• No results found

Through rose-colored glasses: On cyberutopianism and the digital platform economy

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Through rose-colored glasses: On cyberutopianism and the digital platform economy"

Copied!
55
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

The  tenacity  of    

cyberutopianism    

in  the    

digital  platform  economy

 

 

Through    

rose-­‐colored    

glasses    

 

The  tenacity  of    

cyberutopianism    

in  the    

digital  platform  economy  

 

On  

cyberutopianism    

and  the    

digital  platform  economy  

 

Master thesis MA New Media & Digital Culture Odiel van de Nobelen | 10003656

ovanden@gmail.com | 06 - 811 45 130

Supervisor: dr. Marc Tuters

Second reader: Amanda Wasielewski 23 August 2017

 

Master  thesis  MA  New  Media  &  Digital  Culture  

Odiel  van  de  Nobelen   |  10003656   Supervisor:  dr.  Marc  Tuters  

Second  reader:  dr.  Niels  van  Doorn   23  August  2017  

(2)

Abstract    

Companies  within  the  digital  platform  economy  such  as  Airbnb  and  Uber  are  transforming  the   ways  we  live,  work  and  generate  value.  There  are  various,  conflicting  observations  about  this   new  emergent  digital  economy.  On  the  one  hand  it  is  imagined  as  progress  and  liberating   empowerment  by  its  advocates.  While  on  the  other  hand  critics  raise  concerns  that  this  

(unregulated)  digital  economy  is  a  glide  path  to  work  precarity,  entrenches  existing  inequalities,   redistributes  risks  or,  simply  formulated:  operates  by  exploitative  mechanisms.  Despite  these   concerns  companies  within  the  digital  platform  economy  are  very  successful.  This  success  can   partly  be  explained  from  a  basic  economic  perspective  which  focuses  of  transaction  costs.   Besides  the  economic  argument  of  transaction  costs  this  thesis  will  mainly  focus  on  the  concept   of  cyberutopianism.  I  will  sketch  a  genealogy  of  cyberutopianism,  a  discursive  tradition  rooted   in  the  1960s  counterculture  that  emerged  during  the  early  days  of  the  Internet  in  the  1990s.  I   will  use  this  concept  to  examine  how  the  Internet  and  platform  economy  today  –  more  

specifically  Airbnb  ―  are  framed  in  utopian  terms  throughout  history.  Following  the,  on  the  first   sight,  strange  gap  between  the  exploitative,  “dystopian”  side  and  the  utopian,  appealing  side  of   the  digital  platform  economy  this  thesis  aims  to  answer  the  following  question:  what  makes  the   cyberutopian  discourse  celebrating  the  digital  platform  economy  sustainable  despite  the   exploitative  mechanisms  in  this  new  economy?  The  argument  of  this  thesis  is  unfolded  in  three   parts.  I  will  show  that  cyberutopianism  is  necessary  as  an  ideological  legitimization  of  the   darker,  exploitative  side  of  the  digital  platform  economy.  Furthermore,  it  remains  attractive   because  it  describes  an  utopian,  ameliorated  future  engineered  through  technology  (“making   the  world  a  better  place”),  while  at  the  same  time  it  epitomizes  the  desire  for  the  restoration  of   an  enchanted,  non-­‐alienated  condition  of  the  past.  

 

Keywords  

Cyberutopianism;  digital  platform  economy;  Airbnb;  exploitation;  ideology;  Silicon  Valley;  

(3)

Table  of  Contents  

 

Introduction  ...  4  

1.  Economics  101:  transaction  costs  ...  11  

2.  Cyberutopianism  ...  16  

1.1  The  1990s:  utopian  speculation  about  the  Internet  ...  16  

2.2  The  dot-­‐com  bubble  and  Web  2.0  ...  20  

2.3  The  digital  platform  economy:  rearticulated  cyberutopianism  ...  23  

2.4  Criticism  ...  27  

3.  The  digital  platform  economy:  a  critique  ...  29  

Commodification  ...  30  

Inequality:  privileging  few  ...  32  

Exploitation:  regulatory  gaps  ...  34  

Exploitation:  redistribution  of  risk  ...  35  

4.  Tenacity  of  cyberutopianism  ...  38  

4.1  Making  the  world  a  better  place:  solutionism  ...  39  

4.2  Imaginaries  ...  42   Conclusion  ...  46   References  ...  51              

(4)

Introduction  

In  one  of  the  latest  episodes  of  the  Dutch  satire  television  program  Zondag  met  Lubach  (VPRO),   host  Arjen  Lubach  presented  a  list  of  “nice  brands”  (“Lubachs  Leuke  Merken  Lijst”),  which   included  brands  such  as  Tony  Chocolonely  (100%  slave  free  chocolate)  and  Triodos  Bank   (sustainable  banking).  Lubach  ended  the  list  with  Airbnb,  which  he  considered  the  most  

“sympathetic”  company  of  all  because  it  is  part  of  the  so-­‐called  “sharing  economy”.  On  platforms   such  as  Airbnb  everyone  can  become  a  host  or  supplier  with  one  mouse  click  and  share  their   underutilized  human,  social,  and  real  capital  with  strangers.  Lubach  enthusiastically  concluded   that  this  is  the  biggest  advancement  of  the  sharing  economy.  However,  this  enthusiasm  in   reality  is  to  a  large  extent  not  really  justified.  Hence  the  abundance  of  concerns  and  critiques  on   the  exploitative  mechanisms  of  this  new  digital  economy.  This  thesis  questions  why  utopian   visions  on  the  new  digital  platform  economy  remain  appealing  and  endure  despite  a  less  rosy-­‐ colored  side  they  fail  to  account  for.  

The  home-­‐sharing  platform  Airbnb  is  at  the  forefront  of  the  buzz  around  the  new   emerging  digital  economy.  Airbnb  co-­‐founder  Joe  Gebbia  explained  in  a  2016  TED  Talk  why   home-­‐sharing  through  the  platform  is  so  great:  “we  just  [discovered]  it  was  possible  to  make   friends,  while  also  making  rent”  (03:47-­‐03:51).  There  is  a  belief  that  companies  within  this  new   digital  economy  form  a  viable  alternative  to  distant,  impersonal  and  centralized  corporations.   Furthermore,  proponents  suggest  that  the  companies  are  about  to  bring  a  new,  digitally   enabled,  people-­‐driven  economy:  an  economy  that  is  able  to  abolish  economic  injustice  by   facilitating  direct  interactions  between  individuals.  For  example,  this  vision  is  reflected  in   Airbnb’s  statement  when  they  speak  about  “communities  of  regular  people,  occasionally  sharing   the  homes  they  live  in  as  an  alternative  to  large,  corporate  hotel  chains”  (“Introducing  the   Airbnb  Economic”).    

