• No results found

The Forward Premium Puzzle During Times of Crisis

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "The Forward Premium Puzzle During Times of Crisis"

Copied!
52
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)
(2)

 

Abstract 

(3)
(4)

1 INTRODUCTION

A
 large
 number
 of
 academic
 papers
 have
 investigated
 empirically
 whether
 the
 forward
rate
is
an
unbiased
predictor
of
the
future
spot
exchange
rate
or
not.
These
 tests
are
closely
connected
to
Uncovered
Interest
Parity
(UIP)
theory,
which
states
 that
 the
 expected
 rate
 of
 depreciation
 of
 a
 currency
 against
 another
 currency
 is
 equal
 to
 the
 interest
 rate
 differential
 between
 the
 two
 countries’
 assets.
 Consequently,
investors
assume
that
the
expected
change
in
the
exchange
rate
must
 be
offset
by
the
opportunity
costs
of
holding
funds
in
this
currency,
i.e.
the
interest
 rate
differential.
Furthermore,
in
a
situation
where
Uncovered
Interest
Parity
does
 not
hold,
the
profit
opportunity
exists
by
taking
a
short
position
in
a
low
interest‐rate
 currency
 to
 finance
 the
 purchase
 of
 a
 high
 interest‐rate
 currency,
 while
 taking
 advantage
 of
 the
 fact
 that
 the
 low
 interest‐rate
 currency
 is
 inclined
 to
 depreciate
 relative
to
the
high
interest‐rate
currency.



Surprisingly,
 past
 studies
 have
 shown
 that
 the
 forward
 rate
 is
 not
 an
 unbiased
 predictor
of
the
future
spot
exchange
rate
for
a
large
variety
of
currencies
and
time
 periods
(Fama,
1984;
Froot
and
Thaler,
1990;
Macdonald
and
Taylor,
1992;
Isaard,
 1996).
These
studies
have
not
only
shown
that
the
UIP
condition
does
not
hold,
but
 also
 that
 the
 higher
 interest
 rate
 currency
 tends
 to
 appreciate
 rather
 than
 depreciate.
This
term
is
formally
known
as
the
“forward
bias”
or
“forward
premium
 puzzle”.


How
 the
 forward
 bias
 has
 changed
 over
 time
 and
 different
 economic
 periods
 has
 been
 investigated
 by
 many
 scholars
 before
 (Baillie
 &
 Bollerslev,
 2000;
 Flood
 and
 Rose,
2002;
de
Koning
&
Straetmans,
1997).



(5)

As
 a
 considerable
 amount
 of
 time
 has
 passed
 since
 the
 last
 studies
 about
 the
 changes
in
the
forward
bias
over
time
have
been
conducted,
the
following
paper
is
 going
to
shed
light
onto
the
question
of
how
the
forward
bias
has
changed
during
 the
world
financial
crisis
of
2007‐2009.
With
the
burst
of
the
real
estate
bubble
on
 the
US
housing
market
in
2007
and
the
resulting
collapse
of
Lehman
Brothers
in
the
 beginning
of
2008
the
world
has
witnessed
one
of
the
worst
financial
crises
since
the
 great
depression.
The
consequential
worldwide
drop
in
interest
rates
and
the
follow‐ on
worldwide
increase
in
inflationary
pressure
give
reason
to
believe
that
the
overall
 forward
 bias
 has
 changed.
 More
 specifically
 this
 paper
 is
 going
 to
 answer
 the
 following
research
question:


Has the unbiasedness of the forward rate (forward bias) as a predictor of future spot  exchange rates improved during the financial crisis of 2007‐2009? 

(6)

free
 assets
 in
 the
 home
 and
 the
 foreign
 market
 respectively.
 Simply
 stated
 the
 difference
 between
 the
 forward
 and
 spot
 rate
 (the
 forward
 premium)
 should
 be
 equal
to
the
interest
differential
between
two
countries’
assets.
Since
every
variable
 in
the
above
equation
is
known
beforehand,
any
deviation
in
the
model
would
mean
 excessive
profits
and
therefore
cannot
exist
in
equilibrium.
CIP
has
been
validated
by
 several
 studies
 to
 lie
 within
 the
 bounds
 implied
 by
 existing
 transaction
 costs
 (Obstfeld
and
Taylor,
2004;
Clinton,
1988;
Frenkel
and
Levich,
1975).



In
 addition,
 assuming
 risk
 neutral
 rational
 agents,
 the
 expected
 change
 in
 the
 exchange
 rate
 would
 be
 equal
 to
 the
 interest
 rate
 differential
 between
 two
 currencies
assets,
also
known
as
the
Uncovered
Interest
Parity
condition,
depicted
in
 equation
(2):


Δst+1e
=
it
–
i*t






 
 
 (2)


Where
 Δst+1e
 is
 the
 log
 of
 the
 expected
 change
 in
 the
 exchange
 rate
 during
 the
 period
t+1
and
it
and
i*t
are
the
nominal
interest
rates
on
risk
free
assets
in
the
home
 and
the
foreign
market
respectively.



Since
the
presence
of
an
expected
variable
makes
it
difficult
to
test
for
UIP
directly,
it
 has
 been
 tested
 empirically
 by
 assuming
 rational
 expectations,
 CIP
 and
 the
 non
 existence
 of
 a
 risk
 premium
 in
 the
 forward
 rate
 (risk
 neutral
 efficient
 market
 hypothesis).
Rearranging
equations
(1)
and
(2)
then
allows
us
to
discuss
UIP
in
terms
 of
the
contextual
relationship
between
spot
and
forward
exchange
rates
by
replacing
 the
interest
rate
differential
(it
–
i*t)
with
the
forward
premium/discount.


Δst+1e
=
ft
‐
st




 
 
 (3)


UIP
has
then
been
generally
tested
as
the
null
hypothesis
of
α
=
0
and
β
=
1
and
the
 disturbance
 term
 ηt+1
uncorrelated
 to
 any
 information
 available
 at
 time
 =
 t
 in
 the
 equation
 (also
 known
 as
 the
 Fama‐regression,
 named
 after
 its
 inventor
 Eugene
 Fama):


(7)

Considering
(4),
one
can
assume
that
any
realized
change
in
the
exchange
rate
must
 be
equal
to
the
prevailing
forward
premium,
which
is
the
market’s
best
prediction
of
 the
future
exchange
rate
using
all
available
information.



However,
in
a
world
with
oligopolistic
players
in
financial
markets,
underdeveloped
 money
 markets,
 exchange
 or
 capital
 controls
 or
 risk
 of
 such
 controls,
 differential
 taxation,
limited
supply
of
capital,
sovereign
immunities,
transaction
costs
and
other
 inconveniences,
the
forward
rate
may
not
be
a
perfect
predictor
of
the
future
spot
 rate
(Pasricha,
2006).

 At
this
point
it
is
worth
clarifying
a
few
things
about
equation
(4)
and
its
underlying
 assumptions.
Equation
(4)
is
not
a
direct
test
of
UIP
but
rather
a
test
of
whether
the
 forward
rate
is
a
perfect
predictor
of
the
future
spot
exchange
rate.
The
reason
for
 this
is,
that
under
UIP
the
term
on
the
left
hand
side
should
be
the
expected
change
 in
 the
 exchange
 rate,
 in
 this
 equation,
 however,
 it
 is
 the
 actual
 change
 in
 the
 exchange
 rate.
 Therefore,
 equation
 (4)
 can
 only
 be
 seen
 as
 a
 test
 of
 UIP
 if
 one
 assumes
rational
expectations,
which
states
that
the
expected
exchange
rate
in
the
 next
period
will
on
average
equal
the
actual
exchange
rate
although
it
might
deviate
 by
 a
 random
 error
 (the
 average
 of
 the
 random
 error
 being
 zero).
 Or,
 put
 it
 differently:
On
average
economic
agents
do
not
systematically
over
or
under
predict
 the
exchange
rate
(Pilbeam,
2006).

This
can
be
defined
as:


st+1e = st+1 + ut+1











(5)
 


Where
 st+1e is
 the
 expected
 exchange
 rate
 at
 t+1,
 st+1 is
 the
 actual
 exchange
 rate
 observed
at
t+1
and
ut+1 is
the
random
error
(on
average
zero).


Equation
 (5)
 is
 a
 quite
 strong
 assumption,
 especially
 if
 one
 considers
 that
 various
 scholars
 have
 rejected
 the
 rational
 expectations
 hypothesis
 in
 the
 past
 (see
 Dominguez,
1986;
Liu
and
Maddala,
1992;
Cavaglia
et
al,
1994).



