• No results found

Measuring multi-product banks' market power using the Lerner index

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Measuring multi-product banks' market power using the Lerner index"

Copied!
17
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

University of Groningen

Measuring multi-product banks' market power using the Lerner index

Shaffer, Sherrill; Spierdijk, Laura

Published in:

Journal of Banking & Finance

DOI:

10.1016/j.jbankfin.2020.105859

IMPORTANT NOTE: You are advised to consult the publisher's version (publisher's PDF) if you wish to cite from

it. Please check the document version below.

Document Version

Publisher's PDF, also known as Version of record

Publication date:

2020

Link to publication in University of Groningen/UMCG research database

Citation for published version (APA):

Shaffer, S., & Spierdijk, L. (2020). Measuring multi-product banks' market power using the Lerner index.

Journal of Banking & Finance, 117, [105859]. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2020.105859

Copyright

Other than for strictly personal use, it is not permitted to download or to forward/distribute the text or part of it without the consent of the author(s) and/or copyright holder(s), unless the work is under an open content license (like Creative Commons).

Take-down policy

If you believe that this document breaches copyright please contact us providing details, and we will remove access to the work immediately and investigate your claim.

Downloaded from the University of Groningen/UMCG research database (Pure): http://www.rug.nl/research/portal. For technical reasons the number of authors shown on this cover page is limited to 10 maximum.

(2)

ContentslistsavailableatScienceDirect

Journal

of

Banking

and

Finance

journalhomepage:www.elsevier.com/locate/jbf

Measuring

multi-product

banks’

market

power

using

the

Lerner

index

Sherrill

Shaffer

a,b

,

Laura

Spierdijk

c,∗

a University of Wyoming, Department of Economics and Finance, 10 0 0 East University Ave., Laramie, WY 82071, USA b Centre for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis (CAMA), Australian National University, Australia

c University of Groningen, Faculty of Economics and Business, Department of Economics, Econometrics and Finance, P.O. Box 800, AV Groningen 9700, the Netherlands

a

r

t

i

c

l

e

i

n

f

o

Article history: Received 8 October 2019 Accepted 17 May 2020 Available online 20 May 2020 JEL classification: D43 L13 G21 Keywords: Lerner index Multi-product banks Market power Cost functions

a

b

s

t

r

a

c

t

TheaggregateLernerindexisapopularcompositemeasureofmulti-productbanks’marketpower,based ontotalassetsasthesingleaggregateoutputfactor.WeshowthattheaggregateLernerindexonly quali-fiesasaconsistentlyaggregatedLernerindexifthreeconditionshold.Undertheseconditions,the aggre-gateLernerindexreducestoaweighted-averageoftheproduct-specificLernerindices.Wetestthethree conditionsforasampleofU.S.bankscoveringtheyears2011–2017.Allthreeconditionsarerejectedand weshowthattheymaycauseaneconomicallyrelevantbiastotheaggregateLernerindex,depending ontheeconomic context.Asageneralsolution,wepropose usingthealways consistentlyaggregated weighted-averageLernerindexwheneveracompositeLernerindexisneeded.

© 2020 The Author(s). Published by Elsevier B.V. ThisisanopenaccessarticleundertheCCBYlicense.(http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/)

1. Introduction

TheLernerindexisawidelyusedmeasureofmarketpowerin the economic literature, whose historical and theoretical founda-tions have beenextensively discussedin the literature (Amoroso, 1933; Lerner, 1934; Amoroso, 1938; 1954; Landes and Posner, 1981;ElzingaandMills,2011;Giocoli,2012;ShafferandSpierdijk, 2017). A firm’s Lerner index compares the market output price withthefirm’smarginalcosts ofproduction,wheremarginal-cost pricingisreferredtoasthe“socialoptimumthatis reachedin per-fect competition” (Lerner, 1934, p.168). A positive Lernerindex is generally associated with the presence of market power and re-ducedconsumerwelfare.

The Lernerindex was originally derived for a firm producing asingleproduct.Themulti-productextension oftheLernerindex comprises separate Lernerindicesforeach productcategory. This followsfromtheresultthatproduct-specificmarginal-costpricing also characterizes the long-run competitive equilibrium of multi-productfirms(Baumoletal.,1982;MacDonaldandSlivinski,1987). Multi-product measures ofmarket powerare relevant forthe banking sector, where banks earna substantial part of their in-comefrominvestmentsandoff-balancesheetactivities,inaddition

Corresponding author.

E-mail addresses: Shaffer@uwyo.edu (S. Shaffer), L.Spierdijk@rug.nl (L. Spierdijk).

tolending.Forinstance,forU.S.commercialbankswithtotalassets exceeding$100million,thesumofsecuritiesincomeandrealized capitalgainswasabout14%ofoperatingincomeduringthe2011– 2017period,onaverage.Forthesamegroupofbanks,non-interest incomeconstitutedonaverageabout18%ofoperatingincome dur-ing thisperiod.1 Foran overviewofsuch trends intheEuropean

bankingsector,seee.g.Lepetitetal.(2008).

Despite the multi-product character of banks, the ‘aggregate’ Lernerindexhas neverthelessremained popularin the empirical bankingliterature.ThisLernerindexisbasedontotalassetsasthe singleaggregate output factor.ToobtainthisLernerindex,banks’ outputpriceistypicallycalculatedastheaveragerevenue(i.e., to-talrevenuedividedbytotalassets),whiletheestimateofmarginal costs is based on an aggregate cost function with total assetsas thesingleoutputfactor.Product-specificLernerindices– basedon the average revenue per product and a multi-product cost func-tion– haveonlybeenusedoccasionallyinbanking.Otherstudies makeuseofaweighted-averageofproduct-specificLernerindices (henceforthreferredtoas‘the’weighted-averageLernerindex).

Table 1provides an overviewof recent banking studies using theLernerindex.Thesestudies,publishedbetween2013–2020,are grouped intothree categories on the basis of the type of Lerner

1 Source: authors’ own calculations using Call Report data for the 2011–2017 pe- riod; see Appendix A.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2020.105859

(3)

Table 1

Recent Lerner index studies in banking.

author(s) output(s) sample period country/region

Aggregate Lerner index

Saif-Alyousfi et al. (2020) total assets 1996–2016 6 G.C.C. countries Hirata and Ojima (2020) total assets 1996–2016 Japan

Memanova and Mylonidis (2020) ∗ total earning assets 1997–2010 125 countries

Wang et al. (2020) total (earning) assets 2006–2015 19 E.U. countries Phan et al. (2020) total assets 2004–2014 4 Asian countries Shamshur and Weill (2019) total assets 2015 9 E.U. countries

Biswas (2019) total assets 1978–2004 13 countries

Deli et al. (2019) ∗ total earning assets 1997–2014 U.S.

Silva-Buston (2019) total assets 2000 –2007 25 E.U. countries Leroy and Lucotte (2019) total assets 1997–2014 16 E.U. countries Clark et al. (2018) total assets 2005–2013 CIS countries Hryckiewicz and Kozlowski (2018) total assets 1996–2014 54 countries Bergbrant et al. (2018) total assets 2000, 2005, 24 Eastern and Central

2009 E.U. countries Spierdijk and Zaouras (2018) total assets 2000–2014 U.S.

Feng and Wang (2018) total assets 2004–2014 U.S. and Europe Cubillas et al. (2017) total assets 1989–2007 104 countries

Fosu et al. (2017) total assets 1995–2013 U.S.

