• No results found

Rijksuniversiteit  Groningen   Faculty  of  Economics  and  Business

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Rijksuniversiteit  Groningen   Faculty  of  Economics  and  Business"

Copied!
58
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

 

 

 

 

Rijksuniversiteit  Groningen  

Faculty  of  Economics  and  Business  

 

 

 

DISPOSITIONAL  OPTIMISM  AND  PORTFOLIO  COMPOSITION  

Combined  Master’s  Thesis  in  Economics  and  Finance  

EBM000A20  

 

 

 

LOU  HARTMANN  

S  2502836  

 

 

 

Supervisor:  Dr.  Viola  Angelini  

 

 

 

June  2015  

(2)

Abstract:    

In  this  research  project,  we  analyse  the  impact  of  dispositional  optimism  on  the   probability  of  buying  risky  assets.  We  examine  therefore  data  of  the  year  2002  from   Germany,  using  logit  and  multinomial  logit  regression  models.    

At  the  first  view,  we  find  that  optimistic  people  rather  tend  to  hold  safe  assets  only,  but   the  marginal  effect  at  the  mean  of  this  finding  is  close  to  zero.  In  a  second  step,  we   subdivide  the  observations  into  five  different  groups  depending  on  their  level  of  

optimism.  We  find  then  a  parabolic  relationship  between  optimism  and  the  probability   of  holding  risky  assets.  The  probability  is  thus  the  highest  for  people  that  we  qualify  as  

(3)

I  would  like  to  thank  very  much  my  supervisor,  Dr.  Viola  Angelini  for  all  the  useful   feedback  and  support  throughout  the  entire  process  of  writing  this  thesis.    

 

Furthermore,  I  would  like  to  express  my  gratitude  to  Dr.  Mark  Kramer  and  Jun.  Prof.   Israel  Waichman  whose  inspiring  lectures  on  Behavioural  Finance  at  the  

Rijksuniversiteit  Groningen  respectively  the  Ruprechts-­‐Karls-­‐Universität  in  Heidelberg   provoked  my  interest  in  this  topic.    

(4)

DISPOSITIONAL  OPTIMISM  AND  HOUSEHOLD  PORTFOLIO  CHOICES      

1.  INTRODUCTION    

In  traditional  neo-­‐classical  economics,  human  beings  are  usually  considered  to  be  fully   rational.  However,  this  assumption  of  completely  rational  humans  was  already  criticised   in  the  late  19th  century  (Veblen  (1898)).  Indeed,  when  it  comes  to  decision-­‐making,   including  but  not  limited  to  financial  decision-­‐making,  human  behaviour  is  often  not   consistent  with  the  predictions  of  the  models  and  axioms  of  the  neo-­‐classical  utility   theory  (Kahneman  and  Tversky  (1979)).  Among  the  biases  that  lead  humans  to  behave   in  a  different  way  than  predicted  by  the  neo-­‐classical  utility  theory,  the  optimism  bias   plays  a  role.  People  tend  to  be  optimistic  in  an  unrealistic  way  about  future  life  events   (Weinstein  (1980)).    

 

The  goal  of  this  research  project  is  to  figure  out  if  and  how  portfolio  decisions  are   affected  by  dispositional  optimism.    

 

Scheier  and  Carver  (1985)  provide  a  definition  for  dispositional  optimism  in  terms  of   expected  outcomes.  Optimists  tend  to  expect  a  desirable  outcome.  Dispositional   optimism  1  is  thus  a  trait  of  personality  that  leads  to  expectations  of  favourable   outcomes.      

 

In  this  paper,  we  analyse  the  relationship  between  dispositional  optimism  and  the   probability  of  buying  risky  assets.  It  seems  for  two  reasons  intuitive  that  optimism  is   one  of  the  driving  forces  when  people  decide  what  assets  they  want  to  buy.  First  of  all,   optimism  is  likely  to  lead  directly  to  higher  expected  returns  on  assets,  and  second  via   the  channel  of  overconfidence.  Dispositional  optimism  is  likely  to  lead  to  overconfidence   (Nofsinger  (2005)).      

On  an  empirical  basis,  optimistic  persons  tend  to  be  overconfident  (Fabre  and  François-­‐ Heude  (2009))  as  both  biases  are  closely  linked  (Taylor  and  Brown  (1988)).  

Overconfident  persons  tend  to  overestimate  their  abilities  on  the  stock  market  and  may   therefore  have  a  higher  probability  to  buy  risky  assets.  Barber  and  Odean  (2000)  find                                                                                                                  

(5)

that  the  most  active  investors  underperform  the  market  the  most  and  provide   overconfidence  as  explanation  for  this  finding.  Thus,  one  can  expect  a  link  between   overconfidence  and  behaviour  on  the  stock  market.      

 

Portfolio  composition  is  one  of  the  most  complex  financial  decisions  that  individuals   have  to  make  and  is  therefore  worth  being  analysed  in  detail.  A  big  challenge  in  this   research  project  is  to  find  a  valid  way  of  measuring  optimism.    

Puri  and  Robinson  (2007)  analysed  the  relationship  between  financial  decision-­‐making   and  optimism  by  constructing  an  indicator  of  optimism  comparing  self-­‐reported  life   expectancy  and  the  life  expectancy  implied  by  actuarial  life-­‐tables.  They  compared  the   self-­‐reported  expectations  and  the  statistical  life  expectancy  of  the  individuals  and   interpreted  the  expectations  as  optimism  if  they  were  higher  than  the  statistical  life   expectancy  issued  from  the  actuarial  life  tables.    

 

We  use  a  similar  approach,  however,  we  do  not  consider  life  expectancy  but  life  

satisfaction  as  relevant  variable.  In  our  setting,  we  compare  the  expected  life  satisfaction   in  five  years  at  a  given  moment  in  time  to  the  realized  life  satisfaction  five  years  later.   The  idea  behind  our  main  measure  of  optimism  is  that  we  interpret  the  miscalibration   between  expected  life  satisfaction  and  actual  life  satisfaction  in  five  years  from  that   moment  in  time  as  optimism  or  pessimism.    

 

We  have  data  from  the  German  Socio  Economic  Panel  (SOEP).  This  data  is  collected  on   households  in  all  parts  of  Germany.  We  use  the  year  2002  as  it  provides  all  the  relevant   information  we  need  for  this  study:  we  need  data  on  portfolio  composition,  a  bundle  of   control  variables  and  the  data  on  life  satisfaction  that  we  require  to  construct  our   optimism  measures,  i.e.  current  life  satisfaction,  expected  life  satisfaction  in  five  years   and  the  realized  life  satisfaction  five  years  later.  