(8)

3 LITERATURE REVIEW

As
mentioned
earlier
UIP
has
become
famous
as
a
theoretical
model,
which
is
often
 rejected
by
data.
Froot
and
Thaler
(1990),
for
example,
report
in
a
famous
survey
an
 average
value
of
‐0,88
for
the
β
in
equation
(4).
Similar
results
have
been
found
in
 Sarno,
 Valente
 and
 Leon
 (2005),
 Hochradl
 and
 Wagner
 (2006),
 Flood
 and
 Rose
 (2002),
Bansal
and
Dahlquist
(2000)
etc.
Therefore
I
am
going
to
take
a
closer
look
at
 some
of
the
possible
explanations
of
the
forward
bias,
which
have
emerged
in
the
 literature.



3.1 Explanations for the bias

Generally,
 the
 explanations
 for
 the
 forward
 premium
 puzzle
 fall
 into
 one
 of
 the
 following
three
categories.


3.1.1 Risk premium

UIP
sets
known
variables
equal
to
unknown
variables,
which
stands
in
contradiction
 to
the
theoretical
intuition
that
investors
are
risk
averse
and
demand
a
risk
premium
 in
case
of
uncertainty.


(9)

Backwardation
and
Contango
can
be
explained
by
an
excess
of
market
participants,
 who
use
forward
contracts
as
a
hedge,
compared
to
market
participants,
who
use
 forwards
as
pure
investments.
For
further
explanation
we
can,
for
example,
take
a
 look
at
the
market
for
crude
oil.
If
oil
producers
want
to
hedge
their
oil
production
 against
falling
oil
prices,
they
sell
their
oil
forward.
In
the
situation
where
oil
is
not
 demanded
in
the
same
amount
as
it
is
supplied
we
have
excess
supply
of
oil
in
the
 forward
 market.
 This
 excess
 supply
 can
 be
 counterbalanced
 by
 investors
 who
 buy
 the
oil
in
the
forward
market,
demanding
however
a
risk
premium,
which
the
risk
 averse
oil
producers
are
willing
to
pay.
The
risk
aversion
of
the
oil
producers
can
be
 explained
by
the
fear
of
falling
oil
prices,
but
mainly
by
the
fear
of
not
being
able
to
 sell
the
oil
right
after
it
has
been
pumped
out
of
the
ground.
In
that
case
inventory
 costs
would
occur.
Oil
producers
than
have
an
interest
to
sell
their
production
early
 in
the
forward
market
for
a
price,
which
is
below
the
expected
price,
by
an
amount
 equal
 to
 the
 inventory
 costs.
 In
 this
 case
 the
 forward
 rate
 will
 be
 lower
 than
 the
 expected
oil
price.



The
other
way
around,
in
a
situation
where
we
have
an
excess
demand
for
oil
in
the
 forward
 market
 by
 oil
 consumers
 who
 want
 to
 hedge
 themselves
 against
 price
 fluctuations,
Contango
will
occur.



Contango
situations
can
occur
when
the
buyer
is
very
dependent
on
the
product.
For
 example,
a
just‐in‐time
producer
of
car
tires
is
willing
to
pay
a
higher
than
expected
 price
 in
 the
 forward
 market
 for
 caoutchuc
 to
 ensure
 that
 the
 raw
 material
 is
 available
 at
 the
 right
 time
 to
 prevent
 a
 stop
 in
 production
 due
 to
 raw
 material
 shortage.



Connecting
this
to
the
FX
market
one
can
say
that
if
investors
are
risk
averse,
then
 the
 forward
 premium
 can
 no
 longer
 be
 seen
 as
 a
 pure
 estimate
 of
 the
 expected
 change
in
future
exchange
rates,
but
must
rather
be
seen
as
the
sum
of
the
expected
 change
 in
 the
 exchange
 rate
 and
 a
 risk
 premium.
 Thus,
 if
 the
 dollar
 is
 viewed
 as
 riskier
than
the
foreign
currency,
dollar
interest
rates
would
have
to
be
higher
even
if
 the
exchange
rate
is
not
expected
to
change
(Froot
and
Thaler,
1990).


(10)

Equation
(6)
illustrates
this
relationship.
It
is
the
same
as
equation
(3)
except
a
risk  premium
component
is
added.

 Fama
(1984)
showed
that
any
explanation
relaying
on
a
risk
premium
for
a
negative
 beta
must
satisfy
either
the
fact
that
there
is
a
negative
correlation
between
the
risk
 premium
and
expected
depreciation
or
that
the
risk
premium
is
more
volatile
than
 the
expected
depreciation.
Unfortunately,
both
risk
premium
models
fail
(Froot
and
 Frankel,
 1989;
 Lewis,
 1995;
 Lucas,
 1982).
 
 Also,
 the
 fact
 that
 the
 unbiasedness
 hypothesis
seems
to
hold
better
in
emerging
markets
might
be
a
sign
that
a
time‐ varying
risk
premium
may
not
be
the
explanation
for
the
forward
bias
as
one
would
 expect
these
markets
to
be
riskier,
but
more
on
that
later.


3.1.2 Forecast errors

Forecast
 errors
 can
 be
 due
 to
 irrational
 expectations
 and/or
 rational
 systematic
 errors.
Froot
and
Frankel
(1987)
show
that
market
participants’
forecasts
of
future
 exchange
rates
could
have
come
closer
to
the
actual
change
in
the
exchange
rate,
if
 they
 had
 relied
 on
 historical
 data.
 The
 reason
 for
 that
 could
 be
 due
 to
 rational
 systematic
errors.
Systematic
errors
can
occur
due
to
an
insufficient
sample
size.
If
 market
participants
expect
an
extreme
exchange
rate
change
for
which
the
chances
 are
 small
 but
 still
 exist
 an
 insufficient
 small
 sample
 size
 might
 not
 capture
 this
 extreme
event.



The
 so
 called
 “peso
 problem”
 is
 an
 example
 of
 that.
 Even
 though
 the
 Mexican
 government
 fixed
 the
 Mexican
 peso
 against
 the
 US
 dollar
 at
 a
 constant
 rate,
 the
 peso
 sold
 at
 a
 forward
 discount
 between
 1955
 and
 1975.
 Of
 course,
 the
 large
 depreciation
 expected
 by
 investors
 eventually
 occurred,
 but
 one
 could
 not
 have
 guessed
this
from
the
1955‐1975
sample
alone.
In
this
case
the
empirical
test
shows
 a
 systematic
 error
 even
 though
 the
 market
 participants
 expectations
 are
 rational
 (Froot
and
Thaler,
1990).


(11)

supply
process
can
explain
about
half
of
the
error
implicit
in
forward
rates.
However,
 the
errors
do
not
seem
to
have
died
out
over
time,
which
is
evidence
against
models
 of
learning
about
once‐and‐for‐all
shifts
in
the
regime
(Froot
and
Thaler,
1990).    

3.1.3 News Model

The
 basic
 rational
 behind
 the
 news
 model
 is
 that
 if
 foreign
 exchange
 markets
 are
 efficient,
meaning
that
current
market
prices
reflect
all
available
information,
then
 any
 difference
 between
 the
 forward
 rate
 and
 the
 corresponding
 rate
 that
 later
 transpires
must,
in
an
efficient
market,
be
due
to
the
arrival
of
new
information
(see
 Pilbeam,
 2006).
 Consequently,
 since
 the
 information
 that
 results
 in
 changes
 in
 expectations
about
exchange
rates
must
be
new,
fluctuations
in
the
spot
exchange
 rate
cannot
be
predicted
by
the
lagged
forward
rate.
Moosa
(2002)
tests
the
News
 Model
 as
 an
 explanation
 for
 the
 forward
 bias
 based
 on
 a
 sample
 of
 quarterly
 observations
covering
six
exchange
rates
during
the
period
of
1975‐2000.
He
rejects
 the
 hypothesis
 that
 the
 News
 Model
 can
 explain
 the
 fluctuations
 in
 the
 exchange
 rate
 and
 therefore
 the
 forward
 bias.
 Instead
 he
 finds
 more
 support
 for
 the
 Risk
 Premium
as
an
explanatory
variable
for
the
forward
bias.
Overall,
however,
empirical
 evidence
 for
 the
 News
 Model
 is
 mixed
 (Frankel,
 1981;
 Edwards,
 1983;
 Hoffman
 &
 Schlagenhauf,
 1985;
 Hardouvelis,
 1988;
 Hogan
 &
 Roberts,
 1991),
 but
 in
 general
 it
 seems
 that
 no
 combination
 of
 news
 variables
 in
 the
 model
 has
 yet
 been
 able
 to
 explain
the
entire
volatility
of
exchange
rates.



