• No results found

Cover Page The handle

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Cover Page The handle"

Copied!
17
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

The handle http://hdl.handle.net/1887/42959 holds various files of this Leiden University dissertation

Author: Wang, Jinxian

Title: Trends in social assistance, minimum income benefits and income polarization in an international perspective

Issue Date: 2016-09-15

(2)

social assistance and minimum income benefits across 26

OECD

countries, 1990 – 2009

ABSTRACT

Recent studies show that social assistance benefit replacement rates have declined in many OECD countries. The aim of this study is to explore the determinants of these developments in social assistance benefit schemes. As such, we seek to make two contributions. First, this paper provides insight into the role of political, institutional and socio-economic drivers of the vari- ation in social assistance benefits across countries and over time. Remarkably, in comparison to other welfare state programs, the comparative political economy literature has paid little attention to the developments of social assistance benefit schemes. The second contribution has an empirical character.

One explanation for the lack of scholarly attention for social assistance benefits is the limited availability of data. Cross-national data on social expenditures and income replacement rates are available for several welfare state programs, but not for social assistance benefits. Presenting minimum income benefit replacement rates, this study analyzes the developments of social assistance benefits across 26OECDcountries over the past two decades.

3.1 INTRODUCTION

With the return of mass unemployment in Europe and otherOECDcountries and with substantial cutbacks in first-tire social insurance, social assistance has become more important as a safeguard against low income and poverty.

Almost allOECDcountries have minimum income benefit schemes for house- holds that do not have sufficient other resources to support themselves (Adema, 2006). A number of studies in the comparative welfare state literature show that the generosity of social assistance benefits has declined in many

Earlier versions of this chapter were presented at the 23rdInternational Conference of Europeanists (CES, 2016) and the 11thEuropean Network for Social Policy Conference (ESPAnet, 2013). We thank all participants and Koen Caminada, Kees Goudswaard, Carlo Knotz, Michal Polakowski, David Rueda, Duane Swank, Dorota Szelewa, Stefan Thewissen, Tim Vlandas and Chen Wang for useful suggestions and comments. The study has received support under the European Commission’s 7th Framework Programme (FP7/2013-2017) under grant agreement n°312691, InGRID – Inclusive Growth Research Infrastructure Diffusion.

(3)

OECDcountries over the past few decades (Cantillon and Van den Bosch, 2002;

Hölsch and Kraus, 2004; Immervoll, 2009; Lødemel and Moreira, 2014; Nelson, 2008). More specifically, recent studies show that in some countries govern- ments have increased the generosity of social assistance benefit schemes, but that these increases were not enough to keep the benefit levels in line with the wages (Van Mechelen and Marchal, 2013; Wang and Van Vliet, 2016).

Interestingly, there is substantial variation in the developments of social assistance benefits across countries. In some countries, benefits decreased more than in other countries and in a number of countries social assistance benefits were increased. The question is how to explain this variation. To date, the sources of this variation have not been examined. The aim of this study is to explore the determinants of the developments in social assistance benefits across 26OECDcountries over the past two decades.

One of the most discussed explanations for declining generosity levels of welfare state programs is the pressure stemming from economic developments, such as economic globalization or increased unemployment rates (Busemeyer 2009; Cameron, 1978; Garrett and Mitchell, 2001; Pierson, 2001; Steinmo, 1994;

Swank 2001). With regard to globalization, governments tend to cut tax burdens in order to facilitate competitive conditions for domestic firms due to increasing competitiveness pressures in global markets. The resulting budgetary pressure triggers or contributes to reductions of social protection levels. Similarly, soaring levels of unemployment lead to high levels of social expenditures, which may put pressure on social assistance benefit schemes.

