• No results found

ACT Response to OPTA Consultation Document on Integral Tariff Regulation for End- users and Interconnection Services

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "ACT Response to OPTA Consultation Document on Integral Tariff Regulation for End- users and Interconnection Services"

Copied!
30
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

ACT Response to

OPTA Consultation Document on

Integral Tariff Regulation for

End-users and Interconnection

Services

(2)

1.

Introduction and summary

This ACT-document is written on behalf of the following ACT-members: Colt, Energis, Versatel and WorldCom. BT Ignite has already submitted its own response, which on many issues is coherent with the ACT viewpoints included in this

document.

ACT welcomes OPTA's consultation document on Integral Tariff Regulation, dated 26 November 2001 (reference: OPTA/EGM-IBT/2001/203548) that outlines OPTA's proposals for the implementation of structural remedies in order to prevent price squeeze.

ACT's key messages are as follows.

Price squeeze issues

• ACT believes that the price squeeze problem is among others caused by KPN’s retail tariffs being low and their interconnection prices being high by international standards. We again want to point out that the latter is surprising given that

demographics and operating conditions in the Netherlands suggest that Dutch interconnection prices should be amongst the lowest in Europe. KPN call

termination prices may not be truly LRIC based whilst their call origination prices are substantially higher than in most other EU countries, partly due to the EDC-cost-model. Analysis of relative retail and interconnection tariffs leads to the view that a price squeeze is more likely to occur in the Netherlands elsewhere in

Europe.

(3)

to put the non-discrimination principle above the causality (cost orientation) principle.

• ACT is strongly in favour of the proposals done by OPTA to take structural remedies (accounting separation, price cap wholesale tariffs) to mitigate risks for price squeeze to happen in the future. But ACT also believes it will continue to be essential to apply (a substantially improved) price squeeze tests in order to

evaluate whether specific KPN retail tariffs result in price squeeze.

• ACT believes the existing price squeeze test needs to be improved. The fact that alternative operators cannot interconnect as efficiently as KPN should be taken into account in the input costs of the model. Further the retail mark-up needs to be increased, and the KPN end-user charges need to be corrected with the highest possible (and not average) discounts that are available to end-users. The scope of the price squeeze test should be extended to include all services i.e. 06760

terminating, DSL, leased lines, etc.

• ACT questions the need for the continuation of the retail price cap after the current control period ends in July 2002.

A Price Cap for Interconnection services

• ACT welcomes a migration from the current annual review system of KPN’s interconnection tariffs to a multiple-year system. ACT is strongly in favour of the introduction of a price cap system. Migration to a price cap system will increase the predictability and the ability of the whole telecoms industry to plan with greater confidence, something that is strongly needed in The Netherlands.

• However, setting any price cap control of the form RPI-X is not a straight forward task. The potential for over-recovery of costs can be managed by firstly building robust models in consultation with the whole industry and secondly by ensuring appropriate regulatory intervention if problems arise. The key tasks involved are firstly establishing a reasonable set of starting prices and secondly calculating an appropriate “X”.

• Further work on starting prices is strictly required. The starting prices should not be current interconnection prices. The current LRIC-model needs to be reviewed in detail to understand why termination tariffs are as high as they are. In addition a set of true LRIC-based (instead of EDC-based) call origination tariffs need to be developed and used as the starting prices. ACT looks forward to hearing how OPTA intends setting starting prices for any price cap.

(4)

Separated Accounts Issues

• ACT fully support OPTA’s proposals to oblige KPN to keep separate accounts for its Retail and Network business. The proposal to adopt a non-discriminatory “purchase model” is essential to a fair competitive playing field, and will also provide useful data in support of price squeeze tests.

• It is essential that such accounts meet the objectives of the EC Interconnection Directive, and adhere to the principles of the EC Recommendation on Accounting Separation and Cost Accounting. Data from the accounts should be published.

• ACT strongly recommends separate accounts per service, e.g. for leased lines and local loop unbundled, as well as for the other interconnect and special access services.

• ACT strongly recommends that OPTA consult the market players over the methodologies employed, and the form and content of accounting separation and the reports to be published.

• ACT believes that the level of wholesale-specific charges should be investigated, to ensure they are reasonably incurred, efficient and allocated appropriately.

Allocation of Wholesale specific costs

ACT agrees with the approach suggested by OPTA. ACT believes that in the current situation it is justified that the principle of non-discrimination should overrule the principle of cost-causation, at the least as a temporary measure.

We agree with OPTA that the “cost asymmetry” associated with wholesale specific costs, that is presented by OPTA as one of the main causes of price squeeze, justify the suggested step of "proportional cost allocation” in the light of the promotion of sustainable competition.

(5)

BiBa-specific Issues

• ACT believes that unbundling of the BiBa tariff (on the “flower structure” approach) could be attractive. However, if this would be done, it would require careful implementation to avoid exploitation by KPN.

• ACT further believes a solution to the BiBa problem cannot be achieved without action at the wholesale level, especially regarding local interconnection. Currently local interconnection is economically unfeasible for alternative operators. The resolution of the outstanding issues on local interconnect is essential to ensure the correct economic signals are given to competing operators.

• In the meantime it will continue to be essential that an (improved) version of the price squeeze test price is applied by OPTA to stimulate competition in the local calls market.

• ACT does not favour the introduction of local call resale at this time.

• There is merit in OPTA’s proposal to enable operators to obtain local interconnect charges where a call would have been handled at the local level in KPN’s

network. However, this would only be workable if local interconnect tariffs are efficient.

Further market consultation required

ACT deems it essential that OPTA further consults the market on the following issues:

• Design of the Price Squeeze Test.

• Price Cap for Interconnection and Special Access services and in particular the appropriate starting prices and the setting of the X parameter.

(6)

2.

