• No results found

University of Groningen Faculty of Economics and Business MSc International Economics and Business

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "University of Groningen Faculty of Economics and Business MSc International Economics and Business"

Copied!
41
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

University of Groningen

Faculty of Economics and Business

MSc International Economics and Business

Master Thesis

Foreign Direct Investment and Regional Economic Growth

In China:

A Panel Data Study of 1997-2009

Author: Lin Wang

Student Number: 1928902 Email: L.Wang.12@student.rug.nl Thesis Supervisor: Dr. Dirk Akkermans

(2)

Abstract

This paper investigates the relationship between inward FDI and regional economic

growth in China from 1997 to 2009, using a panel data study. Surprisingly, FDI

inflows to the coastal region is significantly yet negatively related to its economic

growth rate, while inward FDI to the central and western regions has an insignificant

impact on their economic growth as we expected. Labor costs suggest a positive effect

on non-coastal regions and a negative effect on their coastal counterpart. In addition,

WTO accession shows a significantly positive relationship with China‟s economic

growth. A second analysis is also provided to find out whether the economic

development in the coastal region can actually affects that in the central and western

regions. The answer is yes, though there is no significant difference of economic

growth between the non-coastal regions.

(3)

Contents

Introduction 3

Background 3

Problem Statement 4

Literature Review 6

FDI and Economic Growth 6

Human Capital and Economic Growth 8

Labor Costs and Economic Growth 10

WTO and Economic Growth 11

Methodology 13

Methodology Description 13

Data Measurement 14

Analysis I: Coastal versus Non-coastal 17

Diagnostic Tests I 17

Empirical Results I 23

Analysis II: Coastal to Non-coastal 26

(4)

Introduction

Background

Foreign direct investment (FDI) has been one of the most discussed topics over

decades. Under the trend of economic globalization, the relationship between FDI and

economic growth has also been widely studied. While China has emerged as a major

recipient of foreign direct investment, FDI in China is one of the most remarkable outcomes of China‟s Reform and Open Policy, which was adopted in the late 1978. Since 1993, China has already held a position second only to the United States as the

largest host country for FDI (Buckley et al., 2002). Most importantly, FDI has played an important role in contributing to the country‟s economic development and institutional reform (Long, 2005).

As a matter of fact, almost no studies on FDI in China have failed to point out the

highly unbalanced geographical distribution of FDI within the country. The enormous

land area of China is unavoidably associated with tremendous contrasts in conditions

between provinces. Several articles have already pointed out that the degree of

economic development varies substantially across different areas of China, and the

geographic distribution of FDI is characterized by its concentration in coastal areas

(Buckley et al., 2002; Wen, 2005; Zhang, 2006). For instance, in 1996, nearly 90% of

FDI inflows to China were concentrated in coastal provinces, whereas the central

region received only 9% and the west region only 2% of the total FDI inflows

throughout that year (Cheung & Lin, 2004). While an overall positive impact of FDI

on economic growth is supported by empirical literature, China with its large country

and economy size means that this finding may have mixed up different regional

impacts.

In order to shed some light on the nexus of FDI inflows with regional economic

growth in China, this paper is organized as following. The first chapter brings up

(5)

methodology are explained in the third chapter. Two analyses are presented in the

following two chapters respectively. And the last one concludes.

Problem Statement

Since the economic reform and opening up to the outside world, China has attracted

increasingly large amount of foreign capital inflows, which can be divided into three

categories: foreign loans, foreign direct investment and other foreign investment. It

has been confirmed that between 1979 and 2000, China‟s actual usage of foreign

capital amount to more than 500 billion dollars, among which over two thirds are in

the form of direct investment (Fung et al., 2002). According to China‟s statistics, most

inward FDI to China have consumed by the industrial sectors in the east coastal

provinces. More strikingly, more than 85 percent of China‟s annual FDI inflows have

been invested in the coastal region. Four provinces, Guangdong, Jiangsu, Shanghai

and Zhejiang, have been recognized as the largest recipients and received more than half of China‟s FDI inflows. While Chinese government advocated development of western China and provided a set of preferential policies to attract FDI to the west in

2000, the increase in share of FDI inflows from 1999 to 2001 in the western region

was still less than 2% (Wen, 2005).