Simultaneously, increasing exposure to economic globalization and unemploy- ment rates may lead to an increased demand from voters for social protection in order to compensate the increased economic insecurity. Whether the budget- ary pressure or the increased demand for social protection dominates depends on the political constellation and the institutional settings, which differ between welfare state programs (Burgoon, 2001). Providing benefits to the long-term unemployed, typical labor-market outsiders, social assistance benefit schemes form a peculiar type of welfare state program. As the long-term unemployed are not very organized and therefore weakly represented in the policy-making process, social assistance benefits may form an easy target when policy-makers have to deal with budgetary pressure. In this study, we assess the role of economic developments in the changes of social assistance benefits, accounting for several political and institutional factors.

This study seeks to make two contributions to the comparative political economy literature on the reform of social protection programs. In the com- parative political economy literature, the determinants of the benefit levels of several welfare state programs have been examined, including unemploy- ment benefits, sick pay benefits, and pension benefits (e.g. Allan and Scruggs, 2004; Hicks and Freeman, 2009; Korpi and Palme, 2003; Swank, 2011), except social assistance benefits. Hence, the first contribution of this study is that it provides insight into the changes of social assistance benefits. The second

(4)

contribution has an empirical character. One explanation for the lack of scholar- ly attention for the determinants of social assistance benefits is the limited availability of data. Cross-national data on social expenditures and income replacement rates are available for several welfare state programs, but not for social assistance benefits. Presenting minimum income benefit replacement rates, this study analyzes the developments of social assistance benefits across 26 advanced capitalist democracies.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we discuss the literature and hypotheses regarding the determinants of minimum income benefits. Section 3 describes the data and measures of minimum income replacement rates and the independent variables as well as the methods used in the empirical analysis. Subsequently, Section 4 presents the developments of the minimum income replacement rates and the results of the regression analysis. Section 5 concludes.

3.2 SOCIAL ASSISTANCE BENEFITS,GLOBALIZATION AND DOMESTIC FACTORS

3.2.1 Social assistance and minimum income benefits

Social assistance or minimum income benefits can be defined as public transfers that are aimed at helping individuals and households obtain an adequate standard of living (Adema, 2006; Immervoll et al., 2015). Another characteristic of minimum income benefits is that these schemes are generally means-tested and non-contributory schemes. Since basic social assistance allowances are usually supplemented with other low-income programs, such as child supple- ments and tax credits, we use the terms ‘social assistance’ and ‘minimum income’ benefits interchangeably in this paper. An important goal of minimum income benefit schemes is preventing and reducing financial poverty. However, several recent studies have shown that in manyOECDcountries social assistance benefits are not effective in lifting households out of poverty (Figari et al., 2013;

Marchal et al., 2014; Nelson, 2013). Moreover, there are no signs that the trend of declining benefit levels has come to an end.

3.2.2 Pressure from globalization and unemployment

A first explanation for the declining trends in social assistance benefit levels may be the budgetary pressure stemming from economic globalization. Over the past few decades, the process of globalization has accelerated rapidly across

OECD countries, which has triggered an extensive scholarly debate on the relationship between economic openness and welfare generosity. In particular, governments seem to be confronted with two essential but seemingly conflict- ing goals – opening markets for a prosperous economy versus keeping gen-

(5)

erous welfare benefits (Ha, 2008). In this respect, the efficiency hypothesis states that globalization has put pressure on welfare states to roll back social benefits and implement efficiency-oriented reforms. In more generous welfare regimes, investors and manufactures cannot compete effectively with their counterparts because of higher tax burdens and labor market rigidities which are associated with more generous social welfare (Steinmo, 1994). In order to reduce competit- ive pressures for exposed sectors, policy makers are inclined to reduce social security levels and tax burdens to lower labor costs and to improve the competitiveness of domestic producers (Garrett and Mitchell, 2001; Leibrecht et al., 2011). Subsequently, policy makers respond to policy changes in com- petitor nations, resulting in a policy competition and a so-called ‘social race to the bottom’. So far, a number of studies have reported negative relationships between international economic integration and welfare state generosity (Allan and Scruggs, 2004; Burgoon, 2001; Busemeyer, 2009; Jahn, 2006; Korpi and Palme, 2003; Swank, 2005).