Price squeeze: issues and solution directions

I. The interested parties may feel there are other issues that pertain to the (causes of) price squeeze in addition to those stated in this document. If this is the case, the interested parties are asked to provide the Commission with any relevant information.

ACT fully agrees with OPTA that it is essential to implement structural remedies against price squeeze. In general we agree with OPTA that these remedies should consist of:

• Further attuning the tariff regulation systems for end-user and interconnection services;

• Obliging KPN to keep proper separate sets of accounts (accounting separation); and

• The introduction of non-discriminatory allocation of the so-called "wholesale specific costs" on a proportionate basis to KPN as well.

We further agree with OPTA that even within such a modified future tariff regulation system it will continue to be necessary to apply price squeeze tests in order to evaluate whether specific KPN retail tariffs result in price squeeze. These price squeeze tests will continue to be essential to prevent that:

• KPN is pricing anti-competitively. KPN's end-user tariffs for a service, including all discount schemes, may never be below the service's underlying interconnection costs and a mark-up for the retail-costs that are related to this service.

• KPN is acting in a discriminatory way. KPN must be shown to be purchasing interconnection services on the same basis as it charges other operators. This is fundamental requirement of the EU’s Interconnection directive and is carried forward into the new legislative proposals.

In addition to what is stated in the consultation document ACT believes that there are some other relevant issues that need to be taken into account in relation to price squeeze issues in the Netherlands. These are discussed below.

Relatively low end-user tariffs and relatively high interconnection prices

In its response to the consultation document BT Ignite correctly argues that the key problem in the Netherlands is that KPN’s end-user tariffs are relatively low (amongst the cheapest in the EU) whereas KPN’s wholesale (interconnection) tariffs are

(7)

Further information on the margins between retail and wholesale in different European countries can be found in section 7.3 of “Tariff Regulation – The Way Forward.” Also in the past ACT has never been able to understand why the Dutch interconnection tariffs are relatively high given the fact that the demographics and operating conditions in the Netherlands would suggest that interconnection tariffs should be amongst the lowest in the EU. ACT strongly doubts whether the current Dutch interconnection tariffs are truly LRIC-based. And also in this context it is important to repeat that ACT believes that OPTA should replace the existing EDC-model to set originating tariffs by an LRIC-EDC-model1. This also has implications for setting starting prices in the context of a potential price cap for interconnection tariffs. ACT strongly doubts whether KPN's current tariffs would bea reasonable starting point for a price cap.

Removal and/or relaxation of the retail price cap

Further we question whether there is a need to continue with end-user tariff regulation in the form of price caps when the current controls end in July 2002. The main

purpose of such a price cap would be to provide consumer protection in the absence of any competition. Given the fact that retail prices are relatively low in the Netherlands and that at least in some of the relevant product and services markets competition is growing, relaxation of the current price cap and/or focussing on particularly the non-competitive products and services such as line rental should be considered by OPTA. To avoid any misunderstanding, this loosening of retail price controls does not

however imply a reduced requirement for regulation of interconnection and wholesale prices nor to test for a price squeeze.

If a price cap would still be needed, it would minimally need to be in line with decreases in interconnect- and special access tariffs i.e. RPI – X (retail) <= RPI –Y (interconnect & special access).

ACT understands that OPTA will organise a separate consultation on this specific issue in February/March 2002 and we are more than happy to further contribute to that consultation.

Redesign of Price Squeeze Tests needed

The current price squeeze tests seem inadequate to provide competitors of KPN with a sufficient margin on their services. For a more in depth analysis the Price Squeeze Test, please also refer to Section 7.3 of the ACT report “Tariff Regulation – The Way Forward”. The main issues are summarised below. ACT is happy to discuss this further with OPTA.

1

(8)

The retail mark-up is too low.

In response to the original Price Squeeze consultation in November 2000 ACT-members have already statedthat the retail mark-up of 23% that is used in the price squeeze test is insufficient and far too low. We understand that the 23% mark-up was based on information provided by KPN from their accounts and that the mark-up was based on KPN's overall retail costs for all KPN’s PSTN retail services, compared with the network costs for those services. However, the cost causation factors of retail costs are quite different to the factors that cause network costs to arise. It is quite possible, therefore, that the retail mark-up will need to be reviewed on a regular basis,

particularly in response to changes in network tariffs, or changes in the underlying accounting data on retail costs. In addition the network costs (e.g. the rates for special access and interconnect termination services) have changed in the meantime and will change in the future, as a result of OPTA setting new interconnection tariffs. We believe it is inappropriate to continue to calculate the retail mark-up using the 23%, since the cost basis of network charges has now changed. ACT therefore urges OPTA to review the 23% uplift, in the light of the recent changes in network charges and retail costs.

In order to provide an adequate tariff floor, OPTA must include representative cost levels for the following additional costs in the retail mark-up (leading to an increase in the mark-up:

• New entrant’s own network cost;

• New entrant’s economies-of-scale disadvantage for retail costs;

• New entrant’s minimal return on investment.

Furthermore, using an equal mark up percentage for all services hardly seems to acknowledge the fact that different the services may have substantially different retail specific costs in relation to their network costs.

The reference of wholesale costs to which the mark up is applied is incorrect. It should reflect the cost level of a competitor of KPN, which requires the following changes:

• The wholesale costs must not be based on weighted tariffs based on KPN’s internal; routing, but on a realistic level of interconnection (i.e. the level at which sufficient competition is present); currently this is the regional level;

(9)

The current price squeeze test does miss its goal of ensuring a margin on 06760 Internet traffic for new entrants completely. The test only fixes the bottom floor of the retention for KPN. It does not make any assumptions about a sustainable margin between retail and wholesale tariffs. As defined in the current Guidelines in the price squeeze test for 06760 Terminating, KPN can fix the retention as long as it is set above a bottom level. It is currently set at the 23% but nothing would prevent KPN from requiring a higher percentage. The test does not take into account the fact that the margin for the Telco offering the 06760 Terminating service is equal to the

difference between the KPN end-user tariff and the by KPN required retention. Hence an increase in the retention and a decrease of the KPN retail tariffs immediately affects the new entrant’s margin, potentially squeezing this margin. The same issue arises with the 06760 Collecting service, where KPN can squeeze the margin of new entrants by downwards pressure on the 06760 minute-based retail tariffs or on the combination of 06760 minute-based retail tariffs with a subscription.