Although a large volume of studies have proved the positive role played by FDI in China‟s economic development, there is still a lack of systematic studies on the impacts of FDI on China‟s economic performance at a sub-national level, as argued

also in Lheem and Guo (2004). This paper aims to study the relationship between

inward FDI and economic growth at the regional level in China for the period of

1997-2009, using recent time-series and provincial-level data. In the mean time, it

also tries to give insights into how the economic growth in different regions can affect

each other. The key issue here is how to explain the unbalanced FDI distribution and

(6)

Generally, this study of FDI‟s impacts on China using provincial data is desirable for

a number of reasons. First of all, it contributes to the FDI-growth nexus literature by

using the empirical results at regional level of China. Secondly, we seek to augment

the empirical evidence concerning the economic impacts of inward FDI to different

regions in China using most recent data. Last but not least, an understanding of how

FDI affects different regions is important to the design of policies to attract and

promote foreign capital. This study mainly focuses on the central question: how we

can explain the relationship between regional economic growth and regional FDI

distributions in China. To be specific, the specialized research questions are as

follows:

Is the extent of uneven FDI distribution at the regional level directly related to the regional economic growth in China during 1997-2009?

Is there any difference between the impacts of FDI inflows on economic growth in the coastal region and those in the central and western regions?

(7)

Literature Review

FDI and Economic Growth

The impact of foreign direct investment on economic growth is one of the most

controversial topics in the area of economics research. Existing empirical evidence on

the relationship between foreign direct investment inflows and economic growth is

inconclusive, as Wijeweera et al. (2010) argues, despite there are plausible theoretical

grounds for presuming a positive nexus. Mullen and Williams (2005), as well as Choe

(2003) conclude that FDI has a positive effect on economic growth. Carkovic and

Levine (2005) argue FDI does not have any significant impact on economic growth in

the host country, while Mencinger (2003) finds inward FDI is negatively related to

economic growth. Borensztein et al. (1998), Alfaro et al. (2000), and Alfaro et al.

(2008) find that FDI will promote economic growth only when certain economic

conditions are met in the host country, such as a threshold level of human capital.

Markusen and Venables (1999) suggest FDI is likely to be an engine of host countries‟

economic growth, and by its very nature, FDI may bring into host economies special

resources such as management know-how, skilled labor, and access to international

production networks. Moreover, FDI may result in technology transfers and spillover

effects. According to Lheem and Guo (2004), FDI promotes economic growth by

providing external capital, and through growth, spreads the benefits all over the

economy. They also believe inward FDI may enhance capital formation, and also

promote employment augmentation. It is argued that FDI usually brings with it

advanced technology, and better organization management. Hence, virtually, FDI is

one of the most essential engines for economic growth especially in developing

countries.

In fact, most emerging economies are now actively attracting FDI inflows. Emerging

economies have become more receptive to inward FDI, and most of them see FDI

(8)

2002). Mencinger (2003) points out the economic benefits of FDI are considered to be

twofold. On the one hand, FDI can help countries if their domestic savings are

insufficient to finance economic expansion; on the other hand, the presence of a

foreign corporate is associated with positive externalities. Zhang (2006) argues that,

in the case of China, perhaps the most prominent contribution of FDI is augmenting China‟s manufacturing exports. Concretely, foreign-invested enterprises not only expand China‟s export volumes, but also upgrade its export structure. He further

argues that, FDI seems to have brought extra gains to China in facilitating its

transition toward a market system which started in the late 1970s. Huang (2009) finds

FDI has a positive and statistically significant impact on economic growth as theory

predicts, using the augmented Solow-Swan model of Mankiw et al. (1992) to analyze

provincial-level data of China over the reform period 1978-2003.

However, due to regional differences, such as social, economic, and institutional

dissimilarities, the relationship between FDI and economic performance is expected

to vary within China, from region to region and even from province to province.

Generally speaking, there are three regions can be categorized, the coastal, the central

and the western region, and each region consists of several provinces. They are

distinguished not only by their geographic features, but also by the level of their

economic development, degree of economic openness, quality of institution, and

factor endowments. Wen (2005) finds that FDI inflows can generate a demonstration

effect in identifying regional market conditions for investment in fixed assets. This

effect on regional exports and regional income growth has varied across the east

coastal, central and western China ever since the second half of 1990s. In Buckley et

al. (2002), the authors argue that host country conditions strongly influence the

growth relationship at both the national and the provincial levels. Their results also

suggest that FDI favors growth in the economically stronger provinces, and the full

benefits of FDI can be realized when competitions of both the foreign and local origin

(9)

It is also shown in Fujita and Hu (1999), the income disparity between the coastal and

the interior area has been increasing, with the industrial production showing a strong

agglomeration towards the coastal area. More importantly, globalization (measured by

export and FDI) and economic liberalization had significantly promoted the increase

of regional disparity. As indicated in Graham and Wada (2001), FDI in China has

stimulated much growth in income, which could almost not have been realized in the

absence of this investment. FDI has significantly benefited the coastal region while

most of the rest of China has much less benefits. Zhang (2006) using provincial data

over the period of 1992-2004 shows that FDI seems to promote income growth across

China. Moreover, this positive growth effect seems to rise over time and to be

stronger in the coastal rather than in the inland regions. Thus, according to the above,

we expect to see a positive relationship between FDI and economic growth in east

coastal provinces but not in the central and western regions.