Although  renting  out  (underutilized)  rooms  and  homes  is  hardly  something  new,  the   lowering  of  transaction  costs  by  the  platforms  −  the  costs  that  are  associated  with  market   exchange  −  make  it  easier  for  people  to  join  the  market  and  therefore  arguably  offer  flexibility  in   the  way  we  work  and  live.  According  to  Airbnb  the  additional  income  hosts  earn  through  the   platform  “helps  them  pay  their  bills,  start  new  businesses  and  pursue  new  projects”.  Tom  Slee,   author  of  the  book  What’s  Yours  Is  Mine:  Against  the  Sharing  Economy  (2015),  explains  this   advantage  of  the  lowering  of  transaction  costs  by  the  platform  as  follows:  “Each  exchange   [within  this  digital  economy]  helps  someone  make  a  little  money  and  helps  someone  save  a  little   time:  what’s  not  to  like?”  (1).    

In  its  own  rosy  narrative,  the  $31-­‐billion  start-­‐up  Airbnb  is  a  “financial  lifeline”  for   countless  families,  “helps  [people]  make  ends  meet”,  provides  a  financial  boost  to  communities  

(5)

and  small  businesses  and  benefits  social  and  environmental  impact  (“Unlocking  economic   opportunity”).  Airbnb  further  stresses  this  narrative  through  its  website  Airbnbcitizen.com  by   showing  the  steps  the  company  is  taking  to  “democratize  capitalism”  and  “create  economic   opportunities”,  using  technology  to  help  people  connect  and  empower  their  community.    

Thus,  both  from  an  ideological  perspective,  which  focuses  on  altering  the  face  of  

capitalism,  and  from  an  economic  perspective,  which  focuses  on  lowering  transaction  costs,  this   digital  economy  seems  to  be  successful  and  working  very  efficient.  This  thesis  will  make  the   claim  that  there  exists  a  utopian  discourse  about  this  new  emerging  digital  economy.  This   discourse  exists  of  promises,  for  example  that  the  digital  platform  economy  enhances  

communality,  creates  economic  opportunities  and  offers  flexibility  in  the  way  we  work  and  live.   There  is  the  enticing  image  that  we  are  to  be  liberated  from  the  constraints  of  a  permanent   career  and  given  new,  entrepreneurial  opportunities  (Srnicek  1).  Also,  in  this  discourse  the   digital  platform  economy  is  lauded  for  its  ability  to  usher  in  a  new  phase  of  capitalism  which  is   more  democratic,  participatory,  and  de-­‐alienating  for  individuals  (Fischer  229).    

This  thesis  will  examine  this  discourse  in  relation  to  Airbnb,  since  it  is  an  important   figurehead  of  this  emerging  digital  platform  economy.  It  will  do  so  through  the  lens  of  the   (cyber)utopian  visions  on  new  digital  technologies,  which  stem  from  the  1990s.  In  this  period   the  Internet  was  still  in  its  infancy  and  was  regarded  as  the  means  for  achieving  an  “ideal”   society.  For  example,  in  the  early  1990s  Nicholas  Negroponte,  founder  of  MIT  Media  lab,   declared  that  the  Internet  was  about  to  “flatten  organizations,  globalize  society,  decentralize   control,  and  help  harmonize  people”  (Negroponte  in  Turner,  From  Counterculture  1).  Media   scholar  Ethan  Zuckerman  argues  that  these  ideas  about  the  Internet,  which  place  it  at  the  center   of  visions  of  a  world  made  better  through  connection,  are  so  abundant  that  this  is  coined  the   neologism  “cyberutopianism”  (30).  In  cyberutopianism,  a  new  paradigm  shift  on  the  web  is  not   only  conceptualized  as  a  technological  innovation,  but  is  also  a  “rhetorical  move”  that  

consecrates  a  new  genre  of  technology  (Stevenson,  “The  cybercultural  moment”  1089).   According  to  Zuckerman,  this  cyberutopian  perspective  offers  us  the  reassurance  that   technological  innovations  are  both  essential  and  sufficient  to  ensure  the  public  good  (31).  

However,  despite  Arjen  Lubachs  enthusiasm  at  first,  when  looking  at  the  political  

economy  of  the  digital  platform  economy  it  appears  not  as  auspicious  as  it  is  often  presented  (of   course,  Lubachs  enthusiasm  turned  out  to  be  feigned).  Sharing  economy  critic  Sebastian  Olma   summarizes  the  exaggerated  buzz  around  emerging  digital  platform  economy:  “under  flashy   headlines  such  as  ‘sharing  is  the  new  owning’  it  is  heralded  as  the  solution  to  the  current   financial  crisis,  the  path  towards  a  more  sustainable  economy  or  even  the  harbinger  of  a  post-­‐ capitalist  society”  (“Never  mind  the”  n.pag.).  It  is  arguable  that  the  peer-­‐to-­‐peer  rentals   facilitated  by  Airbnb  help  people  earn  some  extra  money  and  therefore  create  economic  

(6)

opportunities  but  contrary  to  the  euphoric  thoughts  about  the  advent  of  the  digital  platform   economy,  there  is  controversy  arising  in  both  scholarly  research  and  media  outlets.    

Specifically  for  Airbnb  there  are  concerns  that  “home-­‐sharing”  causes  pressure  on  the   housing  market  and  creates  problems  related  to  the  liveability  of  popular  Airbnb  areas  in  a  city   (see  for  example  Benjamin  Walker’s  take  on  the  “Airbnb  Economy”).  Besides  these  criticisms,   there  is  a  countermovement  arguing  that  contrary  to  the  belief  in  entrepreneurial  opportunities   and  flexibility  brought  by  the  platform  companies,  these  so-­‐called  opportunities  in  reality  entail   a  new  precariousness  of  work.  Furthermore,  there  are  concerns  with  regards  to  redistribution   of  risk,  the  commodification  of  human  interaction  and  the  amplification  of  inequality.  In  other   words,  while  the  digital  platform  economy  increases  participation  through  lowering  

transactions  costs  and  seems  to  be  working  very  efficient  —  as  celebrated  by  many  scholars  —   looking  at  the  political  economy  of  this  digital  economy  it    cannot  be  denied  that  it  operates  by   exploitative  mechanisms.    