Also, new entrant can be faced with a “reciprocity” squeeze. The current KPN terminating tariffs have been set based upon the BU-LRIC model. In this model, the costs of "efficient KPN" are based upon larger economies of scale than Telco’s

currently have. For a Telco without economies of scale, the average terminating tariffs could be below the actual cost level. Telco’s are forced to offer their terminating service under their own cost level.

Ex ante predatory pricing test must be available for all retail services on which

effective competition must be safeguarded. For instance, DSL and leased line services should be included. See also “Tariff Regulation – The Way Forward”.

Discriminatory Cost Advantages of KPN

The term ‘discriminatory cost advantage’ refers to the situation where KPN, as a vertically integrated firm and as a party with significant market power, has lower costs in offering a retail service than its competitors. This may allow KPN to undercut the prices of its competitors and thus force them out of the market. OPTA must do everything it can to eliminate discriminatory cost advantages in a structural way, i.e. using the non-discrimination principle in EU legislation to the strictest possible extent.

In the consultation document, OPTA has identified a key discriminatory cost advantage, the cost allocation of wholesale specific costs. OPTA indeed proposes here to eliminate this cost advantage by using a more strict interpretation of the non-discrimination principle and a less strict interpretation of the cost orientation principle (causality).

(10)

• Discriminatory cost allocation of wholesale specific services (as mentioned above, for a/o telephony, C(P)S, Collocation)

• Use of a cost basis for the use of facilities that results in higher costs for new entrants that for KPN itself, (e.g. wholesale prices for the local loop are based on EDC CCA, while KPN as a vertically integrated company enjoys – lower -costs based on HCA);

• On net traffic (Telco’s have higher costs than KPN for providing the same service a/o because of their own network costs)

• Inefficiency of interconnection (Telco’s cannot currently interconnect in the most efficient and cost-effective way, interconnection at the local level is not possible and, even then, interconnecting to all 600 local exchanges is very inefficient)

Some discriminatory cost advantages may disappear over time, as KPN’s market share and that of its competitors become of (in order of magnitude) comparable size. For this reason, the only measures OPTA can take is strict application of the non-discrimination principle, and to put the non-non-discrimination principle above the

causality (cost orientation) principle. Non-discrimination is more important to create a level playing field than cost orientation.

The use of strict application of the non-discrimination principle is here to be preferred over the use of a price squeeze test. Not only does, in case of a discriminatory cost advantage, the price squeeze test not protect against KPN undercutting prices of Telco’s, it also would cause KPN to make excessive (i.e. not cost oriented) profits on services. Strict application of the non-discrimination principle however would result in an ‘equal cost opportunities’ situation for KPN and Telco’s, which creates a level playing field.

For a more in depth analysis of discriminatory cost advantages, please also refer to Chapter 3 of “Tariff Regulation – The Way Forward”.

Capacity Based Charging

The minute based interconnect system seriously harms the new entrants. Where incremental minutes do not incur additional costs or very low costs to the incumbent, the new entrant pays the same amount for each additional minute.

(11)
(12)

3.

Introduction of a price cap for interconnection tariffs

II.a. Interested parties are asked to provide the Commission with their viewpoints and insights with reference to the desirability of a possible migration to a multiple-year system for tariff regulation of KPN's interconnection and special access services, and to the applicable requirements in that respect with reference to a system of this type; II.b. When replying, interested parties are also asked to provide detailed

comments on the considerations put forward by the Commission in this respect, in particular with reference to the question of whether the current situation in the market is suitable for sufficient predictability of the correct cost and volume developments.

ACT welcomes OPTA's consideration to migrate from the current system of KPN’s interconnection tariffs to a multiple-year system. ACT is strongly in favour of the introduction of a price cap system. The main advantage of such a system is well described in paragraph 23 of the consultation document. Key benefit is that interconnection prices will become more predictable over a longer period of time, which is something that is strongly needed in the Netherlands, where in the past couple of years the development of interconnection tariffs was totally unpredictable and resulted in huge uncertainty for new entrants pricing and investment strategies. Migration to a price cap system will increase the ability of the whole telecoms industry to plan with greater confidence.

We further agree with OPTA that a price cap system will result in lower

administrative costs for all parts of the industry and that such a system in principle can create the right economic incentives for KPN to improve its efficiency in delivering interconnection services. However, the extent to which this will be the case fully depends on how the price cap is designed, especially in terms of the starting prices that are set at the beginning and how the “X” is defined.

We agree with OPTA that there are potential risks in introducing a price cap system. But we believe these risks are manageable and can be mitigated by putting enough time and energy in building a robust system price cap, with adequate checks and balances in place. The most important preconditions for such a robust system the are the development of stretching and realistic values for the “X” as well as an adequate set of starting prices.

ACT believes a price cap system should be introduced as soon as possible, preferably starting July 2002, but only if the two main components of such a new system are perfectly thought through and further developed, in liaison with market parties. These two components are:

• Setting reasonable starting prices

(13)

A lot of additional work is needed to set reasonable starting prices. Setting adequate starting prices is also needed to mitigate the risk identified by OPTA that KPN may over-recover or under-recover the costs of an efficient operator. ACT considers that in the short term there is a greater risk that KPN will over-recover their costs through making “unexpected cost reductions”. Such over-recovery is more likely because KPN’s wholesale costs have until now not been subjected to any detailed external scrutiny, because KPN never published any separated regulatory accounts.