 

In  the  survey,  people  were  asked  to  self-­‐report  their  life  satisfaction  in  2002  on  a  scale   from  0  to  10.  At  the  same  moment,  they  were  asked  to  report  their  expected  life   satisfaction  in  five  years.  Five  years  later,  in  2007  they  were  asked  again  about  their   current  life  satisfaction.    

(6)

Our  main  measure  of  optimism  compares  the  expected  life  satisfaction  in  2007,  as  it  was   estimated  in  2002  and  the  actual  life  satisfaction  in  2007.  This  variable  is  created  in  the   same  fashion  by  Abolhassani  and  Alessie  (2013).  However,  they  do  not  interpret  this   forecast  error  explicitly  as  optimism  but  as  evidence  that  people  are  not  fully  rational   when  they  make  their  expectations  or  as  evidence  that  new  information  may  appear   during  the  time  period  of  five  years  with  an  impact  on  the  life  satisfaction.  Our  

alternative  measure  of  optimism  just  compares  the  difference  between  the  expectation   for  2007  and  the  life  satisfaction  at  the  moment  when  this  expectation  was  reported,  in   2002.  This  measure  is  used  as  optimism  measure  by  Abolhassani  and  Alessie  (2013).      

This  way  of  measuring  optimism  using  life  satisfaction  as  proxy  was,  as  far  as  we  know,   not  used  before  in  the  literature  to  assess  portfolio  composition.  We  will  present  the   measures  of  optimism  we  use  more  in  detail  in  section  (3).  Unfortunately,  we  only  have   access  to  data  that  indicates  what  types  of  assets  households  own  and  no  information   about  the  proportions  of  the  different  types  of  assets  in  their  portfolio.  We  can  thus  only   evaluate  the  probability  that  a  household  owns  a  certain  type  of  assets  and  not  draw  any   conclusions  about  the  share  of  wealth  in  each  type  of  assets.    

 

This  paper  is  organized  as  follows:  in  section  (2),  we  provide  a  brief  overview  of  the   existing  literature  on  optimism  and  overconfidence  and  explain  the  link  between  these   two  concepts.  In  section  (3),  we  present  the  data  we  use.    

 

(7)

In  section  (6),  we  provide  possible  interpretations  for  these  at  the  first  view  maybe   contradictory  findings.  Finally,  we  conclude  this  research  project  in  section  (7).    

2.  LITERATURE  REVIEW    

In  standard  portfolio  theory,  the  choice  of  assets  should  be  made  by  combining  in  an   efficient  way  maximum  expected  return  and  minimum  variance.  However,  assumptions   have  to  be  made  in  that  case  about  the  expected  return  on  assets  and  covariance  

between  them  (Markowitz  (1952)).  Markowitz  considers  the  formation  of  beliefs  as   „first  stage“  and  the  portfolio  composition  given  the  beliefs  as  the  „second  stage“  of  the   process  of  portfolio  selection.  In  his  analysis,  he  focuses  above  all  on  the  second  stage.   He  defines  portfolios  as  efficient  if  it  is  not  possible  to  get  the  same  expected  return  with   a  lower  variance  and  no  higher  expected  return  with  the  same  variance.  In  order  to   make  the  beliefs  required  to  end  up  with  expectations,  Markowitz  suggested  to  use   statistical  computations  first  and  to  let  adjustments  of  these  forecasts  be  done  by   experts  if  they  consider  this  as  necessary.  He  concludes  however  that  his  well-­‐known   paper  does  not  consider  in  depth  the  first  stage  of  portfolio  composition  (p.91):  „the   formation  of  the  relevant  beliefs  on  the  basis  of  observation.“  

 

In  this  research  project,  we  would  like  to  figure  out  if  and  how  optimism  impacts   portfolio  composition.  Optimism  is  likely  to  have  an  influence  on  the  formation  of   beliefs.  Formation  of  beliefs  is  actually  hard,  if  not  impossible,  to  combine  with  the   concept  of  the  fully  rational  homo  economicus.  A  behavioural  approach  is  therefore  in   our  opinion  required  to  do  so.  Behavioural  economics  is  defined  by  Mullainathan  and   Thaler  (2000)  in  the  abstract  of  their  working  paper  as  „combination  of  economics  and   psychology  that  investigates  what  happens  in  markets  in  which  some  of  the  agents  display   human  limitations  and  complications.“  Optimism  can  be  seen  as  one  of  these  human   complications.    

 

(8)

Brissette,  Scheier  and  Carver  (2002)  find  that  optimistic  people  are  better  able  to  deal   with  stressful  life  events.  Rasmussen,  Scheier  and  Greenhouse  (2009)  conclude,  by   reviewing  83  studies  on  the  topic,  that  optimism  is  a  significant  predictor  for  good   physical  health.    

 

Optimism  and  overconfidence  are  two  similar  and  closely  related  concepts.  Fabre  and   François-­‐Heude  (2009)  provide  the  following  definitions:  optimism  is  (p.80)  „the   tendency  or  inclination  to  perceive  an  event  or  an  action  as  more  likely  to  result  in  a   favourable  outcome,  irrespective  of  the  objective  probability  of  that  outcome  actually   occurring.“  On  the  other  hand,  they  define  overconfidence  as  (p.80)  „the  tendency  to   overestimate  the  probability  of  achieving  one’s  objectives  as  a  result  of  a  presumptuous   belief  in  one’s  abilities  or  attributes  as  they  may  be  used  to  bring  about  a  particular   outcome.“  Thus,  the  main  difference  between  both  concepts  is  the  role  of  one’s  own   impact  on  the  final  outcome.  Furthermore,  as  Fabre  and  François-­‐Heude  underline,   Scheier  and  Carver  (1985)  argue  that  dispositional  optimism  is  stable  in  nature,   whereas  McGraw  et  al.  (2004)  showed  that  some  information  on  the  overconfidence   bias  during  a  five-­‐minute-­‐break  is  already  enough  to  significantly  reduce  

overconfidence.      

Weinstein  (1980)  finds  in  a  study  that  students  tend  to  suffer  from  an  optimistic  bias,   especially  in  situations  that  seem  controllable  to  them,  which  shows  thus  that  there  is  a   strong  link  between  the  concepts  of  optimism  and  overconfidence.    

This  finding  is  in  line  with  the  one  of  Langer  (1975)  who  finds  that  people  think  they   have  an  influence  in  situations  in  which  the  outcome  is  basically  decided  by  luck.  Also   Svenson  (1981)  shows  evidence  of  overconfidence:  he  concludes  that  80%  of  the  

students  in  his  study  would  consider  themselves  as  being  in  the  top  30%  of  car  drivers.      

