• No results found

University of Groningen A global value chain perspective on trade, employment, and growth Ye, Xianjia

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "University of Groningen A global value chain perspective on trade, employment, and growth Ye, Xianjia"

Copied!
9
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

University of Groningen

A global value chain perspective on trade, employment, and growth

Ye, Xianjia

IMPORTANT NOTE: You are advised to consult the publisher's version (publisher's PDF) if you wish to cite from it. Please check the document version below.

Document Version

Publisher's PDF, also known as Version of record

Publication date: 2017

Link to publication in University of Groningen/UMCG research database

Citation for published version (APA):

Ye, X. (2017). A global value chain perspective on trade, employment, and growth. University of Groningen, SOM research school.

Copyright

Other than for strictly personal use, it is not permitted to download or to forward/distribute the text or part of it without the consent of the author(s) and/or copyright holder(s), unless the work is under an open content license (like Creative Commons).

Take-down policy

If you believe that this document breaches copyright please contact us providing details, and we will remove access to the work immediately and investigate your claim.

Downloaded from the University of Groningen/UMCG research database (Pure): http://www.rug.nl/research/portal. For technical reasons the number of authors shown on this cover page is limited to 10 maximum.

(2)

References

Acemoglu, Daron. 2002. “Directed technical change.” The Review of Economic Studies 69 (4): 781–809.

Acemoglu, Daron, and David Autor. 2011. “Skills, tasks and technologies: implications for employment and earnings.” In Handbook of Labor Economics, edited by David Card and Orley Ashenfelter, vol. 4(B), 1043–1171. Elsvier.

Acemoglu, Daron, Gino Gancia, and Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2015. “Offshoring and directed technical change.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 7 (3): 84–122. Anderson, James E. 1979. “A theoretical foundation for the gravity equation.” The

Amer-ican Economic Review 69 (1): 106–116.

Anderson, James E., and Eric Van Wincoop. 2003. “Gravity with gravitas: a solution to the border puzzle.” The American Economic Review 93 (1): 170–192.

Angrist, Joshua D., and Alan B. Krueger. 1999. “Empirical strategies in labor economics.” Chap. 23 in Handbook of Labor Economics, edited by David Card and Orley Ashen-felter, vol. 3(A), 1277–1366. North Holland.

Antr`as, Pol, and Davin Chor. 2013. “Organizing the global value chain.” Econometrica 81 (6): 2127–2204.

Antr`as, Pol, and Stephen R. Yeaple. 2014. “Multinational firms and the structure of inter-national trade.” In Handbook of Interinter-national Economics, edited by Gita Gopinath, Elhanan Helpman, and Kenneth Rogoff, 4:55–130. Elsevier.

Artal-Tur, Andr´es, Juana Castillo-Gim´enez, Carlos Llano-Verduras, and Francisco Requena-Silvente. 2011. “The factor content of regional bilateral trade: the role of technology and demand.” International Review of Economics & Finance 20 (2): 157–172. Autor, David H., David Dorn, and Gordon H. Hanson. 2013. “The China syndrome:

local labor market effects of import competition in the United States.” American Economic Review 103 (6): 2121–2168.

. 2015. “Untangling trade and technology: evidence from local labour markets.” The Economic Journal 125 (584): 621–646.

Autor, David H., Frank Levy, and Richard J. Murnane. 2003. “The skill content of recent technological change: an empirical exploration.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 (4): 1279–1333.

Balassa, Bela. 1965. “Trade liberalisation and “revealed” comparative advantage.” The Manchester School 33 (2): 99–123.

Baldwin, Richard. 2006. “Globalisation: the great unbundling (s).” Economic Council of Finland.

. 2013. “Trade and industrialization after globalization’s second unbundling: how building and joining a supply chain are different and why it matters.” In Globalization in an age of crisis: multilateral economic cooperation in the twenty-first century,165–

(3)

128

Baldwin, Richard, and Fr´ed´eric Robert-Nicoud. 2014. “Trade-in-goods and trade-in-tasks: an integrating framework.” Journal of International Economics 92 (1): 51– 62.

