations  are  more  likely  to  be  influenced   by  the  number  of  quality  signals  on  a  CV  than  private  foundations.  Interviews  with  professionals  in   the  art  sector  showed  that  there  are  alternative  ways  to  increase  the  chance  of  receiving  subsidies.   Personal  connections,  the  artist’s  reputation  and  the  way  the  application  was  presented  turned  out   to  be  other  important  factors  in  the  selection  process.    

                                                               

(3)

  Contents     1.  Introduction                     4     2.  Theoretical  framework                 5   2.1  Signalling  theory                 5       2.1.1  Reviews                 6       2.1.2  Awards                 7       2.1.3  Expositions               7   2.2  CVs                     8   2.3  Stardom                   8   2.4  Hypotheses                   8     3.  Empirical  setting                   9     3.1  Art  subsidies  in  the  Netherlands             9     3.2  New  cultural  policy                 10  

  3.3  Cultural  foundations               11  

    3.3.1  Financing                 12  

    3.3.2  Requirements               13  

    3.3.3  Mission  and  criteria             13     4.  Methods                     14     4.1  Data                   15       4.1.1  Independent  variables             15       4.1.2  Dependent  variables             16     4.2  Interviews                   16     5.  Results                     16     5.1  Data                   16     5.2  Interviews                   20  

    5.2.1  Summary  interview  Lino  Hellings           20       5.2.2  Summary  interview  Thijs  Tromp           21     6.  Discussions                     23       6.1  Concluding  remarks               26     References                     28     Appendix                     32                

(4)

1.  Introduction  

Since  the  recession  hit  the  Netherlands  in  2008,  large  reforms  in  the  art  and  culture  sector  have   been  planned.  In  2013  the  government  imposed  budget  cuts  on  the  cultural  sector,  which  amounts   to  200  million  euros  ,  or  20%  (Ministerie  van  Onderwijs,  Cultuur  en  Wetenschap,  2013).  On  top  of   this  national  cut,  municipalities  and  provinces  had  to  cut  their  annual  budgets  with  an  additional   10%  (Berenschot,  2012).    

Subsidies  are  an  essential  source  of  income  for  artists.  Almost  two-­‐thirds  of  the  total  income  of  the   art  sector  consists  of  subsidies  (Berenschot,  2011).  Because  artists  already  had  to  compete  for   subsidies  (Rengers  and  Plug,  2001),  it  is  expected  that  these  budget  cuts  will  increase  competition   for  subsidies  among  artists.  Furthermore,  many  cultural  foundations  are  becoming  stricter  in  their   requirements  for  subsidies.  For  instance,  artists  are  required  to  show  ‘cultural  entrepreneurship’,   which  means  that  production  of  art  has  to  better  suit  consumer  demand  (Ministerie  van  Onderwijs,   Cultuur  en  Wetenschap  2013).    Another  core  point  of  the  new  policy  is  an  increased  focus  on  artists   at  the  top  of  their  discipline  (Ministerie  van  Onderwijs,  Cultuur  en  Wetenschap  2013).  This  could   potentially  lead  to  complications,  as  art  can  be  difficult  to  compare  and  rank  (Currid,  2007).  

Most  cultural  products  can  be  regarded  as  experiential  goods  (Hirsch  1972,  Holbrook  and  Hirschman   1982).  This  means  that  when  someone  plans  on  buying,  viewing  or  otherwise  ‘consuming’  a  piece  of   art,  one  can  only  be  sure  about  the  quality  of  the  product  after  it  has  been  experienced  (Wijnberg   and  Gemser,  2000).  This  makes  pre-­‐purchase  quality  judgments  difficult  to  make.  Moreover,  cultural   products  are  generally  taste-­‐driven  and  not  performance  driven,  which  makes  the  assessment  of   their  value  even  more  difficult  (Currid,  2007).    When  the  evaluation  of  an  unobservable  product  is   difficult,  alternative  mechanisms  can  be  used  to  determine  the  quality  of  a  product  (Ali  and  Nauges   2007,  Emons  1997).  According  to  the  signalling  theory  (Spence,  1973),  certain  signals  can  be  used  as   proxies  of  product  quality.  These  signals  can  convey  information  about  a  product  or  producer’s   unobservable  qualities.  Examples  of  quality  signals  are  awards,  reviews  and  endorsements  (Kirmani   and  Rao,  2000).  Typically,  this  information  can  be  found  on  an  artist’s  Curriculum  Vitae  (CV).  The  use   of  CVs  is  very  common  in  the  art  sector  (e.g.,  Ammodo  2012,  Amsterdam  Fund  for  the  Arts  2012,   Mondriaan  Foundation  2012,  Prins  Bernhard  Foundation  2012)  since  they  are  often  used  to  leave  an   impression  on  clients  or  employers  (Nemanick  and  Clark,  2000).    

Almost  all  subsidies  in  the  Netherlands  are  distributed  by  public  and  private  cultural  foundations   such  as  the  Mondriaan  Foundation  and  the  Prins  Bernhard  Foundation.  Providing  roughly  a  quarter,   or  1,16  billion  euros,  of  the  total  income  of  the  cultural  sector,  the  impact  of  the  cultural  foundations   on  art  in  the  Netherlands  is  substantial  (Berenschot/de  Volkskrant,  2012).  Most  cultural  foundations   require  a  CV  to  be  included  in  the  application  as  it  often  contains  most  of  the  artist’s  past  activities   and  accomplishments  such  as  expositions,  reviews  and  awards.  Furthermore,  many  cultural   foundation  mention  artistic  quality  as  one  of  the  most  important  criteria  for  personal  subsidies.   Perhaps  information  on  artists’  CVs  can  function  as  a  quality  signal,  which  can  influence  the   foundation’s  appraisal  of  the  applying  artist.  

The  focus  of  this  study  is  to  explore  how,  and  on  what  basis,  cultural  foundations  assign  personal   subsidies  to  artists.  Additionally,  the  role  of  quality  signals  found  on  artist  CVs  will  be  investigated.   Personal  subsidies  will  be  defined  as  merit-­‐based  scholarships,  (residency)  grants  or  stipends.    

(5)

 

Thus,  the  main  research  questions  will  be:    

How  do  cultural  foundations  select  the  artists  that  receive  personal  subsidies?  Do  quality  signals  have   an  effect  on  the  selection  committees  of  cultural  foundations?  