(9)

with  increasing  mood  like  optimism  lead  to  overconfidence.  According  to  Hilton  (2001),   the  idea  of  being  better  than  the  average,  which  actually  is  driven  by  overconfidence,  is   part  of  the  optimism  bias  definition.    

 

So,  there  is  evidence  from  the  literature  that  people  tend  to  suffer  from  optimism  and   overconfidence  biases  and  that  the  concepts  are  indeed  closely  related.  This  is  likely  to   have  an  impact  on  financial  decisions.    

 

Odean  (1998)  shows  that  overconfidence  is  a  potential  source  of  inefficient  decision-­‐ making.  This  finding  is  confirmed  by  a  paper  of  Barber  and  Odean  (2000):  they  conclude   that  active  retail  investors  underperform  the  market  the  most  and  they  explain  this   observation  basically  by  the  overconfidence  of  these  active  investors.  Barber  and  Odean   (2002)  drew  similar  conclusions  when  analysing  the  switch  to  online  trading  in  the   1990s.  The  retail  investors  who  made  strong  performances  on  the  financial  markets   with  phone  based  trading  were  likely  to  switch  to  online  trading.  Their  good  earlier   performances  lead  to  overconfidence.  When  trading  online,  these  investors  traded  much   more  and  showed  worse  performances.    

 

Puri  and  Robinson  (2007)  show  an  empiric  relation  between  optimism  and  a  broad   range  of  economic  and  financial  variables.  Using  data  from  the  United  States,  they  find   that  optimistic  individuals  are  more  likely  to  invest  in  individual  stocks  rather  than   mutual  funds  or  other  equity  investment  vehicles.  Furthermore,  they  test  whether   moderate  and  extreme  optimists  behave  in  the  same  fashion  and  find  several  differences   between  these  two  types  of  optimists:  moderate  optimists  take  rather  prudent  economic   decisions,  whereas  extreme  optimists  do  not.  They  finally  conclude  that  moderate  

optimism  can  improve  the  economic  decision-­‐making,  whereas  extreme  optimism  is   clearly  bad.    

 

(10)

Sengmuller  conclude  that  some  investors  get  some  non-­‐monetary  benefits  from  trading.   What  they  call  „entertainment  trading“  can  be  seen  as  some  kind  of  leisure  activity  that   increases  utility,  even  though  it  may  even  lead  to  losses.  In  a  similar  spirit,  Kumar  finds   that  some  people’s  desire  to  gamble  impacts  their  behaviour  on  the  stock  market,  even   though  they  underperform  institutional  investors.    

 

Given  the  existing  literature,  it  seems  very  likely  that  optimism  somehow  impacts   financial  decision-­‐making.  We  would  like  to  confirm  or  reject  this  hypothesis  using  data   from  Germany.  If  we  find  evidence  that  optimism  has  an  influence  on  portfolio  

composition,  we  would  like  to  assess  that  impact.      

3.  DATA  AND  METHODOLOGY    

The  data  we  use  to  conduct  this  study  is  issued  from  the  German  Socio  Economic  Panel   (SOEP).  Wagner,  Frick  and  Schupp  (2007)  describe  this  panel  in  detail.  The  SOEP  exists   since  1984  and  the  DIW  Berlin,  the  German  Institute  for  Economic  Research,  hosts  it.   Every  year,  more  than  10000  private  households  are  sampled.    

 

In  this  study,  we  focus  especially  on  data  concerning  the  year  2002,  as  it  is  this  year  over   which  we  get  all  the  relevant  data  on  expected  life  satisfaction  in  five  years  and  portfolio   composition  that  are  crucial  for  this  study.  Some  questions,  such  as  the  life  satisfaction   in  five  years,  are  not  asked  in  every  questionnaire  but  only  in  some  waves.  So,  most  of   our  variables  are  included  in  the  SOEP  core  study  of  2002  and  the  questionnaire  of   2003,  asking  about  the  behaviour  of  individuals  and  households  in  the  previous  year.   We  assume  that  the  decision-­‐making  is  done  jointly  at  the  household  level.  We  therefore   consider  all  individuals  within  a  household,  but  we  will  cluster  the  standard  errors  to   take  intra-­‐household  correlation  into  account.  Furthermore,  we  use  a  self-­‐assessed  risk   attitude  measure  of  the  individuals.  This  self-­‐assessment  was  done  in  2004.  In  order  to   construct  the  optimism  measure,  we  also  have  to  take  into  account  the  self-­‐assessed  life   satisfaction  in  2007.    

(11)

a)  How  to  measure  optimism?      

The  common  measure  of  optimism  that  is  often  used  in  psychology  is  the  Life   Orientation  Test  LOT  (Scheier  and  Carver  (1985))  and  its  successor  LOT-­‐R,  the  Life   Orientation  Test  Revised  (Scheier,  Carver  and  Bridges  (1994)).  As  we  do  not  dispose  of   data  from  LOT  or  LOT-­‐R  tests,  we  need  to  create  a  proxy  for  optimism.    

Puri  and  Robinson  (2007)  developed  an  indicator  of  dispositional  optimism  based  on   the  difference  between  self-­‐reported  life  expectancy  and  the  life  expectancy  implied  by   actuarial  life-­‐tables.  This  miscalibration  was  used  then  to  investigate  the  relationship   between  optimism  and  a  wide  range  of  economic  outcomes.  

 

Following  this  idea,  we  also  compare  two  variables  to  measure  optimism.  Whereas  Puri   and  Robinson  used  expected  and  actuarial  life  expectation,  we  focus  on  life  satisfaction.      

First,  in  2002,  people  were  on  an  individual  level  asked  to  assess  their  expected  life   satisfaction  in  five  years  on  a  scale  from  0  to  10.  Five  years  later,  in  2007,  people  were   asked  about  their  current  life  satisfaction,  again  on  a  scale  from  0  to  10.  We  compare  the   expected  future  life  satisfaction  as  it  is  reported  in  2002  and  the  actual  life  satisfaction  in   2007.  The  difference  can  thus  range  between  -­‐10  and  10.  This  is  a  way  to  measure  the   gap  between  an  expectation  in  2002  and  the  real  situation  five  years  later.  It  can  thus  be   interpreted  as  optimism  if  it  is  positive  -­‐  and  as  pessimism  otherwise.  In  figure  1,  we   show  the  distribution  of  self-­‐reported  life  satisfaction  in  2007.  In  figure  2,  the  expected   life-­‐satisfaction  in  2007,  reported  in  2002,  is  shown.    