Despite  these  negative  aspects  of  digital  platforms,  the  platform  economy  does  not  show   signs  of  slowing  down.  Airbnb  has  grown  extremely  rapidly,  with  more  than  three  million   accommodation  listings  worldwide  and  150  million  users  and  a  total  valuation  of  $31  billion  the   company  is  one  of  the  biggest  successes  of  the  digital  platform  economy.  Arguably,  there  is  a   mismatch  between  cyberutopianism  and  a  reality,  which  seems  to  be  fairly  dismal.  How  can  this   be  explained?  This  is  the  question  that  functions  as  a  starting  point  for  my  investigation  of   cyberutopianism  in  this  thesis.  More  specifically,  my  research  question  is:  what  makes  the   cyberutopian  discourse  celebrating  the  digital  platform  economy  sustainable  despite  the   exploitative  mechanisms  in  this  new  economy?  

By  answering  this  question  I  will  contribute  to  the  new  media  field  by  using  a  history  of   cyberutopianism  to  reflect  on  and  critique  a  contemporary  phenomenon  –  the  digital  platform   economy.  So  far,  the  concept  of  cyberutopianism  has  primarily  been  used  in  relation  to  the  early   days  of  the  Internet  in  the  1990s  and  its  conceptualization  as  a  “cyberspace”  (e.g.,  Streeter,   2010;  Turner,  2006)  and  pronouncements  of  web  2.0  (e.g.,  Stevenson,  2016;  Dahlberg,  2011).   My  research  is  new  in  that  it  applies  the  concept  to  the  discussion  of  platform  economies.   Throughout  this  thesis  I  hope  to  provide  an  insight  in  or  bridge  the  (on  the  first  sight)  strange   gap  between  the  exploitative,  “dystopian”  side  on  the  one  hand  and  the  utopian,  attractive  side   of  the  digital  platform  economy  on  the  other  hand.  I  will  show  that  cyberutopianism  functions   as  a  legitimation  for  the  less  rosy-­‐colored  side  of  the  platform  economy.  Moreover,  this  thesis   illustrates  that  this  utopian  way  of  thinking  about  new  digital  technologies  is  regenerative,  as  I   will  show  the  utopian  discourse  of  the  platform  economy  is  nothing  new,  but  is  a  recurring   phenomenon.    

(7)

   

Methodology  &  justification  

Due  to  its  novelty  and  diversity  there  are  various,  ambiguous  observations  on  the  new  platform   economy  in  scholarly  research.  The  recent  paradigmatic  shift  on  the  web  has  been  dubbed  “the   sharing  economy”  (e.g.,  Lessig,  2008)  or  “collaborative  economy”  (Botsman  &  Rogers,  2010),   whereas  scholars  less  convinced  of  its  beneficence  have  named  it  “the  gig  economy”  (e.g.,  Smith,   2016;  Kessler,  2014;  Scholz  &  Schneider,  2016)  or    “platform  capitalism”  (e.g.,  Lobo,  2014;   Srnicek,  2016).  According  to  business  academic  Russell  Belk  there  are  two  commonalities  in  the   descriptions  of  the  new  digital  economy:  the  use  of  temporary  access,  non-­‐ownership  models  of   utilizing  consumer  goods  and  services  and  the  reliance  on  Web  2.0  technologies  to  enable  this   (“You  are  what  you  can  access”  1595).  Henceforth,  I  will  refer  to  this  new  emergent  economy  as   the  “digital  platform  economy”,  as  it  is  a  more  neutral  term  that  encompasses  the  diversity  of   the  (often)  unrelated  digital  phenomena  enabled  by  the  platforms  (Kenny  and  Zysman,  “The  rise   of”  61-­‐69).  More  importantly,  I  will  concentrate  on  for-­‐profit  platforms,  which  function  as  online   intermediaries  between  transactions  mediated  by  money,  rather  than  non-­‐profit  organizations   facilitating  more  genuine  sharing  practices  such  as  foodswapping  (Thuisafgehaald)  or  

ridesharing  (Toogethr).  

  In  order  to  unravel  the  tenacity  of  cyberutopianism  in  relation  to  the  digital  platform   economy  and  its  cultural  underpinnings,  I  will  provide  a  theoretical  analysis  throughout  this   whole  thesis,  which  is  situated  in  the  field  of  critical  media  studies.  This  thesis  is  build  up  in  four   main  chapters,  aiming  to  form  a  dialectical  structure.  As  a  starting  point  for  this  thesis,  I  will   attempt  to  bring  some  clarity  to  the  success  of  the  digital  platform  economy  from  an  economic   perspective.  Here  I  will  use  Ronald  Coase’s  (1907)  early  notion  of  transaction  costs,  as  this  is  a   central  concept  to  the  understanding  of  the  success  of  the  digital  platform  economy.  

Furthermore,  I  will  shortly  address  the  idea  of  the  network  effect  in  relation  to  the  success  of   the  digital  platform  economy.  Although  this  thesis  will  primarily  focus  on  the  cultural  

underpinnings  of  the  digital  platform  economy,  I  will  not  ignore  the  economic  dimension  since  it   is  useful  for  both  reflecting  on  the  success  and  the  darker  side  of  the  digital  platform  economy.    

In  the  second  part  of  this  thesis  I  will  discuss  the  ideological  component  that  is  at  play   relation  to  the  success  of  the  digital  platform  economy.  Here,  I  will  examine  the  concept  of   cyberutopianism  throughout  its  more  than  two  centuries  spanning  history  and  its  

countercultural  roots.  I  will  approach  the  concept  genealogically,  taking  into  account  that  the   story  I  am  delineating  in  this  thesis  is  just  one  narrative  in  a  bigger  network,  without  a  very   clear-­‐cut  origin  or  endpoint.  As  for  Foucault,  genealogy  is  the  alternative  to  the  linear  

development  of  history  so  conceived  and  “opposes  itself  to  the  search  for  origins”  (qtd.  in  Prado   33).    

(8)

The  analysis  of  cyberutopianism  forms  the  basis  for  answering  my  research  question  on   why  this  discursive  tradition  remains  appealing  while  it  has  disappointed  us  in  the  past  .  In  this   chapter  I  hope  to  clarify  that  cyberutopian  thinking  is  a  recurring  phenomenon  and  still  very   present  in  the  digital  platform  economy.  I  will  develop  my  argument  in  three  steps.  The   contemporary  cyberutopian  discourse  is  difficult  to  analyze  without  going  back  to  some  of  the   cultural  history  of  the  technology  and  innovation  hub  Silicon  Valley. The  San  Fransisco  Bay  Area   is  widely  regarded  as  one  of  the  most  significant  geographical  and  intellectual  homes  of  the   information  technologies  (Zandbergen  32).  So  first,  I  will  address  cyberutopianism  during  the   1990s  and  its  ideological  touchstone,  the  1960s  counterculture  in  the  San  Fransisco  Bay  Area.   Then,  I  will  discuss  the  dot-­‐com  collapse  at  the  end  of  the  1990s  and  the  resurfacing  of  

cyberutopianism  with  the  emergence  of  web  2.0.  Finally,  I  will  provide  a  discussion  of  the   rearticulated  cyberutopianism  within  the  digital  platform  economy.  Here  I  will  show  that  it  is   noticeable  that  there  was  not  only  utopian  thinking  about  new  digital  technologies  and  the   Internet  when  it  was  still  a  novelty  in  the  1990s,  but  that  there  is  a  regenerative  belief  in  digital   technology  as  a  transformative  force  throughout  recent  history.    