Hypothesis 1: All else being equal, foreign direct investment has a significant positive

impact on economic growth in the east coastal region.

Hypothesis 2: All else being equal, foreign direct investment does not have a

significant impact on economic growth in the central and western regions.

Human Capital and Economic Growth

Many studies have confirmed human capital is one of the primary determinants of

economic growth (Van et al., 2010; Tsai et al., 2010; Noorbakhsh et al., 2001;

Mankiw et al., 1992). Early as in Frank (1960), it is argued that education has made

an increasingly large contribution to output, and investment in human capital is a

major component of economic growth, since education is considered as the main form

of increasing human capital.In Galor and Moav (2004), it is stated that investment in

human capital will eventually replace physical capital as the main engine of economic

growth. Besides, Lee and Lee (1995) show that a higher initial level of human capital

per worker will lead to a higher growth rate of real GDP per worker. With regard to

(10)

Wang and Yao (2003) find the accumulation of human capital was quite rapid and it

contributed significantly to the growth and welfare in China.

Actually, several articles have also already pointed out the importance of a

threshold-level human capital as a determinant of inward FDI. Ciruelos and Wang

(2005) suggest a complementarity between FDI inflows and human capital in less

developed countries. They argue that for FDI from developed countries to promote

technology diffusion in less developed countries, a certain threshold of human capital

has to be reached. Borensztein et al. (1998) also find the direct effect of FDI on

growth is negative in countries with low levels of human capital. To be more specific,

only countries with sufficiently high levels of human capital have the ability to exploit

the technological transfers and spillover effects associated with inward FDI. Lheem

and Guo (2004) give an additional argument says, the most important contribution of

FDI is likely to be the fact that the productivity of FDI is higher than those of

domestic investments, while this higher productivity occurs only when the host

country has a minimum threshold stock of human capital.

Broadman and Sun (1997) mention that a host region‟s labor supply influences foreign investors‟ location decisions not only in terms of input costs, but also through the quality of the labor force. They expect locations with highly skilled workers

(measured by education levels) could compete more favourably than their

counterparts in FDI attractiveness. Besides, Noorbakhsh et al. (2001) find out human

capital is a statistically significant determinant of FDI inflows, and its importance has

become increasingly greater over time. More importantly, they argue the geographical

distribution of FDI may be affected by the level of human capital in the host country.

In the case of China, Fleisher et al. (2005) conclude the impacts of human capital may

operate through spillovers from wealthy to poor provinces. Furthermore, in Buckley

(2002), it is shown that for the most economically backward provinces, increases in

investment in human capital make a positive contribution to economic growth. Under

(11)

China, has a positive impact on economic growth in the east coastal region which has

comparatively higher level human capital, rather than in the central and western

regions.

Hypothesis 3: All else being equal, the level of human capital, as a determinant of

inward FDI to China, is positively related to economic growth in the coastal region.

Hypothesis 4: All else being equal, the level of human capital, as a determinant of

inward FDI to China, is not significantly related to economic growth in the central and western regions.

Labor Costs and Economic Growth

The level of labor costs has been proved to be an essential factor in affecting the

economic growth of an area. Storper (2010) considers factors such as labor costs,

regulations, and business climates, are explanations for why a city does well or poorly

in its economic development. Besides, Huang (2009) argues differences in labor

markets, industrial structure, and resource endowments, can lead to gaps in regional

per capita income even in equilibrium. In the study of Asian countries by Seguino

(2000), it is also confirmed that low unit labor costs, obtained by offering low wages,

will stimulate investment and exports. The resulting foreign exchange used to

purchase capital and intermediate goods will thus raise productivity and economic

growth rates.

Foreign investors usually aim to take advantage of host countries‟ cheaper factor

inputs. In this regard, labor cost is often considered one of the most important factors

(Broadman & Sun, 1997). Bellak et al. (2008) suggest that higher unit labor costs as

well as higher total labor costs are negatively associated with FDI, by analysing the

determinants of FDI across several Central and Eastern European Countries. Liu and

Pearson (2010) also reveal market size, labor costs, and business ethics are important

factors for promoting FDI to China, using primary data provided by 43 managers of

(12)

level is a critical determinant of FDI and high labor costs have significantly negative

effect on FDI, after controlling for labor productivity. Cheng and Kwan (2000) also

argue wage costs have a negative effect on FDI, by estimating the effects of FDI

determinants in China‟s 29 provinces from 1985 to 1995. Especially, Boermans et al.