Contrary to the efficiency hypothesis, the compensation hypothesis predicts a positive relationship between economic openness and benefit levels. For example, Cameron (1978) explains a positive correlation between trade ex- posure and social expenditures by suggesting that governments in open economies tend to provide a variety of income supplements to shelter their economies form the competitive risks in the international economy. Cameron’s finding, and his explanation of it, has had a lasting influence on studies of welfare state developments. Particularly, in the industrialized countries, increasing imports from less developed countries have reduced demand for labor and increase the labor market elasticity, leading to increased individual perception of insecurity (Ha, 2008; Scheve and Slaughter, 2004). As a result, rising risks and insecurity from world markets force governments to com- pensate for those who have been harmed by increasing globalization (Brady et al., 2005; Rodrik, 1998).

In addition, several studies have found mixed results for the association between openness and social policy changes (Bretschger and Hettich, 2002;

Hicks and Zorn, 2005) whereas another body of research reports no widespread or insignificant effects (Castles, 2001; Ivesen and Cusack, 2000; Kittel and Winner, 2005). One explanation for the mixed results is that the impact of globalization varies across different types of welfare state programs as these programs are embedded in different political constellations and institutions.

In this regard, Burgoon (2001) argues that employee organizations on the one hand and employers organizations on the other respond differently to increased economic openness. In line with the efficiency hypothesis, employers organiza- tions can be expected to seek for lower production costs and a more productive production process in response to increased globalization. As social assistance benefits impose higher labor costs – via taxation – whereas they do not increase productivity (contrary to for example active labor market policies), employers organizations can be expected to support social assistance benefit cuts. On

(6)

the other hand, employees may experience more economic risks as a result of globalization. In line with the compensation hypothesis, it can be expected that trade unions will oppose benefit cuts and that they will even ask for more generous social assistance benefits. Taken together, the impact of globalization on social policies depends on the institutional setting of the specific program.

In the case of social assistance benefits, this does not lead to a clear hypothesis on beforehand, as the preferences of employers and employees are opposed to each other. Social assistance benefits are not included in Burgoon’s (2001) classification, but we would classify social assistance benefits in the group of programs with ‘conflictual politics’ and ‘indeterminate outcome’, like unem- ployment benefit schemes.

Similarly, domestic economic developments may put pressure on social assistance benefit schemes and they may increase the demand for social pro- tection. First of all, increased levels of unemployment lead to higher expend- itures on unemployment benefits and social assistance benefits. This increased spending puts pressure on the government budget and this may trigger benefit cuts (Allan and Scruggs, 2004; Hicks and Freeman, 2009). At the same time, higher levels of unemployment also lead to a higher perceived risk of becoming unemployed for employees. This will increase the demand for social protection (Jensen, 2011; Persson and Tabellini, 2000; Van Vliet et al., 2012).

Finally, the trend of deindustrialization acrossOECDcountries may affect social policy changes in a similar way as globalization does according to the compensation hypothesis. Structural labor market changes resulting from the transitions from an industrial economy to an economy that is largely based on service sectors, can cause economic risks for employees. This increases the demand for social protection (Iversen and Cusack, 2000). Thus, we hypothesize that deindustrialization is positively associated with minimum income replace- ment rates.

3.2.3 Domestic institutions

In addition to effects of globalization, the developments in social assistance benefits can be expected to be driven by a number of domestic factors.