In  order  to  do  so,  I  will  build  on  the  work  of  various  scholars,  mainly  using  Fred  Turners   (2006)  and  Thomas  Streeters  (2011)  historical  critiques  of  the  Silicon  Valley  (US)  culture  and   ideology.  Silicon  Valley  functions  as  a  geographical  metaphor,  which  marks  a  global,  digital   industry  with  its  own  practices  and  ideology  (Turner,  From  Counterculture  149-­‐151)  and   therefore  is  an  important  key  in  the  understanding  of  cyberutopian  thinking.  Additionally,   Turners  work  illustrates  how  this  utopian  thinking  stems  from  the  1960s  counterculture  and   how  these  (countercultural)  ideals  are  still  existent  today.  The  first  part  of  the  second  chapter   will  discuss  this  argument,  which  is  reaffirmed  by  Richard  Barbrook  and  Andy  Cameron’s  notion   of  the  “Californian  Ideology”.  Using  this  term  Barbrook  and  Cameron  describe  the  amalgamation   between  post-­‐hippy  counterculturalism  and  neoliberal  determinism.  In  order  to  illustrate  the   echoing  of  earlier  promises  of  the  web  during  the  mid-­‐2000s,  after  the  dot-­‐com  collapse,  I  will   focus  on  Tim  O’Reilly’s  understanding  of  Web  2.0.  Here,  I  aim  to  show  that  the  promises  of  the   early  Internet  and  web  2.0  again  very  much  echo  in  the  descriptions  of  the  digital  platform   economy.  

  The  historical  outline  of  cyberutopianism  forms  the  basis  for  the  final  part  of  the  second   chapter,  in  which  I  jump  to  the  present  in  order  to  discuss  the  digital  platform  economy  and  the   belief  in  its  transformative  potential.  I  will  argue  that  a  (rearticulated)  cyberutopian  rhetoric   can  be  detected  in  the  descriptions  celebrating  the  revolutionary  potential  of  the  digital   platform  economy.  The  digital  platform  economy  in  this  cyberutopian  discourse  is  heralded  as   the  “anti-­‐corporate,  utopian  answer  to  twentieth-­‐century  discontentment”,  potentially  

(9)

and  economic  impact  of  new  Internet  technologies  resonates  in  the  descriptions  of  the  digital   platform  economy.  I  will  examine  the  revival  of  this  new,  somewhat  toned  down,  

cyberutiopianism  using  Michael  Stevensons  notion  of  “web  exceptionalism”  (a  term  explaining   how  a  the  web  is  conceived  as  a  source  of  change)  (“The  web  as  an  exception”  3-­‐26).    

To  underpin  my  argument,  I  will  use  both  advocates  of  this  emerging  economy  such  as   Arun  Sundarajan,  Rachel  Botsman  and  Roo  Rogers  as  well  as  statements  by  digital  platform   Airbnb.  I  will  do  so  in  order  to  point  out  the  limitations  of  the  cyberutopian  discourse  and  in   order  to  problematize  this  thinking.  The  work  of  Evgeny  Morozov  (2011)  and  Ethan  Zuckerman   (2013),  both  critical  of  the  cyberutopian  strain  of  thought,  is  useful  here.  Although  Ethan  

Zuckerman  points  out  that  the  term  cyberutopianism  tends  to  be  used  in  the  context  of  critique,   mostly  because  of  its  alleged  naivety,  he  also  asserts  that  is  useful  to  consider  its  appeal.  This   thesis  is  set  out  to  do  so.  Subsequently,  this  thesis  will  bring  together  both  aspects  of  

cyberutopianism:  what  it  overlooks  (the  “naïve”  side)  and  its  appeal.    

The  third  chapter  of  this  thesis  deals  with  cyberutopianism  and  its  claims  about   democratization,  entrepreneurial  opportunities,  empowerment  and  flexibility  in  the  digital   platform  economy.  As  mentioned  before,  from  a  political  economy  perspective  it  can  be  argued   that  the  digital  platform  economy  operates  by  exploitative  mechanisms.  In  terms  of  

methodology  this  chapter  will  determine  that  the  digital  platform  economy  has  a  darker  side.  In   this  chapter  I  will  argue  that  a  critical  perspective  on  the  digital  platform  economy  is  important,   because  the  cyberutopian  discourse  is  used  by  platforms  such  as  Airbnb  as  a  way  to  legitimatize   the  evasion  of  existing  regulations  and  protections  –  creating  an  exploitative  mechanism.  Or,  to   put  it  differently,  I  will  first  address  cyberutopianism,  to  then  show  how  this  (ideological)   discourse  is  used  as  a  legitimation  of  more  problematic  aspects.  This  critical  approach  to  the   digital  platform  economy  will  consider  aspects,  which  are  mainly  situated  within  a  Marxist   critique  of  contemporary  capitalism  (commodification,  exploitation,  inequality)  (Fuchs,  Marx  in   the  age  399-­‐400)  without  sticking  to  one  specific  theory.  This  third  chapter  is  divided  into  four   subparagraphs,  which  will  address  four  critiques  of  the  digital  platform  economy:  it  disrupts   through  evading  regulation,  it  redistributes  risk,  draws  on  commodifying  daily  life  and   privileges  few.  These  claims  are  predominantly  underpinned  by  scholarly  work  situated  in  a   Marxian  tradition,  including  Paul  Mason,  Maurizio  Lazaratto,  Martin  Kenny  and  John  Zysman,   Nick  Srnicek  and  Douglas  Rushkoff.  