Leroy and Lucotte (2017) total assets 2004–2013 97 large European banks Shaffer and Spierdijk (2017) total assets 1976–2014 Dewey county, U.S. Delis et al. (2016) total earning assets 1997–2009 131 countries Carbó-Valverde et al. (2016) total assets 1994–2010 Spain Calderon and Schaeck (2016) total assets 1996–2010 124 countries

Dong et al. (2016) total assets 2002–2013 China

McMillan and McMillan (2016) total assets 1994–2009 U.S. Fernández et al. (2016) total assets 1989–2008 110 countries Andrievskaya and Semenova (2016) total assets 1998, 2001, 63–102 countries

2005, 2010

Clerides et al. (2015) ∗ total earning assets 1997–2010 148 countries

Anginer et al. (2014) total assets 1997–2009 63 countries

Fu et al. (2014) total assets 2003–2010 14 Asia Pacific countries Mirzaei and Moore (2014) total assets 1999–2011 146 countries Beck et al. (2013) total assets 1994–2009 79 countries Hainz et al. (2013) total assets 2000–2005 70 countries

Weill (2013) total assets 2002–2010 27 E.U. countries

Product-specific Lerner indices

Wang et al. (2020) loans, deposits 2006–2015 19 E.U. countries Spierdijk and Zaouras (2018) loans, securities 2010–2014 U.S.

Degl’Innocenti et al. (2017) loans, customer deposits 1993–2011 Italy

Huang et al. (2017) loans, investments, non-interest income 1998–2010 5 E.U. countries Titotto and Ongena (2017) loans, loan advancements to banks, 2000–2014 28 E.U. countries

securities, other earnings assets, derivatives, guarantees (OBS), committed credit lines (OBS)

Forssbæck and Shehzad (2015) loans, deposits 1995–2007 48 countries Weighted-average Lerner index

Tsionas et al. (2018) loans, securities 1984–2007 U.S. Ahamed and Mallick (2017) loans, securities 1994–2012 India Das and Kumbhakar (2016) loans, investments 1991–1992, India

2000–2001, 2009–2010 Bolt and Humphrey (2015) consumer loans, business loans and securities 2008–2010 U.S. Hakenes et al. (2015) loans, securities and OBS items 1995–2004 Germany Inklaar et al. (2015) interbank loans, commercial loans, 1996–2006 Germany

securities, OBS items

Kick and Prieto (2015) consumer loans, business loans and securities 1994–2010 Germany Restrepo-Tobón and Kumbhakar (2014) loans, securities 1976–2007 U.S. Buch et al. (2013) interbank loans, customer loans, 2003–2006 Germany

securities, OBS items

Notes: This non-exhaustive table lists some recent studies (published since 2013) using aggregate, product-specific and weighted-average Lerner indices. Studies that appear more than once employ different Lerner indices. The abbreviation OBS stands for ‘off-balance sheet’. All studies listed use the translog cost function to estimate the marginal-cost component of the Lerner index, apart from the ones marked with a star. They use a semi-parametric quasi-linear specification. The aggregate Lerner index, used by the studies in the upper panel, is the key focus of our study.

index used: the aggregate Lerner index (upper panel), product-specificLernerindices(middlepanel)andtheweighted-averageof theproduct-specificLernerindices(lowerpanel).

Inthe economicliteratureabout‘consistentaggregation’, func-tionsdependingonvariousdisaggregatevariablesaretransformed intofunctions that depend on a single aggregate variable,or se-riesofdisaggregatefunctionsaretransformedintoasingle

aggre-gate function (e.g., Gorman, 1959; Berndt andChristensen, 1974; Chipman, 1974; Vartia, 1976; Brown et al., 1979; Blackorby and Schworm, 1988; Kim, 1986; Blackorby and Primont,1980; Black-orbyandRussell, 1999). Examplesare theaggregation ofafirm’s multi-productcost function (dependingonmultiple outputs)into a single-product cost function (depending on a single aggregate output) and the aggregation of multiple firms’ efficiency indices

(4)

intoasingleindustry-levelaggregateefficiencyindex.Intheseand other cases,theaggregationmustbedone‘consistently’toensure thattheaggregatedformsharestheparticulareconomicand math-ematical properties associated with the underlyingdisaggregated forms.

To ourbest knowledge,the literature has onlyconsidered the consistent aggregationoffirm-specificmeasures of marketpower into industry-wide measures (e.g., Schroeter and Azzam, 1990; Morrison Paul, 1999; Neven and Röller, 1999). In particular, the consistent aggregation of product-specific Lerner indices has not yet been addressed. According to the aforementioned literature, however,consistentaggregationisanecessarypropertyforthe ag-gregateLernerindextorepresentasummary measureofa multi-productbank’smarketpowerindifferentoutputmarkets.The con-tinueduseinthebankingliteratureofapotentiallyinconsistently aggregatedLernerindexisakeymotivationforourstudy.

Our theoretical contribution to the literature is twofold.First, we define the concept of a consistently aggregated Lerner index in linewiththe aforementionedconsistent-aggregation literature. Second, we derive three conditions under which the aggregate Lerner indexis consistently aggregated. Ifthese consistency con-ditions hold, this Lerner index reduces to the weighted-average Lerner index. Ifany of theseconditions isrejected, however,the aggregate Lerner indexis no longer consistently aggregated. This partofour studyalso providesthemissinglink amongthethree differenttypesofLernerindicesusedintheliteratureandincluded inTable1.

Although one of the aforementioned conditions has been de-scribed as “extremely restrictive” in the literature (Brown et al., 1979),whetherthethreeconditionsholdforagivensampleis ul-timately an empirical matter. We therefore provide an empirical application in addition to our theoretical analysis.Our contribu-tionisthatweprovideanempiricalstrategytotesttheconsistency conditions,appliedtoasampleofU.S.commercialbanksobserved during the 2011–2017 period. Here we distinguish among three linesofbusinessofmulti-productbanks:lending,investmentsand off-balance-sheet activities. We find that all three conditions are statisticallyrejected,whichmeansthattheaggregateLernerindex is not consistentlyaggregatedforour sampleofbanks. We show that the statistically rejected conditions may cause economically relevant distortions to the aggregate Lerner index, dependingon theeconomiccontext.

Ouranalysisraisesthequestionwhytheaggregateindexshould beusedinthefirstplace.Theuserofthisindexshouldatleasttest whetherit isconsistently aggregatedfortheparticular sampleat hand.Thisalreadyturnsouttorequirethecalculationofthe com-ponents of the weighted-average Lerner index. Furthermore, will show thatsome cost functions(suchasthewell-known translog) areneverseparableintotaloutput.Basedonsuchacostfunction, the aggregateLernerindexis apriori knowntobe inconsistently aggregated. Such a cost function is therefore not suitable forthe purposeofestimatingtheaggregateLernerindex,althoughitcould stillprovideagoodfittothedata.

As an efficient solution to theseissues, we propose usingthe weighted-averageLernerindexwheneveracompositeLernerindex is needed. Because the weighted-average Lerner index is always consistentlyaggregatedregardlessoftheunderlyingcostfunction, thisindexcansimplybebasedonacostfunctionthatfitsthedata wellwithoutfurtherconcernsaboutthiscostfunction’s separabil-ityproperties.

Thesetupoftheremainderofthisstudyisasfollows.Westart witha literature review inSection 2.Section 3 containsthe the-oretical framework and derives the conditions under which the aggregate Lerner index is consistently aggregated. The setup of our empirical analysis is outlined in Section 4, while the em-pirical results are presented and discussed in Section 5. Lastly,

Section6concludes.Anonlineappendix withsupplementary ma-terialisavailable.

2. Literaturereview

Froman economicperspective,marketpowerresultsinhigher prices and lower quantities, which reduces consumer and total welfare relative to what can be attained in a hypothetical per-fectly competitive outcome. This is the main reason why policy-makers care aboutmarket power andgenerally seekto suppress it.Banks’central roleintheprovision ofcredit,thepayment sys-tem,thetransmissionofmonetarypolicyandinmaintaining finan-cialstabilityleadstoparticularlylargeconcernsabouttheirmarket power.