(2009) use a factor analysis to investigate what drives the uneven regional distribution

of FDI inflows to 31 provinces in China from 1995 to 2006, and find out foreign

investors choose to invest more in provinces with lower labor costs, larger market size,

and better institutions. Hence, while the provinces with higher labor costs compete in

their efforts to attract FDI less favourably, our expectation is that this factor is likely

to generate a negative relationship with provincial inward FDI. Thus, we would

expect labor costs, as a determinant of inward FDI to China, has a positive impact on

economic growth in the central and western regions which have relatively lower labor

costs, but has a negative effect in the east coastal region which has comparatively

higher labor costs.

Hypothesis 5: All else being equal, the level of labor costs, as a determinant of

inward FDI to China, is negatively related to economic growth in the coastal region.

Hypothesis 6: All else being equal, the level of labor costs, as a determinant of

inward FDI to China, is positively related to economic growth in the central and western regions.

WTO and Economic Growth

The significance of entry into WTO is a topic can be barely avoided when discussing

about the relationship between FDI and economic growth in China. After 15 years of

negotiations, China became the 143rd member of the World Trade Organization

(WTO) On December 11, 2001 (IMF, 2002). As addressed in Ding et al. (2009), China‟s entry into WTO represents a „second opening‟ for the country ever since the landmark Reform and Open Policy launched in 1978. They argue that the resulted

rapidly increasing foreign trade has greatly boosted China‟s economic development,

(13)

into WTO, as Wang (2003) states, China and its trade partners would both benefit

from further realization of each other‟s comparative advantages in a freer trade

environment, and it is good for bilateral economic growth. Furthermore, Daniel III

(2004) in his study concludes that China‟s entry into WTO has already resulted in a

more efficient economy and an increased rate of economic growth. He considers these

two effects are both resulted from the restructuring of China‟s economy from a closed

central planned economy to a more or less open market economy, followed by the

WTO accession.

In the study of Buthe and Milner (2008), by statistically analyzing 122 developing

countries from 1970 to 2000, they find out joining international trade agreements

allows developing countries to attract more FDI and thus increase economic growth.

Actually, in recent years, China has become one of the most favorite destinations for

global investment because of its preferential foreign investment policies, improving

investment environment, inexpensive labor, increasing purchasing power, and

especially the entry into WTO (Ali & Guo, 2005). Wen (2005) argues that, indeed,

China‟s accession to WTO made it more closely integrated into the world economy

ever since, and it is becoming the largest FDI recipient country. Speaking of the role

WTO plays in the relationship between FDI and economic growth for China, Tuan

and Ng (2004)1 state that FDI-led growth is expected to characterize China‟s future economic growth after the WTO accession, and rapid FDI growth is expected to

continue in the future. It is especially worth mentioned that in Tuan and Ng (2004)2, they conclude further FDI absorption after WTO accession will be followed by

agglomeration economies, which may further strengthen China‟s current biased

regional growth pattern.

Hypothesis 7: All else being equal, China’s accession to the World Trade

(14)

Methodology

Methodology Description

Two analyses are performed in this research. At the beginning, multiple regression

models will be run to test the relationship between regional FDI and economic growth

in China respectively in regard to our hypotheses. And the second step, which is also

a highlight of this paper, we add another analysis to find out whether the economic

growth and FDI inflows in the coastal region have any effects on that of the central

and western regions. The regression models are formed as below. These models will

be discussed in detail later in this section.

Analysis I: Coastal versus Non-coastal

GROit=α1+β1FDIit-1+β2HUMit+β3LABit+β4WTO+β5COS+β6(COS*FDIit-1)+εit (1)

GROit=α1+β1FDIit-1+β2HUMit+β3LABit+β4WTO+β5COS+β6(COS*LABit)+εit (1a)

GROit=α1+β1FDIit-1+β2HUMit+β3LABit+β4WTO+β5COS+β6(COS*HUMit)+εit (1b)

Analysis II: Coastal to Non-coastal

GROi2t=α2+γ1GROi1(t-1)+γ2FDIi1(t-1)+γ3HUMi2t+γ4LABi2t+γ5CEN+εit (2)

In the first regression model (1), the impact of inward FDI in province i on its annual

GDP growth at time t is shown in this equation. Dependent variable GROit indicates

the economic growth rate in the host province i at time t, while the independent

variable FDIit-1 in this research represents FDI inflows in the province i at time t-1.