In  the  next  section,  the  relevant  concepts  and  theories  will  be  explained  in  more  detail.  Also,  to   better  understand  how  cultural  foundations  operate,  a  brief  overview  of  art  subsidies  in  the   Netherlands  will  be  given,  along  with  a  description  of  the  new  cultural  policies.  Then,  the  different   guidelines  and  criteria  of  the  public  and  private  cultural  foundations  will  be  explained.    

This  study  follows  a  mixed-­‐methods  approach.  Using  quantitative  data  from  students  who  attended   the  Rietveld  Academy  in  Amsterdam,  the  relationship  between  quality  signals  and  personal  subsidies   will  be  explored.  Additionally,  interviews  with  professionals  from  the  art  sector  will  be  used  to  shed   light  on  both  sides  of  the  subsidy  allocation  process.  

2.  Theoretical  Framework  

2.1  Signalling  theory  

Cultural  goods  can  be  seen  as  experiential  goods  (Hirsch  1972,  Holbrook  and  Hirschman  1982).  The   value  of  an  experience  good  is  based  on  the  consumption  experience  and  its  hedonic  aspects  in   particular  (Cooper-­‐Martin,  1991).  Therefore,  in  this  paper,  a  high  quality  experience  good  will  be   described  as  one  that  has  high  hedonic  value.    

The  quality  of  a  cultural  good  is  often  difficult  to  determine  (Wijnberg  and  Gemser,  2000).  This  is   partially  because  people  can  only  determine  the  value  of  an  experience  good  for  themselves  after   the  experience  itself.  Another  reason  is  that  cultural  products  are  taste-­‐driven  and  not  performance   driven,  which  makes  the  assessment  of  their  value  difficult  (Currid,  2007).  Perceived  quality  has  been   proven  to  have  strategic  value  and  influences  the  decision  making  process  of  potential  consumers   (Zeithaml,  1988).  This  is  also  true  in  the  cultural  industries,  where  recognition  and  attribution  of   value  are  linked  to  product  differentiation  (Wijnberg  and  Gemser,  2000).  

Spence’s  signalling  theory  (1973)  describes  signals  as  proxies  of  product  quality.  Signals  can  convey   information  about  the  unobservable  qualities  of  a  product  or  its  producer.  This  can  help  close   information  gaps  and  reduce  uncertainty  in  pre-­‐purchase  decision  making.  Guarantees,  

advertisements,  pricing,  endorsements  and  brand  extensions  are  all  examples  of  quality  signals.     At  the  base  of  a  quality  signal  lies  either  an  up-­‐front  expenditure  or  a  credible  commitment  (Kirmani   and  Rao,  2000).  Both  mean  that  a  sender  is  risking  something  when  a  quality-­‐related  claims  turn  out   to  be  false.  An  example  of  a  signal  with  an  up-­‐front  expenditure  is  an  advertisement.  A  producer   decides  to  spend  money  on  advertising  for  its  product  now,  with  the  expectation  to  recover  it  in  the   future.  A  rational  consumer  realizes  that  when  a  producer  spends  a  large  amount  of  money  on   advertising  the  supposed  quality  of  a  product  that  is  actually  low-­‐quality,  it  won’t  be  able  to  recoup   these  advertising  costs  if  no  future  purchases  (other  than  trial  purchases)  will  follow.  Therefore,  the   quality-­‐related  claims  are  likely  to  be  true.  When  a  signal  involves  a  credible  commitment,  there  are   no  costs  when  the  signal  is  transmitted  but  only  when  the  producer  defaults  on  its  quality  claim.  

(6)

These  types  of  signals  can  also  be  called  default-­‐contingent  signals.  An  example  of  a  signal  which   involves  a  credible  commitment  is  a  warranty.  When  a  producer  offers  warranty  over  his  product,  a   rational  consumer  deduces  that  the  quality  of  this  product  must  be  good.  This  is  because  a  producer   wouldn’t  knowingly  offer  warranty  over  a  low-­‐quality  product  as  this  would  lead  to  high  costs  in   refunds  or  repairs  (Kirmani  and  Rao,  2000).  

Quality  signals  can  originate  from  different  sources  such  as  the  producers  themselves  or  from  third   parties.  Quality  signals  originating  from  the  producer,  such  as  advertisements,    can  be  perceived  as   biased.  Third  parties  are  not  directly  involved  in  the  exchange  between  consumer  and  producer  and   are  perceived  as  being  trustworthy  (Dean  and  Biswas,  2001).  Third  party  sources  can  provide  quality   evaluations  by  ranking,  reviewing  and  rating  products.  To  be  credible,  however,  signals  coming  from   these  third  party  sources  must  contain  a  ''bonding''  component,  a  potential  cost  to  the  sender  if  the   signal  is  false  and  the  product  is  of  low  quality  (Ippolito,  1990).  Bond  vulnerability  increases  when   the  sender  of  a  quality  signal  has  more  to  lose.  When  a  source  with  high  bond  vulnerability  is  willing   to  risk  high  costs,  such  as  losing  its  credibility,  it  indicates  a  strong  belief  in  the  quality  of  the  

product.      

According  to  the  literature  on  quality  signals,  the  more  accurate,  specific  and  clear  a  signal,  the  more   likely  it  will  provide  information  that  is  useful  in  an  assessment  of  product  quality  (Dawar  and  Parker   1994,  Kirmani  and  Rao  2000).  Furthermore,  the  attribution  theory  states  that  cues  from  low-­‐

credibility  sources  will  be  given  less  weight  by  consumers  in  their  decision-­‐making  process  than   those  from  high-­‐credibility  sources  (Eagly  and  Chaiken,  1975).  Consumers  will  not  blindly  accept  any   quality  signal,  but  will  attempt  to  assess  for  themselves  whether  the  source  of  the  cue  is  credible  or   not  (Gemser  et  al.,  2008).  A  signal  originating  from  a  highly  credible  source  can  therefore  be  more   convincing  than  a  less  credible  source  (Eagly  and  Chaiken,  1975).  

Because  the  empirical  setting  of  this  paper  is  the  art  sector,  three  third  party  sources  that  are   common  in  the  art  world  will  be  described  in  the  next  section.    