Drivenby theseconcerns,boththetheoretical andthe empiri-calliteraturehaveinvestigatedtheimpactofbanking competition on variouseconomic outcomes, includingfinancial stability, bank efficiency,informationsharingandeconomicgrowth(e.g.,Degryse etal.,2018;Coccorese,2017).Thetheoreticalliteraturehasoffered mixedpredictionsabouttheeffectsofbankingcompetitionon eco-nomicoutcomes.Forexample,the‘competition-stability’view pre-dicts a positive impact of banking competition on financial sta-bility,whilethe‘competition-fragility’viewconjectures the oppo-site. A similar ambiguity applies to thecompetition-growth rela-tion,forwhich partialequilibrium modelstend topredict a neg-ativerelationandgeneralequilibriummodelsa positiveone.Also thecompetition-efficiencyrelationissubjecttosuchdiverging the-oretical results: a positive relation is predicted by the ‘efficient-structure’hypothesis,whilethe‘quiet-lifehypothesis’conjecturesa negativerelation.Thelastcontroversythatwementionisthe rela-tionbetweenbankingcompetitionandrelationshiplending.While some studies predict that banks operating in a highly competi-tiveenvironmentcouldbeinhibitedfromforminglong-term lend-ing relationships with small and medium-sized enterprises, oth-ersconjecturethat banking competitionboosts relationship lend-ing(e.g.,PetersenandRajan,1995;BootandThakor,2000).

Becauseof thewidespread ambiguityin thetheoretical litera-ture,theimpactofbankingcompetitionisultimatelyan empirical matter.Consequently,thereexistsanabundantempiricalliterature thatanalyzesthe effectofbanking competitiononeconomic out-comes.WerefertoDegryseetal.(2018)andCoccorese(2017)fora recentoverviewofthisliteratureandadiscussionofthereported effectsofbankingcompetitiononeconomicoutcomes.

The aforementioned empirical banking studies rely on certain measures of market power. Popular measures besides the Lerner index include market shares (such as the four-bank concentra-tion ratio and the Herfindahl-Hirschman index), the Rothschild-Bresnahanconductindex(also knownastheconductparameter), the Panzar-Rosse H-statistic and the Hay-Liu-Boone index (also known as the performance-structure-conduct indicator); see e.g.

Shaffer and Spierdijk (2017) and Degryse et al.(2018). Although allofthesemeasuresmayfailtocorrectlyindicatetheabsenceor presenceofmarket power inspecific cases,concentration indices are widelyconsidered to fall shortas areliable measure of mar-ket power in general. Also the Panzar-Rosse H-statistic has been showntobeunfitasameasureofmarketpowerandhasbeen rel-egatedtothesamecategoryastheconcentrationmeasures(Hyde andPerloff,1995;Bikkeretal.,2012;ShafferandSpierdijk,2015).

Blair and Sokol (2014, p. 325) report that the Lerner index has become “the standard measure of market power (...) among economists”, while Shaffer andSpierdijk (2017) call it a measure that is among the “scant handful of ‘least objectionable’ methods”.

The value of the Lerner index is monotonically associated with consumerwelfare losses from market power for given costs and demandfunctions.Ithasalsobeenshowntorepresenttheslopeof asocialwelfarefunction(DansbyandWillig,1979).Likeany

(5)

mea-sureof market power, also the Lernerindex hascertain concep-tual limitations, relatedto issues such as inefficiency,economies ofscale anda lackof profitmaximizing behavior (e.g.,Scitovsky, 1955; Cairns, 1995; Koetter et al., 2012; Spierdijk and Zaouras, 2017;2018).Foramoredetaileddiscussionandcomparisonofthe propertiesofthepopularmeasuresofbankingcompetition,we re-fertoShafferandSpierdijk(2017)andDegryseetal.(2018).

The initialversionsoftheaforementioned measuresofmarket

power havein common that they assume that a bank (or other

firm)producesasingleoutputfactor.Forsomeofthesemeasures, extensions to the multi-output case have been proposed (e.g.,

Gelfand and Spiller, 1987; Suominen, 1994; Feenstra and Levin-sohn,1995;Shaffer,1996;Barbosaetal.,2015).FortheLerner in-dex,originallyderivedbyLerner(1934)forafirmproducinga sin-gle product, the multi-product extension is fairly straightforward andreliesontheresultthatproduct-specificmarginal-costpricing alsocharacterizes the long-run competitive equilibrium of multi-productfirms(Baumoletal.,1982;MacDonaldandSlivinski,1987).

Baumoletal.(1982)andMacDonaldandSlivinski(1987)showthis formarkets withmulti-product firms only and formarkets with both single- and multi-product firms, respectively. Their proofs makeuseoftheconceptofaperfectlycontestablemarket (PCM). Theyshowthat,forbothsingle-andmulti-productfirmsinaPCM market,thefirst-orderconditionsimplymarginal-costpricing.This argumentthencarriesovertocompetitiveequilibrium, whichisa specificformofaPCM.

From the upper panel of Table 1 it becomes apparent that

the aggregate Lerner indexhas remained popular in the empiri-calbankingliteraturedespitebanks’multi-productcharacter. Com-monlyuseddatasources suchasBankScopeandtheU.S.Call Re-portsprovide sufficiently detaileddata to obtain product-specific Lernerindices.ThepopularityoftheaggregateLernerindex there-fore seems largely driven by the convenience of using a single-outputmeasure ofmarketpower (forinstance,asan explanatory variableinaregressionanalysis).

The economic literature has paid only limited attention to

the consistent aggregation of measures of market power. For

example, the banking studies listed in the lower panel of

Table 1 use a weighted-average of product-specific Lerner in-dices without addressing the topic of consistent aggregation.

Gischeretal.(2015)criticizethe waythe aggregateLernerindex’ averagerevenueiscalculated,butdonotrefertoconsistent aggre-gation.Afew studiesconsiderthe consistentaggregationof firm-specific measures of market power into industry-wide measures (e.g.,SchroeterandAzzam,1990;MorrisonPaul,1999;Nevenand Röller,1999),while othersaggregate Lernerindices overfirms or outputs by means of share weighting without reference to con-sistent aggregation(e.g., Spiller and Favaro, 1984; Encaoua etal., 1986; Verboven, 1996; Chirinko andFazzari, 2000). As explained intheintroduction,it remains tobe seen iftheaggregate Lerner indexisaconsistentlyaggregatedmeasureofmarketpower.

3. TheLernerindexandconsistentaggregation

This sectionwill showthat theaggregate Lernerindexis con-sistentlyaggregatedonlyunderthreeconditions.Allproofsforthis sectioncanbefoundinAppendixB.

3.1.Definitions

Product-specific andweighted-average LernerindicesWe assume amulti-producttotal costfunction c(y,w), wherey=

(

y1,...,yn

)

and w=

(

w1,...,wK

)

. Here yj ≥ 0 denotes the level of the jth

output and wk ≥ 0 the value of the kth exogenous input price,

for j=1,...,n and k=1,...,K. The marginal costs with respect

toeachoutputaredenotedMCj

(

y,w

)

=

c

(

y,w

)

/

yj>0.The

ob-served market output priceof the jthoutput is written asPj(y),

withPj(y)>0foryj>0.Althoughthispricewillusuallyalso

de-pendonvariablesother thany,we suppressthisforsimplicityof notation.

The Lernerindexfor thejthoutput is definedfor yj > 0 and

captures the relative markup of the market output price over marginal costs. Specifically, the product-specific Lernerindices in thebankingliteratureusetheaveragerevenueearnedoneach out-putfactor,denotedR¯j

(

y

)

=Rj

(

y

)

/yj,asthemarketoutput price.2

Thisyields L j

(

y, w

)

= ¯ R j

(

y

)

− MCj

(

y, w

)

¯ R j

(

y

)

. (1)

The studies in the second panel of Table 1 estimate product-specific Lernerindicesandtypically useloans, securitiesand off-balancesheetitemsastheoutputfactors.