Baltagi, Badi, and James Griffin. 1988. “A general index of technical change.” Journal of Political Economy 96 (1): 20–41.

Baumol, William J. 1967. “Macroeconomics of unbalanced growth: the anatomy of urban crisis.” The American Economic Review 57 (3): 415–426.

Becker, Sascha. O., Karolina Ekholm, and Marc-Andreas Muendler. 2013. “Offshoring and the onshore composition of tasks and skills.” Journal of International Economics 90 (1): 91–106.

Bems, Rudolfs, Robert C. Johnson, and Kei-Mu Yi. 2013. “The great trade collapse.” Annual Review of Economics 5 (1): 375–400.

Bergstrand, Jeffrey H. 1985. “The gravity equation in international trade: some microeco-nomic foundations and empirical evidence.” The Review of Ecomicroeco-nomics and Statistics 67 (3): 474–481.

. 1989. “The generalized gravity equation, monopolistic competition, and the factor-proportions theory in international trade.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 71 (1): 143–153.

Berndt, Ernst R. 1991. The Practice of Econometrics: Classic and Contemporary. Addison-Wesley Publishing Company.

Binswanger, Hans P. 1974. “The measurement of technical change biases with many factors of production.” American Economic Review 64 (6): 964–976.

Blackorby, Charles, and R. Robert Russell. 1989. “Will the real elasticity of substitution please stand up? (A comparison of the Allen/Uzawa and Morishima elasticities).” American Economic Review 79 (4): 882–888.

Blinder, Alan S., and Alan B. Krueger. 2013. “Alternative measures of offshorability: a survey approach.” Journal of Labor Economics 31 (2): S97–S128.

Bowen, Harry P., Edward E. Leamer, and Leo Sveikauskas. 1987. “Multicountry, mul-tifactor tests of the factor abundance theory.” The American Economic Review 77 (5): 791–809.

Brecher, Richard A., and Ehsan U. Choudhri. 1993. “Some empirical support for the Heckscher-Ohlin model of production.” Canadian Journal of Economics: 272–285. Bryce, David J., and Sidney G. Winter. 2009. “A general interindustry relatedness index.”

Management Science 55 (9): 1570–1585.

Chen, Natalie. 2004. “Intra-national versus international trade in the European Union: why do national borders matter?” Journal of international Economics 63 (1): 93– 118.

Chirinko, Robert S. 2008. “σ: the long and short of it.” Journal of Macroeconomics 30 (2): 671–686.

(4)

Choi, Yong-Seok, and Pravin Krishna. 2004. “The factor content of bilateral trade: an empirical test.” Journal of Political Economy 112 (4): 887–914.

Christensen, Laurits R., Dale Jorgenson, and Lawrence J. Lau. 1973. “Transcendental logarithmic production frontiers.” Review of Economics and Statistics 55 (1): 28–45. Clark, Colin. 1940. The conditions of economic progress. Alianza Editorial SA, Madrid. Conley, Timothy G., and Bill Dupor. 2003. “A spatial analysis of sectoral

complemen-tarity.” Journal of Political Economy 111 (2): 311–352.

Davis, Donald R., and David E. Weinstein. 2001. “An account of global factor trade.” The American Economic Review 91 (5): 1423–1453.

Dedrick, Jason, Kenneth L. Kraemer, and Greg Linden. 2009. “Who profits from inno-vation in global value chains?: a study of the iPod and notebook PCs.” Industrial and Corporate Change: 1–36.

Denny, Michael, and Doug May. 1977. “The existence of a real value-added function in the Canadian manufacturing sector.” Journal of Econometrics 5 (1): 55–69. Diewert, Walter E., and Terence J. Wales. 1987. “Flexible functional forms and global

curvature conditions.” Econometrica 55 (1): 43–68.