3.1.4 Non-linearities

(12)

Lyons
 (2001)
 was
 the
 first
 to
 come
 up
 with
 the
 theory
 of
 limits
 to
 speculation.
 Financial
institutions
usually
only
take
up
a
currency
trading
strategy,
if
this
strategy
 is
expected
to
yield
a
Sharpe
ratio
(excess
return
per
unit
of
risk)
that
is
higher
or
 equal
to
the
one
implied
by
alternative
trading
strategies,
such
as
a
simple
buy
and
 hold
equity
strategy.
Over
the
last
50
years
a
buy
and
hold
strategy
in
US
equities
has
 yielded
a
Sharpe‐ratio
of
about
0,4
on
an
annual
basis
(Lyons,
2001).
Lyons
(2001)
 than
argues,
that
it
is
only
when
beta
equals
about
‐1
or
3
that
the
Sharpe
ratio
for
 currency
strategies
is
about
the
same
as
that
of
equities.
As
long
as
the
beta
stays
 within
 this
 band
 of
 inaction,
 no
 speculative
 capital
 will
 be
 allocated
 to
 exploit
 the
 forward
 bias
 and
 it
 will
 persist.
 His
 explanation
 for
 the
 persistence
 of
 the
 forward
 bias
has
then
basically
four
parts.
Part
one,
as
just
mentioned,
if
speculative
capital
is
 not
allocated
to
exploit
the
forward
bias,
then
the
forward
bias
will
persist.
Part
two,
 institutions
with
a
competitive
advantage
in
exploiting
the
forward
bias
allocate
their
 speculative
capital
based,
in
large
part,
on
Sharpe
ratios.
Part
three,
Sharpe
ratios
of
 reliable
 currency
 strategies
 that
 exploit
 the
 forward
 bias
 are
 roughly
 0,4
 on
 an
 annual
 basis,
 similar
 to
 that
 of
 a
 simple
 buy
 and
 hold
 equity
 strategy.
 Part
 four,
 because
a
Sharpe
ratio
of
0,4
is
well
below
most
institutions’
minimum
threshold
for
 inducing
capital
allocation,
the
anomaly
persists.



Non‐linearities
 have
 empirically
 been
 proven
 by
 Sarno,
 Valente
 and
 Leon
 (2006).
 They
show
that
for
relatively
small
deviations
from
the
band
of
inaction,
only
some
 investors
are
willing
or
able
to
invest
in
currencies.
But
as
the
deviations
get
larger,
 more
and
more
traders
will
start
to
invest.
As
a
consequence,
the
forces
of
supply
 and
 demand
 begin
 to
 work
 and
 push
 beta
 back
 toward
 the
 band
 of
 inaction:
 a
 reversion
back
to
where
UIP
holds.


The
 larger
 the
 deviations
 from
 the
 band
 of
 inaction,
 the
 faster
 the
 market
 forces
 actively
drive
beta
towards
unity
and
we
find
that
UIP
holds.


In
 other
 words,
 once
 Sharpe
 ratios
 are
 substantial
 enough
 to
 attract
 speculative
 capital,
violations
of
UIP
become
mean
reverting
at
a
magnitude
that
is
dependent
 on
the
size
of
the
Sharp
ratio.






By
 taking
 these
 results
 into
 account,
 one
 can
 see
 that
 beta
 is
 a
 function
 of
 time‐ varying
Sharpe
ratios
and
is
likely
to
vary
over
time.



(13)

3.2 Trading the Forward Bias

In
 practice,
 however,
 we
 find
 investors
 (especially
 banks),
 who
 typically
 allocate
 capital
 based
 on
 Sharpe
 ratios
 speculating
 in
 the
 foreign
 exchange
 markets
 all
 the
 time,
 betting
 against
 UIP
 and
 receiving
 profitable
 returns,
 even
 after
 adjusting
 for
 transaction
 costs
 (see
 ZEW
 Bericht,
 2006).
 
 According
 to
 Sarno,
 Velente
 and
 Leon
 (2006)
 this
 should
 not
 happen
 in
 an
 efficient
 market
 because
 once
 the
 deviations
 become
 large
 enough,
 market
 forces
 would
 work
 to
 peter
 out
 any
 excessively
 profitable
opportunities
until
equilibrium
is
reached
where
UIP
holds.


Therefore,
it
must
be
true
that
strategies
exist
which
allow
investors
to
profit
from
 the
forward
bias.


3.2.1 Carry-trade strategies

Carry‐trade
 strategies
 seek
 to
 exploit
 the
 fact
 that
 the
 forward
 rate
 is
 not
 an
 unbiased
 predictor
 of
 the
 future
 exchange
 rate.
 
 Investors
 can
 profit
 from
 selling
 short
 a
 low
 interest‐rate
 currency
 to
 fund
 the
 purchase
 of
 a
 high
 interest
 rate
 currency,
while
at
the
same
time
exploiting
the
fact
that
low
interest‐rate
currencies
 are
inclined
to
depreciate
relative
to
the
high
interest‐rate
currency.

A
recent
study
 by
Burnside
et
all
(2006)
tested
these
carry‐trade
strategies
only
to
find
that
a
simple
 two‐currency
strategy
does
not
yield
Sharpe
ratios
that
are
high
enough
to
attract
 speculative
capital,
since
greater
returns
per
unit
of
risk
can
be
achieved
with
other
 investment
opportunities.



3.2.2 Multi-currency strategies

Multi‐currency
strategies
are
strategies
where
a
portfolio
is
constructed
consisting
of
 multiple
 currencies.
 Using
 diversification
 one
 can
 get
 rid
 of
 the
 unsystematic
 risk
 associated
with
currency
trading
and
receives
a
deposit
portfolio
that
yields
a
higher
 return
 than
 single
 currency
 strategies.
 Furthermore,
 multi‐currency
 strategies
 are
 not
 solely
 based
 on
 Sharpe
 ratios,
 contrary
 to
 the
 LSH
 approach,
 but
 also
 take
 downside
 and
 covariance
 risk
 into
 consideration.
 This
 strategy
 was
 compared
 to
 other
investment
strategies
by
Wagner
and
Hochradl
(2007).



(14)

The
Deutsche
Bank
Forward
Rate
Bias
Trading
System
is
also
adopting
a
diversified
 strategy.
The
strategy
consists
of
going
long
the
three
highest
yielding
currencies
and
 going
short
the
three
lowest
yielding
currencies.
This
strategy
has
yielded
estimated
 Sharpe
ratios
averaging
0,77
for
the
past
16
years
(see.
Fig.
1).
As
one
can
see
from
 Fig.
2
this
strategy
has
been
quite
successful.



3.2.3 Option strategies

A
second
strategy
proposed
by
Wagner
and
Hochradl
(2006)
aimed
at
exploiting
the
 forward
bias
is
an
option
strategy.
Given
that
the
prices
for
options
are
based
on
the
 Black
 &
 Scholes
 Formula,
 it
 is
 possible
 for
 an
 investor
 to
 speculate
 against
 the
 forward
 rate
 by
 placing
 a
 call
 option
 if
 he
 or
 she
 thinks
 the
 forward
 rate
 is
 overpriced,
or
a
put
option
if
he
or
she
feels
that
the
forward
rate
is
under
priced.
A
 strategy
including
options
is
very
risky
and
should
therefore
be
used
only
for
a
small
 percentage
 of
 the
 portfolio
 depending
 on
 the
 risk
 aversion
 of
 the
 fund
 manager
 applying
this
strategy.


However,
 option
 strategies
 also
 record
 significantly
 higher
 returns
 than
 the
 tested
 benchmarks
and
with
these
strategies
even
very
small
deviations
of
UIP
can
result
in
 profitable
returns.



3.2.4 Long Horizon Strategy

(15)

3.3 Unbiasedness at very short and long horizons

3.3.1 Long horizons

Most
 literature
 on
 UIP
 typically
 focuses
 on
 short
 maturities,
 usually
 forward,
 spot
 and
interest
rates
of
maturity
less
than
a
year.
This
is
most
likely
due
to
the
fact
that
 it
 is
 more
 difficult
 to
 obtain
 data
 of
 longer‐term
 rates
 in
 offshore
 markets
 (Chinn,
 2006).
 Nevertheless,
 several
 researchers
 in
 the
 past
 have
 tested
 the
 unbiasedness
 hypothesis
 and
 found
 that
 UIP
 seemed
 to
 hold
 better
 in
 the
 long
 run.
 Chinn
 and
 Meredith
 (2004),
 for
 example,
 show
 that
 panel
 beta
 coefficients
 are
 positive
 and
 closer
 to
 unity
 for
 5‐
 and
 10‐year
 government
 bond
 yields
 than
 for
 government
 bonds
 maturing
 1
 year
 or
 less
 (see
 Fig.3).
 Similar
 results
 were
 found
 by
 Alexius
 (2001),
Flood
and
Tylor
(1997)
and
Lothian
and
Simaan
(1998).
As
already
mentioned
 in
the
previous
section,
a
different
approach
to
test
long‐run
UIP
was
recently
taken
 by
Chin
and
Liang
(2009).
They
developed
a
trading
strategy
assuming
that
if
long‐ run
 UIP
 holds
 ex
 post,
 then,
 if
 a
 foreign
 long‐run
 bond
 produces
 a
 lower
 holding
 period
return
than
a
home
bond
of
the
same
maturity,
for
their
remaining
lives
the
 foreign
 bond
 should
 produce
 a
 return
 higher
 than
 the
 home
 bond.
 Their
 strategy
 was
 tested
 for
 investment
 horizons
 of
 1‐,
 2‐
 and
 3‐years
 and
 they
 show
 that
 the
 return
 increases
 with
 the
 investment
 horizon,
 being
 interpreted
 as
 giving
 further
 support
for
long‐run
UIP.