The weighted-average Lerner index based on n ≥ 2 product-specificLernerindicesisdefinedas

L WA

(

y, w

)

= n



j=1

ω

j

(

y

)

L j

(

y, w

)

, (2)

with revenue shares as the weights, as suggested by

Encaouaetal.(1986):

ω

j

(

y

)

= R j

(

y

)

R A

(

y

)

, R A

(

y

)

= n  j=1 R j

(

y

)

. (3)

By rewriting (2) using short-hand notation that leaves out the functions’argumentsforthesakeofreadability,wefind

L WA = n  j=1

ω

jL j= n  j=1



R j R A R j− MCj R j



= n  j=1



R j R A R j/y j− MCj R j/y j



= n j=1R j− n j=1y jMC j R A = R A− n j=1

ω

jMC j R A . (4)

Here

ω

¯j=yj/nj=1yj denotes theoutput shareof theithoutput and R¯A=RA/nj=1yj the average revenue on total output. From (4), we see that LWA is defined for values ofy withnj=1yj>0

(which we will henceforth denote by y=0

)

and that it can be viewedasasingle-outputLernerindexwithR¯A asthemarket

out-put price and weighted-average marginal costs as the marginal costs. The weighted-average Lernerindexhas recentlybeen used invariousbankingstudies;seethelowerpanelofTable1.3

AggregateLernerindexThestartingpointoftheaggregateLerner index isthe existence ofan aggregate output factor y, with cor-responding market output price PA(y) > 0 for y > 0, cost

func-tion cA(y, w) and associated marginal cost function MCA

(

y,w

)

=

cA

(

y,w

)

/

y>0.Specifically, theaggregate Lernerindexuses

to-taloutputnj=1yjastheaggregateoutput factorandtheaverage

revenue earned on total output (R¯A) asthe market priceof total

output.Theindexisdefinedfory=0andwritesas L A

(

y, w

)

= ¯ R A

(

y

)

− MCA

(

nj=1y j, w

)

¯ R A

(

y

)

. (5)

2 As shown in Shaffer (1983) , the average revenue can reflect any two-part tariffs or nonlinear pricing schedules. Average revenue also has the advantage of reflecting actual transaction prices even when they deviate from posted prices (due to errors, idiosyncratic negotiations with selected counterparties, etc.).

3 Because these studies typically write the weighted-average Lerner index in a different way, their index is not directly recognizable as a share-weighted average. Using short-hand notation that leaves out the functions’ arguments for the sake of readability, these studies write L WA = ( ¯R A − AC  nk=1 e k) / ¯R A , where AC denotes aver- age costs and e k the elasticity of the multi-product cost function c with respect to the k th output.

(6)

The empirical banking studies listed in the upper panel of

Table1haverecentlyusedtheaggregateLernerindex.

Consistent aggregation Using the same notation as before, we continue to consider a K-input and n-output bank with input-price vector w, output vector y, multi-product cost function c(y, w) and market output prices Pj(y) for j=1,...,n. In this

set-ting,we consider theproduct-specific Lernerindices Lj(y,w) and someLernerindexL

(

y,w

)

:D× RK

+→R(withD⊂ Rn+)ofwhichwe wouldliketoknowwhetheritisconsistentlyaggregated.Wewill writeL=

(

L1,...,Ln

)

andP=

(

P1,...,Pn

)

todenotevectorsof

val-ues of product-specific Lernerindices andoutput prices, respec-tively,where LRn andPRn

+.Furthermore, we willhenceforth assume thatyDandw∈RK

+,evenifwedonotexplicitly men-tionthis.

To define a consistently aggregated Lerner index in line with the literature,we proceed ina waycomparabletoBlackorby and Russell (1999).From them, wetake the requirementsof aggrega-tion, monotonicity and (non-)competitive indication, resulting in thefollowingdefinition:

Definition 3.1. A Lerner index L(y, w) is consistently aggregated if there exists a differentiable function F:Rn× Rn

+× Rn+→R that satisfiestherequirementsofaggregation,monotonicity,and (non-)competitiveindication:

(i) [Aggregation] L

(

y,w

)

=F

(

L1

(

y,w

)

,...,Ln

(

y,w

)

,P1

(

y

)

,

...,Pn

(

y

)

,y

)

forally,w.

(ii) [Monotonicity]

F(L,P,y)/

Lj>0forallL,P,y.

(iii)[(Non-)competitive indication] F

(

0,...,0,P,y

)

=0 and

F

(

1,...,1,P,y

)

=1forallP,y.

Under the aggregation requirement, L is a function of the product-specific Lerner indices, ensuring an economic interpreta-tionasasummarymeasureofabank’sproduct-specificLerner in-dices.The monotonicityrequirementensures that Lincreases fol-lowing a ceteris paribus increase in one of the product-specific Lerner indices. The requirement of (non-)competitive indication is imposed to ensure that L shares the particular economic and mathematical properties associated withthe underlying product-specific Lerner indices.The first partof requirement(iii) ensures that L is0 ifeach Ljis 0,which impliesthat both Landeach Lj

have 0 as the competitive benchmark value. To see this, we re-callfromtheliterature review thatproduct-specific marginalcost pricingcharacterizes long-run competitiveequilibriumin markets withonlymulti-productfirms,aswellasmarketswithboth single-andmulti-product firms(BaumolandBradford,1970; MacDonald andSlivinski, 1987). The second partofrequirement (iii)ensures that Lis 1 ifeach Lj is 1. Hence, if all product-specific marginal costs arezero,then theaggregateindexmusthavethevalue that corresponds to zeromarginal costs at theaggregate level. In Ap-pendixBitisshownthattwoothernaturalpropertieswithrespect to (non-)competitive indication are automatically satisfied under

Definition3.1.

ToseethattheclassofconsistentlyaggregatedLernerindicesis notempty,considershare-weightedLernerindicesoftheform L SW

(

y, w

)

= n  j=1 s jL j

(

y, w

)

, 0< s j < 1, n  j=1 s j=1. (6)

Here the shares sj are allowed to be functions of the form sj=

sj

(

P1

(

y

)

,. . .,P1

(

y

)

,y

)

.Evidently, thisclass ofLernerindices satis-fiesthe requirementsofDefinition3.1andis therebyconsistently aggregated. Thisalsoholdsfortheweighted-average Lernerindex asdefinedinSection3.1.Afurthercharacterizationoftheclassof consistentlyaggregatedLernerindicesisprovidedinAppendixB.

Weneed sometheory beforewecan concludewhetherornot thepopularaggregatedLernerindexisconsistentlyaggregated.

Separabilityintotal outputSeveralstudies aboutconsistent ag-gregationoffunctionsshow that thisconceptis insome way re-latedto‘separability’oftheunderlyingfunctions(e.g.,Berndtand Christensen,1974).Sucharelationalsoturnsouttoexistincaseof theaggregate Lernerindex,wherethefunctionofrelevanceisthe multi-productcostfunction.Weprovideadefinitionofthetypeof separabilitythatisrelevantinourcase.

Brownetal.(1979)defineaseparablemulti-productcost func-tion as a cost function c(y, w) for which a single-output cost function cA(y, w) and an output aggregation function h(y) exist

suchthatc

(

y,w

)

=cA

(

h

(

y

)

,w

)

forally,w.Theoutputaggregation

functionaggregatesthevectorofoutputsyintoascalarmeasureof aggregateoutputh(y).Stateddifferently,aseparablemulti-product costfunctionisequaltoasingle-outputcostfunctionwith aggre-gateoutputh(y)asthesingleoutputfactor(Kim,1986).

Definition 3.2. Amulti-productcost functionc(y, w) isseparable intotaloutputifthereexistsasingle-outputcostfunctioncA(y,w)

suchthatc

(

y,w

)

=cA

(

nj=1yj,w

)

forally,w.

Hence,a multi-product costfunction that isseparablein total outputreduces toa single-outputcostfunction withtotaloutput n

j=1yjastheaggregateoutputfactor.

3.2.Consistencyconditions

AggregateLernerindexInlinewiththeliterature about consis-tentaggregation,wefindastrongrelationbetweenseparabilityin totaloutputofthemulti-productcostfunctionandconsistent ag-gregationoftheaggregateLernerindex.

Result 3.1. Assume that banks’ multi-product cost function is givenby c(y,w), withcorresponding LWA(y, w) as definedin(4).