FDIit-1 is taken a one-year lag to correct for the possible endogeneity problem, which

will be discussed in depth in the next chapter. The second and the third independent

variables, HUMit and LABit, are control variables. HUMit stands for the level of human

capital in province i at time t, while LABit stands for labor costs in province i at time t.

There are also two dummy variables included in the equation. WTO equals 1 when

measured after 2001 (from 2002) and 0 before 2001 (including 2001) in the end of

(15)

COS is 1 when the province being tested belongs to coastal region, and 0 to other regions. The last independent variable is an interaction term of coastal region dummy

and independent variable FDIit-1. We add this term on the ground that, according to

Brambor et al. (2006), an interaction term should be included in the regression

equation whenever the hypothesis is conditional in nature. Lastly, εit is the error term.

The only thing changed among these three equations is the interaction term.

COS*LABit in regression (1a) is for testing Hypothesis 3&4, the potential different

impacts of labor costs on coastal and non-coastal regions. Similarly, in regression (1b),

COS*HUMit is used to test Hypothesis 5&6, the possible different impacts of human

capital on different region groups.

Next, regression model (2) describes whether the economic growth and FDI inflows

to the coastal region may also influence the situation in the central and western

regions. We take GROj2t as the growth rate of the central and western regions at time t,

while j2 represents provinces in these two regions. By the same token, GROi1(t-1)

measures the growth rate of the coastal region at time t-1, and j1 delegates coastal

region provinces. The second independent variable FDIi1(t-1) represents inward FDI in

the province j1 at time t-1. These two variables are both taken a one-year lag to solve

the potential endogeneity issue. Besides, we also add another two variables HUMi2t

and LABi2t, as control variables. They respectively indicate human capital and labor

costs in the central and western regions. CEN is the central region dummy, which

means a central region province when it equals to 1 and 0 a western region province.

Last but not least, εjt is the error term of equation (2).

Data Measurement

Several relevant literatures that divide all 31 provinces of China into 3 regions

actually include 28 provinces while eliminate Tibet, Chongqing and Hainan (Lee,

1994; Buckley et al., 2002; Tang & Selvanathan, 2005). We tend to be in line with

Cheung and Lin (2004) which involves 30 provinces merely except Tibet. In fact,

(16)

note that, Chongqing has been separated from Sichuan province as a centrally

administrated municipality in 1997, thus articles before this year could not possibly

include Chongqing as a research object. While Hainan is a small island apart from the

mainland, most studies try not to include it into any of those three regions. However,

in order to give a whole picture of China‟s economic development, we consider

Hainan still takes an important part which cannot be ignored. Table 1 below describes

how the 30 provinces are classified into 3 regions.

Table 1 Summary of region classification

Region Provinces Number

Coastal Beijing, Tianjin, Hebei, Liaoning, Shanghai, Jiangsu, Zhejiang, Fujian, Shandong, Guangdong, Guangxi, Hainan

12

Central Shanxi, Inner Mongolia, Jilin, Heilongjiang, Anhui, Jiangxi, Henan, Hubei, Hunan

9

Western Chongqing, Sichuan, Guizhou, Yunnan, Shaanxi, Gansu,

Qinghai, Ningxia, Xinjiang

9

All the data needed to run our regression can be found in various issues of China

Statistical Yearbook, from National Bureau of Statistics of China

(http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/statisticaldata/yearlydata/). Growth rates are

calculated as a percentage using regional annual GDP data by province, and corrected

by inflation rates. The annual inflation rates are found in WDI (World Development

Indicators) from World Economic Outlook Database April 2011 of IMF (International

Monetary Fund). In China Statistical Yearbook, regional FDI data is reported

annually as actually used foreign direct investment by each province rather than FDI

inflows to those provinces. We consider this actually used FDI data can be an even

better measurement. Human capital is the number of graduates of higher education

institutions and specialized secondary schools, while labor costs are measured as the

average year wages of staff and workers by region. As for the dummy variable WTO,

we take 2002 as a dividing year, since it is the first full year after China‟s entry to

WTO and the first year in which China exceeded the US in attracting FDI (Na &

(17)

Table 2 Summary of data description

Variable Description Source

Growth rate

Calculated from regional annual GDP data as a percentage: [(GDP this year-GDP last year)/GDP last year*100%]-inflation rate this year

China Statistical

Yearbook,1997-2010

Regional FDI

Actually used foreign direct investment by region (USD)