Following  the  first  three  chapters,  this  leads  up  to  a  discussion  on  why  we  sustain   committed  to  the  exploitative  modes  of  the  digital  platform  economy.  In  the  fourth  chapter  of   this  thesis  I  will  consider  the  attractiveness  and  tenacity  of  cyberutopianism  in  a  deeper  sense.   Here,  I  want  to  go  further  than  just  arguing  that  this  utopian  rhetoric  is  produced  and  sustained   solely  as  a  marketing  technique  in  order  to  attract  attention  from  venture  capitalists  and  users  

(10)

and  legitimize  the  exploitative  mechanism  I  discussed  in  the  third  chapter.  I  would  like  to  argue   that  the  appeal  of  cyberutopian  discourse  employed  by  the  digital  platform  economy  is  

threefold.    

First,  cyberutopianism  partially  describes  a  utopian,  ameliorated  future  engineered   through  technology,  rendering  cyberutopianism  attractive.  New  technologies,  digital  platforms   more  specifically,  are  imbued  with  these  promises  of  “creating  a  better  world”.  This  belief   suggests  that  any  social  problem  can  be  subject  to  a  “technological  fix”  (Weinberg  41-­‐48).  In   what  follows  I  will  elucidate  this  technological  determinism  using  a  framework  consisting  of   Alvin  Weinberg’s  notion  of  the  technological  fix,  Evgeny  Morozov’s  critique  on  these  quick   technological  fixes  to  social  problems  using  the  term  “solutionism”  (2013)  and  Fred  Turners   notion  of  Silicon  Valley’s  prototyping  culture.    

Second,  I  will  argue  that  cyberutopianism  epitomizes  the  desire  for  the  reversion  of  an   enchanted,  non-­‐alienated  condition  that  makes  us  committed  to  this  cyberutopian  belief,  here  I   will  mostly  draw  on  Thomas  Streeter’s  work  The  Net  Effect:  Romanticism,  Capitalism,  and  the  

Internet.  Within  this  context,  the  Internet  becomes  a  “myth”  (Mosco,  2004),  or  a  “social  

construction”  (Streeter,  2011).  Sociologist  Vincent  Mosco  argues  that  myths  about  the  Internet   are  more  than  simply  lies  that  exploit  people,  he  argues  that  this  myth-­‐making  matters  greatly   (3).    

Concluding,  I  will  argue  that  these  cultural  processes  of  romanticization  and  

mythmaking  underlying  cyberutopianism  help  it  to  sustain  despite  the  exploitative  dynamics  of   the  digital  platform  economy.  These  deeper  understandings  of  cyberutopianism  will  show  that   cyberutopianism  is  more  than  solely  pro-­‐business  talk  and  is  needed  as  a  legitimation  for  the   exploitative  side  of  the  digital  platform  economy,  which  I  addressed  in  the  third  chapter.  

(11)

1.  Economics  101:  transaction  costs    

Before  I  move  to  a  discussion  of  the  ideological  component  that  is  at  play  in  the  cyberutopian   configurations  of  the  digital  platform  economy,  I  would  like  to  consider  another  way  of  looking   at  the  success  of  the  digital  platform  economy:  from  a  basic  economic  perspective.  In  this  part  of   the  thesis  I  will  address  these  basic  economics  of  the  digital  platform  economy  from  a  

transaction  cost  perspective,  as  this  is  a  crucial  aspect  for  the  understanding  of  its  success.   Airbnb,  as  the  platform  that  exemplifies  the  digital  platform  economy,  will  be  used  as  an   illustrative  example.    

The  Airbnb  platform  portrays  itself  on  the  website  Airbnbcitizen.com  as  an  alternative  to   large,  corporate  hotel  chains  but  remarkably,  the  platform  today  is  so  successful  it  has  more   listings  than  the  top  three  hotel  chains  combined    and  is  still  growing  (“Airbnb  2016  

highlights”).  The  question  is:  how  can  the  success  of  Airbnb,  since  the  platform  was  founded  in   2008,  be  explained  while  renting  out  (underutilized)  rooms  and  homes  is  hardly  something   new?  To  start  with,  it  has  been  noted  that  the  financial  crisis  in  2008  marked  the  advent  of  the   digital  platform  economy.  In  his  book  Platform  Capitalism  (2016)  Nick  Srnicek  examines  the   rapid  growth  of  platform  based  businesses.  He  explains  the  trends  that  allowed  the  digital   platform  economy  to  emerge:    

Plagued  by  global  concerns  over  public  debt,  governments  have  turned  to  monetary  policy  in   order  to  ease  economic  conditions.  This,  combined  with  increases  in  corporate  savings  and   with  the  expansion  of  tax  havens,  has  let  loose  a  vast  glut  of  cash,  which  has  been  seeking  out   decent  rates  of  investment  in  a  low-­‐interest  rate  world.  Finally,  workers  have  suffered   immensely  in  the  wake  of  the  crisis  and  have  been  highly  vulnerable  to  exploitative  working   conditions  as  a  result  of  their  need  to  earn  an  income.  All  this  sets  the  scene  for  today’s   economy  (35).  

 

However,  this  crisis  and  the  advent  of  technological  advances,  such  as  cloud  computing,  

algorithmic  techniques,  wireless  Internet  access,  the  rising  capabilities  of  the  Internet  and  social   networking  just  partly  explain  why  the  digital  platform  economy  (just  recently)  came  to  rise   (Horton  and  Zeckhauser  2).  

To  cover  the  whole  success  story  we  have  to  go  back  to  the  concept  of  transaction  costs,   first  introduced  by  Ronald  Coase  in  his  article  “The  Nature  of  the  Firm”  (1937).  Not  specifically   naming  transaction  costs  as  such,  Coase  discussed  the  “costs  to  using  the  price  mechanism”  for   coordinating  economic  activity  (390).  With  this  understanding  the  idea  of  transaction  costs  was   born:  “costs  that  stand  separate  from  and  in  addition  to  ordinary  production  costs”  (Langlois  6).   Thus,  those  are  the  costs  that  are  associated  with  market  exchanges.  Decades  later,  Coase’s   transaction  cost  theory  can  be  used  as  a  way  to  shine  a  light  on  the  fast  growth  of  the  digital   platform  economy  from  an  economic  perspective.  In  his  article  Coase  explains  the  importance  of   transaction  costs:  “In  order  to  carry  out  a  market  transaction  it  is  necessary  to  discover  who  it  is  

(12)

that  one  wishes  to  deal  with,  to  inform  people  that  one  wishes  to  deal  with  and  on  what  terms,   to  conduct  negotiations  leading  up  to  a  bargain,  to  draw  up  a  contract,  to  undertake  the   inspection  needed  to  make  sure  that  the  terms  of  the  contract  are  being  observed,  and  so  on”   (15).  Coase  used  the  concept  of  transaction  costs  to  explain  the  existence  of  firms:  if  many   people  cooperate  they  can  capture  efficiencies  individuals  cannot  by  lowering  transactions  costs   which  occur  in  a  transaction  between  the  agents  in  the  market  (Henten  and  Wildekinde  2).    