(12)

  Figure  1:  histogram  of  the  self-­‐reported  life  satisfaction  in  2007    

 

Figure  2:  histogram  of  the  expected  life  satisfaction  in  2007,  reported  in  2002    

In  this  setting,  we  need  to  have  data  from  the  same  individuals  in  2002  and  2007.  We   furthermore  only  can  use  those  observations  where  there  is  also  information  available   on  the  assets  owned  by  their  household  and  on  the  control  variables  described  later  in   this  section.  For  these  reasons,  we  can  use  only  14566  observations,  even  though  almost   24000  reported  their  life  satisfaction  in  2002.  If  we  consider  only  the  individuals  who   live  in  a  household  that  reported  to  own  at  least  some  assets,  we  are  left  with  13211   observations.  The  descriptive  statistics  of  these  samples  are  reported  in  detail  in  

(13)

even  higher  than  they  expected  it.  The  opposite  holds  for  people  who  reported  0  

initially.  About  1%  of  our  observations  reported  twice  a  life  satisfaction  of  10,  less  than   0.1%  reported  twice  a  life  satisfaction  of  0.  We  will  consider  these  observations  as   „neutral  optimists“.  In  table  1,  we  present  the  frequencies  of  the  self-­‐reported  levels  of   expected  life  satisfaction  in  five  years  and  the  current  life-­‐satisfaction  in  2007.    

 

Table  1:  Frequencies  of  self-­‐reported  expected  life  satisfaction  in  five  years  from  now  in  2002  and  actual   life  satisfaction  in  2007:    

  Exp.   Act.   0   1   2   3   4   5   6   7   8   9   10   Total   0   4   4   2   6   2   9   4   4   4   1   0   40   1   2   5   7   6   5   10   5   12   7   2   2   63   2   6   4   19   18   24   25   22   19   33   11   5   186   3   6   3   23   26   34   80   48   57   67   17   6   367   4   1   2   26   35   51   101   74   93   81   18   7   489   5   7   7   31   96   117   350   241   285   272   84   30   1520   6   1   6   19   41   95   227   270   370   419   126   45   1619   7   5   5   22   45   96   301   371   719   1006   360   98   3028   8   4   1   10   32   60   227   283   723   1643   818   280   4081   9   1   3   4   6   7   40   51   178   449   503   199   1441   10   1   0   0   1   7   15   19   38   77   83   136   377   Total   38   40   163   312   498   1385   1388   2498   4058   2023   808   13211    

If  we  consider  these  13211  observations,  which  are  our  most  restrictive  sample,  we   identify  an  average  level  of  optimism  of  0.257.  So,  the  average  observation  of  this   dataset  is  what  we  will  qualify  later  as  a  neutral  optimist.    

 

In  order  to  distinguish  between  mild  and  extreme  optimism,  Puri  and  Robinson  

(14)

some  observations  with  an  optimism  level  if  3  as  strong  optimists  and  some  others  as   mild  optimists,  which  would  in  our  opinion  not  make  that  much  sense.    

As  our  measure  of  optimism  is  a  discrete  one,  we  prefer  to  replace  this  definition  of   extreme  optimism  by  an  absolute  one.  

 

If  the  level  of  optimism  computed  in  this  way  is  3  or  higher,  we  qualify  individuals  as   „strongly  optimistic.“  In  the  same  way,  we  qualify  people  with  a  negative  level  of   optimism  of  -­‐3  or  lower  as  „strongly  pessimistic.“    

 

According  to  this  measure,  9.36%  of  these  13211  observations  are  strong  optimists  and   6.21%  are  strong  pessimists.  The  remaining  observations  are  subdivided  into  weak   optimists,  who  have  a  level  of  optimism  of  1  or  2,  neutral  optimists  with  a  level  of   optimism  of  0,  and  weak  pessimists  for  which  we  found  a  level  of  optimism  of  -­‐1  or  -­‐2.     32.76%  of  the  population  are  weakly  optimistic,  28.20%  neutral  and  23.46%  weakly   pessimistic.    

 

As  alternative  optimism  measure,  we  focus  on  the  gap  between  the  self-­‐reported   estimated  life-­‐satisfaction  in  five  years  and  the  current  life  satisfaction.  As  the  current   life  satisfaction  and  the  expected  life-­‐satisfaction  in  five  years  have  both  been  rated  on  a   scale  from  0  to  10,  the  difference  can  range  here  once  again  between  -­‐10  and  10.  The   idea  behind  this  measure  is  that  optimistic  people  are  likely  to  think  that  their  life   satisfaction  will  go  up  in  the  future,  using  their  current  life  satisfaction  as  a  benchmark.   The  interpretation  of  the  optimism  levels  can  be  done  in  the  same  way  than  with  the   optimism  measure  described  earlier.  Both  indicators  have  been  constructed  in  the  same   way  by  Abolhassani  and  Alessie  (2013).    

 

(15)

The  mean  optimism  level  in  this  sample  excluding  the  observations  without  any  assets  is   however  smaller,  0.008.      

Note  that  using  this  alternative  measure  of  optimism,  and  the  same  definitions  of  strong-­‐   weak-­‐  and  neutral  optimism  as  earlier,  we  have  a  much  larger  fraction  of  neutral  

optimists:  50.27%  of  the  individuals  can  be  qualified  as  neutral,  23.28%  as  weakly   optimistic,  20.32%  as  weakly  pessimistic.  Only  2.80%  are  strongly  optimistic  and  3.33%   strongly  pessimistic.  

 

Indeed,  the  correlation  coefficient  between  the  self-­‐reported  life  satisfaction  in  2002  and   the  estimation  for  the  life  satisfaction  in  five  years,  done  in  2002  is  0.7249,  whereas  the   correlation  coefficient  between  the  estimation  for  the  life  satisfaction  in  five  years  and   the  actual  life  satisfaction  five  years  later  is  only  0.4473.  

 

Thus  in  total,  we  have  four  different  samples  that  we  will  use  to  run  regressions:  two   samples  include  observations  of  life  satisfaction  in  2007  and  two  do  not.  In  both  cases,   one  of  the  samples  includes  the  observations  without  any  assets  and  the  other  does  not.   Detailed  descriptive  statistics  tables  of  the  four  samples  we  use  are  reported  in  appendix   A.    

 

To  check  for  validity,  Puri  and  Robinson  compared  their  optimism  measure  with  the   outcome  of  the  LOT-­‐R  questionnaire.  As  we  do  not  dispose  from  data  about  this  test,  we   verify  whether  three  kinds  of  worries  of  the  individuals  in  2002  are  correlated  and  have   a  significant  impact  on  our  optimism  measure.    