Disdier, Anne-C´elia, and Keith Head. 2008. “The puzzling persistence of the distance effect on bilateral trade.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 90 (1): 37–48. Ebenstein, A., A. Harrison, M. McMillan, and S. Phillips. 2014. “Estimating the impact

of trade and offshoring on American workers using the Current Population Surveys.” Review of Economics and Statistics 96 (4): 581–595.

Egger, Peter, and Michael Pfaffermayr. 2004. “Distance, trade and FDI: a Hausman– Taylor SUR approach.” Journal of Applied Econometrics 19 (2): 227–246.

Ellison, Glenn, Edward L. Glaeser, and William R. Kerr. 2010. “What causes indus-try agglomeration? evidence from coagglomeration patterns.” American Economic Review 100 (3): 1195–1213.

Erumban, Abdul Azeez, Reitze Gouma, Gaaitzen J. de Vries, Klaas de Vries, and Marcel P. Timmer. 2012. WIOD Socio-Economic Accounts (SEA): sources and methods. h ttp://www.wiod.org/publications/source_docs/SEA_Sources.pdf. University of Groningen.

Ethier, Wilfred J. 1982. “National and international returns to scale in the modern theory of international trade.” The American Economic Review 72 (3): 389–405.

Feenstra, Robert C. 1998. “Integration of trade and disintegration of production in the global economy.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 12 (4): 31–50.

Feenstra, Robert C. 2015. Advanced international trade: theory and evidence. Princeton University Press.

Feenstra, Robert C., and Gordon H. Hanson. 1996. “Foreign investment outsourcing and relative wages.” In The Political Economy of Trade Policy: Papers in Honor of Jagdish Bhagwati, edited by Robert Feenstra and Douglas A. Irwin, 89–127. MIT

(5)

130

. 1997. “Foreign direct investment and relative wages: evidence from Mexico’s maquiladoras.” Journal of International Economics 42 (3-4): 371–393.

. 1999. “The impact of outsourcing and high-technology capital on wages: esti-mates for the United States, 1979–1990.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (3): 907–941.

. 2003. “Global production sharing and rising inequality: a survey of trade and wages.” In Handbook of International Trade, edited by Kwan E. Choi and James Harrigan, 119–145. Blackwell Publishing.

Feenstra, Robert C., Robert Inklaar, and Marcel P. Timmer. 2015. “The next generation of the Penn World Table.” American Economic Review 105 (10): 3150–3182. Feenstra, Robert C., James R. Markusen, and Andrew K. Rose. 2001. “Using the gravity

equation to differentiate among alternative theories of trade.” Canadian Journal of Economics 34 (2): 430–447.

Feng, Andy, and Georg Graetz. 2015. Rise of the machines: the effects of labor-saving innovations on jobs and wages. Discussion Paper 1330. CEP.

Firpo, Sergio, Nicole M. Fortin, and Thomas Lemieux. 2011. Occupational tasks and changes in the wage structure.Discussion Paper 5542. IZA.

Goos, Maarten, Alan Manning, and Anna Salamons. 2014. “Explaining job polarization: routine-biased technological change and offshoring.” American Economic Review 104 (8): 2509–2526.

Grossman, Gene M., and Esteban Rossi-Hansberg. 2008. “Trading tasks: a simple theory of offshoring.” American Economic Review 98 (5): 1978–1997.

Hakura, Dalia S. 2001. “Why does HOV fail?: the role of technological differences within the EC.” Journal of International Economics 54 (2): 361–382.

Harrison, Ann, John McLaren, and Margaret McMillan. 2011. “Recent perspectives on trade and inequality.” Annual Review of Economics 3:261–289.

Hausmann, Ricardo, Jason Hwang, and Dani Rodrik. 2007. “What you export matters.” Journal of Economic Growth 12 (1): 1–25.

Hausmann, Ricardo, Lant Pritchett, and Dani Rodrik. 2005. “Growth accelerations.” Journal of Economic Growth 10 (4): 303–329.

Haveman, Jon, and David Hummels. 2004. “Alternative hypotheses and the volume of trade: the gravity equation and the extent of specialization.” Canadian Journal of Economics 37 (1): 199–218.