China Statistical

Yearbook,1998-2010

Human capital

Number of graduates of higher education institutions and specialized secondary schools (person)

China Statistical

Yearbook,1998-2010

Labor costs

Average year wage of staff and workers by region (yuan)

China Statistical

Yearbook,1997-2009

WTO 1 represents 2002-2009 and 0 stands for

1997-2001

COS 1 indicates coastal region and 0 otherwise

COS*FDI Interaction term of coastal region dummy and regional FDI

COS*Lab Interaction term of coastal region dummy and labor costs

COS*Hum Interaction term of coastal region dummy and

human capital

(18)

Analysis I: Coastal versus Non-coastal

Diagnostic Tests I

Several diagnostic tests are conducted in this section to assure accuracy and reliability of the empirical results. It has to be mentioned that the conclusions we can obtain from diagnostic tests of (1a) and (1b) are the same as we get here for regression (1). Those results are shown in appendices at the end of this paper. Table 3 below shows the descriptive statistics of our research sample. Note that there are two obvious outliers, which are also the minimum and maximum of Growth group, namely 48.99% for Beijing (2001) and -9.96% for Hubei (2001). Therefore, we try to cast back and find out what exactly happened in 2001 has made these two numbers so different from the others. The only relevant information we can think of is that Beijing, as the capital of China, successfully bid for the 2008 Olympic Games on July 13, 2001, and in the end of which China also joined WTO. Both events could have significantly affected the economic growth of Beijing 2001, while the influence of WTO is also what we want to prove in this paper. We are not able to make sure, however, why the economic growth rate of Hubei 2001 can be the only negative one in the whole sample. In order to keep our sample integrated and give a full image of regional FDI‟s impacts on China‟s economy, both outliers are not deleted.

Table 3 Descriptive Statistics

Obs. Minimum Maximum Mean Std. Deviation

Growth 390 -9.9554 48.9926 12.436329 5.0746776

FDI 388 2470000 4.E12 2.88E11 6.963E11

Labor Costs 384 4564 56565 14033.77 8401.958 Human Capital 390 6029 850498 169660.39 162089.639 WTO 390 0 1 0.62 0.487 COS 390 0 1 0.40 0.491 Valid N (listwise) 382 Multicollinearity

Multicollinearity refers to the situation when there are two or more variables in a

(19)

sufficiently estimate their separate effects on the dependent variable because the

p-value is higher even if these variables are significant determinants of the dependant

variable (Hill et al., 2007). In order to detect possible multicollinearity, a correlation

matrix of all variables is presented in Table 5. All pairs of correlation we obtained are

relatively low, with the highest 0.620, which thus suggests little collinearity. That is to

say, multicollinearity is not a problem in respect of this research.

Table 5 Correlations Matrix

Growth FDI Labor

Costs Human Capital WTO COS Growth 1 FDI 0.120* 1 Labor Costs 0.334** 0.606** 1 Human Capital -0.023 0.078 0.202** 1 WTO 0.479** 0.324** 0.620** -0.098 1 COS 0.018 0.381** 0.275** 0.096 0.000 1

*. Correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed). **. Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).

Normality

A histogram of residuals is created by Stata as below. Unbiased coefficient

estimations in a linear regression model should based on the assumption that error

terms and also values of dependent variables are normally distributed (Hill et al.,

2007). The least square estimators should have an approximate normal distribution, if

the Gauss-Markov assumption holds. As we can see from Graph 1, the residuals of

our sample are centred at zero and reasonably bell-shaped, which may suggest a

normal distribution. Thus we further conduct a Jarque-Bera test to formally check the

(20)

Graph 1 Histogram of Residuals

Jarque-Bera test is based on two measures, namely skewness and kurtosis (Hill et al.,

2007). It suggests a perfect symmetry of residuals when the skewness is 0, and

indicates a normal distribution when the kurtosis value is 3. The null hypothesis (H0)

of this test suggests the residuals are normally distributed. As we can get from our

results, the value of the calculated Jarque-Bera statistics 3008.6044 is far greater than

the critical value (5.99) of chi-squared distribution with two degrees of freedom

obtained at a 5% significant level. Furthermore, in our case, the estimated values of

skewness and kurtosis are respectively 1.7300 and 16.8773, which do not suggest a

normal distribution. Thus, the null hypothesis should be rejected. While

non-normality of residuals is mainly resulted from issues of heteroskedasticity and

autocorrelation, certain tests are conducted in the following parts to check whether

those problems exist.

Next, Q-Q plots are used to check whether all variables are normality distributed.