Ideally, before implementing a price cap, LRIC cost-models would have been built and re-run over several years with results of the model stabilising or showing a discernible trend. This is not the case in the Netherlands. An LRIC-model was only built recently and LRIC-prices were only set once before. As said in the above we have reason to believe that the resulting termination tariffs are not truly LRIC based yet. Further we are extremely worried by the fact that the originating access tariffs are still based on the EDC-model which results in call origination tariffs in The

Netherlands being relatively higher than in other EU member states. In the light of the above ACT would strongly object to the use of the current interconnection prices as the starting prices in any price cap system. In sum we believe that the following is the minimum work that needs to be undertaken to establish a set of reasonable starting prices:

• The current LRIC-model needs to be reviewed in detail to understand why interconnection prices are as high as they are.

• A set of true LRIC-based (instead of EDC-based) call origination tariffs needs to be developed and used as the starting prices. It is crucial that these prices need to be in the lower range of the benchmark prices in other EU countries.

• Checks need to be made with the new starting prices and retail prices to ensure that the new system does not institutionalise a price squeeze.

ACT believes that setting a reasonable X is not just a question of estimating

appropriate efficiency gains. The calculation of a reasonable X is a discrete modelling exercise that usually involves forecasting revenues, operating costs and capital

employed. “X” is usually a variable parameter within these models that is set in such a way that the business under consideration earns the required rate of return at the end of the tariff period.

(14)

Whatever the form of the final model it is likely that it will need to consider at least some of the following:

• Market demand and market share forecasts by service. These combined with routing factors will give estimates of network demand by component.

• Operating cost cost/volume elasticities. These estimate how operating costs vary as volumes change and are used to estimate operating (non-capital) costs.

• Estimates of static efficiency gains: how unit operating cost might be expected to decrease if there were no changes in volumes

• Asset price movements and asset/volume elasticity's. These are used to generate the required capital expenditure and model forecasts of mean capital employed. A further key consideration for any modelling exercise will be technical progress. This is likely to be important over the short to medium term as circuit switched traffic migrates to IP platforms. This makes the modelling exercise more difficult – but not impossible, and may lead to consideration of revised depreciation models.

(15)

4.

Accounting separation

III. Interested parties are asked to comment on the Commission’s plan to oblige KPN to keep separate sets of accounts, a measure advocated by the European Commission, whereby KPN’s retail business would purchase from KPN’s network business under the same conditions and cost basis as the parties interconnecting via KPN.

ACT supports OPTA's plans to oblige KPN to implement accounting separation to the full extent as recommended by the European Commission. Only by doing so the key accounting objectives of the interconnection directive (cost-orientation, transparency and non-discrimination) can be properly be assessed and proven. Separated accounts specifically recognise the “vertically-integrated” nature of an incumbent operator such as KPN, which has been notified as having Significant Market Power in both the retail and interconnect (wholesale) markets. Proper accounting separation should help to prevent possible abuses of such market power. This would include price / margin squeeze, but also could extend to cover such issues as potential over-charging and cross-subsidies. ACT is also fully in favour of KPN being obliged to publish its financial reports – only by doing this can market players gain confidence in the system and its outputs.

However, the extent to which the system (and its resulting statements) meets the regulatory objectives will strongly depend on the precise nature of the accounting separation system to be installed. This includes the inputs and assumptions used, the calculations and allocation methodologies, and the nature of the outputs and reports. Some of the key aspects will be considered in the following paragraphs.

EC Recommendation

ACT believes that the EC “Recommendation document” concerning the

implementation of accounting separation and cost accounting systems would provide a useful starting point for the intended migration of KPN’s costing systems. Some of the key aspects of the Commission Recommendation which ACT would like to highlight are :

• There are at least four broad business lines for which separated accounts should be produced – Core Network, Local Access Network, Retail and Other (further dis-aggregated accounts within these business lines may be considered appropriate)

• As well as being based on cost-orientation, the costing system should be sufficiently detailed to allow the allocation of costs to unbundled network components and to determine the cost of unbundled interconnection services

• Public consultation on allocation methods is considered desirable

(16)

• Efficiency factors may be necessary, to ensure that costs reflect those of an efficient operator

• The reports should include P&L and balance sheet for each business, together with a reconciliation with the statutory accounts of the company as a whole. Transfer charges between the businesses should be clearly identified

• Publication – there is clear indication that information should be made available to interested parties to demonstrate non-discrimination. In particular, the importance of a statement showing the average cost of network components is highlighted. ACT believes some of the above issues highlight areas where further clarification may be required on OPTA’s intended approach. In particular ACT believe that OPTA should:

• Oblige KPN to produce separate reports on the Local Access business, as distinct from the Core Network business – an appropriate level of supplementary detail may be necessary to support pricing of local loop unbundling services;

• Require not only reports on the Retail business, but, as necessary, a dis-aggregated set of reports on some of the key products and services within the Retail business. In particular, this would help in the assessment of price squeeze, by providing information on retail costs for the various retail services. Such information may provide a more rigorous approach to identifying the retail costs, compared with the current 23% retail mark-up.

• Consider what level of supporting detail that KPN should be required to produce to support interconnect rates (see also comments below)

• Address the issue of the appropriate cost basis (e.g. current costs)

• Oblige KPN to publish its methodology documents, as well as the outputs of the system itself, and ensure that the system and its outputs are independently audited. ACT believes that OPTA should consider consulting with the industry over the

(17)

Reports required for proving cost-orientation, non-discrimination and transparency.

ACT believes there are some deficiencies in the Commission Recommendation, especially in the area of proving the cost-orientation, transparency and non-discrimination of network charges.