Anders  Henten  and  Iwona  Wildekinde  use  this  transaction  cost  theory  as  a  basic   framework  to  explain  the  development  of  the  digital  platform  economy.  They  explain:  “The   lowering  of  transaction  costs  facilitated  by  Internet-­‐based  platforms  allows  for  the  exchange  of   goods  and  services  between  people  that  would  not  otherwise  have  been  possible  –  simply   because  of  the  very  high  costs  of  searching,  contacting  and  contracting  that  this  would  require”   (12).  As  the  connecting  power  of  the  Internet  allows  for  considerable  decreases  of  transaction   costs,  the  Internet  provides  a  foundation  for  new  businesses,  such  as  Airbnb,  to  emerge.  Carl   Dahlman  crystallizes  these  costs  by  describing  them  as  search  and  information  costs,  bargaining   and  decision  costs,  and  policing  and  marketing  costs  (148).  These  businesses  provide  services   which  overcome  transaction  cost  barriers.  Sebastian  Olma  adds  to  this:  “What  companies   like  Uber,  AirBnB,  TaskRabbit  or  Postmates  have  in  common  is  that  they  are  platforms   coordinating  supply  and  demand  of  products  and  services  that  in  their  present  form  were   previously  unavailable  on  the  market”  (In  defence  of  167).  

The  importance  of  transaction  costs  in  understanding  the  success  the  digital  platform   economy  is  best  illustrated  in  an  example.  Imagine  a  situation  where  you  are  willing  to  pay   someone  150  euro’s  for  a  one  night  stay  in  their  studio  in  Amsterdam.  However,  there  may  also   be  someone  who  is  willing  to  rent  his  or  her  studio  for  less  money.  In  this  lies  a  potential  for  a   more  beneficial  trade.  Before  platform  companies  such  as  Airbnb  emerged,  finding  that  one   person  willing  to  rent  their  studio  for  less  than  150  euro’s,  making  up  an  agreement  and   bargaining  the  price  would  take  time  and  would  potentially  cost  money.  Transaction  cost   barriers  are  thus  preventing  this  more  beneficial  trade  from  taking  place.  Noticeably,  this  is   where  Airbnb  jumps  in:  it  makes  it  easier  for  users  of  the  platform  to  find  potential  guests  for   their  Airbnb  listing,  it  draws  up  a  contract  and  terms  and  conditions  for  the  exchange  and   therefore  prevents  from  high  transaction  costs  to  occur  (Horton  &  Zeckhauer  8).    

In  addition,  Airbnb,  and  other  platforms  alike,  has  made  it  possible  to  provide  

individuals  tools,  which  were  previously  only  available  to  firms  such  as  reputation  systems.  For   example,  the  Airbnb  reputation  system,  which  allows  guests  and  hosts  to  voluntarily  review  and   validate  members  of  the  Airbnb  community,  is  an  aspect  of  the  market  that  individual  hosts   would  find  too  costly  (or  even  impossible)  to  build  and  maintain.  Also,  Airbnb  offers  “host   protection  insurance”,  which  provides  coverage  for  Airbnb  hosts  and  landlords  during  the  stay  

(13)

of  their  guests.  It  would  be  more  costly  if  an  individual  would  get  such  insurance.  According  to   Coase,  the  decrease  of  transaction  costs  by  joining  up  in  larger  economic  entities  (firms)  instead   of  functioning  as  an  individual  economic  agent  is  a  crucial  approach  for  the  explanation  of   industrial  structures;  it  is  the  most  efficient  way  of  organizing  things.  Ultimately,  in  line  with   Coase’s  argument,  platforms  within  this  new  digital  economy  are  the  new  kind  of  firms.      

Besides  this  notion  of  transaction  costs,  understanding  the  basic  functioning  of   platforms  is  helpful  for  explaining  the  success  of  the  digital  platform.  Platforms  are  often   described  as  intermediaries,  connecting  different  actors  (Gillespie  353)  and  making  it  easier  for   people  to  connect.  Economists  Jean-­‐Charles  Rochet  and  Jean  Tirole  describe  platforms  as  “multi-­‐ sided  markets”:  these  markets  consist  of  (more  than)  two  different  kinds  of  users  (providers,   users,  advertisers)  who  are  served  by  the  same  platform  (990).  Nick  Srnicek  explains  the  basic   functioning  of  platforms:    

At  the  most  general  level,  platforms  are  digital  infrastructures  that  enable  two  or  more   groups  to  interact.    They  therefore  position  themselves  as  intermediaries  that  bring   together  different  users:  customers,  advertisers,  service  providers,  producers,  suppliers,   and  even  physical  objects.  More  often  than  not,  these  platforms  also  come  with  a  series  of   tools  that  enable  their  users  to  build  their  own  products,  services,  and  marketplaces  (43).   The  affordances  of  digital  technologies,  which  make  it  possible  to  lower  transaction  costs,  create   new  opportunities  for  providers  of  services,  such  as  Airbnb  hosts,  to  enter  the  market.  Airbnb   speaks  of  this  in  terms  of  “entrepreneurial  opportunities”.  This  allows  people  to  earn  some  extra   money  and  arguably  offers  flexibility  in  live  and  work.  As  a  platform,  Airbnb  is  able  to  facilitate   the  connection  between  accommodation  providers  and  users  of  the  platform,  eliminating  the  so-­‐ called  “middleman”  and  reducing  the  trust  and  reputational  barriers  for  providers  to  enter  the   digital  platform  economy.  The  elimination  of  this  middleman  is  one  of  the  reasons  why  Airbnb  is   lauded  as  an  alternative  to  distant,  large  hotel  chains:  it  enables  the  direct  interaction  between   peers.  Digital  platform  economy  proponent  Arun  Sundararajan  argues  in  his  book  The  Sharing   Economy:  The  End  of  Employment  and  the  Rise  of  Crowd-­‐Based  Capitalism  (2016)  that  the  

“crowd”  within  the  digital  platform  economy  replaces  the  corporation  at  the  center  of  capitalism   and  is  therefore  often  envisioned  as  a  return  to  older  days  free  from  corporate  dominance  (2).   To  follow  Sundararajan,  Airbnb  is  thus  about  more  than  money  exchange.  Because  of  this  direct   exchange  between  peers  there  is  also  intimacy  associated  with  renting  accommodation  through   Airbnb.  Sundararajan  explains  this  intimacy  as  an  important  factor  in  the  success  of  the  digital   platform  economy.  He  notes  that  whilst  staying  in  a  house  through  Airbnb  “One  sees  family   pictures,  trinkets  from  travel  to  other  countries,  the  choices  made  of  linens  and  towels,  spices  in   the  kitchen”  (40).  