From the graphs we may conclude that the dependent variable Growth is nearly

normally distributed, while FDI, Labor Costs and Human Capital can be transformed

to normal distributions. Thus, we use natural logarithm normality transformation

method to treat all these three variables. The Q-Q plot of the dependent variable

Growth is shown in appendices.

(21)

Heteroskedasticity

Heteroskedasticity usually occurs when the variances for all observations are not the

same. The assumption for OLS (ordinary least square) estimator suggests a constant

variance for the error term will thus be violated under this circumstance. Although

heteroskedasticity may not bias the coefficient estimates of OLS, it may lead to an

underestimation of the variances and the standard errors of the coefficients

(Wooldridge, 2002). Ignoring heteroskedasticity and using incorrect standard errors

will lead to confidence intervals that are wider than they should be (Hill et al., 2007).

Thus OLS model is no more the best estimator when the problem of

heteroskedasticity appears. To test heteroskedasticity we use a Breusch–Pagan test,

also called a Lagrange Multiplier (LM) test, with the results shown in Table 4. The

null hypothesis of this test assumes a constant variance for the error term. In our case,

as the p-values of all variables are greater than 0.05, the null hypotheses should not be

rejected, which means heteroskedasticity does not occur in our sample. A robustness

test is no longer necessary.

Table 4 Results of Heteroskedasticity

Variable LM value p-value

(ln)FDI_1 0.0602 0.8062 (ln)Labor Costs 0.7421 0.3890 (ln)Human Capital 1.3017 0.2539 WTO 2.7473 0.0974 COS 0.0768 0.7816 COS_(ln)FDI_1 0.0228 0.8799 Autocorrelation

Autocorrelation occurs in the situation where the error terms are correlated.

Autocorrelation problem does not bias the coefficient estimates in an OLS model but

may lead to an underestimation of standard errors (Hill et al., 2007). In order to

examine for autocorrelation in our panel data, we perform a Wooldridge test by Stata

using the xtserial command. As we get from the test result, the p-value 0.0098 is

(22)

autocorrelation should be rejected. Thus, there is autocorrelation problem exist in our

sample. We will conduct a simple yet useful method, the xtregar command, to correct

for this problem. This command implements the methods derived in Baltagi and Wu

(1999) to deal with fixed and random effects models with an AR (1) disturbance, and

also can accommodate unbalanced panels whose observations are unequally spaced

over time. Therefore, the original xtreg command will be replaced by xtregar in our

panel data estimation.

Hausman Test

A panel data regression method should be implemented for this research. There are

generally three statistical regression estimators for a panel data analysis, the OLS

estimator, the fixed effects estimator, and the random effects estimator (Hill et al.,

2007). The OLS estimator tends to be inconsistent when one of the problems

(non-normality of residuals, heteroskedasticity, autocorrelation, and multicollinearity)

occurs. Therefore, the OLS estimator seems not to be the most ideal model for our

research, and we will choose between the fixed effects estimator and the random

effects estimator. In general, the fixed effects estimator is always safe to use as it

allows correlation between the explanatory variables and the unobserved components

(Wooldridge, 2002). However, the fixed effects estimator is not capable of estimating

coefficients on time-invariant variables such as the dummy variable COS in our

sample. In contrast to COS, WTO is not strictly time-invariant regarding this research.

In order to statistically decide which model to choose, we conduct a Hausman test.

This test is designed to check for any correlation between the error term and the

regressors within a random effects model, by comparing the coefficient estimates

from the random effects model to those from the fixed effects model (Hill et al., 2007).

The null hypothesis (H0) is organized as there is no correlation between the error term

and any of the explanatory variables. If the null hypothesis is not rejected, then the

random and fixed effects estimates should be similar; whereas a rejection of the null

(23)

explanatory variables, thus the random effects estimator is inconsistent (Hill et al.,

2007). In our case, the null hypothesis cannot be rejected due to the insignificant

p-value 0.9923. Therefore, the fixed effects estimator and random effects estimator

are both feasible. Considering of the time-invariant variable in our regression equation,

we finally choose the random effects estimator.

Endogeneity

The problem of endogeneity occurs when one of the independent variables is

correlated with the error term in a regression model. It implies that the regression

coefficient estimates in an OLS model may be biased. Theoretically, endogeneity can

arise as a result of sample selection errors, measurement error in explanatory variables,

omitted variables, and simultaneity (Wooldridge, 2002). In our research, simultaneity

appears to be the main source of endogeneity. Simultaneity is also called as reverse

causality. It indicates that two variables are codetermined, with one affecting the other.