2.1.1  Reviews  

Because  of  their  independence  of  the  producers,  art  critics  can  be  seen  as  credible  third  party   sources  (Dean  &  Biswas,  2001).  According  to  Debenedetti  (2006),  critics  are  integral  to  the   economics  of  cultural  products:  “Being  part  of  the  media  industry  and  contemporaneous  with  the   works  they  critique,  their  complex  links  with  creators  and  managers  upstream  and  with  the  public   downstream  put  critics  at  the  center  of  a  system  of  material  and  symbolic  relations  that  make  them   key  actors  in  the  cultural  industries”.  According  to  Cameron  (1995),  criticism,  either  positive  or   negative,  is  equivalent  to  advertising  because  it  increases  visibility  and  awareness  of  the  artist.  Art   critics  can  be  seen  as  opinion  leaders  in  the  cultural  sector,  as  they  can  often  determine  the  success   or  failure  of  cultural  offerings  (Reddy,  Swaminathan,  &  Motley,  1998).  Debenedetti  (2006)  describes   critics  as  “a  special  provider  of  information  in  a  market  characterized  by  consumer  uncertainty  over   the  value  of  cultural  goods  and  by  the  difficulty  of  developing  practical  knowledge  to  inform   decision-­‐making”.    

In  the  case  of  experience  products  such  as  art,  reviews  can  help  close  information  gaps  because  they   offer  the  indirect  experience  of  non-­‐tangible  attributes  (Nelson,  1970).  Consumers  perceive  critics  as   credible  sources  because  of  their  expertise  and  independence  (Levin,  Levin  &  Heath,  1997).  A  critic’s  

(7)

reputation  depends  on  his  ability  to  identify  talent  and  originality,  but  also  its  ability  to  spot   potential  superstars  (Cameron,  1995).  When  a  critic  claims  to  have  found  a  new  star  but  the  artist   does  not  live  up  to  the  expectations,  the  critic’s  credibility  suffers.  This  has  to  do  with  the  potential   costs,  or  “bond”,  a  third  party  source  (such  as  a  critic)  can  be  subjected  to  (Ippolito,  1990).  In  the   case  of  a  false  quality  signal  (when  the  supposed  quality  does  not  match  the  actual  quality),  this  cost   would  be  the  loss  of  reputation,  perhaps  the  most  valuable  asset  a  third  party  source  possesses   (Dean  &  Biswas,  1990).  The  willingness  of  a  third  party  source  to  risk  these  costs  will  be  perceived  by   others  as  an  indication  of  quality  (Dean  &  Biswas,  2001).    

2.1.2  Awards  

Awards  play  an  important  role  in  the  cultural  industry  because  they  offer  a  way  for  consumers  to   assess  the  quality  of  a  cultural  product  (Gemser,  Leenders  and  Wijnberg,  2008).  It  is  therefore  similar   to  a  (positive)  review,  but  in  a  more  easily  recognizable  and  accessible  form.  An  award  is  essentially   an  endorsement  in  the  form  of  a  ‘seal  of  approval’  of  an  award  committee  or  a  jury  of  critics  (Dean  &   Biswas,  2001).  Research  showed  that  expert  “selectors",  with  their  considerable  knowledge  and   credibility,  play  an  important  role  when  the  value  of  cultural  products  is  hard  to  determine  

(Wijnberg  and  Gemser,  2000).  Critical  consensus  on  cultural  products  has  been  proven  to  serve  as  a   strong  quality  signal  for  cultural  products  (Basuroy,  Desai  &  Talukdar,  2006).  Similar  to  reviews,  the   bond  or  potential  cost  is  at  the  core  of  the  credibility  of  the  quality  signal.  When  the  sender  (the   jury)  defaults  on  the  quality  claim,  its  reputation  suffers  (Dean  &  Biswas,  2001).      

2.1.3  Expositions  

In  past  research,  exhibitions  and  art  shows  history  have  been  used  as  indicators  of  the  quality  of   visual  art    (Bonus  and  Ronte,  1997).  Artists  and  galleries  often  collaborate  by  exhibiting  and  selling   the  artist’s  art  in  the  gallery  holder’s  gallery.  Usually,  the  resulting  revenue  is  split  between  the   gallery  and  the  artist  (Caves,  2003).  An  exposition  can  function  as  a  quality  signal  because  the  gallery   is  essentially  a  third  party  source.  It  is  expected  that  a  gallery  is  motivated  to  exhibit  “high  quality”   cultural  products  because  of  its  higher  perceived  value  (Zeithaml,  1988).  According  to  Kirmani  and   Rao  (2000),  when  a  sender  of  a  quality  signal  defaults  on  this  quality  claim,  it  can  have  two   consequences:  the  loss  of  up-­‐front  expenditures  or  damage  to  its  reputation.    

A  gallery  resembles  a  retail  store  where  shelf  space  is  limited.  Two  paintings  cannot  hang  on  the   same  spot  at  the  same  time.  Chu  (1994)  argues  that  when  a  shop  offers  a  certain  product,  it  signals   the  quality  of  the  product  to  customers.  This  is  because  rational  consumers  expect  shop  owners  to   prefer  selling  high  quality  products  as  they  have  a  higher  chance  of  being  sold.  The  same  could  be   true  for  galleries.  When  an  exposition  takes  place,  the  gallery  holder  is  risking  the  costs  associated   with  promoting  and  organizing  the  exposition.  Additionally,  the  gallery  holder  risks  the  opportunity   cost  of  not  having  another,  more  successful,  exposition  in  its  gallery.    

Also,  because  rational  consumers  expect  galleries  to  look  for  ways  that  benefit  its  reputation,  they   assume  that  they  will  not  knowingly  exhibit  low-­‐quality  art.  When  a  gallery  promises  an  exposition   with  high  quality  art  but  defaults  on  this  promise,  its  reputation  will  be  damaged  (Rao,  Qu  &  Ruekert   1999).  This  in  turn,  could  harm  future  sales.    

(8)

It  is  assumed  that  rational  consumers  are  aware  of  the  previously  mentioned  risks  that  galleries  are   facing.  Galleries  can  therefore  be  seen  as  a  third  party  source  that  sends  out  signals  about  the   quality  of  art.  Using  the  same  reasoning,  a  past  exposition  can  be  viewed  as  a  quality  signal  for  the   displayed  art.    