Another  aspect  of  the  success  of  the  digital  platform  economy  is  that  the  software  of  the   platforms  creates  the  ability  to  coordinate  economic  exchanges  on  a  large  scale.  Since  Airbnb  

(14)

does  not  own  any  property  itself,  the  success  of  Airbnb  thus  lies  in  that  they  are  facilitating   connection  and  coordination  of  exchanges  between  large  numbers  of  users  and  providers   (recent  statistics  shows  that  there  is  an  average  of  500.000  nightly  Airbnb  stays)  (“Inside   Airbnb”).  Airbnb  then  takes  a  percentage  of  each  exchange  through  the  platform  in  order  to   make  profit.  Airbnb  explains  this  exchange  on  a  large  scale  as  follows:  “Hosting  itself  is  centuries   old,  but  hosting  through  a  digital  platform  at  a  volume  of  1  million  guest  arrivals  per  night  is   new”  (“Policy  Toolchest  2.0").    

Although  enabling  hosting  on  such  a  large  scale  is  key  to  the  success  of  Airbnb,  I  will   shortly  digress  from  my  main  argument  to  address  that  this  is  also  central  to  concerns  related  to   the  livability  of  popular  Airbnb  areas  (due  to  nuisance  and  the  consequences  of  real  estate   speculators  in  residential  areas  of  popular  Airbnb  cities).  Also,  these  concerns  conflict  with   Sundararajan’s  notion  of  intimacy.  The  open-­‐source  data  tool  “Inside  Airbnb”  shows  that  many   Airbnb  hosts  are  renting  out  residential  properties  permanently  as  “hotels”,  as  opposed  to   "occasionally"  sharing  the  residence  in  which  they  live.  This  is  clearly  not  a  case  of  “ordinary”   people  making  some  money  through  the  platform,  as  Airbnb  and  its  advocates  suggest.    

 Along  with  the  lowering  of  transaction  costs  and  technological  affordances,  a  network   effect  reinforces  the  strong  position  of  platforms  such  as  Airbnb  and  influences  the  constant   growth  of  users  (Mason  25).  This  network  effect  works  as  follows:  every  time  a  new  

accommodation  provider  joins  the  Airbnb  platform,  the  value  of  the  network  increases  because   there  is  more  for  the  Airbnb  user  to  choose  from.  Therefore  it  will  be  more  like  that  other  users   join  the  Airbnb  platform.  Of  course,  it  works  the  other  way  around  as  well:  every  time  a  user   joins  the  platform  it  makes  it  more  attractive  for  an  accommodation  provider  to  join  Airbnb.  In   conclusion:  the  network  effect  explains  that  the  more  people  join  Airbnb,  the  more  valuable  and   profitable  the  platform  becomes.  According  to  Srnicek  this  leads  to  platforms  having  a  natural   tendency  towards  monopolistic  dominance  (Srnicek  45)  

In  this  chapter  I  considered  the  (basic)  economic  reasons  for  the  success  of  Airbnb.  Seen   in  terms  of  these  economics  101,  Coase’s  notion  of  transaction  costs  is  still  very  relevant  today   for  the  understanding  of  the  success  of  platform  companies  within  the  digital  platform  economy.   Essentially,  platforms  are  the  new  firms  and  are  the  most  efficient  way  of  organizing  things.  Due   to  the  lowering  of  transaction  costs,  platforms  lower  the  barriers  for  people  to  join  the  market   and  offer  tools,  which  would  be  inefficient  and  too  costly  for  individuals  to  maintain.    

On  top  of  that,  the  success  of  digital  platforms  is  reinforced  by  a  network  effect.  This   term  explains  that  services  such  as  Airbnb  become  more  valuable  when  more  people  use  it.   Also,  this  creates  a  strong  monopoly  position  for  the  platforms.  I  consider  this  basic  notion  of   transaction  costs  crucial  for  the  understanding  of  the  success  of  the  digital  platform  economy,   but  of  course  there  is  more  to  it.  In  the  next  chapter  I  will  discuss  the  success  of  the  digital  

(15)

platform  economy  in  terms  of  ideology.  In  order  to  do  so,  I  will  first  draw  a  historical  outline  of   ideas  that  show  how  the  web  was  framed  in  cyberutopian  terms,  to  then  jump  to  the  present   phenomenon  of  the  digital  platform  economy.  

(16)

2.  Cyberutopianism  

A  cyberutopian  discourse  about  the  Internet’s  transformative  potential  has  been  around  since   its  heydays  in  the  mid-­‐1990s.  During  these  years,  the  utopian  speculations  about  the  Internet’s   economic,  political  and  social  impact  were  at  its  strongest.  This  belief  in  the  transformative   potential  of  Internet  technology  stems  from  the  early  1990s  when  creatives,  designers,  hackers   and  hippies  in  Silicon  Valley  built  their  cyberutopian  vision  of  reality  (Olma  “Never  mind  the”).     For  example  in  Wired’s  March  1993  very  first  issue,  founder  Louis  Rossetto  declared   that  “the  Digital  Revolution  is  whipping  through  our  lives  like  a  Bengali  typhoon,”  bringing  with   it  “social  changes  so  profound  their  only  parallel  is  probably  the  discovery  of  fire”  (qtd.  in   Turner,  From  counterculture  207).  In  this  period  Internet  was  presented  as  a  non-­‐hierarchical   network  free  from  exploitation,  which  would  empower  citizens,  stimulate  economy  and   enhance  democracy.  This  chapter  will  explain  the  emergence  of  cyberutopianism  during  the   1990s  and  how  this  discourse  about  technology  is  rooted  in  the  counterculture  of  the  1960s.  It   will  show  how  this  discourse  resonates  in  the  contemporary  discourse  about  new  digital   technologies.  Even  after  the  burst  of  the  dot-­‐com  bubble  in  2001,  which  shattered  the  hopes   about  the  Internet  of  the  1990s,  cyberutopianism  resurfaces  within  the  rise  of  web  2.0  in  the   mid-­‐2000s  and  the  digital  platform  economy  more  recently.    