 

The  three  kinds  of  worries  we  take  into  account  are  the  following:  1)  Economic  worries,   2)  Job  worries  and  3)  Peace  worries.  Worries  about  economic  development  may  be  a   proxy  for  pessimism  in  financial  matters.  Being  worried  about  the  own  job  security  is   strongly  linked  to  the  personal  situation  of  the  individuals  and  will  therefore  probably,   just  as  the  general  view  on  economic  development,  influence  the  financial  decision-­‐ making.  The  peace  worries  are  rather  driven  by  the  character  or  the  attitude  of  a  person,   as  the  risk  exposure  to  military  conflicts  in  Germany  is  actually  the  same  for  each  

(16)

from  1  to  3,  where  3  means  very  concerned,  2  somewhat  concerned  and  1  not  concerned   at  all.    

 

We  find  that  there  is  a  negative  statistical  significant  pairwise  correlation  between  our   measure  of  optimism  and  each  of  the  three  types  of  worries,  which  means  that  people   who  are  less  concerned  by  these  worries  are  rather  optimistic.  Furthermore,  running  a   linear  regression  of  optimism  on  the  three  types  of  worries  and  a  bundle  of  control   variables,  we  find  that  each  of  the  three  worries  is  significant  at  the  1%  level.  People   who  worry  more  are  significantly  less  optimistic  according  to  our  optimism  measure.   The  same  holds  for  our  alternative  measure  of  optimism.  These  correlations  and  linear   regressions  will  be  reported  in  the  appendix  B.    

 

b)  How  to  measure  portfolio  composition?      

In  order  to  assess  the  portfolio  composition  of  the  households,  we  subdivided  the  assets   of  households  into  three  different  risk  classes,  in  a  similar  way  as  it  was  done  by  

Barasinska,  Schäfer  and  Stephan  (2008):  saving  accounts  and  home  ownership  saving   contracts  are  considered  as  safe  assets,  life  insurance  policies  and  fixed  interested   securities  are  considered  as  relatively  risky  assets  and  other  securities  and  operating   assets  are  considered  as  risky  assets.    

 

The  data  on  portfolio  composition  is  collected  at  the  household  level.  One  person  of  each   household  reported  the  types  of  assets.  We  assume  through  the  whole  analysis  that  the   decisions  are  taken  jointly  within  a  household,  so  that  we  do  not  consider  the  

individuals  who  reported  the  portfolio  composition  only.  We  include  all  the  individuals   of  the  households  over  which  we  have  data  on  the  portfolio  composition  into  the  sample.      

(17)

who  hold  assets  that  we  earlier  qualified  as  relatively  risky  but  no  risky  assets,  no   matter  whether  they  hold  safe  assets  or  not,  and  3)  the  risky  assets  holders,  who  hold   among  others  also  other  securities  and  operating  assets.  Note  that  the  four  categories,   no  assets,  safe  assets  only,  relatively  risky  asset  holders  and  risky  asset  holders  are   mutually  exclusive.    

 

Including  the  individuals  of  households  that  report  not  to  possess  any  assets  in  the   sample  of  our  initial  measure  of  optimism,  9.33%  are  non-­‐asset  holders,  17.28%  have   safe  assets  only,  35.51%  are  qualified  as  relatively  risky  asset  holders  and  the  remaining   37.91%  do  have  risky  assets  in  their  portfolio.  Excluding  the  observations  without  any   assets,  we  have  19.06%  safe  asset  holders,  39.15%  relatively  risky  asset  holders,  and   41.80%  risky  asset  holders.  

 

As  already  mentioned,  in  most  of  our  settings  we  drop  all  the  no  asset  holders  from  the   sample  and  we  only  take  into  account  the  individuals  of  households  that  possess  at  least   some  assets  as  we  think  that  households  that  report  not  to  hold  any  assets  are  not  useful   to  draw  any  conclusions  about  the  link  between  optimism  and  portfolio  composition.  In   this  case,  we  only  have  three  categories,  safe,  relatively  risky  and  risky,  which  are  still   mutually  exclusive.  Nonetheless,  we  will  include  the  individuals  of  households  without   assets  in  some  settings  in  order  to  check  for  the  robustness  of  our  findings.  

In  some  set-­‐ups,  we  will  merge  the  categories  of  relatively  risky  and  risky  asset  holders.      

c)  What  control  variables  do  we  include?      

In  a  first  step,  we  will  consider  the  control  variables  used  by  Puri  and  Robinson  (2007)   in  order  to  replicate  their  results  as  closely  as  possible.  However,  several  adaptations   have  to  be  made,  given  that  we  use  a  different  optimism  measure  and  have  a  different   set  of  data.  The  independent  variables  used  by  Puri  and  Robinson  are:  optimism,  age,   college,  excellent  health,  male,  net  worth,  risk  tolerance,  self-­‐employed  and  white.      

(18)

variable  when  it  comes  to  decision-­‐making  about  portfolio  composition.  We  furthermore   replace  the  variable  „white“  by  dummy  variables  of  the  German  regions.  We  think  that  in   Germany  in  2002,  the  regions  where  people  live  have  a  more  important  impact  than  the   ethnical  background  of  the  people  on  their  portfolio  composition.    

 

The  age  of  the  individuals  in  our  sample  of  the  initial  measure  of  optimism,  excluding  the   individuals  without  assets,  ranges  from  17  to  92  years.  The  average  age  is  approximately   46  and  a  half  year.  We  do  not  take  into  account  the  different  types  of  higher  education   that  exist  in  Germany,  such  as  for  example  universities  or  Fachhochschulen,  but  we  only   consider  whether  or  not  the  individuals  got  a  degree  of  higher  education  in  our  college   dummy.  Also  higher  education  degrees  obtained  outside  Germany  are  included  in  this   dummy  variable.  In  the  most  restrictive  sample,  21.66%  of  the  asked  individuals  do  have   a  higher  education  degree.  Furthermore,  we  control  for  male  individuals  as  well  as  for   self-­‐employed  ones.  Self-­‐employed  people  may  have  another  perception  of  risk  in   financial  matters  and  therefore  behave  in  a  different  way  while  making  financial   decisions  than  people  who  are  employed  or  retired.  For  these  reasons,  it  may  be   interesting  to  control  for  self-­‐employment.  

48.12%  of  the  participants  of  the  survey  are  male  and  5.96%  are  self-­‐employed  in  the   sample  with  13211  observations.    

 

Puri  and  Robinson  mainly  control  for  health  because  their  measure  of  optimism  is   directly  linked  to  life  expectancy,  which  is  among  others  driven  by  the  current  state  of   health  of  a  person.    