2.2  CVs  

An  artist’s  review-­‐,  award-­‐  and  exposition  history  can  typically  be  found  on  his  or  her  Curriculum   Vitae  (CV).    The  use  of  CVs  is  very  common  in  the  art  sector  (e.g.,  Ammodo  2012,  Amsterdam  Fund   for  the  Arts  2012,  Mondriaan  Foundation  2012,  Prins  Bernhard  Foundation  2012).  Previous  research   showed  that  a  CV  is  an  important  starting  point  in  the  applicant  selection  process  as  it  provides  the   first  means  to  attributions  a  selector  can  make  about  a  candidate  (Knouse,  1989).  The  content,   length,  format  of  a  CV  have  all  been  shown  to  influence  the  judgment  of  applicants  (Nemanick  and   Clark  2000,  Thoms,  McMasters,  Roberts  and  Dombkowski  1999,  Toth  1999).  Research  showed  that   hen  the  evaluation  of  an  unobservable  product  is  difficult,  proxies  can  be  used  to  determine  the   quality  of  a  product  (Ali  and  Nauges  2007,  Emons  1997).  It  is  therefore  assumed  that  cultural   foundations  rely  on  the  quality  signals,  found  on  artists  CVs,  when  they  assess  the  quality  of   applicants  for  subsidies.    

2.3  Stardom  

Rosen  (1981)  described  the  phenomenon  of  superstars,  wherein  relatively  small  numbers  of  people   earn  large  amounts  of  money  and  dominate  the  activities  in  which  they  engage.    In  markets  such  as   the  cultural  sector,  a  tendency  exists  for  the  market  share  and  reward  to  be  disproportionally   skewed  toward  most  talented  people  in  the  industry.  The  classical  music  market  for  example  has   never  been  larger  than  it  is  today.  However,  there  are  remarkably  few  full-­‐time  soloists.  Only  a   handful  is  considered  as  the  top  and  enjoys  very  large  income  while  most  consumers  can’t   differentiate  between  ‘first’  and  ‘second’  rank  performers  in  a  blind  hearing.  Rengers  (2001)  also   found  evidence  of  rewards  structurally  flowing  to  the  same  artists,  which  he  called  the  ‘winner-­‐ takes-­‐all’  hypothesis.  According  to  Adler  (1985),  this  phenomenon  of  stardom  exists  mostly  when   consumption  requires  knowledge.  Adler  argues  that  people  have  to  acquire  knowledge  about  an   artistic  activity  before  it  can  be  understood  and  fully  appreciated.  This  requires  discussion  with   others  who  also  have  some  knowledge  of  the  same  artists.  In  this  situation,  everyone  is  better  off   choosing  the  most  popular  artist  because  it  minimizes  searching  costs.  As  a  result,  certain  superstars   are  being  patronized  while  their  talent  is  not  significantly  greater  than  that  of  others.  On  a  smaller   scale,  this  effect  of  stardom  is  expected  to  also  exist  in  the  Dutch  art  sector.  Thus,  it  is  expected  that   relatively  few  artists  receive  the  most  rewards,  which  in  this  context  means  subsidies.  Because  a   subsidy  could  function  like  a  third  party  quality  signal  similar  to  an  award,  it  is  possible  that  receiving   a  subsidy  is  easier  for  artists  who  already  received  one  in  the  past,  which  supports  the  winner-­‐takes-­‐ all  hypothesis.  It  is  therefore  expected  that  of  all  subsidized  artists,  most  have  received  more  than   one  personal  subsidy  in  their  career.  

2.4  Hypotheses  

Cultural  foundations  that  provide  personal  subsidies  attempt  to  judge  applicants  based  on  their   previous  activities  and  accomplishments,  as  documented  in  an  artist’s  CV  (e.g.,  Amsterdam  Fund  for   the  Arts  2012,  Mondriaan  Foundation  2012,  Prins  Bernhard  Foundation  2012).  The  content  of  CVs  

(9)

has  been  shown  to  influence  the  judgment  of  applicants  (Nemanick  and  Clark,  2000).  The  previous   section  showed  that  third  party  signals  like  awards,  exposition  history  and  reviews  are  likely  to   influence  quality  perceptions.  Artistic  quality  is  often  mentioned  as  one  of  the  most  important   criteria  the  foundations  judge  applicants  on  (e.g.,  Mondriaan  Foundation,  2012).  It  is  therefore   expected  that  cultural  foundations  are  influenced  by  quality  signals  and  award  personal  subsidies  to   the  artists  that  send  out  the  most  quality  signals.  In  other  words,  the  artists  that  received  personal   subsidies  are  expected  to  have  provided  the  most  quality  signals  through  their  CVs.  Here,  personal   subsidies  will  be  defined  as  merit-­‐based  scholarships,  (residency)  grants  or  stipends.    

Following  the  assumption  that  a  subsidy  itself  could  also  function  as  a  quality  signal,  the  first   hypothesis  tests  if  subsidized  artists  are  more  likely  to  have  received  more  than  one  subsidy  in  their   career.  Subsidized  artists  will  be  defined  as  artists  that  have  received  at  least  one  personal  subsidy  in   their  career.  

H1.  The  average  amount  of  personal  subsidies  that  subsidized  artists  received  is  significantly  higher   than  1.    

The  next  two  hypotheses  explore  the  relation  between  quality  signals  and  performance.    

H2.  The  total  number  of  quality  signals  on  a  CV  is  significantly  different  for  artists  who  have  received   personal  subsidies  compared  to  those  who  have  not.    

H3.  The  total  number  of  expositions,  reviews  and  awards  on  an  artist’s  CV  have  a  significant  effect   on  performance,  measured  by  total  number  of  personal  subsidies  received.  

To  further  examine  which  type  of  quality  signal  has  the  strongest  effect  on  the  number  of  subsidies   received,  the  quality  signals  will  be  separated  into  categories:  reviews,  awards  and  expositions.  It  is   assumed  that  the  most  effective  type  of  quality  signals  is  the  one  that  is  the  most  commonly  found   on  subsidized  artists’  CVs.  Furthermore,  the  total  amount  of  subsidies  will  be  divided  into  public  and   private  subsidies  in  order  to  analyze  potential  differences  between  public  and  private  foundations.   It  is  expected  that  the  content  of  an  artist’s  CV  is  not  the  only  relevant  factor  in  the  subsidy  

allocation  process.  This  process  is  likely  to  be  influenced  by  other  internal  and  external  factors  such   as  the  distinctive  features  of  the  selecting  cultural  foundations  and  the  environment  in  which  these   foundations  operate.  In  the  next  section,  a  brief  overview  of  the  Dutch  subsidy  climate  will  be  given,   along  with  a  description  of  the  new  cultural  policies  of  2013-­‐2016.  Then,  the  different  guidelines  and   criteria  of  the  public  and  private  cultural  foundations  will  be  explained.    