Explanations
for
the
validity
of
UIP
over
longer
horizons
include:
Weaker
exogeneity
 of
long‐term
rates
as
monetary
authorities
can
only
directly
affect
the
short
rate,
and
 indirectly
the
long
rate
(Chinn
&
Meredith,
2004);
“Preferred
Habit
Model”
meaning
 that
 short‐
 and
 long‐term
 bond
 markets
 are
 segmented
 from
 each
 other
 (Lim
 and
 Ogaki,
 2003);
 Differences
 in
 expectations
 at
 short
 and
 long
 horizons
 (Frankel
 and
 Froot,
1987).



3.3.2 Very short horizons

(16)

not
 actually
 devalued,
 they
 appreciate
 intraday
 because
 investors
 need
 to
 be
 compensated
 for
 the
 risk
 they
 take.
 Overnight
 they
 can
 be
 compensated
 by
 the
 interest
 differential,
 but
 this
 is
 not
 possible
 during
 the
 day.
 Chaboud
 and
 Write
 (2003)
 basically
 investigated
 in
 the
 opposite
 direction.
 Instead
 of
 taking
 a
 look
 at
 intraday
 data,
 when
 no
 interest
 was
 paid,
 they
 considered
 the
 over
 night
 period
 when
interest
did
occur.
The
rationale
behind
this
is
that
if
trading
is
liquid
around
 this
time,
one
should
expect
to
see
a
jump
in
the
exchange
rate
at
exactly
this
point
 to
 offset
 the
 interest
 differential,
 similar
 to
 the
 situation
 when
 a
 stock
 goes
 ex
 dividend.

Their
findings
show
that
in
all
cases,
but
the
yen‐dollar
trade,
the
slope
 coefficient
is
positive
and
not
significantly
different
from
unity.



3.4 Unbiasedness in Emerging Markets

(17)

it
=
rt
+
π



 

 
 
 (7)
 


where
it
is
the
nominal
interest
rate,
rt
is
the
real
interest
rate
and
π
is
the
expected
 rate
of
inflation.
The
nominal
interest
rate
is
the
actual
exchange
rate
observed
in
 the
 market
 and
 the
 real
 interest
 rate
 is
 the
 nominal
 interest
 rate
 adjusted
 for
 inflation.
 Thus,
 an
 increase
 in
 expected
 inflation
 π
 will
 lead
 to
 an
 increase
 in
 the
 nominal
interest
rate
it.
 If
real
interest
rates
are
the
same
internationally
rt
=
r*t
then
the
nominal
interest
 rates
differ
solely
by
expected
inflation.
 
 it
–
i*t
=
π
‐
π*



 
 
 (8)
 


Equations
 (1)
 and
 (2)
 indicate
 that
 the
 interest
 differential
 is
 also
 equal
 to
 the
 expected
change
in
the
exchange
rate
and
the
forward
premium/discount.
We
can
 then
summarize
the
link
between
interest
rates,
inflation
and
exchange
rates
in
the
 following
equation:
 
 it
–
i*t
=
π
‐
π*
=
Δst+1e
=
ft
‐
st




 
 
 (9)
 


Interesting
 to
 note
 at
 this
 point
 is
 that
 according
 to
 Pilbeam
 (2006)
 a
 greater
 variance
 of
 the
 expected
 domestic
 inflation
 rate
 raises
 the
 relative
 riskiness
 of
 domestic
bonds
as
compared
to
foreign
bonds
and
vice‐versa.
That
means
we
would
 expect
 that
 in
 cases
 of
 high
 inflation
 volatility
 the
 risk
 premium
 in
 equation
 (6)
 should
increase.
However,
Bansal
and
Dahlquist
(2000)
and
Flood
and
Rose
(2002)
 both
 affirm
 the
 opposite,
 saying
 that
 in
 countries
 with
 high
 inflation
 volatility
 UIP
 holds
 better,
 in
 which
 case
 one
 would
 expect
 the
 risk
 premium
 in
 equation
 (6)
 to
 decrease
 (zero
 if
 UIP
 holds).
 This
 can
 be
 used
 as
 another
 argument
 against
 a
 risk
 premium.










(18)

whose
coefficients
are
usually
negative.
They
interpret
their
results
indeed
as
proof
 of
 the
 non‐existence
 of
 the
 time‐varying
 risk
 premium
 as
 one
 would
 expect
 that
 emerging
markets
should
be
seen
as
riskier
than
developed
markets.



Taking
 the
 above
 results
 into
 account
 one
 would
 consequently
 suggest
 that
 any
 trading
 strategy
 that
 tries
 to
 exploit
 the
 forward
 bias
 in
 emerging
 markets
 should
 fail.
 However,
 the
 opposite
 seems
 to
 be
 the
 case.
 As
 one
 can
 see
 from
 Fig.
 4
 the
 Deutsche
 Bank
 G10
 Currency
 Harvest
 Index
 (which
 includes
 only
 G10
 currencies)
 performed
 significantly
 worse
 than
 its
 counterpart,
 the
 Global
 Currency
 Harvest
 Index
 (which
 includes
 next
 to
 G10
 currencies
 also
 emerging
 market
 currencies),
 which
is
obviously
contradicting
to
the
findings
above.
Also
interesting
to
note
is
that
 the
Balanced
Currency
Harvest
Index,
which
has
always
a
two
to
three
mix
of
G10
 currencies
and
non‐G10
currencies
in
its
portfolio
performs
best.



3.5 Impact on Firms Cost of Debt

According
to
the
European
Central
Bank
(2008),
residents
of
the
countries
that
have
 joined
the
EU
since
2004,
but
are
not
yet
part
of
the
Euro
area,
issue
almost
80%
of
 their
foreign
currency
denominated
debt
securities
in
euro.
Also,
euro‐denominated
 debt
securities
account
for
about
60%
of
international
issuance
in
the
UK,
Sweden
 and
Denmark
and
more
than
50%
in
North
America.





In
 practice,
 firms
 are
 motivated
 to
 issue
 foreign
 currency
 debt
 for
 three
 reasons.

 First,
 firms
 may
 structure
 their
 financial
 obligations
 to
 match
 the
 currency
 composition
 of
 expected
 cash
 inflows.
 In
 this
 way,
 they
 achieve
 a
 “natural
 hedge”
 and
 minimize
 their
 currency
 risk
 exposure.
 Second,
 they
 may
 wish
 to
 tap
 broader
 and
more
liquid
markets
in
the
major
international
currencies.
Especially
borrowers
 in
 emerging
 markets
 may
 decide
 to
 target
 international
 investors
 because
 their
 domestic
 currency
 markets
 are
 too
 thin
 or
 virtually
 absent,
 in
 particular
 for
 long
 maturities.
And
third,
firms
may
reduce
their
cost
of
capital
by
issuing
debt
in
those
 countries
that
offer
the
lowest
effective
borrowing
costs.



(19)

Alternative
1:
Un‐hedged
domestic
currency
borrowing
at
cost
(1+r)
 Alternative
2:
Un‐hedged
foreign
currency
borrowing
at
costs
E(s1
÷
s0)(1+r*)
 Alternative
3:
Hedged
foreign
currency
borrowing
at
costs
(f0
÷
s0)(1+r*)
 
 Here
r
is
the
domestic
interest
rate,
r*
is
the
foreign
interest
rate,
St
is
the
time
t
 exchange
rate,
expressed
in
units
of
domestic
currency
per
unit
of
foreign
currency.
 F0
is
the
t
=
0
forward
rate
for
purchasing
foreign
currency
at
t
=
1.
If
markets
were
 efficient
than
the
costs
of
each
alternative
should
be
the
same:
 
 1+r
=
E(s1
÷
s0)(1+r*)
=
(f0
÷
s0)(1+r)





 


 
 
(10)
 


By
 taking
 logs
 and
 rearranging
 the
 first
 equality
 of
 equation
 (6)
 we
 arrive
 at
 the
 standard
expression
of
UIP:
 
 r
=
r*
+
E0(s1‐s2)






 
 
 

(11)
 
 Equation
(7)
states
that
the
domestic
interest
rate
is
the
foreign
interest
rate
plus
 any
expected
foreign
currency
appreciation.