Even  though  our  measure  of  optimism  is  not  directly  linked  to  health,  we  will  also   control  for  health  in  our  regressions.  It  is  possible  that  people  who  have  a  good  state  of   health  are  more  likely  to  have  a  longer  planning  horizon.  Therefore  they  may  make   other  financial  decision  than  people  who  suffer  from  illnesses.  We  include  a  dummy   variable  into  the  regressions  that  takes  the  value  1  if  people  reported  that  they  have  a   very  good  state  of  health  and  0  otherwise.    

 

Income  and  wealth  are  likely  to  play  a  crucial  role  in  portfolio  composition.  The  income   we  take  into  account  is  the  monthly  net  household  income.  The  monthly  average  

(19)

again  the  household  level.  As  only  few  participants  of  the  SOEP  core  study  provide   complete  and  detailed  information  about  their  wealth  missing  values  were  imputed.   Both  of  these  measures  are  expressed  per  thousands  of  euros  in  all  our  regressions.    

As  our  dataset  is  representative  for  Germany  around  the  year  2000,  it  seems  more   interesting  to  control  for  the  region  where  people  are  from  rather  than  for  the  skin   colour,  as  it  was  done  by  Puri  and  Robinson,  who  used  data  from  the  United  States.  We   therefore  subdivide  Germany  into  five  regions:  North,  South,  East,  West  and  Berlin.  As   North,  we  define  the  Bundesländer  Schleswig-­‐Holstein,  Niedersachsen,  Hamburg  and   Bremen,  as  West  Nordrhein-­‐Westfalen,  Hessen  and  Rheinland-­‐Pfalz,  as  South  Saarland,   Baden-­‐Württemberg  and  Bayern,  as  East  Thüringen,  Sachsen,  Sachsen-­‐Anhalt,  

Mecklenburg-­‐Vorpommern  and  Brandenburg.  In  the  most  restrictive  sample,  13.36%  of   the  individuals  in  are  from  the  North,  27.48%  from  the  South,  31.35%  from  the  West,   24.21%  from  the  East  and  3.60%  are  from  Berlin.  The  proportions  are  roughly  

unchanged  in  the  three  other  samples.      

In  the  SOEP  questionnaire  of  2002,  there  is  no  question  included  concerning  the  self-­‐ reported  risk  attitude  of  the  individuals.  We  therefore  assume  that  the  risk  attitude  did   not  change  between  2002  and  2004  and  measure  the  risk-­‐attitude  using  the  scale  from  0   to  10  on  which  the  individuals  were  asked  in  2004  to  rate  their  own  willingness  to  take   risk  in  financial  matters.  A  high  reported  numbers  reflects  a  high  willingness  to  take   risks  in  financial  matters.    

 

d)  What  methodology  do  we  use?      

The  first  regressions  we  will  run  are  logit  regressions.  We  prefer  logit  to  probit   regressions  in  order  to  stay  consistent  with  the  multinomial  logit  regressions  that  we   will  run  later.  As  dependent  variable,  we  will  use  mainly  the  dummy  variable  risky   assets.  We  will  also  run  the  same  regressions  using  another  dummy  variable  that  we  will   call  „relatively  risky  and  risky“  and  takes  the  value  of  1  if  an  observation  is  qualified  as   relatively  risky  or  risky  asset  holder  and  0  otherwise.    

(20)

measure  of  optimism.  Then,  in  a  second  step,  we  replace  that  one  by  our  alternative   measure  of  optimism.    

In  order  to  get  a  clearer  view  on  the  impact  of  optimism,  we  will  then  in  a  third  step   replace  the  measures  of  optimism  going  from  -­‐10  to  10  by  five  dummy  variables:  strong   optimism,  weak  optimism,  neutral  optimism,  weak  pessimism  and  strong  pessimism.  As   already  stated,  we  qualify  people  as  strongly  optimistic  or  pessimistic  if  their  level  of   optimism  is  in  absolute  terms  larger  than  3.  Weak  optimism  means  that  their  level  of   optimism  is  1  or  2,  weak  pessimism  -­‐1  or  -­‐2  and  neutral  optimism  0.  Finally,  we  will  run   multinomial  logit  regressions.  There,  we  use  the  three  asset  classes  safe,  relatively  risky   and  risky  as  dependent  variables  and  regress  them  on  the  measure  of  optimism  and  the   usual  bundle  of  control  variables.  As  already  stated,  we  will  cluster  the  standard  errors   to  take  intra-­‐household  correlation  into  account.  The  results  of  these  regressions  will  be   provided  in  the  following  section.    

 

4.  RESULTS    

First,  we  regressed  risky  as  well  as  relatively  risky  and  risky  assets  onto  the  discrete   optimism  variable  and  the  bundle  of  control  variables  we  described  earlier,  including   the  five  different  regions  we  defined  in  section  (3).  Table  2  shows  the  outcome  of  these   regressions  excluding  the  observations  that  hold  no  assets  at  all.  The  same  regressions,   including  the  observations  without  any  assets  can  be  found  in  appendix  D1.  In  order  to   stay  consistent  with  the  multinomial  logit  regressions  we  will  run  later  in  this  section,   we  will  use  logit  regressions  to  estimate  the  impact  of  the  different  variables  onto  the  

(21)

Table  2:  Logit  regression  of  the  dummy  variables  risky  assets  and  “relatively  risky  and  risky  assets“  onto   our  standard  measure  of  optimism  and  the  usual  bundle  of  control  variables  excluding  the  observations   without  assets.  Standard  errors  are  clustered  at  the  household  level.  Marginal  effects  are  measured  at  the   mean.           Coefficients:       Marginal  Effects:       VARIABLES   RISKY   REL.  RISKY+  