Let h

(

y

)

=n

j=1yj. If there exists a single-output cost function

cA(y, w) such that c

(

y,w

)

=cA

(

h

(

y

)

,w

)

for all y, w, then LA in (5) based on cA is consistently aggregated and LA=LWA.

Con-versely,ifcis notseparableinh(y),thenLA based onany

single-output cost function cA is not consistently aggregated and LA=

LWA.

The implications ofthis resultare as follows.If banks’ multi-productcostfunctionisseparableintotaloutput,then the aggre-gate Lerner indexLA is consistently aggregated and equal to the

weighted-average Lerner index LWA. If banks’ multi-product cost

function is not separable in total output, it is either separable in a different aggregate output measure or not separable at all.

Result3.1tells usthat,ineithercase, theaggregate Lernerindex basedonanysingle-outputcostfunctionwemaycomeupwithis notconsistentlyaggregatedandnotequaltotheweighted-average Lernerindex.

ThepracticalconsequenceofResult3.1isthatwefirsthaveto verifywhetherbanks’ multi-productcost function is separablein total output beforewe canuse the aggregate Lernerindex inan empiricalsetting. Wenote that itdoesnot seem very likelythat separabilityintotaloutputwilloftenexistinpractice.Brownetal. (1979, p. 257) call the implications of separability in an aggre-gateoutputfactor“extremelyrestrictive”.Ifseparabilityinsome ag-gregate output factor is already considered extremely restrictive, thenseparabilityina specificaggregateoutput factor(namely to-tal output) will be even more restrictive. The restrictiveness of separabilityintotal outputstems fromthe implied propertythat themarginalcostsarethesameforall outputs.Thisproperty fol-lowsimmediatelyfromthemulti-productcostfunction’sfunctional formunderseparabilityintotaloutputasgiveninDefinition3.2.

Empiricalaggregate Lerner indexThe studies referred to in the upperpanelofTable1makeuseofthe‘empirical’aggregateLerner indexLe

A, whichdiffersfromthe‘theoretical’ aggregateLerner

(7)

factor,namelytotalassetsinsteadoftotaloutput.Italsomakesuse ofadifferentrevenue,namelythesumofinterestandnon-interest (INI)incomeinsteadofthe sumoftheproduct-specific revenues. WewilluseResult3.1toderivetheconditionsunderwhichLe

A is

consistentlyaggregated.

Westartwiththefollowingobservation.Dependingonthe cho-senbanking model,theremaybe a non-equivalencebetween to-tal assets andtotal output and betweenINI income andthe to-talrevenue.Some componentsoftotal assetsmaynotbe consid-ered an output, while other components are viewed as an out-putbutare not part oftotal assets. Forexample,total assets in-clude fixed assets, which are considered an input instead of an

output in the commonly used intermediation model of banking

(Klein,1971; Monti,1972;SealeyandLindley,1977).Furthermore, off-balancesheetactivities are not includedin totalassets,while they are often considered to be an output factor (e.g., DeYoung andRice, 2004; Wheelock andWilson, 2012). These two sources ofnon-equivalenceworkinoppositedirectionsregardingthe mis-matchbetweentotalassetsandtotaloutput,sototalassetscould potentiallyeitheroverstateorunderstatetotal outputfor individ-ualbanksintheintermediationmodel.

Alsothe directionofthenon-equivalence betweenINI income andthetotal revenue isambiguous.For instance,servicefeeson depositsarepartofINI income,butare notpartofthetotal rev-enueaccordingtotheintermediationmodelofbanking(where de-positsareconsideredaninputinsteadofan output).Furthermore, capitalgainsontheoutputfactorsecuritiesarenotpartofINI in-come;they are listedasa separate item onbanks’ income state-ment.Yet securitiesare includedintotal assetsandpart oftheir revenuestemsfromthesecapitalgains.

Wecanthuswritetotalassetsasthesumofcertainnon-output variablesandsome ofthe output factors.Similarly, INIincome is writtenasthesumoftheincomeoncertainnon-outputvariables andtherevenueonsome oftheoutputfactors.Stated differently, thereareincluded non-outputvariables andexcluded output fac-tors.Informally,wethuswrite

total assets = total output− excluded outputs +included non-outputs;

INI income = total revenue− revenueon excluded outputs +income on included non-outputs,

where we note that the excluded outputs and included

non-outputsmaydifferbetweentotalassetsandINIincome.

Wewillnowformalizetheaboveconsiderations,whileallowing foranybanking modelandnot just theintermediation modelas considered above. We assume that there are additional variables ˜

y1,. . .,y˜m,whichareconsiderednon-outputvariablesaccordingto

thechosenbankingmodel.Incaseoftheintermediationmodelof banking,thevariablesy˜1,...,y˜mincludefixedassetsanddeposits.

Withz=

(

y˜1,...,y˜m,y1,...,yn

)

,wecannowwritetotalassetsand

INIincomeas,respectively,

k

(

z

)

=h

(

y

)

− jJ yj+  kK ˜ yk, QA

(

z

)

=RA

(

y

)

−  L R

(

y

)

+  pP Qp

(

z

)

, (7)

forincomefunctionsQp.

Writing z=0forvaluesofzwithk(z) >0,wedefine Q¯A

(

z

)

=

QA

(

z

)

/k

(

z

)

for z=0. We can then write the empirical aggregate

Lernerindexas L e A

(

z,w

)

= ¯ Q A

(

z

)

− MCA

(

k

(

z

)

, w

)

¯ Q A

(

z

)

. (8)

In Appendix B, we prove that Le

A is not consistently aggregated

ifk

(

z

)

=h

(

y

)

or QA

(

z

)

= RA

(

y

)

for some y,z=0. By contrast, if

Table 2

Lerner indices and consistency conditions.

composite index conditions for consistent aggregation LA [SEP]

LWA always consistently aggregated Le

A [SEP], [EQ1], [EQ2] Le

WA [EQ2]

Notes: This table lists the condition(s) that must hold for each index to qualify as a consistently aggregated Lerner index. Here L A is defined in (5) , L WA in (4) , L eA in (8) , and Le

WA in (9) .

k

(

z

)

=h

(

y

)

and QA

(

z

)

=RA

(

y

)

for all y, z (“noexcluded outputs

andnoincludednon-outputs”),wecanuseResult3.1todetermine whetherLe

A isconsistently aggregated.This leadsto thefollowing

result:

Result 3.2. Assume that banks’ multi-product cost function is given by c(y, w). Consider Le

A as defined in (8), based on some

single-outputcostfunction cA.Ifk

(

z

)

=h

(

y

)

orQA

(

z

)

=RA

(

y

)

for

somey,z=0,thenLe

A isnotconsistentlyaggregated.Conversely,if

k

(

z

)

=h

(

y

)

andQA

(

z

)

=RA

(

y

)

forally,z,thenLeA

(

z,w

)

=LA

(

y,w

)

forallwandy,z=0andResult3.1applies.

Result3.2leadstothefollowingthreenecessaryandsufficient conditionsforLe

A tobe consistentlyaggregated:separabilityin

to-tal outputofthe multi-productcost function ([SEP]), equivalence of total output and total assets ([EQ1]) andequivalence of total revenueandINIincome([EQ2]).Theintuitionbehindthese consis-tency conditionsisasfollows.The firstconsistency condition en-suresthatthesingle-outputaggregatecostfunctionusedforLe

A

co-incideswiththe underlyingmulti-productcost function.The sec-ond andthird conditionsensure that theaggregate output factor andthemeasuredrevenueontheaggregateoutputfactorusedfor

Le

Aarebothconsistentwiththechoiceofoutputsintheunderlying

multi-productcostfunction.Ifanyoftheseconditionsdonothold, thenLe

A willnotbeconsistentlyaggregated.