Helpman, Elhana. 1984. “The factor content of foreign trade.” The Economic Journal 94 (373): 84–94.

Herrendorf, Berthold, Richard Rogerson, and ´Akos Valentinyi. 2013. “Two perspectives on preferences and structural transformation.” American Economic Review 103 (7): 2752–2789.

(6)

Hidalgo, C´esar A., Bailey Klinger, Albert-Laszlo Barab´asi, and Ricardo Hausmann. 2005. “The product space and its consequences for economic growth.” Unpublished work-ing paper, the earlier version for the Science paper.

. 2007. “The product space conditions the development of nations.” Science 317 (5837): 482–487.

Hijzen, Alexander, Holger G¨org, and Robert C. Hine. 2005. “International outsourcing and the skill structure of labour demand in the United Kingdom.” Economic Journal 115 (506): 860–878.

Hillberry, Russell, and David Hummels. 2003. “Intranational home bias: some explana-tions.” Review of Economics and Statistics 85 (4): 1089–1092.

Hummels, David L. 1999. “Toward a geography of trade costs.” Unpublished Mimeo, University of Chicago.

Hummels, David, Jun Ishii, and Kei-Mu Yi. 2001. “The nature and growth of vertical specialization in world trade.” Journal of International Economics 54 (1): 75–96. Humphrey, John, and Olga Memedovic. 2003. “The global automotive industry value

chain: what prospects for upgrading by developing countries.” UNIDO Sectorial Studies Series Working Paper.

Humphrey, John, and Hubert Schmitz. 2002. “How does insertion in global value chains affect upgrading in industrial clusters?” Regional studies 36 (9): 1017–1027. Jarreau, Joachim, and Sandra Poncet. 2012. “Export sophistication and economic growth:

evidence from China.” Journal of Development Economics 97 (2): 281–292. Jin, Hui, and Dale W. Jorgenson. 2010. “Econometric modeling of technical change.”

Journal of Econometrics 157 (2): 205–219.

Johnson, Robert C., and Guillermo Noguera. 2012. “Accounting for intermediates: pro-duction sharing and trade in value added.” Journal of international Economics 86 (2): 224–236.

. 2016. “A portrait of trade in value added over four decades.” NBER Working Paper No. 22974.

Jorgenson, Dale W. 1986. “Econometric methods for modeling producer behavior.” In Handbook for Econometrics, edited by Zvi Griliches and Michael D. Intriligator, 3:1841–1915. Noord-Holland.

Kali, Raja, Javier Reyes, Joshua McGee, and Stuart Shirrell. 2013. “Growth networks.” Journal of Development Economics 101:216–227.

Karabarbounis, Loukas, and Brent Neiman. 2014. “The global decline of the labor share.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (1): 61–103.

Koopman, Robert, Zhi Wang, and Shang-Jin Wei. 2012. “Estimating domestic content in exports when processing trade is pervasive.” Journal of development economics 99 (1): 178–189.

(7)

132

Krugman, Paul. 1980. “Scale economies, product differentiation, and the pattern of trade.” The American Economic Review 70 (5): 950–959.

Krusell, Per, Lee E. Ohanian, Jos´e-V´ıctor R´ıos-Rull, and Giovanni L. Violante. 2000. “Capital-skill complementarity and inequality: a macroeconomic analysis.” Econo-metrica 68 (5): 1029–1053.

Lai, Huiwen, and Susan Chun Zhu. 2007. “Technology, endowments, and the factor con-tent of bilateral trade.” Journal of International Economics 71 (2): 389–409. Lemoine, Francoise, and Deniz ¨Unal-Kesenci. 2004. “Assembly trade and technology

transfer: the case of China.” World Development 32 (5): 829–850.

Lenzen, Manfred, Daniel Moran, Keiichiro Kanemoto, and Arne Geschke. 2013. “Build-ing Eora: a global multi-region input–output database at high country and sector resolution.” Economic Systems Research 25 (1): 20–49.