RISKY   RISKY   REL.  RISKY  +  RISKY               Optimism   -­‐0.019   -­‐0.051***   -­‐0.005   -­‐0.005***     (0.012)   (0.015)   (0.003)   (0.002)   Age   -­‐0.016***   -­‐0.027***   -­‐0.004***   -­‐0.003***     (0.002)   (0.002)   (0.000)   (0.000)   Male   -­‐0.196***   -­‐0.022   -­‐0.048***   -­‐0.002     (0.026)   (0.032)   (0.006)   (0.003)   College   0.578***   0.275***   0.142***   0.028***     (0.056)   (0.081)   (0.014)   (0.008)   Self-­‐Employed   0.440***   0.623***   0.108***   0.063***     (0.097)   (0.169)   (0.024)   (0.017)   Risk  Tolerance   0.206***   0.125***   0.051***   0.013***     (0.011)   (0.014)   (0.002)   (0.002)   Household  Income  2   0.221***   0.501***   0.054***   0.051***     (0.026)   (0.051)   (0.007)   (0.005)   Net  Wealth  3   0.218***   0.237***   0.054***   0.024***     (0.021)   (0.035)   (0.005)   (0.003)   Very  Good  Health   -­‐0.221***   -­‐0.288***   -­‐0.054***   -­‐0.030***     (0.077)   (0.102)   (0.019)   (0.010)   North   -­‐0.245   -­‐0.102   -­‐0.060   -­‐0.010     (0.158)   (0.192)   (0.039)   (0.020)   West   -­‐0.396***   -­‐0.029   -­‐0.097***   -­‐0.003     (0.147)   (0.179)   (0.036)   (0.018)   South   -­‐0.462***   -­‐0.284   -­‐0.114***   -­‐0.029     (0.149)   (0.182)   (0.037)   (0.018)   East   -­‐0.197   0.146   -­‐0.048*   0.015     (0.148)   (0.179)   (0.036)   (0.018)   Constant   -­‐0.881***   0.985***         (0.173)   (0.224)         Observations       13,211   13,211       Log  likelihood     Pseudo  R2   -­‐7572.895     0.157   -­‐5440.802     0.154        

Standard  errors  in  parentheses  

***  p<0.01,  **  p<0.05,  *  p<0.1    

                                                                                                               

(22)

 

The  unreported  regression  of  safe  assets  only  onto  the  same  explanatory  variables   provides  the  same  significance  levels  and  the  opposite  sign  for  each  and  every  variable   than  the  relatively  risky  and  risky  regression,  as  the  three  categories  of  asset  holders  are   mutually  exclusive  and  the  non-­‐asset  holders  are  dropped  from  the  sample.    

 

We  find  that  optimism  is  negatively  correlated  to  holding  relatively  risky  or  risky  assets,   but  the  impact  on  risky  assets  only  is  not  significant.  The  marginal  effect  of  optimism  at   the  mean  is  in  the  case  of  relatively  risky  assets  -­‐0.005.  The  marginal  effect  is  thus   negative,  but  really  close  to  0.    

 

We  furthermore  find  that  age  reduces  the  likelihood  of  holding  risky  assets  and  that   female  participants  of  the  study  are  more  likely  to  hold  risky  assets  than  males.  The   gender  has  however  no  significant  effect  any  more  when  we  consider  risky  and   relatively  risky  assets  at  the  same  time.  As  we  assumed  that  members  of  a  household   decide  together  on  the  portfolio  composition,  we  will  not  put  too  much  weight  on  this   finding.    

College  education,  self-­‐employment,  a  self-­‐reported  risk  loving  attitude  in  financial   matters,  high  income  and  high  net  wealth  increase  the  probability  of  holding  risky   assets.    

 

The  fact  that  people  with  higher  income  and  higher  net  wealth  are  more  likely  to  hold   risky  assets  is  probably  linked  to  the  fact  that  they  need  to  spend  a  lower  share  of  their   income  or  wealth  on  consumption  goods.  As  they  can  save  more,  they  are  likely  to  have  a   rather  diversified  portfolio  –  including  risky  assets.    

 

(23)

are  more  likely  to  have  risky  assets.  Being  able  to  take  the  right  financial  decisions  is  a   required  quality  in  both  cases:  if  people  want  to  become  self-­‐employed  and  if  people   want  to  become  active  on  the  stock  market,  so  it  is  not  surprising  that  in  many  cases,   self-­‐employed  people  also  own  risky  assets.    

 

A  very  good  health  makes  it  less  likely  to  hold  risky  assets,  which  is  at  the  first  view   maybe  counter-­‐intuitive.  It  could  be  that  this  is  just  due  to  the  reporting  style  of  the   people,  that  some  are  just  more  „enthusiastic“  about  reporting  their  health.  However,  it   is  also  possible  that  reporting  a  very  good  health  includes  another  dimension  of  risk   aversion.  People  who  report  that  their  health  is  „very  good“  instead  of  „good“  are  more   likely  to  have  done  regular  medical  checks  which  give  them  the  possibility  to  have  a   clearer  picture  of  their  state  of  health.  This  attitude  may  capture  a  non-­‐financial  type  of   risk  aversion.  To  check  whether  this  explanation  holds,  we  replace  in  the  regression  the   dummy  variable  very  good  health  by  a  dummy  variable  „healthy“,  which  includes  all   people  that  reported  to  have  a  good  or  very  good  health.  In  this  case,  there  is  no   significant  effect  of  health  on  portfolio  composition  any  more.  These  regressions  are   reported  in  appendix  C.    

 

Concerning  the  regions  of  Germany,  the  people  from  the  South  and  from  the  West  tend   to  have  a  lower  probability  of  holding  risky  assets  than  people  in  Berlin.  Controlling  for   all  the  other  variables  we  have  reported  in  this  table,  it  is  possible  that  regional  cultural   differences  in  financial  matters  are  the  reason  for  this  finding.  It  may  be  that  people  in   the  South  and  in  the  West  have  a  more  conservative  way  of  dealing  with  their  savings   than  people  in  other  parts  of  Germany.  In  appendix  G,  we  decompose  the  regions  into   the  different  Bundesländer.  We  see  that  the  coefficient  is  negative  and  significant  at  the   1-­‐percent-­‐level  in  Nordrhein-­‐Westfalen  (West),  Rheinland-­‐Pfalz  (West)  and  Baden-­‐ Württemberg  (South),  but  also  in  Schleswig-­‐Holstein  (North).  In  Bayern  (South),  the   coefficient  is  negative,  but  significant  at  the  10-­‐percent-­‐level  only.  In  the  other  Länder   that  we  consider  as  South  or  West,  i.e.  Saarland  (South)  and  Hessen  (West),  there  is  no   significant  effect.  When  we  consider  relatively  risky  and  risky  assets  together,  the  effects   of  the  regions  in  Germany  are  insignificant.      