Partisanship is traditionally considered to be an important factor to explain the variation in the generosity of welfare state programs (Hicks and Swank, 1992). Specifically, left-wing governments are usually more inclined to rep- resent the interests of employees and to pursue expansionary policies in reaction to economic shocks (Cusack et al., 2006; Garret and Lange, 1991; Korpi, 2003). However, several scholars point out that partisan effects have become less important in determining the trajectory of public social spending in recent years (Castles, 2001; Kittel and Winner, 2005; Kwon and Pontusson, 2010;

Potrafke, 2009). Vis (2009), on the contrary, argues that there is no evidence for diminishing partisan effects on social transfers. With respect to social

(7)

assistance benefits, a positive relationship between left-wing governments and means-tested social assistance might be expected (George, 1998). However, Jessoula et al. (2014) argue that left-wing parties may prefer more to support broader (occupational) social insurance programs rather than social assistance benefits, whereas right-wing parties may actually support social assistance benefits, rather than social insurance programs, as a less expensive program to help those harmed by market failures. Inspired by these studies, we examine to what extent the left-wing parties are positively related to social assistance benefits.

Trade unions are usually considered as important actors in welfare state reforms and as strong defenders of social insurance programs (Rueda, 2007;

Starke, 2006). However, it is unclear whether trade unions have similar policy preferences with respect to social assistance benefits as they have regarding social insurances. A first reason why trade unions may have deviating prefer- ences with regard to social assistance benefits is that the recipients of these benefits are mainly long-term unemployed, whereas trade unions mainly represent the interests of the employed and the short-term unemployed workers. A second reason is that in many countries, trade unions have been involved in the organization of social insurances. In order to protect the legitimacy of their organizations and the number of union members, trade unions have an incentive to defend the generosity of social insurance schemes (Olson, 1965). Moreover, when trade unions are involved in the organization of social insurance schemes, they have also a considerable degree of influence on policy changes. In contrast, trade unions do not have a formal responsibility in the provision of minimum income benefits, as they are provided by the state (Clegg, 2014). Nevertheless, trade unions may have an important incentive to resist social assistance benefit cuts. The most important power source that unions posses is their control over the labor supply (Rothstein, 1992). When benefit levels fall and the means of existence are affected, workers may have an incentive to underbid the union-set wage level. This will put pressure on the wage levels and the control of unions over the labor supply will be dimin- ished, which forms a threat to union strength (Rothstein, 1992; Wallerstein, 1989). Hence, we hypothesize that trade unions are positively associated with social assistance benefit levels.

With respect to institutional factors, it has been argued and shown in previous studies that the level of coordination of bargaining between social partners is associated with the generosity of the welfare benefits (e.g. Ebbing- haus and Hassels, 2000; Swank and Martin, 2001). In a more centralized system bargaining, trade unions have more influence in the policy-making process and because of that they can limit benefit cuts more effectively. Hence, we expect that collective wage-bargaining is positively related to social assistance benefits. In addition, political institutions may be relevant factors in the social assistance policy-making process. Political constraints such as veto points reduce the feasibility of policy changes (Bonoli, 2001; Henisz, 2002). Therefore,

(8)

we test whether political constraints are negatively linked to changes in social assistance benefits. Finally, the study accounts for the type of electoral system.

In a system of proportional representation, parties with egalitarian policy goals are provided with more institutional opportunities to pursue widely supported policies or to resist benefit cuts (Martin and Swank, 2004; Swank, 2001). Thus, it is expected that proportional representation electoral systems are positively associated with social assistance benefits.

3.3 DATA,MEASURES AND METHOD

3.3.1 Dependent variable

The dependent variables of this study is the net minimum income replacement rate, which is defined as the ratio of the net minimum income benefit level to the net average production worker wage. This indicator gives an impression of the level of social assistance benefits relative to the wages in a country (Wang and Van Vliet, 2016).

Specifically, data for minimum income benefits are derived from the Social Assistance and Minimum Income Benefit Interim Dataset (Nelson, 2013). The minimum income benefit package includes basic allowance, child supplements, other supplements and tax credits.1The denominator, the average production worker wage, is defined as the in-work wage after deducting taxes. For the average production worker wage, we used data from theOECDand Van Vliet and Caminada (2012).2

1 One-time social assistance allowance to cover unexpected and urgent needs or regular benefits to cover exceptional needs are not included in this benefit package. Furthermore, housing supplements are not included for two reasons. First, by excluding housing supple- ments, the definition of minimum income benefit is consistent with the definition used in studies on unemployment benefit. In fact, by using this definition, our results for global- ization, as discussed below, are comparable to that using unemployment replacement rates (Van Vliet and Caminada, 2012). Second, the inclusion of housing supplements requires a number of demanding assumptions. Van Mechelen et al. (2011) have shown that the assumptions regarding the actual housing costs strongly determine the resulting benefit indicators. Therefore, we follow Scruggs’ (2005) approach to exclude the housing supple- ments from our minimum income benefit package.