The regulatory objectives would be facilitated by the publication of three specific reports:

(a) Output of Network Costs

(b) Output of Unit Charges of Network Services

(c) Output of detailed transfer charges between the Core Network business and the Retail Business

A brief description of the content of these reports is presented in Appendix 1. Again, ACT would be happy to discuss these issues in more detail with OPTA.

Cost standards and network charging

Section 3.3.3 of OPTA’s consultation document proposes that KPN should present its financial reports in a way that makes it possible to determine whether KPN’s retail organisation purchases wholesale services from KPN’s network against the same terms and tariffs as its competitors. ACT fully supports this principle.

OPTA also state that KPN should apply the EDC system, by which the terminating service should be valued based on the BU-LRIC tariffs – thus keeping the existing regulation model which applies EDC to originating access and BU-LRIC to terminating access.

There are therefore two possible cost standards used for network charging: EDC and BU-LRIC. As OPTA knows ACT is strongly in favour of using the BU-LRIC model both for terminating access and originating access services. In particular where, and as long as, local access competition is limited.

If OPTA would continue to use both, it is essential to reflect the relevant transfer charges for each of the services to use these two approaches in a non-discriminatory manner. To do this would require a detailed assessment of the usage made by KPN retail of both special access services (priced on an EDC basis) and interconnect termination services (priced on BU-LRIC), in order to ensure that the charging principles are applied an a truly non-discriminatory way.

(18)

relating charges to costs. Therefore, it is essential that the KPN system can present information to support the cost-orientation of such network charges.

It is apparent that the main network components can be used by both special access (EDC) services and termination (BU-LRIC) services. This raises a question of how a fully integrated cost model can support both cost bases.

ACT believes that this can be achieved by presenting data on how the network charges relate to underlying costs. This would require an integrated approach to costing the network, and a clear statement of how costs relate to the various charges that are used. In turn, this will require a decision will to be taken on the appropriate basis for presenting the network costs (i.e. should it be on an EDC approach or a LRIC approach or Fully Allocated Costing approach, should it be based on historic costs or current costs). ACT would prefer to see an integrated statement of network costs on the basis of current cost accounting, fully allocated costs.

ACT would welcome OPTA’s views on:

• How KPN’s accounting system would be designed to prove cost-orientation and transparency of network charges, as well as non-discrimination;

• Whether a fully integrated approach will be taken to costing the network, hence providing a clear statement of the costs (preferably on a current cost basis), and how these relate to the network charges.

IV. Interested parties are asked to state their viewpoints and insights regarding the question of whether the introduction of financial reporting along the lines of a purchase model would necessarily mean that KPN’s retail traffic would actually have to use the wholesale-specific facilities and services (such as the wholesale billing system and the Carrier Services organisation).

ACT agrees with OPTA’s conclusion that the implementation of an “actual”

(19)

5.

The allocation of wholesale specific costs

V. Interested parties are asked to submit viewpoints on the judgement that the principle of cost orientation needs to be interpreted more broadly in the case of specific costs, and in such a way that KPN can earn back its wholesale-specific costs through proportional allocation of these costs to all the traffic that uses KPN’s network.

ACT fully agrees with the approach suggested by OPTA. ACT believes that in the current situation it is justified that the principle of non-discrimination should overrule the principle of cost-causation, at the least as a temporary measure. ACT supports the calculation example provided by OPTA in paragraph 50 of the Consultation

Document.

We agree with OPTA that the “cost asymmetry” associated with wholesale specific costs, that is presented by OPTA as one of the main causes of price squeeze, justify the suggested step of "proportional cost allocation” in the light of the promotion of sustainable competition. ACT agrees that the promotion of competition within the context of a level playing field is of paramount importance. Further, it is apparent that the charging solution for wholesale-specific costs may in part depend on the output of the costing analysis. Thus it may be that the existing high level of wholesale-specific costs has created problems, and that these problems are significant enough to justify basing the charges on other principles other than cost causation. In particular, it may be necessary to impute these costs to KPN retail for the purposes of price squeeze tests, in order to ensure sustainable competition.

At the same time ACT is worried by the fact that OPTA says that these wholesale specific costs are the principle cause of price squeeze. ACT believes that such costs, assuming they are efficiently incurred and analysed appropriately in the accounts, should be minimal in size. Regretfully OPTA has never disclosed any specific data on the size of these costs within KPN, which makes it impossible for ACT to judge whether these costs are reasonable or not. As these costs are currently recovered solely from other operators through interconnect and special access services, this situation not only creates a discriminatory cost advantage for KPN, but also does not give an incentive for KPN to ensure these costs are at an efficient level. On the

(20)

ACT believes that such costs are likely to exhibit a high fixed element, therefore, as interconnect volumes increase, the unit costs should decrease significantly.

VI. Interested parties are asked to submit viewpoints on the judgement that the policy intentions formulated in Paragraph 3.4.4 for wholesale-specific costs

incorporated in the EDC reporting should also apply to other types of wholesale-specific costs.

ACT believes that other wholesale-specific costs should be treated in the same manner as described above. Such costs should only be allocated to wholesale traffic exclusively when it can be demonstrated by KPN that existing structural imbalances have been removed. In the interim ACT would favour the approach proposed by OPTA, which would allocate such costs proportional across all wholesale and retail traffic. Thus, in the interests of a level competitive playing field, and pending resolution of the structural imbalances, such costs should also be recovered using a proportional cost allocation approach.

Additionally, there are some costs that could be deemed to be of general benefit to the entire industry (and hence to all customer groups, whether of the incumbent or of competing operators). An example would be CPS system set-up costs. The introduction of CPS benefits the competitive process, and thereby, potentially, benefits all customers in the market. To the extent that CPS creates general

competitive pressures in the market, this will benefit the customers of the incumbent network operator on whom CPS obligations are imposed. Therefore, such costs should be shared equitably across all industry players, rather than only those carriers that “order” CPS from the incumbent operator. This approach has been taken in both the UK and Ireland.