3.  Empirical  setting    

3.1  Art  subsidies  in  the  Netherlands  

Art  is  important  for  the  Dutch  economy.  In  2011,  the  cultural  sector  added  13  billion  euros  (2.4%)  to   the  GDP  Ministerie  van  Onderwijs,  Cultuur  en  Wetenschap  2012).  Art  and  culture  also  adds  to  the   general  livability  of  the  Netherlands  and  draws  businesses,  professionals  and  tourists  to  the  country   (Marlet  and  Ponds,  2011).  Furthermore,  an  estimated  251.000  people  (or  3.2%  of  the  Dutch  labour   force)  have  jobs  in  the  cultural  sector  Ministerie  van  Onderwijs,  Cultuur  en  Wetenschap  2012).   Culture  is  also  an  important  export  product  for  the  Netherlands,  as  it  is  among  the  top  10  export  

(10)

countries  of  ‘cultural  goods’  (UNCTAD/UNDP,  2010).  However,  not  all  the  benefits  of  art  and  culture   can  be  measured  in  money.  Art  and  culture  also  indirectly  contribute  to  society  by  adding  to  a   creative  climate  (KEA/European  Affairs,  2009)  and  strengthening  social  cohesion  (Burton  &  Griffin,   2008).  According  to  research  conducted  by  the  ministry  of  education,  culture  and  science,  75%  of   the  Dutch  citizens  regard  art  and  culture  as  an  important  part  of  society  (Ministerie  van  Onderwijs,   Cultuur  en  Wetenschap  2012).    

Many  art  disciplines  in  the  Netherlands  rely  on  subsidies.  Most  of  the  cultural  institutions  do  not   earn  enough  to  cover  their  costs  (Ministerie  van  Onderwijs,  Cultuur  en  Wetenschap  2012).  For   instance,  the  state  pays  an  average  of  120  euros  of  subsidies  for  each  opera  visitor.  Although  a  lot   cheaper,  a  visit  to  a  museum  still  requires  11  euros  of  subsidy  (van  der  Ploeg,  2002).  At  the  start  of   the  financial  crisis  in  2008,  when  it  became  clear  that  the  neo-­‐liberal  government  had  to  radically   lower  its  expenditures,  voices  from  the  political  right  emerged  which  demanded  the  abolishment  of   art  subsidies,  or  “leftist  hobbies”.  In  2011,  it  was  decided  that  the  government  would  cut  200  million   euros  in  culture  and  art  funding.  This  could  be  viewed  as  part  of  a  long-­‐term  trend  of  changing   cultural  policies  in  the  Netherlands.    

The  60s  could  be  regarded  as  the  heyday  of  Dutch  art  subsidies.  The  government  took  the  role  of  a   “guardian”  for  artists  (Rengers,  2001).  For  instance,  the  Beeldende  Kunst  Regeling  (BKR),  established   in  1956,  made  it  possible  for  artists  to  receive  subsidies  in  exchange  for  pieces  of  art  that  the  

government  would  buy  off  them.  By  1972,  this  policy  resulted  in  an  estimated  220.000  artworks  that   the  government  could  no  longer  handle.  The  arrangement  was  gradually  reduced  and  abolished  in   1987.    In  the  late  90’s  the  term  ‘cultural  entrepreneurship’  was  introduced  by  State  Secretary  of   Culture  and  Media  van  der  Ploeg.  It  marked  the  beginning  of  a  series  of  initiatives  to  make  the   cultural  sector  less  dependent  of  government  funding.  Artists  had  to  better  adapt  to  modern  society   where  free  market  mechanisms  played  an  increasingly  important  role  (Velthuis,  2000).  Other   arrangements  like  the  Wet  Inkomensvoorziening  Kunstenaars  (1999-­‐2005)  and  the  Wet  Werk  en   Inkomen  Kunstenaars  (2005-­‐2012),  originally  designed  as  a  type  of  stimulating  allowance,  were   deemed  ineffective  and  were  therefore  terminated.  It  is  argued  that  these  changes  in  policies  have   great  consequences  for  the  art  sector  in  the  Netherlands.  According  to  Bevers  (2012),  a  period  of   prosperity  in  the  Dutch  art  sector  ended  in  2010.    In  his  research,  Bevers  showed  that  Dutch  art   flourished  between  the  years  1980  and  2010  when  generous  art  policies  contributed  to  a  great   increase  of  representations  of  Dutch  art  abroad  in  that  period.  Between  the  years  of  1996  and  2010,   the  amount  of  expositions  of  Dutch  artists  outside  the  Netherlands  increased  fivefold  compared  to   the  decade  before.  According  to  Bevers,  these  overseas  representations  can  be  seen  as  an  indication   of  quality  of  Dutch  art  in  general.  This  is  because  it  is  generally  not  solely  the  artist’s  decision  to   exhibit  abroad  as  there  has  to  be  a  certain  appreciation  for  their  work  and  they  have  to  be  invited  by   a  gallery.  The  year  2010  marked  the  end  of  this  “Third  Golden  Age”  and  Bevers  attributed  this   change  to  the  Dutch  government  being  less  generous  to  the  art  sector.    

3.2  New  cultural  policy  

The  Ministry  of  Education,  Culture  and  Science  (OCW)  receives  advice  from  the  Raad  voor  Cultuur   (Council  for  Culture)  regarding  the  assignment  of  funding.  Every  four  years,  the  Council  presents  its   recommendations  on  the  perennial,  government-­‐subsidized,  cultural  institutions.  The  

(11)

for  subsidy.  It  has  been  decided  that  for  the  period  2013-­‐2016,  the  government  will  cut  200  million   (or  25%)  from  arts  and  cultural  subsidies  (Ministerie  van  Onderwijs,  Cultuur  en  Wetenschap,  2012).   The  art  sector  is  increasingly  expected  to  cover  more  of  its  own  costs  which  requires  many  artists   and  institutions  to  assume  a  more  market-­‐orientated  approach  and  seek  for  alternative  forms  of   income  (Ministerie  van  Onderwijs,  Cultuur  en  Wetenschap  2012).    As  a  result,  subsidized  

organizations  now  have  to  indicate  in  their  plans  how  they  are  going  to  attract  more  visitors  and   increase  their  income  (Ministerie  van  Onderwijs,  Cultuur  en  Wetenschap  2013).    