2 The OECD has made a fundamental change in the approach of the average wages. The classical approach of calculating the average wage was based on the average wage of a production worker (APW), which refers to the wage level in the manufacturing industry.

The new concept for the average wage refers to the average worker wage (AW), which includes much more sectors. The differences in the levels of the APW and the AW can be significant for individual countries. The transition from APW to AW started in 2005 and the AW is available from 2000 onwards. The APW data is available for all years up to 2005 and for the year 2007. Hence, there is no consistent time series for the period 1990–2009.

In order to have a consistent replacement rate time series, Van Vliet and Caminada (2012) estimated the APW for the years 2006, 2008 and 2009 based on the growth rate of the AW.

(9)

The replacement rate is the simple average of the replacement rates cal- culated for three household types: single persons, lone parents with two children, and households with two parents and two children. It is assumed that each type-case has zero labor earnings and has no access to contributory benefits (Nelson, 2012).

Although replacement rates can be seen as useful measures to compare social rights across countries and over time, they have a number of limitations too (Danforth and Stephens, 2013; Whiteford, 1995). Interestingly, some of these limitations do not seem to apply to minimum income benefit replacement rates as much as they apply to other social security programs. A first limitation is that the duration of benefit programs is often difficult to capture with income replacement rates. Arguably, this issue is less problematic for social assistance benefits than for unemployment benefits, as there is often no maximum dura- tion for social assistance benefits, whereas in many countries the duration of unemployment benefits is maximized. Similarly, social assistance benefit levels are – in absence of policy reforms – usually constant over time, whereas for instance unemployment benefit levels can vary over the unemployment spell of an individual. Furthermore, social assistance benefit levels are usually not related to previous earned income, whereas unemployment or disability benefits are. An important limitation of income replacement rates, that applies as much to social assistance benefits as to other welfare state programs, is that they do not account for variation in institutional characteristics, such as eligibil- ity conditions, work requirements, and benefit sanctions.3

3.3.2 Independent variables

The measures and data sources of the independent variables are presented in Table 3.1. To assess the role of globalization, we include two different variables. The first one is trade openness, measured as the sum of exports and imports of goods and services as a percentage of GDP. The second indicator is capital openness, measured as the sum of inflows and outflows of foreign direct investment as a percentage of GDP. For both indicators, data are taken from the World Bank (2012).4To explore the role of partisan politics, we take

3 An important aspect of social assistance benefit programs is the coverage rate or take-up rate, which measures the extent to which individuals are entitled to the benefits. Recently, the OECD has published the Social Benefit Recipients Database but the data for social assistance benefit recipients are only available for the period 2007-2012 for lone parents (OECD, 2016). Longitudinal internationally comparable information on coverage rates of social assistance benefit recipients is scarce. Therefore, we do not include the coverage rate in our analysis.

4 In addition, we have examined a spatial lag variable that explicitly models the strategic interaction between governments that is presumed in the efficiency hypothesis. Following Swank (2011), we constructed the following measure: 

ܵ݌ܽݐ݈݈݅ܽܽ݃௜ǡ௧ൌ ேିଵ σ ܹ௜ǡ௝ǡ௧כ ݕ௜ǡ௧

௝ୀଵǡ௝ஷ௜

(10)

a conventional measure from the comparative political economy literature, which is the percentage of left-wing cabinet posts (Allan and Scruggs, 2004).