Empiricalweighted-average LernerindexThe studies referred to inthelowerpanelofTable1makeuseofthe‘empirical’ weighted-averageLernerindexLe

WA.Incontrasttothe‘theoretical’

weighted-averageLernerindexLWA asdefinedin(4),itusesINI income

in-stead of the sum of the product-specific revenues RA. Using the

samenotationasforLe

A,wecanthuswrite

L e WA

(

z, w

)

= ˜ Q A

(

z

)

− n j=1

ω

¯j

(

y

)

MC j

(

y,w

)

˜ Q A

(

z

)

, (9)

withQ˜A

(

z

)

=QA

(

z

)

/h

(

y

)

.Followingthe samelineofreasoningas

forLe

A,wecanshowthatLeWAisconsistentlyaggregatedifandonly

ifQA

(

z

)

=RA

(

y

)

forall y,z.Thisresulthasbeenrelegatedto

Ap-pendixB.

The upper panel of Table 2 summarizesthe conditions under whicheachoftheindicesLA,LAe,LWAandLeWAisconsistently

aggre-gated.The statisticaltestingoftheseconditions willplaya major roleintheempiricalpartofouranalysis.

4. Empiricalsetup

This section describes the data sample, banking model and multi-productcostfunctionthatwillbeusedinourempirical ap-plication.

4.1. Dataandbankingmodel

Weuseyear-endCallReportDatatocreateanunbalanced sam-ple ofU.S. commercialbankscovering the 2011–2017period. We

(8)

restrict the sampletocommercial banksthat are partofa bank-holdingcompany,withaphysicallocation inaU.S.stateand sub-jecttodeposit-relatedinsurance.

Thecommonprocedureinthebankingliteratureistochoosea particularbanking modelinorderto definethe outputandinput factors. Subsequently, a specific functional form of the total cost functionischosen. Wefollowthat procedureandbaseourchoice of inputs and outputs on the widely used intermediation model for banking (Klein, 1971; Monti, 1972). More specifically, we as-sumethat banksemploy atechnologywithfourinputsandthree output factors(WheelockandWilson,2012). Thefourinputsthat weconsiderarepurchasedfunds,coredeposits,laborservices,and physicalcapital.Thecorrespondinginputpricesare(i)thepriceof purchasedfundsofbank i=1,...,N inyeart=1,...,T (denoted

w1,it), (ii)thecoredepositinterestrate(w2,it),(iii)thewagerate

(w3,it),and(iv)thepriceofphysicalcapital(w4,it).Totaloperating

costs(cit)aredefinedasthesumofexpensesonpurchasedfunds, coredeposits,personnel,andphysicalcapital.

The three output factors that we consider are total loans and leases (y1,it),total securities(y2,it) andoff-balance sheetactivities (y3,it). For total loans and leases, we use interest and lease

in-come asthe revenue. For total securities (defined asthe sumof hold-to-maturityandavailable-for-salesecurities),weuseinterest anddividend income(alsoknownassecuritiesincome) and real-izedcapitalgainsonsecuritiesastherevenue.Wedefinethe rev-enue fromoff-balance sheetactivities asnon-interest income mi-nus servicefeeson deposits(e.g., DeYoungandRice, 2004; Boyd andGertler,1994). Duetoalackofdirectoutputdata,theoutput associated withtheoff-balancesheetrevenue hasto be obtained indirectly. We convert the adjusted non-interest income to non-interestincomecapitalizationcreditequivalentsusingthemethod of Boyd and Gertler (1994). This method measures off-balance sheetactivities in unitsofon-balance sheetassetsthat wouldbe requiredtogeneratetheobservedlevelofadjustednon-interest in-come.Theresultingquantityservesasouroutputmeasureof off-balancesheetactivities.TheBoyd-Gertlermethodassumesthat on-and off-balancesheet itemsare equally profitable atthe margin.

Clark and Siems(2002) argue that thisassumption is reasonable in fairly competitive markets.4 In such markets, a reallocation of

outputs wouldtakeplaceincaseofunequalprofitmarginsacross differentoutputs.

The banking literature has emphasized therelevance of bank-specificcosttechnologies(e.g.,BergerandHumphrey,1997; Kumb-hakar and Tsionas, 2008). We therefore use banks’ total output in prices ofthe year 2017 to stratify oursample anddistinguish amongfoursizeclasses:(i)lessthan$100million,(ii)$100–500 million,(iii)$500million–1billion,and(iv)morethan$1billion. Thenextsectionwillpresentempiricalresultsforeachsizeclass.

Havingdefinedtherequired variablesandthesize classes,we filterout inconsistentvaluesin thedataandusetrimming to re-move outliers. The exact filtering rules are listed inAppendix A. Thisappendix alsoexplainshowtheCallReportserieshavebeen usedtoconstructthevariablesrequiredforouranalysis.

Table3provides(non-deflated)samplestatisticsonthese vari-ables,includingoutputandrevenueshares,outputquantities, aver-agerevenue,andnumberofbanksandbank-yearobservations.We highlightafewfigures.Onaverage,totalloanshavelargerrevenue andoutputsharesthantotalsecuritiesandoff-balancesheet activ-ities,regardlessofbanksize.Banksinthetwolargestsizeclasses have relatively low average revenue and output shares for loans andsecurities,buthigheraveragesharesforoff-balancesheet

ac-4 One could even argue that this assumption will hold in any profit-maximizing equilibrium. That is, if it did not hold, an allocation with more of the most prof- itable and less of the least profitable of the two outputs would yield a higher profit, which contradicts the assumption of profit maximization.

tivities. Regardless of the size class,loans have the highest aver-agerevenue,followedbyoff-balancesheetactivitiesandsecurities. Banksinthetwolargest sizeclasseshaverelativelylarge average sharesofadjustednon-interest incomeandfiduciaryservicesand theyalsohaveahigheraveragewagerate. Thedispersionin out-putlevelsisrelativelylargeforbanksinthelargestsizeclass.

4.2.Costfunctions

Multi-product cost functions have a long history in banking (e.g., Benston et al., 1982; Shaffer, 1984). It is well-known that the popular translog cost function – introduced by Christensen etal.(1971,1973)– requires a relativelyhomogeneous samplein termsofbanksizeandproductmixtoprovideanaccuratefit(e.g.,

McAllisterandMcManus,1993;FengandSerletis,2010;Wheelock andWilson,2012). Inamulti-productsetting,theproblemofsize heterogeneityisamplifiedduetothepresenceofmultipleoutputs. Evenifthe translogcost function isestimated separately for rel-atively homogeneous samples of banks in terms of total output, therecanstillbesubstantialvariationacrossbanksintermsofone ormoreindividualoutputs.Thisisbecausethevariousoutputsare notperfectlycorrelated.Forinstance,therearebanksthatarelarge intermsofloans,butsmallintermsofsecurities.

Althoughnon-parametricmethodshaveproventheirusefulness inthe modelingof costfunctionsin banking (e.g.,Wheelockand Wilson, 2012; 2018), we confine our analysis to parametric cost functions. The main reason for this choice is that our research questionrequiresusto assesswhetherthe cost functionis sepa-rableintotaloutput.

Inthelightoftheaforementionedproblemsassociatedwiththe translogcost function,we consideranotherparametric cost func-tioninadditiontothetranslog:thegeneralizedLeontiefcost func-tion (Diewert, 1971; Fuss, 1977). Generalized Leontief technolo-gieshave been widely used in banking and other fields, both in asingle- andamulti-product context(e.g.,Thomsen, 2000; Gun-ning and Sickles, 2011; Martín-Oliver et al., 2013; Miller et al., 2013). Multi-product Leontiefcost functions alreadydate back to

Hall (1973). Some basic properties of the translog and general-ized Leontief cost functions are discussed in Appendix C, where itisshownthatbothcostfunctionsdifferintermsofthepossible shapesoftheaverageandmarginalcostfunctions.