Leontief, Wassily W. 1936. “Quantitative input and output relations in the economic systems of the United States.” Review of Economics and Statistics 18 (3): 105–125. . 1949. “Structural matrices of national economies.” Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society: 273–282.

. 1953. “Domestic production and foreign trade; the American capital position re-examined.” Proceedings of the American philosophical Society 97 (4): 332–349. Lewis, W. Arthur. 1954. “Economic development with unlimited supplies of labour.” The

Manchester School 22 (2): 139–191.

Lin, Justin Yifu. 2012. New structural economics: a framework for rethinking development and policy. World Bank Publications.

Lin, Justin Yifu, and Ha-Joon Chang. 2009. “Should industrial policy in developing countries conform to comparative advantage or defy it? A debate between Justin Lin and Ha-Joon Chang.” Development Policy Review 27 (5): 483–502.

Lin, Justin Yifu, and Yan Wang. 2008. “China’s integration with the world: development as a process of learning and industrial upgrading.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series.

Lin, Justin, and C´elestin Monga. 2011. “DPR debate: Growth identification and facili-tation – the role of the state in the dynamics of structural change.” Development Policy Review 29 (3): 259–310.

Los, Bart, Marcel P. Timmer, and Gaaitzen J. de Vries. 2015. “How important are ex-ports for job growth in China? A demand side analysis.” Journal of Comparative Economics 43 (1): 19–32.

. 2016. “Tracing value-added and double counting in gross exports: comment.” American Economic Review: 1958–1966.

Los, Bart, Marcel Timmer, and Gaaitzen J. de Vries. 2015. “How global are global value chains? A new approach to measure international fragmentation.” Journal of Re-gional Science 55 (1): 66–92.

(8)

Mayer, Thierry, and Soledad Zignago. 2011. “Notes on CEPII’s distances measures: the GeoDist database.” CEPII Working Paper, No. 2011–025.

Michaels, Guy, Ashwini Natraj, and John Van Reenen. 2014. “Has ICT polarized skill demand? Evidence from eleven countries over 25 years.” Review of Economics and Statistics 96 (1): 60–77.

Miller, Ronald E. 1966. “Interregional feedback effects in input-output models: some preliminary results.” Papers of the Regional Science Association 17 (1): 105–125. Miller, Ronald E., and Peter Blair. 2009. Input-Output analysis foundations and

exten-sions. 2nd ed. Cambridge University Press.

Nedelkoska, Ljubica, Frank Neffke, and Simon Wiederhold. 2015. “Skill mismatch and the costs of job displacement.” Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association. Neffke, Frank, and Martin Henning. 2008. “Revealed relatedness: mapping industry

space.” Papers in Evolutionary Economic Geography, University of Utrecht 8:19. . 2013. “Skill relatedness and firm diversification.” Strategic Management Journal 34 (3): 297–316.

Neffke, Frank, Martin Henning, and Ron Boschma. 2011. “How do regions diversify over time? Industry relatedness and the development of new growth paths in regions.” Economic Geography 87 (3): 237–265.

Oldenski, Lindsay. 2012. “The task composition of offshoring by US multinationals.” International Economics 131:5–21.

O’Mahony, Mary, and Marcel P. Timmer. 2009. “Output, input and productivity mea-sures at the industry level: the EU KLEMS database.” The Economic Journal 119 (538): F374–F403.

Pasinetti, Luigi L. 1973. “The notion of vertical integration in economic analysis.” Metroe-conomica 25 (1): 1–29.

Puzzello, Laura. 2012. “A proportionality assumption and measurement biases in the factor content of trade.” Journal of International Economics 87 (1): 105–111. Redding, Stephen, and Anthony J. Venables. 2004. “Economic geography and

interna-tional inequality.” Journal of Internainterna-tional Economics 62 (1): 53–82.

Reimer, Jeffrey J. 2006. “Global production sharing and trade in the services of factors.” Journal of International Economics 68 (2): 384–408.