Less  dependence  on  government  funding  and  more  connection  with  the  audience  are  at  the  core  of   the  cultural  policy  of  2013-­‐2016.  All  subsidized  institutions  and  organizations  within  the  cultural   sector  have  to  find  ways  to  engage  more  people  while  finding  alternative  ways  to  finance  their   activities.  In  order  to  receive  funds  for  the  next  period  it  is  required  that  all  institutions  and   organizations  cover  at  least  17,5%  of  the  costs  on  their  own  which  means  that  for  every  €1000  of   funding,  at  least  €175  have  to  be  generated  autonomously.  This  percentage  will  increase  with  1%   every  year  until  2016  (Ministerie  van  Onderwijs,  Cultuur  en  Wetenschap  2013).      

Another  core  point  of  the  new  policy  is  an  increased  focus  on  talent  at  the  top  of  their  discipline,  as   dictated  by  State  Secretary  Zijlstra.  A  smaller  part  of  the  budget  will  go  to  stipends  and  scholarships   for  which  established  artists  will  now  receive  priority  over  starting  artists.  This  policy  is  closely   related  to  the  ambition  to  expand  the  market  by  promoting  Dutch  visual  arts  and  cultural  heritage   abroad.  By  focusing  on  “the  top”  of  the  art  sector,  the  visibility  of  Dutch  art  is  expected  to  increase   which  can  attract  potential  buyers  (Ministerie  van  Onderwijs,  Cultuur  en  Wetenschap  2013).  The   Ministry  of  Education,  Culture  and  Science  also  attempts  to  stimulate  purchasing  and  commissioning   of  visual  art  by  companies  and  private  individuals.  By  introducing  matching  grants,  for  instance,   companies  are  being  stimulated  to  commission  artists  to  create  specific  art  works  (Ministerie  van   Onderwijs,  Cultuur  en  Wetenschap,  2013).    

3.3  Cultural  foundations  

The  largest  part  of  the  budget  cuts  (€125  million)  will  come  from  the  main  cultural  infrastructure   (BIS):  cultural  institutions  and  foundations  that  receive  direct  funding  from  the  government  through   the  Ministry  of  Education,  Culture  and  Science.  The  BIS  now  consists  of  30  museums,  9  orchestras,   16  theatre  companies,  3  opera  companies,  4  dance  companies,  3  festivals  and  15  art-­‐supporting   institutions.  A  total  of  327  million  euros  will  be  divided  between  these  organizations  over  the  coming   4  years.  Also  included  in  the  main  cultural  infrastructure  are  the  six  public  cultural  foundations:  

Fonds  Podiumkunsten:  Foundation  for  institutions  and  artists  in  performing  arts  (dance,  theatre,  

festivals,  music)  

Stimuleringsfonds  Creative  Industrie:  Stimulating  foundation  for  projects  in  the  field  of  architecture,  

design,  e-­‐culture  and  games.  

Mondriaanfonds:  Foundation  for  visual  arts  and  cultural  heritage  that  focuses  mainly  on  museums,  

art  initiatives  and  galleries.  

(12)

Nederlands  Letterenfonds:  Foundation  that  supports  and  promotes  the  Dutch  Literature  with  

subsidies  and  scholarships  for  writers,  translators,  publishers  and  festivals.    

Fonds  voor  Cultuurparticipatie:  Foundation  that  supports  cultural  initiatives  that  cause  active  

participation  to  art.  

The  Mondriaanfoundation  has  merged  with  the  BKVB  foundation  and  in  the  coming  period  the   Culture  Participation  Fund  (Participatiefonds)  will  be  merged  with  the  Performing  Arts  Fund  (Fonds   Podiumkunsten).  These  foundations  have  the  authority  to  provide  funding  to  smaller  institutions,   organizations  and  individuals  with  a  combined  budget  of  133  million  euros  in  2013,  which  is  21%  less   than  2011  (Ministerie  van  Onderwijs,  Cultuur  en  Wetenschap,  2012).  They  play  a  crucial  role  in  the   implementation  of  the  cultural  policy  of  the  government  because  of  their  proximity  to  the  art  sector   in  which  they  operate.  Because  of  this,  they’re  able  to  detect  and  react  to  developments  within  their   art  sector  (Ministerie  van  Onderwijs,  Cultuur  en  Wetenschap  2012).  This  is  in  line  with  the  cultural-­‐ political  principle  that  it  is  not  the  task  of  the  government  to  judge  the  quality  of  cultural  expressions   (Ministerie  van  Onderwijs,  Cultuur  en  Wetenschap  2013)  

Apart  from  the  public  foundations,  a  large  amount  of  private  foundations  exist.  The  largest  of  which   are  the  Prins  Bernhard  Foundation,  VSB  Foundation,  Ammodo  and  SNSReaal  Foundation  with  an   annual  budget  of  25,  17,  15  and  12  million  euros  respectively  (Prins  Bernhard  Foundation  2012,  VSB   Foundation  2012,  Ammodo  2012,  SNSReaal  Foundation  2012).  

Finally,  a  number  of  art-­‐supporting  municipal  and  provincial  foundations  exist,  the  largest  of  which  is   the  Amsterdam  Foundation  for  the  Arts  (AFK)  with  an  annual  budget  of  8  million  euros  (AFK,  2012).   In  total,  the  municipal  and  provincial  foundations  provide  an  estimated  43%  of  the  total  income  of   the  entire  art  sector  (Berenschot,  2012)  while  playing  especially  large  role  in  the  amateur  art  sector.   Most  of  the  estimated  70.000  amateur-­‐art  associations  receive  funding  from  municipalities  (93%),   followed  by  private  foundations  (33%),  the  provinces  (8%)  and  the  pubic  foundations  (3%)  

(Berenschot,  2010).    

All  public,  private,  municipal  and  provincial  foundations  have  different  functions  and  financing.   These  differences  determines  their  criteria  and  guidelines  for  subsidies.  The  differences  between  the   foundations  will  be  explained  in  more  detail  in  the  following  section.  

3.3.1  Financing  

Public  foundations  are  part  of  the  BIS  and  therefore  receive  funds  directly  from  the  Department  of   Education,  Culture  and  Science  (OCW).  Municipal  and  provincial  foundations  receive  their  funding   indirectly  from  the  state  through  the  provinces.    