For the union density and the coordination of wage-setting, we use data from Armingeon et al. (2012) and Visser (2013) respectively. Furthermore, the study accounts for the number of institutional veto points and for the type of electoral system. For deindustrialization, we include the measure proposed by Iversen and Cusack (2000). Finally, the study accounts for the variation in GDP per capita, and the fiscal pressure stemming from the unemployment rate.

Where for each observation of the minimum income replacement rate in country i and year t, yit ,Wijt* yjtgives the weighted sum of the replacement rates in the other countries j in year t. The spatial weighting matrix Wijtis based on the correlation between between the patterns of trade for country i and the patterns of trade for country j for the year t. The trade patterns are based on the bilateral imports and exports between the 26 OECD countries included. The analyses did not yield robust results.

Where for each observation of the minimum income replacement rate in country i and year t, yit ,Wijt* yy gives the weighted sum of the replacement rates in the other countries j injt

year t. The spatial weighting matrix Wijtis based on the correlation between between the patterns of trade for country i and the patterns of trade for country j for the year t. The trade patterns are based on the bilateral imports and exports between the 26 OECD countries included. The analyses did not yield robust results.

(11)

3.3.3 Method

The analyses are based on time-series-cross-sectional data for 26OECDcoun- tries, including: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Japan, New Zea- land, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, Switzer- land, the Netherlands, the United Kingdom, and the United States. The study is focused on the period 1990-2009 as this is the period for which most data are available.

To examine the variation in minimum income benefit replacement rates, this study relies on an error correction model (ECM). The error correction model has become a conventional estimator in studies on pooled time-series- cross-sectional data in the field of comparative political economy (e.g., Ansell and Gingrich 2013; Iversen and Cusack 2000; Swank, 2011; Wren et al., 2013).

In an error correction specification, first-differences of the dependent variable are regressed on the lagged level of the dependent variable and on both the first-differences and the lagged levels of the independent variables. As such, the estimators are able to capture both short-term transitory effects and long- term structural effects of the independent variables by the first differenced variables and the lagged levels respectively (Beck 1991; De Boef and Keele, 2008; Podestà 2006). Furthermore, panel-corrected standard errors are applied to correct for panel-heteroscedasticity and contemporaneous spatial correlation (Beck and Katz, 1995). The estimating equation takes the following general form:

Here, á refers to the intercept.ΔYi,tstands for the changes in the dependent variable in country i and year t. Yi,t-1represents the lagged levels of the depend- ent variable. In this study, Y refers to minimum income replacement rate. X denotes a vector of explanatory variables. The first differences and lagged levels of the explanatory variables are denoted byΔXi,tand Xi,t-1respectively andεi,tis the error term. Long-term effects of the levels (Xi,t-1) are calculated by (ϒj/-β).

3.4 EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

3.4.1 Descriptive statistics

Table 3.2 shows that the net minimum income replacement rates vary consider- ably across the 26OECDcountries and over time. In 1990, the highest replace- ment rates could be observed in Czech Republic, Sweden and Finland, whereas

∆Y

i,t

= α + βY

i,t-1

+ ∑δ

j

X

i,t-1

+ ∑ϒ

j

∆X

i,t

+ ε

i,t

(12)

in 2009, Denmark, Ireland and Italy had the highest replacement rates. In 1990, the countries with the lowest replacement rates were the United States, Germany and Norway. In 2009, the United States, Estonia and Czech Republic were the countries with the lowest replacement rates. These shifts in the rankings already indicate that there have been quite some changes in the course of time. On average, the replacement rates decreased from 50 per cent in 1995 to 42.4 percent in 2009. Moreover, the data show that the replacement rates declined in most of the countries. This declining trend is in line with other studies that reported that benefit levels did not keep up with the wage developments (Van Mechelen and Marchal, 2013). Furthermore, there is quite some variation in the developments of the replacement rates across countries.