4.2.1. Empiricalspecification:translog

We consider a translog cost function similar to

Koetter et al. (2012) and many others. As usual, we impose linearhomogeneityininput pricesbynormalizingtotalcosts and inputpriceswiththepriceofpurchasedfundsw1,it.This normal-ization will be reflected in our notation by the use of variables witha tilde,indicating that they havebeen normalizedwith the priceofpurchasedfunds priorto takingthelogarithmic transfor-mation. Thisresults in thefollowing four-input andthree-output translogcostfunctionforbankiinyeart:

log

(

c it

)

=

α

i+ 4  j=2

β

j,wlog

(

w j,it

)

+

(

1/ 2

)

4  j=2

β

j,ww[log

(

w j,it

)

]2 + 4  j=2  k≥ j

β

jk,wwlog

(

w j,it

)

log

(

w k,it

)

+ 4  k=2 3  =1

β

k,wylog

(

w k,it

)

log

(

y ,it

)

+

3



=1

β

,ylog

(

y ,it

)

+

(

1/ 2

)

3



=1

(9)

Table 3

Sample statistics for U.S. commercial bank data (2011–2017).

ALL CLASS 1 CLASS 2 CLASS 3 CLASS 4

mean s.d. mean s.d. mean s.d. mean s.d. mean s.d.

total loans ( TLNS ) 1,325,996 20,796,483 35,785 17,721 141,414 74,711 410,014 136,794 9,432,481 57,647,651 total securities ( TSEC ) 465,813 8,532,902 14,960 11,991 51,502 41,431 129,769 89,008 3,313,952 23,724,496 off-balance sheet items (OBS,

Boyd-Gertler)

1,263,169 32,892,009 5,337 5,786 31,486 33,288 123,233 96,137 9,682,341 91,763,741 off-balance sheet items (ANII, adjusted

non-interest income)

28,940 659,572 170 181 990 1,014 3,771 2,883 219,849 1,837,628 total assets ( TA ) 2,340,214 43,338,155 62,531 24,578 222,826 99,989 613,052 155,562 16,849,638 120,490,743 total costs ( C ) 47,032 826,296 1,505 673 5,349 2,608 14,896 4,669 332,469 2,296,058 equity ratio ( EQ / TA ) 10.8% 2.7% 11.1% 3.2% 10.7% 2.6% 10.5% 2.3% 10.9% 2.6% revenue share total loans ( ω1 ) 75.5% 14.0% 78.1% 14.1% 76.1% 13.1% 73.9% 13.6% 69.5% 14.9% revenue share total securities ( ω2 ) 13.8% 11.8% 15.4% 13.6% 14.0% 11.7% 12.0% 9.9% 11.5% 8.5% revenue share off-balance sheet items

( ω3 )

10.7% 10.0% 6.5% 6.1% 9.9% 8.3% 14.2% 11.2% 19.0% 14.7% output share total loans ( ˜ ω1 ) 62.7% 17.0% 64.2% 18.1% 63.3% 16.5% 61.9% 16.3% 57.6% 16.6% output share total securities ( ˜ ω2 ) 23.2% 15.6% 26.6% 17.8% 23.5% 15.3% 19.7% 13.0% 17.8% 10.9% output share off-balance sheet items

( ˜ ω3 )

14.2% 12.4% 9.2% 8.4% 13.2% 10.5% 18.5% 13.6% 24.6% 17.3% average revenue total loans 5.4% 1.0% 5.8% 1.0% 5.4% 0.8% 5.1% 0.9% 4.8% 1.1% average revenue total securities 2.4% 1.3% 2.5% 1.7% 2.4% 1.1% 2.5% 1.2% 2.4% 1.0% average revenue off-balance sheet

items

3.2% 0.6% 3.3% 0.7% 3.2% 0.6% 3.2% 0.7% 3.0% 0.7%

average revenue total assets 4.7% 1.4% 4.4% 1.0% 4.7% 1.1% 4.9% 1.5% 5.1% 2.5% price of purchased funds ( w 1 ) 1.2% 0.8% 1.1% 1.0% 1.2% 0.7% 1.3% 0.7% 1.4% 1.0% price or core deposits ( w 2 ) 0.4% 0.3% 0.4% 0.3% 0.4% 0.3% 0.4% 0.3% 0.4% 0.3%

wage rate ( w 3 ) 68.1 18.0 62.3 15.5 67.1 16.3 72.9 18.9 79.7 21.7

price of physical capital ( w 4 ) 34.5% 43.0% 44.8% 51.4% 30.1% 39.5% 30.5% 38.5% 33.6% 37.1% adjusted non-interest

income/operating income

16.9% 10.7% 13.0% 7.2% 16.1% 9.0% 20.3% 11.9% 25.6% 15.0% deposit service fee/operating income 5.2% 4.1% 5.6% 3.9% 5.1% 3.7% 4.9% 4.5% 5.2% 5.2% fiduciary services/operating income 0.8% 3.1% 0.1% 1.0% 0.6% 2.6% 1.7% 4.5% 2.4% 4.7% total output/total assets 106.8% 357.1% 89.6% 14.6% 102.1% 34.7% 114.0% 52.5% 155.2% 995.6% total revenue/(interest

income + non-interest income)

94.1% 5.1% 92.7% 5.6% 94.6% 4.6% 95.1% 5.0% 94.7% 5.5%

# bank-years 30,185 7,973 15,010 3,360 3,842

# banks 5,281 1,683 3,002 893 816

# years 7 7 7 7 7

Notes: The columns captioned ‘mean’ report sample means, while the columns captioned ‘s.d.’ show sample standard deviations. All level variables are in thousands of $. We classify banks on the basis of their total output in 2017 prices. Size classes in prices of the year 2017: 1: less than $ 100 million, 2: $ 10 0–50 0 million, 3: $ 500 million–1 billion and 4: $ 1 billion. Some banks switch from one size class to another over the years if their total output in 2017 prices changes. For this reason, the sum of the number of banks in each size class exceeds the number of banks in the entire sample.

+ 3  =1  m>

β

m,yylog

(

y ,it

)

log

(

y m,it

)

+

β

 CFlog

(

CF it

)

+ T  s=2

β

sd s+

ε

it, (10)

with

α

i a bank-specific effect, ds a time dummy for year s=

2,...,T, CFit avector ofcontrolfactors (suchasthe equityratio), and

ε

it a zero-meanerror termthat is orthogonal to the

regres-sors.Foroutput=1,2,3,themarginalcosts(MC)corresponding to(10)equal MC ,it = c it y ,it

logc it

logy ,it = c it y ,it



β

,y+

β

,yylog

(

y ,it

)

+

4



k=2

β

k,wylog

(

w k,it

)

+



m>

β

m,yylog

(

y m,it

)



.

Aggregate costfunctionTocalculatetheaggregateLernerindex, we estimate the following single-output aggregate translog cost functionintermsoftotaloutputortotalassets(y):

log

(

c it

)

=

α

i+ 4  j=2

β

j,wlog

(

w j,it

)

+

(

1/ 2

)

4  j=2

β

j,ww[log

(

w j,it

)

]2 + 4  j=2  k> j

β

jk,wwlog

(

w j,it

)

log

(

w k,it

)

+

4



j=2

β

j,wylog

(

w j,it

)

log

(

y it

)

+

β

ylog

(

y it

)

+

(

1/ 2

)

β

yy[log

(

y it

)

]2+

β

CF log

(

CF it

)

+ T



s=2

β

sd s+

ε

it. (11)

Such a single-output aggregate translog cost function has been usedin manyLernerstudiesinbanking;see thestudies listedin the upperpanel ofTable 1. The marginal costs corresponding to

(11)equal MC A,it=y c it it

logc it

logy it = c it y it



4 j=2

β

j,wylog

(

w j,it

)

+

β

y+

β

yylog

(

y it

)



. (12)

Conditions forseparability in total output Totest for separabil-ity in total output, we must find the parameter restrictions un-der which themulti-product-cost function in(10) reducesto the aggregate cost function in (11), with total output as the aggre-gate output variable.5 It is readily seen that no such parameter

constraintsexist;thetwo costfunctionsare non-nested.Aformal proofofthisstatementisgiveninAppendixC.