Private  foundations  are  financed  in  many  different  ways.  Foundations  like  the  Prins  

Bernhardfoundation  and  Stichting  DOEN  receive  large  parts  of  their  budgets  (69%  and  62%  in  2011,   respectively)  from  lotteries  like  the  Bankgiroloterij,  Postcodeloterij  and  Lotto  (Prinsbernhard   Foundation  2012,  Stichting  DOEN  2012).  According  to  Dutch  law,  at  least  50%  of  the  income  of   lotteries  has  to  be  spent  in  the  public  interest  (Kansspelautoriteit,  2012).  The  VSB  foundation  and   SNSReaal  Foundation  both  originated  from  banking/insurance  companies  and  are  funded  from  the   interest  on  capital  these  companies  administer.  The  VandenEnde  Foundation  is  founded  and  directly   financed  by  media  tycoon  Joop  van  den  Ende  and  his  wife  Janine.    

(13)

 

3.3.2  Requirements  

The  foundations  also  have  different  requirements  and  guidelines  regarding  the  support  of  arts.   Practically  all  foundations  make  a  distinction  between  legal  persons  (a  group  of  people  or   organization  with  legal  rights  and  responsibilities)  and  natural  persons  (actual  persons).  The  VSB   Foundation,  SNSReaal  Foundation,  Ammodo  and  most  of  the  foundations  in  the  BIS  explicitly  state   that  only  legal  persons  are  eligible  for  their  subsidies.  Most  of  the  municipal  culture  foundations   don’t  make  this  distinction  and  the  same  is  true  for  the  Prins  Bernhard  Foundation,  the  Mondriaan   Foundation  and  the  VandenEnde  Foundation:  both  legal  and  natural  persons  can  apply.  

The  majority  of  the  foundations  exclusively  offer  project-­‐based  subsidies  and  will  not  support   individual  artists.  Only  the  Mondriaan  Foundation,  Prins  Bernhard  Foundation,  VandenEnde   Foundation  and  the  municipal  foundations  offer  a  limited  amount  of  stipends  and  scholarships  to   individuals.  

3.3.3  Mission  and  criteria  

There  are  a  number  of  similarities  and  differences  between  the  various  foundations  in  terms  of   selection  criteria  for  organizations  or  individuals  applying  for  subsidies.  Most  foundations  expect   applicants  to  actively  seek  an  audience  for  their  work.  A  central  question  in  most  applications  is  how   applicants  plan  to  reach  a  broad  as  possible  audience.  Another  common  prerequisite  is  that  artists   and  organizations  show  entrepreneurship  by  looking  for  alternative  ways  of  funding  and  by   marketing  their  work  or  project.  This  emphasizes  this  administration’s  general  cultural  policy  to   engage  more  people  in  the  arts  and  make  the  sector  less  dependent  of  government  funding  

(Ministerie  van  Onderwijs,  Cultuur  en  Wetenschap,  2013).  Another  prevalent  requirement  is  quality,   of  which  each  foundation  has  its  own  definition.  The  Mondriaan  Foundation  and  Prins  Bernhard   Foundation  both  explicitly  mention  quality  as  their  main  criteria.    

The  Mondriaan  Foundation  looks  at  the  relationship  between  the  artist’s  principles  and  the  way   these  are  being  reflected  in  his  or  her  work.  Quality  is  defined  as  the  way  the  artist’s  work  and   attitudes  relate  to  historic  and  modern  context  (Mondriaan  Foundation,  2012)  and  is  determined  by   a  special  committee  of  professionals  active  in  the  art  sector.  The  deeper  meaning  of  the  aesthetic   concept,  the  skillfulness  and  the  imagination  of  the  artist  are  also  given  special  consideration.     The  Prins  Bernhard  Foundation  states  its  mission  as  stimulating  culture  in  the  Netherlands  by   “describing,  reaching  and  preserving”  (Prins  Bernhard  Foundation,  2012).  It  strives  to  support   extraordinary  art  which  is  “of  real  artistic  quality”.  This  is  judged  by  the  craftsmanship  of  the  maker,   the  expressiveness  of  the  work  and  its  contribution  to  the  development  of  the  arts.  Individual   scholarships  are  reserved  for  applicants  with  “demonstrable  talent”,  which  is  defined  as  an  academic   degree  with  an  average  grade  of  8  or  higher.    

Most  private  foundations  have  their  own  particular  mission  and  assign  subsidies  accordingly.  For   instance,  the  VSB  Foundation  was  founded  by  a  group  of  not-­‐for-­‐profit  banking  companies  and  aims   to  enhance  the  quality  of  Dutch  society  by  supporting  artistic  projects  and  individuals  with  money,   knowledge  and  networks.  A  central  theme  within  the  foundation  is  the  enrichment  of  ‘inner  life’  in  

(14)

order  to  inspire  people  to  further  develop  themselves  and  contribute  to  society  (VSB  Foundation,   2013).  

The  SNSReaal  Foundation  also  views  arts  and  culture  as  a  way  to  enrich  life  but  focuses  mainly  on   young  artists  and  new  audiences.  A-­‐typical  and  innovative  projects  that  contribute  to  the  

development  of  the  art  sector  receive  special  attention.  The  same  is  true  for  projects  that  are  topical   and  urgent.  

Stichting  DOEN  aims  for  a  green,  social  and  creative  society.  Its  mission  is  to  strengthen  social   cohesion  in  the  Netherlands  by  supporting  projects  that  stimulate  interaction  between  groups  and   individuals  (Stichting  DOEN,  2013).  Applicants  need  to  describe  how  they  plan  to  meet  these  targets.    

Table  1.  Subsidy  applications  per  foundation  in  2012  

                                   Approved  applications                Total  applications       %     SNSReaal  Foundation          492       3291       15   Stichting  DOEN            125              774       16   Mondriaan  Foundation       1377       3810       36   VSB  Foundation         1437       3291       44   Prins  Bernhard  Foundation     3542       5538       64   Amsterdam  Fund  for  the  Arts        697       1039       67  

Source:    SNSReaal  Foundation  (2013),  Stichting  DOEN  (2013),  Mondriaan  Foundation  (2013),  VSB   Foundation  (2013),  Prins  Bernhard  Foundation  (2013),  Amsterdam  Fund  for  the  Arts  (2013)  

The  previous  overview  of  the  subsidy  structure  for  art  in  the  Netherlands  indicates  that  although   there  are  many  ways  for  artists  to  receive  subsidies,  there  are  always  more  requests  than  there  is   money.  In  some  cases  85%  of  the  applications  are  rejected  (SNSReaal,  2012).  Artists  often  have  to   compete  with  each  other  for  government  funding  (Rengers  and  Plug,  2001)  and  with  less  

scholarships  and  stipends  available  than  before  (Ministerie  van  Onderwijs,  Cultuur  en  Wetenschap   2012),  it  is  likely  that  this  competition  will  increase.  At  the  same  time,  because  art  subsidies  have   become  a  politically  charged  issue,  the  cultural  foundations  expenditures  are  under  increased   scrutiny  (ter  Braak,  2007).  As  a  result,  pressure  on  selection  committees  to  allocate  subsidies   responsibly  has  increased.    