The largest increases can be found in Italy and Denmark with 9.3 and 8.5 percentage points respectively. Substantial decreases are observed in Czech Republic, Slovakia, Sweden and Finland. In these countries, minimum income replacement rates dropped with 49.6, 30.4, 22.2 and 19.6 percentage points respectively. Finally, these developments have resulted in a larger dispersion of minimum income benefits across the countries. Between 2000 and 2009, the standard deviation and the coefficient of variation increased, indicating a diverging trend of minimum income replacement rates.

diverging trend of minimum income replacement rates.

(13)

3.4.2 Regression results

Table 3.3 presents the regression results of the minimum income replacement rates across 26OECDcountries for the period 1990-2009. Model 1 shows that trade openness is negatively and significantly associated with minimum income replacement rates. This result provides evidence for the efficiency hypothesis stating that economic globalization puts pressure on minimum income pro- tection programs. Furthermore, the results show negative coefficients for the unemployment rate.5In line with our expectations, these results suggest that when countries are more exposed to economic globalization or when increased unemployment rates lead to budgetary pressure, social assistance benefit levels are decreased.

Interestingly, Model 2 indicates that capital openness is positively associated with minimum income replacement rates. Apparently, capital openness captures some of the mechanism underlying the compensation hypothesis.

In Model 3, trade openness and capital openness are included simultaneously and the results are comparable to the results shown in Model 1 and 2.

Together, these results provide evidence for both the efficiency and the com- pensation hypothesis. Governments face a globalization dilemma, as increased economic openness increases the demand for social protection, whilst it under- mines the budgetary means for providing such a safety net. As expected, the results show a positive coefficient for deindustrialization. This result suggests that as a consequence of structural transitions on the labor market, the demand for social protection increases in order to compensate the increased levels of economic risks.

Turning to the domestic institutions, the first three models do not report significant results for left-wing governments. In Model 4, country-fixed effects are included. Now, the results indicate a positive and significant coefficient for left-wing governments. Thus, when we focus the analysis on within-country variation, the results suggest that left-wing parties are positively associated with social assistance benefit levels, which is in line with the classical argument regarding partisan politics. With regard to union density, we find positive coefficients for the short run, but the coefficients of the long-run effects are not significant. The positive coefficients provide support for the argument that labor unions try to prevent reductions of benefit levels, as lower benefit levels could undermine wage levels. Furthermore, the results for the level of wage coordination suggest that economy-wide bargaining is positively related with social assistance benefits, which corresponds with our expectation. Political constraints are negatively associated with minimum income replacement rates.

This result is in line with the argument that institutional veto points constrain

5 Long-term effects in error correction models are estimated by dividing the coefficient for the level variable by the negative coefficient for the lagged level of the dependent variable.

Thus, the long-term effect for unemployment in Model 1 is: (-0.104 / -(-0.056) = 1.86.

(14)

the governments’ ability to perform welfare benefit change. Finally, the results indicate that the type of electoral system is not associated with social assistance benefit reform.6

To examine the robustness of our results, we employ a number of sensitiv- ity analyses. First, we add country-fixed effects to the error correction model.

In this model, the variables wage coordination, political constraints and the electoral system cannot be included, as these variables do not vary over time.

As shown in Model 4, the results are largely in line with the results of the first three models.

Subsequently, we examine the sensitivity of the results for the inclusion of Central and Eastern European countries (CEECs), as these countries may follow distinct reform paths (Draxler and Van Vliet, 2010; Fenger, 2007; Lei- brecht et al., 2011). Therefore, we include a dummy variable, that is coded 1 for Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Poland, Slovakia and Slovenia and 0 for the other countries. As shown in Models 5 and 7, the coefficient of this CEEC dummy is not significant and the inclusion of this variable do not alter the results for the other variables.

Finally, we examine the effects of the global financial crisis and the sub- sequent responses of governments on social assistance benefit developments by adding a dummy variable to the regressions, that is scored 1 for 2008 and 2009 and 0 for the years before. Models 6 and 7 show insignificant coefficients for the crisis dummy and largely replicated coefficients for the other variables.