5 Following Aizcorbe (1992) , we do not consider approximate separability such as in e.g. Denny and Pinto (1978) and Kim (1986) , but only exact separability in total output.

(10)

The non-nestedness implies that separability in total output willneverhold;themulti-producttranslogcostfunctioniseither separableinadifferentaggregateoutputmeasure,ornotseparable atall.Thisleadstothefollowingresult:

Result4.1. Assume thatbankshaveamulti-producttranslogcost function c(y, w). Then c is not separable intotal output nj=1yj

andLAin(5)isnotconsistentlyaggregatedregardlessofthe

single-outputtranslogcostfunctioncA usedforLA.

Result 4.1 follows directly from Result 3.1, which states that separability in total output is a necessary condition for the ag-gregateLernerindextobe consistentlyaggregated.Result4.1tells us that the aggregate Lerner index based on any single-output translog cost function we may come up with is not consistently aggregated.

4.2.2. Empiricalspecification:generalizedLeontief

We consider a multi-product cost function similar to the

non-homothetic generalized Leontief (NHT-GL) cost function of

Fuss (1977). Withfour inputsandthree outputs, the total input-factorcostsofbankiinyeartaregivenby:

c it =

α

i+ 4  j=1

β

j,ww j,it+ 4  j=1  k> j 3  =1

β

jk,wwyw 1 2 j,itw 1 2 k,ity ,it + 4  j=1 3  =1

β

j,wyw j,ity ,it+12

4  j=1 3  =1

β

j,wyyw j,ity 2,it

+ 4  j=1 3  =1  m>

β

jm,wyyw j,ity ,ity m,it

+

β

CF CFit+ T



s=2

β

sd s+

ε

it. (13)

Here

α

idenotesabank-specificeffect,CFitavectorofcontrol

fac-tors, ds a time dummyfor year s=2,...,T and

ε

it a zero-mean

error termthat is orthogonal to theregressors. The NHT-GL cost function is linearly homogeneous in input prices. The marginal costscorrespondingto(13)aregivenby

MC ,it =

c it

y ,it = 4  j=1  k> j

β

jk,wwyw 1 2 j,itw 1 2 k,it + 4  j=1

β

j,wyw j,it+ 4  j=1

β

j,wyyw j,ity ,it

+ 4  j=1  m>

β

jm,wyyw j,ity m,it, (14)

foroutput=1,2,3.

Aggregate costfunctionTocalculatetheaggregateLernerindex, we also estimate the following single-output aggregate NHT-GL costfunctionintermsoftotaloutputortotalassets(y):

c it =

α

i+ 4  j=1

β

j,ww j,it+ 4  j=1  k> j

β

jk,wwyw 1 2 j,itw 1 2 k,ity it+ 4  j=1

β

j,wyw j,ity it +1 2 4  j=1

β

j,wyyw j,ity 2it+

β

CF CFit+ T  s=2

β

sd s+

ε

it. (15)

Themarginalcostscorrespondingto(15)equal MC A,it =

c it

y it = 4  j=1  k> j

β

jk,wwyw 1 2 j,itw 1 2 k,it + 4  j=1

β

j,wyw j,it+ 4  j=1

β

j,wyyw j,ity it. (16)

Conditions for separability in total output The aggregate

NHT-GL cost function in (15) is a special case of the

multi-product NHT-GL cost function in (13). As shown in Appendix

C, the necessary parameter restrictions for separability in total output are

β

j,wyy=

β

jm,wyy=

β

j,wyyforsome

β

j,wyy,

β

jk,wwy=

β

jk,wwyforsome

β

jk,wwy and

β

j,wy=

β

j,wy forsome

β

j,wy (j,k=

1,...,4, =1,2,3). Under these 40 linearly independent con-straints,themulti-productNHT-GLcostfunctionin(14)reducesto theaggregateNHT-costfunctionin(15).Wecantesttheparameter constraintsusingaWaldtest.

4.3.Costfunctionestimation

Allcostfunctionsareestimatedintermsofdeflatedlevel vari-ables andby using random-effects (RE) estimation.6 The random

effect

α

iineachspecificationcapturesbank-specificheterogeneity,

includingtime-invariant costinefficiencies, uncorrelatedwith the costfunction’s explanatory variables.Any remaining time-varying costinefficienciesarecontainedintheerrortermanddonothave tobespecifiedanyfurtherforconsistentestimation.Inall specifi-cationswe include,bothlinearlyandquadratically,bank ageasa controlfactortoallowfordifferentcostbehaviorofdenovobanks (due to e.g. new technologies). We also include the equity ratio asa control factor, withthe interpretation ofa quasi-fixed input (e.g.,Mester, 1996).7 The cost functionsare estimated separately

foreachofthefoursizeclasses.

5. Empiricalresults

Ourempiricalanalysisstartswiththeestimatesoftherelevant Lerner indices: (i) LA and LeA (the aggregate Lerner indices), (ii)

LWA andLeWA(theweighted-average Lernerindices),(iii)LTLNS(the

Lernerindexfortotalloansandleases),(iv)LTSEC (theLernerindex

fortotalsecurities) and(v) LOBS (theLerner indexforoff-balance

sheetactivities).We willverifywhetherthe estimatedLerner in-dicespassaninitialscreeningbasedoneconomicplausibility. Sub-sequently, we will turn to the empirical aggregate Lerner index, testthethreeconsistencyconditionsandinvestigatetheeconomic consequencesof usingthisindexanyhoweven ifthe consistency conditionsarerejected.

5.1. EstimatedLernerindices

TheestimatedLernerindicesbasedontheNHT-GLcostfunction arereportedinTable4,while theestimatedLernerindicesbased onthepopulartranslogcostfunctionarereportedinAppendixD.

Non-negativity Variousstudies have established some negative valuesfortheestimatedLernerindices(e.g.FonsecaandGonzález, 2010;Jiménezetal.,2013;Coccorese,2014;Huangetal.,2017). Be-causepricesmustweaklyexceedmarginalcostsinequilibrium un-derprofitmaximization, negativevaluesmayindicatethat some-thingiswrong.Wethereforestartwithanegativitycheck onour Lernerestimates.

The figures inTable 4 make clearthat the NHT-GL cost func-tionshardlyeverproducenegativeestimatesoftheLernerindices

LWA,LWAe ,LA,LAe,LTLNSandLOBS. Furthermore,fortheseLerner

in-dicesthe percentageof significantly positive Lernerindicesis al-most100%ineachsizeclass.Tosavespace,wewillthereforeonly investigatetheLernerindexforsecuritiesinmoredetail.

BecausenegativeLernerindicesareonlya potentialconcernif they are significantlynegative, Table 5 provides detailed informa-tiononthesignandsignificanceoftheestimatedLernerindexfor 6 We used the All Urban Consumer Price Index for deflation; see Appendix A. 7 Estimation results based on fixed-effect estimation are similar and available upon request.

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

A breakdown of the balance sheet in different categories of financial instruments measured at fair value or amortized cost, is presented in respectively Exhibit 7 and 8. 77

Concerning leverage risk which is measured by the shareholders’ equity to total assets ratio there can be stated that it has a predominantly negative influence on

The focus in this thesis is on the potential role of a bank in the matchmaking process; on how banks can have a positive influence on the business angel market by

The extra capacity available due to increased market coupling, netting and the connection to Norway diminishes the effects of M&amp;A in period 2008-2010. Below the effects

The developments of the determinants of the interest margin over the period 1995-2005 are presented in Table A.1 in Appendix C. Looking at its most important determinants, the

To explain the estimated market power of different banks and across countries, the Lerner indices of our two outputs (TEA, OBS) model are regressed on a number of bank-

Is a Laser Beam Printer vendor able to exercise sufficient market power in its proprietary aftermarket for consumables enabling it to freely set prices that would positively impact

For the construction of the strategy portfolio the exposure to the factors value, momentum and low-volatility for each stock are calculated given the phase of the business cycle using