(20)

McBrady
 et
 al.
 (2004)
 examine
 the
 correlation
 between
 aggregate
 bond
 denomination
 choice
 and
 estimates
 of
 uncovered
 and
 covered
 borrowing
 costs
 across
a
broad
set
of
currencies
from
1991
to
2003
to
explore
firm
behavior.
Their
 findings
show
strong
evidence
that
managers
respond
to
measures
of
covered
but
 not
 uncovered
 borrowing
 costs.
 In
 other
 words,
 managers
 do
 take
 the
 fact
 of
 the
 forward
 premium
 puzzle
 into
 account
 when
 making
 decisions
 about
 issuance
 of
 foreign
or
domestic
debt,
however
they
only
exploit
the
fact
that
CIP
fails
in
the
long
 run,
 not
 that
 UIP
 does
 not
 hold.
 According
 to
 McBrady
 et
 al.
 (2004),
 there
 are
 substantial
 deviations
 from
 CIP
 over
 the
 long‐run
 when
 currency
 swap
 rates
 are
 being
 used
 and
 these
 deviations
 are
 large
 enough
 to
 trigger
 one‐way
 arbitrage
 opportunities,
which
are
exploited
by
bond
issuers.



3.6 Test of UIP with survey data

(21)

3.7 Unbiasedness over time

As
mentioned
earlier
the
main
purpose
of
this
study
is
to
investigate
how
the
slope
 coefficient
 in
 the
 Fama‐regression
 has
 changed
 over
 time,
 especially
 during
 the
 financial
crises
2007‐2009.
Past
literature
gives
reason
to
believe
that
not
only
the
 slope
 coefficient
 changes
 over
 time
 but
 also
 that
 tests
 of
 the
 unbiasedness
 hypothesis
may
hold
better
during
times
of
crisis.
Flood
and
Rose
(2002)
test
for
UIP
 using
daily
data
of
23
developed
and
developing
countries
and
find
that
UIP
holds
 better
during
the
1990
and
during
times
of
financial
crisis
in
the
sense
that
the
slope
 coefficient
 from
 a
 regression
 of
 exchange
 rate
 changes
 on
 interest
 differentials
 is
 positive
 and
 sometimes
 even
 insignificantly
 different
 from
 unity.
 Baillie
 and
 Bollerslev
 (2000)
 use
 208
 5‐year
 rolling
 regressions
 starting
 in
 March
 1978
 until
 November
1995
and
also
find
that
the
slope‐coefficient
turned
positive
during
the
 1990´s
after
a
long
period
of
negative
values
during
the
1980´s.
Both
Flood
and
Rose
 (2002)
and
Bansal
and
Dahlquist
(2000)
find
that
UIP
held
better
during
times
of
high
 inflation
and
inflation
volatility,
which
was
especially
the
case
in
Iceland
and
some
 Eastern
European
countries
during
2007‐2009.
Variations
in
the
slope
coefficient
of
 the
 Fama‐regression
 were
 also
 tested
 by
 de
 Koning
 and
 Straetmans
 (1997).
 They
 used
 a
 so‐called
 “return
 to
 normality”
 model
 and
 show
 that
 in
 a
 sample
 of
 six
 bilateral
USD
exchange
rates
most
currencies
follow
a
v‐shape
pattern,
meaning
the
 beta
coefficient
first
drops
until
the
middle
of
the
sample
before
eventually
raising
 again.



(22)

exact
reason
why
carry
trades
perform
so
poorly
during
times
of
crises
is
not
100%
 clear.
What
we
know
is
that
when
speculators
risk
appetite
declines,
as
measured
in
 CBOE
VIX
option
implied
volatility
index
and
the
Ted
spread
(the
difference
between
 3‐month
 LIBOR
 Eurodollar
 and
 the
 3‐month
 T‐Bill
 rates),
 speculators
 unwind
 their
 carry
 trade
 positions
 resulting
 in
 negative
 returns
 for
 such
 strategies
 (see
 Brunnermeier,
Nagel
&
Pedersen,
2009).

So
basically
we
can
say
that
during
times
of
 crises,
 when
 the
 VIX
 index
 and
 the
 TED
 spread
 increase,
 investors
 loose
 their
 risk
 appetite
and
start
unwinding
their
carry
trades
and
we
witness
a
“flight
to
liquidity”
 or
“
flight
to
quality”
resulting
in
a
crash
of
the
investment
currency.



Since
carry
trades
exploit
the
fact
that
the
forward
rate
is
not
an
unbiased
predictor
 of
 the
 future
 spot
 exchange
 rate,
 I
 assume
 a
 negative
 correlation
 between
 carry
 trade
 excess
 returns
 and
 the
 unbiasedness
 hypothesis
 and
 therefore
 expect
 the
 slope
 coefficient
 in
 the
 Fama‐regression
 to
 be
 significantly
 positive
 during
 the
 financial
crisis
2007‐2009.



4 DATA AND ANALYSIS

(23)

month
forward
rates
observed
on
a
monthly
basis),
the
core
of
the
empirical
work
is
 based
on
st and
f1t at
the
monthly
frequency
level,
whereas
I
use
monthly
and
weekly
 observations
of
f3t and f6t in
my
robustness
analysis.
The
entire
analysis
will
be
based
 on
equation
(4).
First,
I
am
going
to
run
the
regression
over
the
entire
sample
period
 for
all
currencies
against
the
USD
in
order
to
reject
the
null
hypothesis
of
beta
=
1.
   H1: The beta coefficient in equation (4) is equal to unity (β = 1) over the entire sample  period.  
 H1
is
tested
in
the
following
way.
 H0: β ‐ 1 = 0  against
the
alternative
 Ha: β ‐ 1 ≠ 0  

The
 t‐value
 to
 test
 if
 the
 beta
 coefficient
 is
 significantly
 different
 from
 one
 is
 determined
as
follows:
 tn‐2,α/2  = (β ‐ 1) ÷ (Std. error of β)   H0
is
rejected
if:

 tn‐2,α/2 > 1,282 or
‐ tn‐2,α/2 < ‐1,282  where
n
=
∝
and
α
=
0,1.
 


(24)

final
estimate
is
based
on
data
from
July
2004
to
August
2009
(the
dates
will
differ
of
 course
 for
 each
 currency
 depending
 on
 the
 sample
 size).
 Based
 on
 previous
 literature
 I
 expect
 the
 beta
 coefficient
 to
 fluctuate
 over
 the
 sample
 period
 and
 to
 turn
positive
and
maybe
even
equal
to
one
during
the
financial
crisis
2007‐2009.





  

H3: The beta coefficient in equation (4) will significantly change during the sample  period and eventually turn positive during 2007‐2009. 

The
 results
 are
 expected
 to
 help
 answer
 the
 research
 question
 of
 whether  the
 unbiasedness
of
the
forward
rate
as
a
predictor
of
the
future
exchange
rate
(forward
 bias)
has
improved
during
the
financial
crisis
of
2007‐2009. 

5 RESULTS

Table
1
shows
the
outcome
of
equation
(4)
for
all
individual
currencies
against
the
 USD
over
the
entire
sample
period
(max.
31.01.1089
–
31.08.1989
/
min.
30.09.2004
 ‐
 31.08.2009).
 One
 can
 see
 that
 in
 16
 out
 of
 24
 cases
 the
 beta
 coefficient
 is
 significantly
different
from
one,
meaning
the
null
hypothesis
of
β
=
1
can
be
rejected
 for
most
of
the
cases,
which
is
in
line
with
previous
literature.
Surprisingly,
however,
 I
find
that
on
average
the
beta
coefficient
is
slightly
positive,
which
is
contradicting
 to
 previous
 research,
 which
 usually
 reports
 a
 negative
 average
 beta
 (see
 previous
 sections).
Argentina,
China,
Thailand
and
Taiwan
are
the
only
countries,
which
have
 a
significant
beta
coefficient
at
the
5%
level,
all
being
positive
(all
emerging
market
 countries).
One
possible
explanation
could
be
that
these
currencies
are
fixed
against
 the
USD
and
therefore
fluctuate
only
very
little.



(25)

positive
even
though
slightly
smaller
as
under
the
1‐month
forward
rates.
However,
 the
number
of
countries
where
H1
can
be
rejected
increases.