In any case, there should be a clear transfer charge between KPN’s network and retail businesses for the usage of such costs, insofar as these are incurred by retail services (i.e. principally, this will be retail services that involve some sort of interconnect, such as fixed to other fixed operators, and fixed to mobile).

In the case of collocation, ACT is not clear whether OPTA mean “LLU-specific” collocation, or other arrangements for physical interconnection of networks (e.g. hand over of voice traffic) at KPN exchanges.

• In the case of LLU-style collocation, KPN should ensure that its retail services (such as DSL) would bear a fair charge for any collocation facilities that are used (e.g. in housing the DSLAM equipment at exchange sites). Such charges should be non-discriminatory, compared with LLU collocation charges.

(21)

6.

The BiBa issue and solution directions

VII.a. Interested parties are asked to submit their viewpoints and insights on the solution direction in which biba would be unbundled. Please include your views on both variants.

VII.b. When replying, interested parties are also asked to comment in detail on the advantages and disadvantages put forward by the Commission in this context.

The BiBa issue refers to the situation where the BiBa retail tariffs are too low for competitors to compete effectively with KPN on these services, given their wholesale costs associated with their current level of interconnection. One (partial) solution for the BiBa issue has been put into effect mid 2001 by means of the price squeeze test that has set a ‘price floor’ for BiBa tariffs. In the consultation document, OPTA proposes to resolve the BiBa issue by unbundling the BiBa tariff into a ‘BiBa local’ and a ‘BiBa regional’ tariff. With the proposed unbundling, OPTA seems to pursue a more structural solution of this problem.

ACT re-affirms that there is still a real problem in BiBa. This is caused by a

combination of low KPN retail tariffs relative to wholesale costs, and impediments in the wholesale market that make it impossible for competing operators to achieve the same network cost base as KPN. OPTA's price squeeze decision taken in July last year has only partially solved the issue.

Unbundling of the BiBa tariff might enable ACT-members to compete for “regional” and “national” BiBa traffic, where currently it has difficulties in doing so. However, the extent to which this will be the case would depend on exactly how the tariff was unbundled, and, crucially, on the resulting price levels for the unbundled services. The precise definition of the tariffs, and the level of retail tariffs relative to wholesale prices, would determine the viability of such a solution.

BiBa unbundling might however be difficult to arrive at. The concept of BiBa unbundling seems to be based on the notion that ‘BiBa local’ traffic can be handled more efficiently than ‘BiBa regional’. In the ‘purest’ case, BiBa local traffic would then be traffic that is handled by only one local exchange (NRC) and BiBa regional is handled by one regional exchange (EVKC) and two local exchanges. This would be undesirable, because in areas that are served by multiple NRC’s the BiBa local tariff would be possible only in fractions of the number area, which is, as OPTA also indicates, undesirable from the principle of transparency.

(22)

same number region and between NRC’s in different number regions are the same! The distribution of BiBa traffic over the hierarchical levels of KPN’s as

communicated in OPTA’s Price Squeeze test guideline is 22% that crosses only the (one) NRC level, 63% that crosses the EVKC level and 15% that even crosses the above EVKC level, it seems unlikely that the ‘lesser pure’ case will yield any substantial efficiency gains.

Furthermore unbundling of BiBa is only likely to be beneficial to competing operators if it is combined with other measures to remove the current obstacles in KPN’s wholesale prices. Such obstacles include: the high “port” charges at the local level; high testing and installation charges, the difficulties in obtaining acceptable

commercial terms for widespread local interconnect; the lack of proper “in-span” interconnect arrangements with KPN, and the ever decreasing margin/gap between local interconnection and regional interconnection tariffs. The issue of cost-efficient local interconnect arrangements is discussed further in answer to question VIIIb, which also highlights other reasons why true widespread local interconnection with KPN currently is not economically feasible for alternative operators.

If these wholesale issues are not resolved, then the unbundling the biba tariff (under either the “network burden” or “flower structure” approaches) could actually harm competition further. This is because KPN may be able to market “local biba” services at a low price (based on a lower network load), and competing operators may still be unable to match these lower costs.

If OPTA was to decide in favour of unbundling biba tariffs, then ACT would prefer this to be done on the basis of the flower structure. However, such a change would need to be carefully designed and implemented to ensure KPN was not able to exploit the change for its own commercial benefit. The “network burden” approach would be particularly inappropriate, and could lead to customer confusion and be unworkable in practice, for reasons that OPTA have already identified.

A combination of relaxation (or even removal) of the price cap for BiBa calls, together with positive actions on removing impediments to local interconnection, would help reduce the price squeeze pressure on BiBa overall. It may also remove some of the causes of the subsidies between “local” and “regional” BiBa calls. However, ACT understand that there may be other reasons that mitigate against the unbundling of biba tariffs, including:

• it is likely to be unpopular with consumers

• it could hinder internet access or other service provider arrangements

• it is contrary to the trend of simplification seen in the rest of Europe

(23)
(24)

7.

Removing obstacles to the local interconnection service

VIII.a. Interested parties are asked for their viewpoints and insights on the Commission’s opinion that the market for local interconnection is, in principle, a competitive market.

ACT does not agree that the market for local interconnection is competitive. This market is dominated by KPN, since it has the majority of customer lines. Therefore the “market” for local interconnection services is not likely to be competitive until or unless the market power of KPN is considerably reduced. Because competing

operators have no alternative supplier for local interconnection services (i.e. access to the majority of end users for either call origination or call termination), this lack of competition means that regulation of KPN is strongly required.