Silva, J. M. C. Santos, and Silvana Tenreyro. 2006. “The log of gravity.” The Review of Economics and statistics 88 (4): 641–658.

Sinopoli, Carla M. 2003. The political economy of craft production: crafting empire in South India, c. 1350–1650. Cambridge University Press.

Sraffa, Piero. 1960. Production of commodities by means of commodities. Cambridge University Press.

(9)

devel-134

Tatemoto, Masahiro, and Shinichi Ichimura. 1959. “Factor proportions and foreign trade: the case of Japan.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 41 (4): 442–446. Teece, David J., Richard Rumelt, Giovanni Dosi, and Sidney G. Winter. 1994.

“Under-standing corporate coherence: Theory and evidence.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 23 (1): 1–30.

Timmer, Marcel P., Erik Dietzenbacher, Bart Los, Robert Stehrer, and Gaaitzen J. de Vries. 2015. “An illustrated user guide to the world input–output database: the case of global automotive production.” Review of International Economics 23 (3): 575– 605.

Timmer, Marcel P., Abdul Azeez Erumban, Bart Los, Robert Stehrer, and Gaaitzen J. de Vries. 2014. “Slicing up global value chains.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 28 (2): 99–118.

Timmer, Marcel P., Bart Los, Robert Stehrer, and Gaaitzen J. de Vries. 2016. “An natomy of the global trade slowdown based on the WIOD 2016 release.” GGDC Research Memorandum 162.

Trefler, Daniel. 1995. “The case of the missing trade and other mysteries.” The American Economic Review 85 (5): 1029–1046.

Trefler, Daniel, and Susan Chun Zhu. 2010. “The structure of factor content predictions.” Journal of International Economics 82 (2): 195–207.

Valentinyi, Akos, and Berthold Herrendorf. 2008. “Measuring factor income shares at the sector level.” Review of Economic Dynamics 11 (4): 820–835.

Vanek, Jaroslav. 1968. “The factor proportions theory: the n—factor case.” Kyklos 21 (4): 749–756.

Wahl, Donald F. 1961. “Capital and labour requirements for Canada’s foreign trade.” Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science 27 (03): 349–358.

Wei, Shang-Jin. 1996. “Intra-national versus international trade: how stubborn are na-tions in global integration?” NBER Working Paper No. 5531.

Wolf, Holger C. 2000. “Intranational home bias in trade.” Review of Economics and Statistics 82 (4): 555–563.

Wolff, Edward N. 1985. 1985. “Industrial composition, interindustry effects, and the U.S. productivity slowdown.” Review of Economics and Statistics 67 (2): 268–277. Xu, Bin, and Jiangyong Lu. 2009. “Foreign direct investment, processing trade, and the

sophistication of China’s exports.” China Economic Review 20 (3): 425–439. Yi, Kei-Mu. 2010. “Can multistage production explain the home bias in trade?” The

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

In contrast the results based on the OECD sample indicate that in case an economy with a TFP level that is higher than 96% of the US, an increase of the average years of

Nowadays, most manufacturing products are produced in global value chains, with different stages of production taking place in different countries in the world.. Underdeveloped

The conventional measure defines bilateral factor exports as the domes- tic factor content of the exporting country that is embedded in its bilateral gross export flows. Under

The average across countries, given in the last row, suggests that task-reallocation within GVCs and biases in technical change have comparable effects on domestic demand

I find that in non-European developing countries, the new comparative advantages emerged mostly in the low-skilled tasks of sophisticated manufacturing sectors, and the

Maar binnen deze meer geavanceerdere industrie¨ en blijven ontwikkelingslan- den laaggeschoolde taken uitvoeren, en de kans van verticale structurele verbetering naar

To be more specific, I focus on the subsample of developing a comparative advantage in medium- and high-skilled labour, and to test the hypothesis whether the existence of a

A global value chain perspective on trade, employment, and growth Ye, Xianjia.. IMPORTANT NOTE: You are advised to consult the publisher's version (publisher's PDF) if you wish to