 
 Table
4
shows
the
results
obtained
when
equation
(4)
was
tested
during
the
financial
 crisis
2007‐2009.
Indeed,
we
can
see
that
the
average
beta
turns
positive
and
now
in
 only
8
out
of
24
cases
H1
can
be
rejected.
China,
Japan,
South
Korea,
New
Zealand
 and
Taiwan
all
have
significant
positive
betas
at
the
10%
level
(for
all
β
>
1).
Worth
 mentioning
is
the
extreme
high
and
significant
beta
of
New
Zealand
which
is
24,339.
 A
beta
above
unity
means
that
the
higher
yielding
currency
depreciated
more
than
 expected
 against
 the
 lower
 yielding
 currency.
 Thus,
 the
 results
 support
 H2
 in
 the
 sense
that
in
most
cases
the
sign
of
the
slope
coefficient
is
positive
and
H1
cannot
be
 rejected
for
the
majority
of
the
cases.
The
robustness
checks
in
Table
5
and
6
also
 show
 a
 positive
 average
 beta.
 Interesting
 to
 note
 is
 the
 average
 beta
 0,924
 when
 equation
(4)
was
tested
with
6‐month
forward
rates,
which
is
very
close
to
one.
In
 order
 to
 increase
 the
 sample
 size
 I
 tested
 equation
 (4)
 during
 the
 financial
 crisis
 2007‐2009
also
with
weekly
observations
(see
Table
7).
However,
weekly
data
was
 only
available
for
18
out
of
the
24
countries.
Again,
we
see
a
positive
average
beta
 and
only
in
seven
out
of
the
18
cases
H1
can
be
rejected
supporting
H2
that
the
beta
 coefficient
is
positive
and
insignificantly
different
from
one.

 
 Charts
1
to
6
show
the
five‐year
rolling
regressions
and
the
corresponding
p‐values
 for
Australia,
Japan,
Switzerland,
Singapore,
Thailand
and
Turkey.
Clearly
in
all
cases
 the
beta
coefficient
varies
significantly
over
time
and
in
all
cases,
except
Turkey,
it
 eventually
 turns
 positive
 and
 above
 one
 during
 2007‐2009
 after
 a
 long
 period
 of
 negative
betas.



(26)

the
beta
coefficient
during
the
period
of
August
1993
and
August
1998.
After
that
 the
 beta
 stayed
 negative
 and
 in
 some
 periods
 even
 significantly
 negative
 until
 the
 period
of
2003‐2009.

 A
similar
picture
is
the
one
for
the
Japanese
Yen.
Here
the
graph
shows
that
there
 are
three
periods
of
positive
betas.
The
first
one
again
during
the
1990s,
the
second
 one
between
1997
and
2002
and
the
last
one
again
during
2003‐2009.
Once
more
all
 of
these
periods
are
times
of
a
financial
crisis.
The
first
period
is
the
one
during
the
 burst
of
the
Japanese
Asset
Price
Bubble,
which
was
the
outcome
of
the
aftermath
 of
the
Plaza
accord
in
1985.
The
second
period
of
positive
betas
is
during
the
time
of
 the
burst
of
the
dot.com
bubble,
which
was
roughly
from
1998
to
2001.
And
the
last
 period
again
is
the
time
of
the
current
financial
crisis.

 Things
look
almost
the
same
in
Switzerland
except
that
the
beta
coefficient
during
 the
 early
 and
 mid
 1990s
 stayed
 between
 0
 and
 1.
 But
 once
 more
 we
 see
 positive
 betas
during
the
burst
of
the
dot.com
bubble
of
1998‐2001
and
the
financial
crisis
of
 2007‐2009.



In
 Singapore
 we
 have
 a
 long
 period
 between
 1989
 and
 2002
 in
 which
 the
 beta
 coefficient
was
mostly
positive
but
almost
never
above
one.
Indeed
the
Asian
Crisis
 did
 not
 affect
 Singapore’s
 economy
 as
 much
 as
 other
 Asian
 countries,
 which
 is
 mainly
 due
 to
 actions
 taken
 by
 the
 government.
 That
 is
 why
 we
 see
 only
 slightly
 positive
betas
in
the
graph
during
that
time.

After
that
we
have
a
longer
period
of
 negative
betas
(sometimes
even
significantly)
before
they
turn
positive
again
during
 the
world
financial
crisis
2007‐2009.


It
is
basically
the
same
in
Taiwan
except
that
the
data
set
does
not
go
back
as
far
in
 time
 as
 it
 did
 in
 the
 previous
 countries.
 But
 again
 we
 have
 slightly
 negative
 betas
 during
the
period
of
2001‐2007
until
the
slope
coefficient
again
(significantly)
turns
 positive
as
soon
as
the
period
of
the
financial
crisis
is
covered.



Only
 Turkey
 shows
 a
 different
 picture.
 Up
 until
 January
 2006
 the
 slope
 coefficient
 was
 almost
 constant
 at
 a
 rate
 of
 ‐0,2
 before
 it
 turned
 slightly
 positive
 for
 a
 short
 period
and
then
turned
negative
again
until
the
end
of
the
observation
period.

  

(27)

different
 from
 one,
 which
 happens
 predominantly
 during
 times
 of
 financial
 crises.
 This
 has
 several
 important
 implications.
 First
 of
 all,
 it
 explains
 why
 carry‐trades
 perform
 so
 poorly
 during
 such
 periods.
 Carry‐trades
 are
 dependent
 on
 the
 phenomena
that
the
higher
yielding
currency
appreciates
against
the
lower
yielding
 currency,
 and
 therefore
 negative
 beta
 coefficients.
 If
 the
 beta
 coefficient
 now
 becomes
positive
and
exceeds
one,
the
exact
opposite
happens.
The
higher
yielding
 currency
will
depreciate
(more
than
expected)
and
the
lower
yielding
currency
will
 appreciate
and
hence,
the
carry
trade
will
have
negative
returns.



(28)

depreciating
less
than
expected
in
this
area,
meaning
investors
gain
on
the
interest
 differential
even
though
they
lose
on
the
exchange
rate
change.



(29)
(30)

Moreover,
as
argued
by
de
Koning
and
Straetmans
(1997),
fixed
coefficient
methods
 such
as
rolling
regressions
often
have
the
disadvantage
of
choosing
the
right
rolling
 window
 size.
 They
 argue
 that
 this
 method
 is
 suboptimal
 in
 detecting
 stochastic
 or
 systematic
 coefficient
 variation,
 when
 it
 is
 indeed
 present
 in
 the
 data.
 A
 better
 model
 in
 that
 case
 would
 be
 the
 so‐called
 “return
 to
 normality”
 model
 (see
 de
 Koning
&
Straetmans,
1997).



(31)

8 BIBLIOGRAPHY

Alexius,  A.  (2001).  Uncovered  Interest  Parity  revisited.  Review  of  International  Economics , 9, 505‐517.    Allayannis, G., Brown, G., & Klapper, L. (2003). Capital structure and financial  risk: evidence from foreign debt use in East Asia. Journal of Finance , 58, 2667‐ 2709.    Baillie, R. T., & Bollerslev, T. (2000). The forward premium anomaly is not as bad  as you think. Journal of International Money and Finance , 19, 471‐488.   

Baldwin,  R.  (1990).  Re.Interpreting  the  Failure  of  Foreign  Exchange  Market  Efficiency Tests: Small Transaction Costs, Big Hysteresis Bands. National Bureau  of Economics Reserach Working Paper N. 3319 .    Bansal, R., & Dahlquist, M. (2000). The forward premium puzzle: different tales  from developed and emerging economies. Journal of International Economics , 51,  115‐144.   

Brunnermeier,  M.  K.,  Nagel,  S.,  Pedersen,  L.  H.,  (2009).  Carry  Trades  and  Currency Crashes. NBER, 313‐347. 

 

Burger,  J.  D.,  &  Warnock,  F.  E.  (2007).  Foreign  participation  in  local  bond  markets. Review of Financial Economics , 16, 291‐304. 

 

Burnside,  C.,  Eichenbaum,  M.,  Kleshchelski,  I.,  &  Rebelo,  S.  (2006,  August).  The  Returns To Curreny Speculation. NBER Working Paper , 1‐59. 

 

Cavaglia,  S.,  Vershoor,  W.,  &  Wolff,  C.  (1994).  On  the  Unbiasedness  of  Foreign  Exchanges: Irrationality or a Risk Premium? Journal of Business , 67, 321‐52.    Chaboud, A. P., & Wright, J. H. (2003, May). Uncovered Interest Parity: It Works,  but not for long. Working Paper , 1‐19.    Chin, C.‐C., & Liang, H.‐M. (2009). The long‐run uncovered interest Parity in view  of a trading strategy. Applied Economics , 41, 2727‐2739.   

Chinn,  M.,  &  Frankel,  J.  (2002).  Survey  Data  On  Exchange  Rates  Expectations:  More  Currencies,  More  Horizons,  More  Tests.  (W.  A.  Dickinson,  Ed.)  Monetary  Policy,  Capital  Flows  And  Financial  Market  Development  In  The  Era  Of  Financial  Globalisation: Essay In Honour Of Max Fry , 145‐67 

 

Chinn,  M.  D.  (2006).  The  (partial)  rehabilitation  of  interest  rate  parity  in  the  floating  rate  era:  Longer  horizons,  alernative  expectations,  and  emerging  markets. Journal of International Money and Finance , 25, 7‐21. 