However, a slightly different question is whether the market for local retail calls services is competitive. ACT notes that the market for local calls is not effectively competitive at present as KPN still has 95% market share. However, ACT agrees that the market for local retail calls should be a competitive market. Therefore, ACT fully support OPTA’s initiatives aimed at removing barriers to the local interconnection service of KPN, which could help to make the local calls retail market more competitive.

The question that remains then is what efficient local interconnection is. The principle of a level playing field dictates that reasonably efficient operators must be able to compete effectively with KPN at all times. This means that price squeeze issues for reasonably efficient operators must be prevented. Currently, the reasonably efficient operators are interconnected at the regional level, because it is impossible to

interconnect at a lower level (due to a/o small difference local and regional interconnect tariffs and lack predictability of these tariffs). Eventually however, reasonably efficient operators may be interconnected at a more efficient level.

Presently however, it is unclear what the most efficient level of interconnection is. As it looks now, interconnection at the regional level may not be the most efficient level of interconnection. However, having Telco’s establish interconnects to all 600 local exchanges is not efficient either. This is clearly demonstrated by the fact that the BU-LRIC model, that represents the network (costs) of an efficient operator, uses

substantially less than 600 local exchanges. In addition, the PRX exchanges have been purchased a long time ago and are most likely due to be phased out in the foreseeable future. Interconnecting to these exchanges therefore is a waste of time and resources. Most likely, the optimum efficient interconnect level will, depending on traffic

(25)

“Austrian variant” that has defined the (most efficient) level of interconnection to be only a few local exchanges.

The most efficient level of interconnection should not be determined based on KPN’s current inefficient network structure, but should be determined based on the network architecture and costs of an efficient operator (see e.g. BU-LRIC model). Only then can competition be as efficient as possible and result in maximum increase of consumer welfare.

Concluding we can state that not the market for local interconnection, but the market for efficient interconnection is a potentially competitive market. Until it is clear what efficient interconnection means, market parties must not be put in a position where they inevitably are forced to roll out to the local level in KPN’s network, unless it would be demonstrated this is the most efficient level.

The consultation document suggests in a number of places that, if Telco’s

‘interconnect’ in the same places as KPN ‘virtually’ does, their costs of providing a service are close to KPN’s costs of providing the same service. This is not true. Telco’s incur substantial costs for interconnection, transmission and switches to convey traffic between their networks and KPN. KPN does not have this disadvantage because it conveys the huge majority of its traffic on-net. Over time, as competition and market shares develop, this disadvantage may fade away, as Telco’s will handle more traffic on-net and KPN will handle more traffic off net. At present however, this cost disadvantage of Telco’s (which is a discriminatory cost advantage of KPN) should be considered and incorporated in OPTA’s policy making.

ACT does not believe that it is realistic to expect that the removal of current obstacles to the local interconnection service will be a solution for the BiBa problem on a short term, also because it will take quite some time to roll out locally (assumed this is economically feasible, which is not the case right now). Therefore, additional

measures to promote competition on the local calls retail (BiBa) market will continue to be essential on the short term. It’s especially important that in the meantime OPTA continues to apply an (improved) version of the existing price squeeze test.

VIII.b. Interested parties are asked to state whether they intend to roll out their network to a local level, and if so, the timeframe and conditions/criteria for this rollout.

(26)

plans will in any case depend on a variety of factors such as product and customer mix, not just on the interconnect arrangements for PSTN traffic.

However, it is also true that the current KPN and tariff arrangements for local interconnection are economically unfeasible for alternative operators.

One of the main problems is that the gap between local and regional interconnect tariffs in The Netherlands is relatively small compared to other EU countries. But if one also takes into account the effect of Port charges (these charges are far higher at Local switches than at regional or national switches) the problem gets even worse, because then Local conveyance charges would exceed Regional conveyance charges in most instances, which clearly illustrates why KPN’s local interconnect

arrangements are punitively expensive for other operators (even before including any build-out costs needed in the operator’s network).

Aside from the concerns on the level of local interconnect tariffs, there are other economic obstacles for migration to local interconnect, also having to do with the question of what efficient local interconnection is. OPTA stated (paragraph 70 of the consultation document) that KPN has a relatively large number of local switches, and that “given the current technology, a smaller number of switches would be sufficient”. OPTA recognises the likelihood that it is not likely to be macro-economically sensible to force KPN’s competitors to roll out to all of these local switches. Additionally, inefficiencies in KPN’s network structure should not be recoverable in interconnect charges – otherwise the wrong investment decisions will result.

As OPTA indicates, the traffic intensity of competing operators is unlikely to justify interconnect at all but the largest KPN local switches.

Competing operators are likely to build their networks using somewhat different network design and technology considerations. Therefore, the mirroring of KPN’s network structure would be inappropriate.

Therefore, ACT urge OPTA to continue to address the issues of local interconnect arrangements and efficient pricing of all interconnect services (origination and termination, and including the access gateway services), so as to ensure that efficient economic signals are provided to operators.

(27)

Only when these kind of measures are taken can operators make the appropriate decisions on whether they want to migrate to Local interconnection with KPN.

IX. Interested parties are asked to submit their viewpoints and insights regarding the solution direction in which the local service would be made available to KPN’s competitors.

ACT considers that this represents a major strategic issue for the development of competition in the Netherlands. The question is whether the focus should remain on encouraging infrastructure competition, or whether the time is ripe to start

encouraging pure resale?

ACT considers that the telecommunications market in the Netherlands is not yet ready for measures intended to encourage resale and that efforts should be focussed on removing remaining barriers to the development of infrastructure competition. In any event the availability of such an offering would need to be limited to only those operators that generally qualify for interconnect terms. Otherwise, if other service providers are allowed into the market at cost-based rates (but without being

infrastructure builders) then this could upset the economics of the retail market, and harm the very operators that the measure was designed to help.