(24)

In  a  second  step,  we  keep  the  same  dependent  variables  and  the  same  control  variables,   however  we  replace  our  initial  measure  of  optimism  by  the  alternative  optimism  

measure,  which  we  defined  as  the  difference  between  the  expected  life  satisfaction  in   five  years  and  the  current  life  satisfaction.  These  results  are  reported  in  Table  3.  The   findings  in  this  setting  are  similar  to  the  ones  of  the  initial  optimism  measure:  optimism   has  again  no  significant  impact  on  risky  assets  only,  but  there  is  still  a  negative  impact  of   optimism  onto  holding  relatively  risky  or  risky  assets.  In  this  setting,  the  marginal  effect   of  the  alternative  optimism  measure  at  the  mean  is  -­‐0.008.  The  marginal  effects  at  the   mean  of  all  the  variables  are  reported  in  appendix  H1.  The  coefficient  of  age  and  the   excellent  health  dummy  variable  are  once  again  negative  and  significant,  whereas   income,  net  wealth,  college  education,  self-­‐employment  and  a  less  risk  averse  attitude   have  a  positive  impact  on  the  probability  of  holding  risky  assets.  The  pattern  does  again   not  change  much  when  considering  risky  assets  only  or  relatively  risky  and  risky  assets   simultaneously.  In  this  setting,  we  excluded  just  as  it  was  done  earlier  the  individuals   who  reported  not  to  own  any  assets  from  the  sample.  The  results  including  these  

(25)

Table  3:  The  initial  measure  of  optimism  is  replaced  by  the  alternative  measure  of  optimism;  the   methodology  we  use  is  still  the  same  than  for  the  regressions  of  table  2.    

 

     

VARIABLES   RISKY   REL.  RISKY  +     RISKY         Alternative  Optimism   -­‐0.007   -­‐0.077***     (0.017)   (0.019)   Age   -­‐0.017***   -­‐0.029***     (0.002)   (0.002)   Male   -­‐0.190***   -­‐0.047*     (0.023)   (0.028)   College   0.610***   0.328***     (0.052)   (0.073)   Self-­‐Employed   0.423***   0.697***     (0.088)   (0.154)   Risk  Tolerance   0.196***   0.118***     (0.010)   (0.013)   Household  Income   0.198***   0.488***     (0.023)   (0.046)   Net  Wealth   0.228***   0.248***     (0.019)   (0.032)   Very  Good  Health   -­‐0.251***   -­‐0.360***     (0.069)   (0.090)   North   -­‐0.327**   -­‐0.198     (0.146)   (0.180)   West   -­‐0.475***   -­‐0.126     (0.135)   (0.170)   South   -­‐0.489***   -­‐0.341**     (0.137)   (0.172)   East   -­‐0.274**   0.005     (0.137)   (0.170)   Constant   -­‐0.721***   1.171***     (0.158)   (0.213)     Observations     Log  likelihood     Pseudo  R2   16,299     -­‐9302.450     0.158   16,299     -­‐6286.784     0.165          

Standard  errors  in  parentheses   ***  p<0.01,  **  p<0.05,  *  p<0.1  

(26)

In  order  to  get  a  more  precise  picture  of  how  optimism  is  related  to  the  different  asset   classes,  we  subdivide  in  a  next  step  the  individuals  into  five  different  subcategories.  As   already  mentioned  in  section  3,  we  qualify  people  as  very  optimistic  if  their  level  of   optimism  is  equal  to  or  larger  than  3.  In  the  same  fashion,  they  are  qualified  as  very   pessimistic  if  their  level  of  optimism  is  -­‐3  or  smaller.  The  remaining  individuals  are   qualified  as  weakly  optimistic  if  their  level  of  optimism  is  1  or  2,  neutral  if  it  is  0,  and   weakly  pessimistic  if  the  level  of  optimism  is  -­‐1  or  -­‐2.  We  use  neutral  optimism  as   benchmark  and  regress  risky  assets  as  well  as  relatively  risky  and  risky  assets  on  these   classes  of  optimism  and  the  control  variables  that  we  also  used  in  the  previous  models.   The  outcome  of  these  models  can  be  found  in  table  4.  The  same  regressions  are  done  

(27)

Table  4:  Replacing  the  discrete  initial  optimism  variable  by  the  subcategories  strong  optimism,  weak   optimism,  neutral  optimism,  weak  pessimism  and  strong  pessimism.    

 

     

VARIABLES   RISKY   REL.  RISKY  +   RISKY         Strong  Optimism   -­‐0.280***   -­‐0.353***     (0.081)   (0.098)   Weak  Optimism   -­‐0.136***   -­‐0.236***     (0.053)   (0.067)   Weak  Pessimism   -­‐0.080   -­‐0.013     (0.058)   (0.071)   Strong  Pessimism   -­‐0.237**   -­‐0.099     (0.099)   (0.110)   Age   -­‐0.016***   -­‐0.027***     (0.002)   (0.002)   Male   -­‐0.198***   -­‐0.024     (0.026)   (0.032)   College   0.571***   0.271***     (0.056)   (0.081)   Self-­‐Employed   0.443***   0.626***     (0.097)   (0.169)   Risk  Tolerance   0.206***   0.125***     (0.011)   (0.014)   Household  Income   0.218***   0.497***     (0.026)   (0.051)   Net  Wealth   0.219***   0.238***     (0.021)   (0.035)   Very  Good  Health   -­‐0.226***   -­‐0.290***     (0.077)   (0.102)   North   -­‐0.252   -­‐0.105     (0.158)   (0.192)   West   -­‐0.400***   -­‐0.032     (0.147)   (0.180)   South   -­‐0.468***   -­‐0.285     (0.149)   (0.182)   East   -­‐0.198   0.141     (0.148)   (0.179)   Constant   -­‐0.770***   1.115***     (0.177)   (0.229)         Observations     Log  likelihood     Pseudo  R2     13,211     -­‐7654.884     0.158   13,211     -­‐5435.028     0.155       Standard  errors  in  parentheses   ***  p<0.01,  **  p<0.05,  *  p<0.1  

 

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

In another article (Ito &amp; Lee, 2005b) the authors compared the impact of 9/11 and its after-effects on airline demand in Australia, Canada, Europe, Japan and the U.S. Using the

A low regulatory context, that has a higher chance for slavery to thrive (Crane, 2013) and where MNCs rather allocate their resources to more profitable activities (Hoejmose

The interest rate variable is significant (with the lagged variant causing the original to lose its significance), however the resulting coefficient is not consistent with

Since new countries had the opportunity to join the free trade area within the borders of the union, surprisingly, influence of trade liberalization on the

Absorptive capacity is an ability of a country to identify or exploit knowledge from environment (Cohen &amp; Levinthal, 1989). An environmental capacity restricts or

Following the economic literature (Culem, 1988; Botric Skuflic, 2006; Pournarakis and Varsakelis 2004; Fabry and Zeghni 2010) and statistical considerations on normality,

Additionally, product role was expected to serve as a moderator of this relationship where the utilitarian role of the product bundle would cause the relationship to go more

We hypothesize that consumers who are more price sensitive react more strongly to dynamic pricing practices and thus price sensitivity has a positive impact on the