 

Clinton, K. (1988). Transaction Costs and Covered Interest Arbitrage: Theory and  Evidence. Journal of Political Economy , 96, 358‐370. 

(32)

de Koning, C., & Straetmans, S. (1997). Variations in the slope coefficient of the   Fama regression for testing uncovered interest parity: Evidence from fixed and  time‐varying coefficient approaches. Working Paper , 1‐26. 

 

DeutscheBank.  (2004).  Global  Markets  Reserach  ­  Trading  the  Bias.  Deutsche  Bank, Global Markets. New York: Deutsche Bank. 

 

Deutsche Bank (2007). db Currency Harvest. Deutsche Bank, Global Markets.    

Deutsche  Bank  (2009).  Deutsche  Bank  Currency  Returns.  Deutsche  Bank,  Global  Markets.  

 

Dominguez,  K.  M.  (1986).  Are  Foreign  Exchange  Forecasts  Rational?  New  Evidence from Survey Data. Economic Letters , 21, 277‐81. 

 

Dumas, B. (1992). Dynamic Equilibrium and The Real Exchange Rate in a   Spatially Seperated World. Review of Financial Studies , 5, 153‐180.   

Edwards,  S.  (1983).  Floating  Exchange  Rates,  Expectations,  and  New  Information. Journal of Monetary Economics , 11 (3), 321‐336. 

 

Eisenberg,  A.,  &  Rudlof,  M.  (2002).  Das  Forward  Premium  Puzzle:  Noch  immer  ein  Rätsel.  In  J.  M.  Kleeberg,  &  H.  Rehkugler,  Handbuch  Portfolio  Management  (Vol. 2, pp. 707‐738 ). Uhlenbruch Verlag. 

 

European Central Bank (2008). The International Role of the Euro. ISSN 1725‐ 6593. 

 

Fahri,  E.,  Fraiberg,  S.  P.,  Gabaix,  X.,  Ranciere,  R.,  &  Verdelhan,  A.  (2009).  Crash  Risk  in  Currency  Markets.  Financial  Economics  and  International  Macroeconomics, Discussion Paper No. 7322 , 1‐36. 

 

Fama,  E.  F.  (1984).  Forward  and  Spot  Exchange  Rates.  Journal  of  Monetary  Economics , 14, 319‐338. 

 

Farka,  M.  (2004).  5­Year  Annualized  Sharpes.  Deutsche  Bank,  Global  Markets.  New York: Deutsche Bank.    Flood, R. P., & Taylor, M. P. (1997). Exchange rate economics, what´s wrong with  the conventional macro aproach? The Microstructure of Foreign Exchange   Markets. University of Chicago for NBER , 262‐301.   

Flood,  R.  P.,  &  Rose,  A.  K.  (2002).  Uncovered  Interest  Parity  in  Crisis.  IMF  Staff  Paper , 49 (2), 253‐266. 

 

Frankel,  J.  A.  (1981).  Flexible  Exchange  Rates,  Prices  and  the  Role  of  "News":  Lessons from the 1970s. Journal of Political Economy , 89 (4), 665‐705. 

(33)

Frankel,  J.  A.,  &  Froot,  K.  A.  (1987).  Using  Survey  Data  to  Test  Standard  Propositions Regrading Exchange Rate Expectations. American Economic Review ,  77, 133‐53.    Frankel, J. A., & Froot, K. A.  (1989). Forward Discount Bias: Is it an Exchange Risk  Premium? The quarterly Journal of Economics , 104 (1), 139‐161.   

Frankel,  J.  A.,  &  Poonawala,  J.  (2006).  The  Forward  Market  in  Emerging  Currencies, Less Biased than in Major Currencies. NBER Working Paper . 

 

Frenkel,  J.  A.,  &  Levich,  R.  M.  (1975).  Covered  Interest  Arbitrage:  Unexploited  Profits? Journal of Political Economy , 83, 325‐338. 

 

Froot,  K.  A.,  &  Thaler,  R.  H.  (1990).  Anomalies:  Foreign  Exchange.  Journal  of  Economic Perspectives , 4 (3), 179‐192. 

 

Graham, J. R., & Harvey, C. R. (2001). The Theory and practice of corporate fiance:  evidence from the field. Journal of Financial Economics , 60, 187‐243. 

 

Hardouvelis,  G.  A.  (1988).  Economic  News,  Exchange  Rates  and  Interest  Rates.  Journal of International Money and Finance , 7 (1), 23‐35.    Hochradl, M., & Wagner, C. (2007). Trading the Forward Bias: Are there Limits to  Speculation? Working Paper , 1‐40.    Hoffman, D. L., & Schlagenhauf, D. E. (1985). The Impact of News and Alternative  Theories of Exchange Rate Determination. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking ,  17 (3), 328‐346.    Hogan, K. M., & Roberts, D. J. (1991). Trade Balance News and Exchange Rates: Is  There a Policy Signal? Journal of International Money and Finance , 10, 90‐99.    Isaard, P. (1996, June). Uncovered Interest Parity. IMF Working Paper .    Johnson, D. (1988). The currency denomination of long‐term debt in the  Canadian corporate sector: an empirical analysis. Journal of International Money  and Finance , 7, 77‐90.   

Kedia,  S.,  &  Mozumdar,  A.  (2003).  Foreign  Currency‐Denominated  Debt:  An  Empirical Examination. Journal of Business , 76 (4), 521‐546.    Keloharju, M., & Niskanen, M. (2001). Why do firms raise foreign currency  denominated debt? Evidence from Finland. European Financial Management , 7  (4), 481‐496.   

(34)

Lewis,  K.  K.  (1995).  Puzzles  in  International  Financial  Markets.  Handbook  of  International Economics , 3, 1913‐1949. 

 

Lim,  H.,  &  Ogaki,  M.  (2003).  A  Theory  Of  The  Exchange  Rates  And  The  Term  Structure  Of  Interest  Rates.  Rochester  Center  For  Economic  Research  Working  Paper No. 504 . 

 

Liu, P. C., & Maddala, G. S. (1992). Using Survey Data to Test Market Efficiency in  the Foreign Exchange Markets . Empirical Economics , 17, 303‐14. 

 

Lothian,  J.  R.,  &  Simaan,  Y.  (1998).  International  financial  relations  under  the  current float, evidence from panel data. Open Economics Review , 9 (4), 293‐313.    Liu, F., & Sercu, P. (2005, July). The Forward Puzzle: Long‐memory Bias, Short‐ term Expectations. Working Paper , 1‐27.    Lucas, R. E. (1982). Interest Rates and Currency Prices in a Two‐Country World.  Journal of Monetary Economics , 10, 335‐359.   

Lustig,  H.,  &  Verdelhan,  A.  (2007).  The  Cross‐Section  of  Foreign  Currency  Risk  Premia  and  US  Consumption  Growth  Risk.  American  Economic  Review  ,  97  (1),  89‐117.    Lyons, R. K. (2001). The Microstructure Approach to Exchange Rates. Cambridge,  Massachusetts, USA: Massachusetts Institute of Technology.    Lyons, R. K., & Rose, A. K. (1995). Explaining Forward Exchange Bias... Intraday.  Journal of Finance , L (4), 1321‐1329.   

Maccallum,  B.  T.  (1994).  A  Reconsideration  of  the  Uncovered  Interest  Parity  Relationship. Journal of Monetary Economics , 33, 105‐132. 

 

Macdonald,  R.,  &  Taylor,  M.  (1992).  Exchange  Rate  Economics:  A  Survey.  IMF  Staff Paper , 39 (1), 1‐57. 

 

Mark,  N.  C.,  &  Moh,  Y.  K.  (2002).  Continuous‐Time  Market  Dynamics,  ARCH  Effects and the Forward Premium Anomaly. Working Paper . 

 

McBrady,  M.  R.,  &  Schill,  M.  J.  (2004,  September).  The  Currency  Denomination  Decision: Do Firms Seek Bargains in International Bond Markets? Working Paper,  1‐34. 

 

Moh,  Y.  K.  (2002).  Exchange  Rate  Dynamics  in  a  Continuous‐Time  Model  of  Uncovered Interest Parity and the Regulated Jump‐Diffusion Interest Differential.  Working Paper . 

 

Moosa,  I.  A.  (2002).  A  Test  of  the  News  Model  of  Exchange  Rates.  Weltwirtschftliches Archiv , 138, 694‐710. 