4.  Methods  

In  order  to  test  the  hypotheses,  quantitative  and  qualitative  data  will  be  used.  This  is  because   quantitative  data  alone  could  give  an  over-­‐simplistic  image  of  the  researched  issue  while  a  mixed   method  can  contribute  to  a  more  expansive,  inclusive,  pluralistic  and  complementary  research   (Johnson  and  Onwuegbuzie,  2004).    

Part  one  consists  of  a  quantitative  study  that  uses  data  from  ex-­‐Rietveld  students  to  explore  the   relation  between  quality  signals  and  subsidies.  Part  two  consists  of  a  qualitative  study  that  uses   interviews  with  professionals  from  the  art  sector  to  add  context  to  the  data.  

(15)

4.1  Data  

For  this  part,  data  was  collected  from  artists  that  graduated  at  the  Gerrit  Rietveld  Academy  between   the  years  1990-­‐2010.  The  Gerrit  Rietveld  Academy  is  a  renowned  Dutch  academy  for  fine  arts  and   design,  located  in  Amsterdam.  It  offers  two  bachelors  programs  and  four  masters  programs  with   specializations  such  as  photography,  fashion  design  and  video.  The  data  used  in  this  study  comes   from  a  larger  database  created  to  track  the  career  advancements  of  Rietveld  alumni.  All  graduates   between  1990  and  2010  received  an  email  informing  them,  in  English  and  in  Dutch,  about  the   research  that  the  Rietveld  is  conducting  in  collaboration  with  the  University  of  Amsterdam.  It  stated   that  the  Rietveld  academy  is  aiming  to  learn  more  about  the  career  development  of  the  Rietveld   alumni  both  in  and  outside  of  the  art  and  design  world.  By  knowing  which  kind  of  careers  alumni   undertake  the  Rietveld  is  “able  to  keep  the  program  in  tune  with  the  ever  changing  artistic  climate,   which  in  light  of  the  current  debate  in  the  Netherlands  is  more  relevant  than  ever”  (Gerrit  Rietveld   Academy,  2011).  Included  in  the  email  was  a  link  to  a  QuestBack  Internet  questionnaire.  The  online   questionnaire  consists  of  closed  questions  about  basic  personal  information  (age,  date  and  place  of   birth)  as  well  as  details  about  the  respondent’s  career  (awards,  reviews,  exhibition  history).  Because   the  questions  are  dependent  on  previous  answers,  the  respondents  only  get  to  view  the  questions   relevant  to  his  or  her  situation.    

The  resulting  database  consists  of  the  career  information  of  640  Rietveld  alumni.  The  self-­‐reported   data  was  verified  and  complemented  by  information  found  on  the  internet.  In  most  cases,  a  CV   could  be  accessed  through  the  personal  website  of  the  artist  while  in  some  other  cases  data  

provided  on  social  media  profiles  such  as  LinkedIn  was  used.  Data  that  could  not  be  verified  was  not   used  in  this  analysis,  which  amounted  to  a  set  of  423  participants.    

4.1,1  Dependent  Variables  

Number  of  subsidies:  The  total  number  of  personal  subsidies  an  artist  has  received  (i.e.  

basisstipends,  startstipends,  scholarships,  grants,  residency  grants).     4.1.2  Independent  variables  

Number  of  exhibitions:  The  total  number  of  group  exhibitions,  solo  exhibitions  and  biennales  and  

artist  has  participated  in  according  to  his  or  her  CV.  

Number  of  awards:  The  total  number  of  awards  and  prizes  that  an  artist  has  won  or  was  nominated  

for,  according  to  his  or  her  CV.    

Number  of  reviews:  The  total  number  of  reviews  of  the  artist’s  work  according  to  his  or  her  CV.    

There  will  be  made  no  distinction  between  positive  or  negative  reviews  as  that  was  beyond  the   scope  of  this  paper.  It  is  assumed  however  that  the  majority  of  the  reviews  are  positive.  This  is   because  critics  can  gain  a  higher  level  of  legitimacy  by  spotting  new  talent  before  they  become   mainstream  (Debenedetti,  2006).  This  can  be  an  incentive  for  critics  to  review  “high-­‐quality”  art  as  it   could  potentially  increase  their  status.  But  according  to  Debenedett  (2006),  “even  a  negative  review   can  contribute  to  the  artistic  legitimization  of  a  work  by  deeming  it  a  valid  subject  for  discussion;  (...)   media  coverage  can  count  as  much  as  the  evaluation  itself”.  

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

Soos wat die geval is by die Afrikaanstalige diskoers, is daar ook heelwat Engelstalige studies 19 wat gefokus is op die manier waarop die opposisie van ’n (ideale)

In the case of type-I nonlinearity, the spectral line bifur- cates; the upper-frequency line corresponds to the dispersion of spin waves in the linear FM/SC bilayer while

Table 4.3 summarizes the total number of violations found in the advertising media*. Pictures of the violations are displayed in Addendum C. A total number of 30 violations

goal of this research question is to serve as the base to achieve solutions able to cope with different types of DDoS attacks.. To do so, we will use

The research questions addressed how attitudes toward Muslim immigrants are affected by news framing (RQ1), and questioned the moderating roles of political knowledge and

According to the Attitudes as Constraint Satisfaction (ACS) model by Monroe and Read (2008) greater knowledge of an attitude subject leads to self-generated attitude

Additionally, the flow through the inlet was measured during 13-hr cross-sectional measurements; boxcores were taken for benthos, sediment composition, and

He obtained a pre-medical degree from University College Utrecht after which he studied medical statistics for a year at the Radboud University in Nijmegen. He