ACT would support the solution direction which obliges KPN to charge its

competitors no more than the local interconnection tariff for handling BiBa traffic that KNP itself could have dealt with low in its own network. However, this will only be effective if the local interconnect prices (including the port charges) are efficient and reasonable. Also, as outlined in the answer to question VIIa, other measures may also be necessary to facilitate the appropriate outcome, such as relaxing or removing the price cap on BiBa calls.

However, ACT also consider that the proposed solution direction should be an interim measure that should be deployed only so long as barriers (adequate and efficient access to local exchanges, the lack of an ISI product, price cap pressures on biba) persist. Once these issues are addressed, the need for continuing with this interim measure should be reviewed.

Further, it is essential to note that this solution is necessary only to deal with issues arising from KPN’s ubiquitous network, and resulting interconnection problems with KPN. It would be wholly inappropriate to impose similar principles (i.e. only

(28)

APPENDIX 1:

Reports Required For Proving Cost-Orientation,

non-discrimination & Transparency

1. Output of Network Costs.

This is similar to the EC recommendation that there should be a Statement showing the average cost of network components. However, the content and scope of this statement should be made more explicit, and should identify :

• All the key network components and other cost activities that are involved in providing (both internally and externally) regulated (i.e. RIO) interconnect (and special access) services and wholesale facilities (i.e. including Local Loop Unbundling and Collocation)

• The operating costs of and capital employed for those components

• The applicable regulatory allowable return on capital employed for those components

• The usage volumes (and the volume definition) for each component

• The total unit costs of each component (operating costs + cost of capital)

• This would apply to both Core Network and Local Access Network components.

Such an output would aid both the objectives of cost-orientation and transparency, and would also facilitate comparison, validation, and evaluation of costs against other SMP operators in other member states.

2. Output of Unit Charges for Network Services.

This is closely related to the EC guidelines, which state that operators need to submit data showing no undue discrimination. However, BT Ignite believes that the more explicit data should be provided.

Such an output should include:

• Identification of all the key network components (elements, or activities), their unit charges, and how the unit charges compare with the unit costs (as

calculated in (i))

(29)

• A clear statement of how the unit Network charges for each of KPN’s Retail Business activities / services are derived from the underlying network components – showing clearly the component usage factors (such as route factors) for each activity, the component unit charges, and the calculation of total unit charges;

The above would achieve three key objectives :

• Demonstration of cost-orientation of network charges;

• Transparency in the way that Network Charges have been calculated, and how these relate to the costs of various network components;

• There would be a clear demonstration of non-discrimination (since the same network unit charges would be applied to both interconnection / wholesale services and retail services).

3. Output of total transfer charges between Network Business and the Retail Business and Activities.

The Unit Charges for Network Services (ii) presents the derivation of network unit charges for interconnect and retail activities. An additional statement is required showing the full derivation of the total transfer charges between network and retail business.

This output should show:

• The various retail activities into which the Retail Business is sub-analysed;

• The relevant volume measures of those activities, for the relevant accounting period (e.g. total call minutes, or total calls, or total lines, etc.)

• The network unit charges that were calculated in (ii), above;

• The product of the unit charges and the volumes, in order to identify the total network charge for the activity – this would reconcile with the Network Charges presented in the Profit and Loss account of the retail activities. Thus, for each activity reported within the “Retail” business, it would be possible to see how the total network transfer charge has been derived from the “Unit Charges of Network Services” (see (ii)) and the service volumes.

Such an output would further reinforce the demonstration of non-discrimination, since users of the accounts can see that the total network charges for each retail service have been derived from the unit network charges, which were themselves calculated in a non-discriminatory way.

(30)

P&L accounts. The total network charges (i.e. total revenue of the Network business) would thus be derived either from other operators or from the Retail Business. It would be clear that the revenues in the Network business would be matched by costs in the Retail business.

Such an output would go beyond the current EC guidelines, which only stated that there should be a matrix summarising the inter-business transfer charges. We would insist that a summary of inter-business transfer charges would be insufficient, since it might not consist of a fully detailed calculation of the transfers. Without this, it is impossible to see if non-discrimination has been properly applied.

In addition, the other reports that were outlined in the EC Guidance should continue to be reported, namely:

• Profit and loss and balance sheet for the Businesses, and, in the case of Retail business, the key activities within that business;

• Matrix summarising the inter-business transfer charges;

• A clear statement of reconciliation to published Statutory Accounts. This may need to show the movement between incremental costs, fully allocated costs, current and historic cost accounting etc. to move from the regulatory accounts to published company’s accounts.

The statements should also make clear the extent to which costs are adjusted for regulatory reasons, such as:

• Cost Exclusions, perhaps because they have been disallowed for regulatory reasons;

• Other adjustments (e.g. on the basis of efficiency assessments, or valuation changes, or allocation methodology changes)

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

Session 3: The approach to country grouping by level of costs 14.15 Presentation of the proposed approach, TERA Consultants. 14.45 Q&amp;A session 15:30

Oxera’s method of estimating the risk free rate is inconsistent with OPTA’s methodology applied in previous price reviews in that it is based on the use of spot market data rather

Based on the previous hypotheses, that both indicate that their particular relation to cost reduction is positive, it is expected that the joint effect of lean and refined cost

Overall, we find that OXERA’s WACC report for the Raad contains recommendations that are not consistent with good regulatory practice, and are likely to cause a downward bias in

The lower limit of the band is determined by the lowest (unweighted) average asset beta (either on the basis of weekly data, or on the basis of daily data), while the upper limit

Education in new information and communication technologies appears essential for the development for the prevention of harmful effects of false information, in

Interested parties are requested to submit to the Commission their viewpoints and insights regarding the desirability of possible migration to a multiple-year system for

We therefore fully agree with OPTA's observations in paragraphs 23 and 24 of the consultation document that the current pricing structure for leased lines effectively results in a