These results suggest that – other than via the other independent variables sich as the increased unemployment rates – social assistance benefits have not been hit by the crisis.

6 We have also examined indirect effects of the domestic institutions by including interaction variables between globalization and unemployment rates and institutional variables. We did not find robust results for such indirect effects.

(15)
(16)

3.5 CONCLUSIONS

This paper engages on the changes in social assistance benefits across 26OECD

countries between 1990 and 2009. In particular, we assess the roles of globaliza- tion, domestic institutions and socio-economic factors in the developments of minimum income replacement rates. These variables have been analyzed extensively in relation to the developments of other welfare state programs, but the drivers of the developments in social assistance benefit programs have not been analyzed yet. Hence, our contribution to the existing comparative welfare state literature first lies in our efforts to explore the variation in social assistance benefit developments across countries and over time. We rely on minimum income replacement rates to measure social assistance benefit levels relative to labor income.

The data show that minimum income replacement rates decreased in most

OECDcountries between 1990 and 2009 and that the developments vary con- siderably across countries. To examine the determinants of social assistance benefits, this study utilizes pooled time-series-cross-sectional data analysis.

The results indicate that budgetary pressure stemming from increased exposure to trade openness and soaring levels of unemployment is negatively related to minimum income replacement rates. These results suggest that when policy- makers are faced with budgetary pressure, social assistance benefits are an obvious program for retrenchments as the long-term unemployed – typical labor market outsiders – are relatively weakly represented in the political arena. Interestingly, our findings suggest that labor unions act as defenders of social assistance benefits. This finding provides empirical support for the argument that trade unions aim to prevent benefit cuts as this could harm the positions of trade unions (Rothstein, 1992; Wallerstein, 1989). An interesting direction for future research would be to examine how trade unions act in policy-changes regarding other dimensions of social assistance benefit schemes.

Clearly, a notable limitation of this study on minimum income replacement rates is that other institutional characteristics, such as eligibility conditions or work requirements, are not taken into account.

Furthermore, the results show positive as well as negative associations between globalization and minimum income benefits. As such, our findings provide evidence for both the efficiency and the compensation hypothesis.

Trade openness puts pressure on government budgets and capital openness induces a higher demand for social protection to compensate the increased economic risks. As a result, policy-makers are faced with a globalization dilemma (Hays, 2009). The electorate has a higher demand for social protection, but economic globalization restricts the budgetary room for manoeuvre.

Finally, our results indicate that social assistance benefits have not been affected by the crisis, other than via other independent variables such as the increased levels of unemployment. This suggests that during 2008 and 2009 social assistance schemes have not been hit by crisis-induced reform initiatives,

(17)

even though these benefit schemes form an obvious target for retrenchments.

However, it may be possible that this conclusion is drawn too early. Future studies should shed more light on the developments of social assistance and minimum income benefits during the second half of the crisis.

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

One of the most discussed explanations for declining generosity levels of welfare state programs is the pressure stemming from economic developments, such as economic globalization

In order to compare the development of social assistance benefits across countries and over time we have constructed a new indicator, the net minimum income benefit replacement

Based on two new indicators, real net minimum income benefit levels and minimum income replacement rates, Chapter 2 empirically analyzes the developments in mini- mum income

Based on two new indicators, real net minimum income benefit levels and minimum income replacement rates, Chapter 2 empirically analyzes the developments in mini- mum income

In some countries, net minimum income benefits increased in real terms, but replacement rates decreased between 1990 and 2009, indicating that the increases in benefit levels did

Relying on two new indicators, benefit levels and replacement rates, we examined the relationship between the Lisbon Strategy and national social assistance benefit developments..

21 Smeeding examined the generosity of income transfer programs by tracing the trend in non-elderly cash and near- cash (food, housing) benefits for OECD countries over the past

The effectives of (high) social spending on (high) antipoverty effects of social transfers and taxes faded away during last decade. Less targeting partly offers an explanation