Whereas  the  previous  chapter  discussed  the  success  of  the  digital  platform  economy  in   economic  terms,  this  chapter  will  address  its  success  in  terms  of  ideology.  The  first  two  

subparagraphs  of  this  chapter  will  have  a  historical  approach.  Here  I  will  illustrate  how  the  web   was  framed  in  utopian  terms  since  its  emergence  in  the  1990s.  Following  this  history  of  

cyberutopian  ideas,  the  concluding  paragraph  will  jump  to  the  present  in  order  to  examine  how   the  digital  platform  economy-­‐related  euphoria  very  much  echoes  preceding  cyberutopianism.   As  such,  I  would  like  to  approach  the  euphoria  about  the  digital  platform  economy  today  as  a   continuation  of  the  discursive  tradition  of  cyberutopianism.  Finally,  in  the  last  paragraph  I  will   explain  how  cyberutopianism  is  at  the  centre  of  criticism  due  to  its  alleged  naivety.  In  more   general  terms,  this  overview  of  cyberutopianism  over  its  more  than  two  decades  spanning   history,  functions  as  a  first  step  in  examining  its  deeper  underlying  themes.        

1.1 The  1990s:  utopian  speculation  about  the  Internet  

On  December  1st  2015,  Facebook  CEO  Mark  Zuckerberg  and  his  wife  Priscilla  Chan  welcomed   their  first  child  into  the  world  by  announcing  the  philanthropy  organization  “Chan  Zuckerberg   Initiative”  in  an  open  letter  on  Facebook.  In  their  letter,  titled  “A  letter  to  our  daughter”,  the   couple  describes  the  current  problems  facing  the  world  and  how  their  foundation  will  address   “advancing  human  potential  and  promoting  equality  ”  by  focusing  on  “personalized  learning,   curing  disease,  connecting  people  and  building  strong  communities”.  In  the  lengthy  letter,  

(17)

pledging  to  make  the  world  a  better  place  for  their  daughter  Max  to  live  in,  Zuckerberg  and  Chan   express  their  belief  that  “we  must  build  technology  to  make  change”.    Further  on  in  the  letter   they  state:  “many  of  the  greatest  opportunities  for  your  generation  will  come  from  giving   everyone  access  to  the  internet”.      

This  cyberutopian  thinking  and  speculating  about  the  transformative  potential  and   cultural,  economic  and  political  impact  of  new  digital  technologies,  which  is  central  in  

Zuckerberg’s  and  Chan’s  letter,  has  been  around  since  the  early  1990s.  In  this  period  the  Web  –   created  by  computer  scientist  Tim  Berners-­‐Lee  in  1990  (Turner  From  counterculture  213)  –  was   still  in  its  infancy.  It  started  off  with  only  a  few  Internet  pages,  which  were  tended  by  

enthusiasts.  Those  adhering  the  Internet  in  its  early  years  as  a  space  for  democratic  culture  with   unlimited  possibilities  and  freedom  from  state  and  other  authoritarian  forms  of  control  cheered   the  coming  of  a  “cyberutopia”(e.g.,  Dyson  et  al.  1994;  Grossman  1995;  Barlow  1996).  In  the   early  1990s,  scholars  and  investors  had  the  vision  of  a  decentralized,  harmonious,  free  and   egalitarian  society  all  induced  by  the  power  of  the  Internet  (Turner,  From  counterculture  1).  The   argument  being  that  information  technologies  would  have  cultural,  economic  and  political   impact  that  would  “empower  the  individual,  enhance  personal  freedom,  promote  democracy   and  radically  reduce  the  power  of  the  nation-­‐state”  (Barbrook  &  Cameron  46).    

During  this  period  the  air  was  filled  with  talks  of  revolution  telling  that  a  digital,  self-­‐ sufficient  generation  would  appear,  gathering  into  collaborative  networks  of  independent  peers   (Turner,  From  counterculture  4).  This  idea  is  rooted  in  the  conceptualization  of  the  web  as  a   “cyberspace”.  Cyberspace  was  envisioned  as  a  disembodied  world,  a  space  symbolizing  a   radically  different  future  that  would  free  individuals  from  “real-­‐world”  physical,  social,  cultural   and  economic  constraints  on  identity,  gender,  geography  and  race  (Stevenson,  “The  web  as   exception”  3).  In  the  combination  between  the  words  cyberspace  and  utopia,  a  term  first  used   by  Thomas  More  in  his  novel  Utopia  in  1516,  lies  the  direct  meaning  of  cyberutopia.  Utopia   means  by  its  Greek  etymology  “no  place”  (outopia),  a  place  that  does  not  exist.  However,  More   came  to  define  it  as  a  perfect,  ideal  place  .  These  two  meanings  of  utopia  have  become  conjoined   and  it  has  come  to  refer  to  a  “non-­‐existent  good  place”  (Yar  5).  In  these  cyberutopian  terms  the   web  was  claimed  to  enable  the  construction  of  new  sorts  of  community,  linked  by  commonality   of  interest  rather  than  location  (Robins  88).  There  was  a  belief  in  transcendence,  that  the  new   technology  would  free  people  from  the  limitations  and  imperfections  of  the  world  (Robins  78).    

The  cybermanifest  “A  Declaration  of  the  indepence  of  cyberspace”  written  by  John  Perry   Barlow  can  be  considered  a  foundational  text  for  these  utopian  visions.  Barlow  wrote  the  text  in   1996  as  a  response  to  the  Telecommunications  Act  in  the  U.S..  He  declares  that  computer-­‐ networked  communication  will  enable  individuals  to  recreate  themselves  and  their   communities  and  to  free  themselves  from  their  bodies  and  constraints  of  the  government.  

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

The different faces of the urban digital economy are becoming increasingly evident in cities, and local government should keep exploring ways to deal with it. In our workstream,

Diverse partijen zijn op zoek naar nuttige toepassingen van rest CO 2 uit industriële bronnen,. energiecentrales, vergistingsinstallaties, afvalverbranding

Tabel 5.3 Constanten uit de benadering van de groei van lengte, gewicht, aantal bladeren en bladoppervlak in zomer en winter periode. groei in de zomer in het een hogere waarde

An experiment was chosen as the research method of this study due to its appropriateness to find out the effect of (in)consistent schemas on the quantity and creativity of

The resonance frequency shift is characterized by proximity-induced magnetic anisotropies: by the positive in-plane uniaxial anisotropy and by the drop of magnetization.. The shift

Crowdsourcing firms, their client firms and the government in Japan have advocated that crowd work provides opportunities for workers to enjoy autonomous working practices,

Using a rational-choice approach, also Anthony Downs (1957) famously argued that it is not rational for individuals to participate in general elections because the personal

As a member of the Law, Science, Technology and Society (LSTS) Research Group, she investigates legal issues related to fundamental rights, privacy, personal