(35)

Obstfeld,  M.,  &  Taylor,  A.  (2004).  Global  Capital  Markets:  Integration,  Crisis  and  Growth. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. 

 

Pasricha,  G.  K.  (2006,  December).  Survey  of  Literature  on  Covered  and  Uncovered Interest Parities. Dissertation Proposal , 1‐30. 

 

Pilbeam, K. (2006). International Finance. New York: Palgrave MacMillan.   

Plantin,  G.,  &  Shin,  H.  S.  (2007,  July).  Carry  Trades  and  Speculative  Dynamics.  Working Paper , 1‐29. 

 

Roll,  R.,  &  Yan,  S.  (2000).  An  explanation  of  the  forward  premium  puzzle.  European Financial Management , 6 (2), 121‐148. 

 

(36)

   

9 APPENDIX

  Figure 1                            Source: Deutsche Bank Global Markets Research        Figure 2    Source: Deutsche Bank Global Markets Research        

Deutsche Bank @

5-Year Annualized Sharpes

18 August 2004 FX R es G lo b al M ar ke ts R es ea rc h Mira Farka ermira.farka@db.com FX Research New York (1) (212) 250-3628 David Folkerts-Landau Managing Director, Head of Global Markets Research

The figure shows annualized Sharpe Ratio measured as a fraction of annual average excess returns over annualized standard deviation for a rolling 5-year period. As shown in the graph, rolling Sharpes for the Forward Rate Bias Strategy are positive and for the most part w ell above 0.3 threshhold maintained as the average S&P500 annuzlaised Sharpe ratio.

The vie ws expressed in this report accurately reflect the personal vie ws of the undersigned lead analyst about the subject issuers and the securities of those issuers. In addition, the undersigned lead analyst(s) has not and will not receive any compensation for provid-ing specific recommendation or vie w in this report. [Mira Farka]

5-Year Annualized Sharpes for the Forward Rate Bias Stretegy

Source: DB GM Research IMPORTANT: Please see conflict disclosures

and analyst certification immediately at the end of the text of this report. Deutsche Bank does and seeks to do business with issuers covered in its reports. As a result investors should be aware that Deutsche Bank may have a conflict of interest that could adversely affect the ob-jectivity of its reports. Investors should con-sider this report only as a single factor in mak-ing their investment decision.

0.00 0.50 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50

Feb-91 Apr-92 Jun-93 Aug-94 O ct-95 Dec-96 Feb-98 Apr-99 Jun-00 Aug-01 Oct-02 Dec-03

Deutsche Bank @

Cumulative Excess Returns

18 August 2004 FX R es ea rc h G lo b al M ar ke ts R es ea rc h Mira Farka ermira.farka@db.com FX Research New York (1) (212) 250-3628

The graph shows the Cumulative Excess Return Index resulting from investing in Forward Rate Bias Strategy. Our results show that de-spite volatility in returns, the Forward Bias Strategy offers attractive excess returns over time. As of August 1, 2004 the Cumulative Ex-cess Return Index stands at 320.

The vie ws expressed in this report accurately reflect the personal vie ws of the undersigned lead analyst about the subject issuers and the securities of those issuers. In addition, the undersigned lead

Cumulative Excess Returns: Forward Rate Bias Stretegy

Source: DB GM Research IMPORTANT: Please see conflict disclosures

and analyst certification immediately at the end of the text of this report. Deutsche Bank does and seeks to do business with issuers covered in its reports. As a result investors should be aware that Deutsche Bank may have a conflict of interest that could adversely affect the ob-jectivity of its reports. Investors should con-sider this report only as a single factor in mak-ing their investment decision.

60 110 160 210 260 310 360

(37)

      37  Figure 3    Notes: Panel beta coefficients at different horizons.   Source: M. Chinn (2006)    Figure 4    Notes: The effective annual return over the period from the Balanced Currency Harvest was 15.22%.  The Global Currency Harvest returned 12.07% and the G10 Currency Harvest returned 8.02%.   Source: Deutsche Bank           

shorter. This interpretation seems to be borne out by

Cheung et al.’s (2005)

finding that interest

parity predicts exchange rates better at long horizons than at short.

Chinn and Meredith (2004)

explain the divergence in short- and long-horizon results by

ap-pealing to a monetary reaction function that responds to exchange rate changes. The approach

broadly follows the mechanism first suggested by

McCallum (1994)

, and re-interpreted

econo-metrically by

Anker (1999)

and

Kugler (2000)

. However, Chinn and Meredith explain the

pat-tern of estimates by appealing to a term structure that links short- to long-maturity bonds; since

the monetary authority can only directly affect the short rate, and indirectly the long rate, there

is less endogeneity of the long-term interest differential.

This interpretation can be re-interpreted in an econometric framework following

Moore

(1994)

and

Villanueva (2005)

.

Chinn and Meredith (2005)

show that long-term rates are

more weakly exogenous than short-term rates, and that this can explain the divergence in results

in a statistical sense.

-0.8 -0.4 0.0 0.4 0.8 1.2 -0.76 -0.76 -0.54 0.09 0.67 0.68

3 mos. 6 mos. 1 year 3 years 5 years 10 years

/

Unbiasedness coefficient value

Fig. 3. Panel beta coefficients at different horizons. Notes: up to 12 months, panel estimates for 6 currencies against US$, euro deposit rates, 1980Q1e2000Q4; 3-year results are zero-coupon yields, 1976Q1e1999Q2; 5 and 10 years, constant yields to maturity, 1980Q1e2000Q4 and 1983Q1e2000Q4. Sources: 3, 6, 12 months, 5 and 10 years from

Chinn and Meredith (2004); 3 years, author’s calculations using data supplied by Geert Bekaert.

Table 3

Ex post depreciation and 10-year government bond yields ^ a b^ Reject H0: b ¼ 1 R2 N Deutschemark 0.001 (0.005) 1.025 (0.225) 0.51 88 Japanese yen 0.027 (0.011) 0.469 (0.202) *** 0.10 88 U.K. pound 0.006 (0.003) 0.767 (0.098) *** 0.45 88 Canadian dollar "0.004 (0.003) 0.672 (0.138) *** 0.09 88 Constrained panela e 0.758 (0.168) 0.56 352

Notes: point estimates from the regression in Eq.(6) (serial correlation robust standard errors in parentheses, calculated assuming approximately 2 # (k " 1) moving average serial correlation).

Sample period: 1983Q1e2004Q4. * (**)[***] Different from null of unity at 10%(5%)[1%] marginal significance level.

a

Fixed effects regression. Standard errors adjusted for serial correlation (assumes k " 1 moving average serial cor-relation, cross averaging across currency pairs).

Forward Bias in the World’s

Currency Markets

Currency forwards are derived from non-arbitrage arguments based on

nominal interest rates. Research shows that currency forwards may be a biased predictor of future spot. In other words statistical analysis

demonstrates that high yielding currencies tend to over-compensate investors for depreciation risk.

Eg:

! Currency 1 has a nominal

yield of 10%

! Currency 2 has a nominal

yield of 5%,

! The 1 year currency

forward has to be priced such that it is expected Currency 1 will

depreciate by 5% in 1 year’s time otherwise an arbitrage would be possible.

Historically there has been a bias that Currency 1 tends not to depreciate

Historic Performance of the Indices

The historic performance of the Deutsche Bank Currency Harvest indices is shown on an excess return basis net of costs. 50 100 150 200 250 300

Sep-00 Sep-01 Sep-02 Sep-03 Sep-04 Sep-05 Sep-06 Sep-07

Balanced Currency Harvest Global Currency Harvest G10 Currency Harvest

Performance of the Currency Harvest Indices:

Excess Return September 2000 – October 2007

Source: Deutsche Bank

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

The purpose of this thesis is to provide an insight into the extent to which the Tribunal has provided victim witnesses a platform for truth telling, as one of the needs of

In South Africa, beauty influencers are predominantly used by mega- brands who dominate the South African cosmetics market in order to reach local consumers.. The title

in ons land zijn aanzienlijke aantallen cliënten uit de zorg werkzaam, vooral bij uitvoerende werkzaamheden in de natuur; Bij Staatsbosbeheer, Natuurmonumenten, de

Globally, the World Health Organisation (WHO) estimates that about 8 million new cases of tuberculosis occur, and that there are about 3 million deaths from tuberculosis, each

Through the African Scholars &amp; Institutions initiative, surveys were conducted in 2010 (East &amp; Southern Africa, with UNICEF) and 2012 (West &amp; Central Africa, with

In this section the third question is answered: Is there a need for new digital language tools amongst the respondents and if so, which? The participants were asked if

The qualitative results from the open-ended network interview questions gives validity to the hypothesis that networking increases opportunity recognition for the firms

Since the forward premium is proven to be positively related to the spot price volatility in the EU ETS market, one can conclude that the spot price