In this paper, the endogeneity problem is caused by a positive reversible causality

between economic growth rate and inward FDI. Not only FDI inflows to a certain

region will accelerate its economic development, but also a host region with higher

economic growth rate tends to attract more inward FDI.

In principle, the method of instrumental variable can be used to solve the problem of

endogeneity. An instrument is a variable which is not included in the regression

equation but is correlated with the endogenous explanatory variables (Hill et al.,

2007). A good instrument should be highly correlated with the explanatory variables

but not with the error term. However, an ideal instrument is hard to find. Thus we use

another simple yet practical method, applying a one-year lag to FDI, to see whether

(24)

Empirical Results I

Table 6 (on Page 25) shows the empirical results of the first analysis. Model (1)

represents the results of a general model before adding dummy variables and

interaction terms. It is shown that FDI inflows, after one year, are significantly and

negatively related to the growth rate at a national level. We will further discuss the

reason why this could happen later by Model (3). While Labor Costs is positively

significant at a 1% level, Human Capital is negatively significant at a 1% level in

Model (1). That is to say, a percentage increase in the average wages of staff and

workers can indicate a rise in economic growth rate, while that in the number of

certain graduates can indicate a drop in economic growth rate. The second model

strongly confirms Hypotheses 7. WTO is significant at a 1% level means China‟s entry

to WTO promotes its economic growth at the national level. Besides, Labor Costs is

still significant and positive in Model (2) as in Model (1), whereas FDI_1 and Human

Capital are no longer significant after adding a WTO dummy.

Model (3) is used to test Hypothesis 1&2 regarding the influence of regional inward

FDI. The dummy variable COS shows a significantly positive result, which means

that coastal region has a significantly higher basic economic growth rate than its

non-coastal counterparts do. And the negatively significant interaction term

COS_FDI_1 suggests that inward FDI to the coastal region has a significantly negative effect on the economic growth rate of this region. There is a trick here: the term „economic growth‟ is not completely equal to „economic growth rate‟, however, we use economic growth rate as a measurement of economic growth. A rise or a fall

in economic growth rate can both indicate an (fast or slow) economic growth, unless

the growth rate is negative.

According to our theory and Hypothesis 1, FDI inflows should boost economic

growth in the coastal region. It seems at first sight that this result in Model (3) is the

opposite. However, we shall argue, the more developed a region is, the lower

(25)

greater economic growth potential. Ironically, it is true in reality. Thus, we may

conclude that an increase of inward FDI may lower the economic growth rate in the

coastal region but still promote its economic growth. Besides, Hypothesis 2 is

confirmed that FDI does not have a significant impact on the economic growth in the

non-coastal regions, according to the insignificant result of FDI_1 in Model (3).

Although Hypothesis 1 is not entirely confirmed, our assumption of a FDI-led growth

is supported.

Hypothesis 5&6 are confirmed by Model (4), with the interaction term COS_Lab for coastal region is negatively significant at a 1% level and Labor Costs for non-coastal

region is still positively significant. It suggests the relatively higher labor costs of the

coastal region are negatively related to its economic growth, while the comparatively

lower labor costs in the non-coastal regions may have a positive impact on their

economic growth. On the contrary, Hypothesis 3 regarding Human Capital in the

coastal region cannot be proved by Model (5). It is possible because we use the

number of higher education and specialized secondary graduates as a measure of

Human Capital, while the boost of China‟s economy at the beginning mainly is resulted from cheap labors with relatively lower education level. Both the interaction

term COS_Hum for coastal region and Human Capital for the other two regions, are

not significant. However, Hypothesis 4 is confirmed. Besides, WTO dummy is

(26)

Table 6 Empirical Results I

Variable (1)General (2)WTO (3)FDI (4)Labor

Costs (5)Human Capital (ln)FDI_1 -0.2702** (0.1271) -0.1975 (0.1275) -0.0714 (0.1351) -0.2315 (0.1280) -0.1933 (0.1293) (ln)Labor Costs 6.1062*** (0.8433) 3.4204*** (1.1370) 3.8333*** (1.1589) 5.2177*** (1.2571) 3.5294*** (1.1629) (ln)Human Capital -0.6401*** (0.2303) -0.2562 (0.2514) -0.2754 (0.2495) -0.2868 (0.2485) -0.1499 (0.2968) WTO --- 3.0207*** (0.8585) 2.8081*** (0.8711) 2.7008*** (0.8686) 2.9141*** (0.8791) COS --- --- 9.4709*** (3.5777) 30.0474*** (9.1845) 3.6370 (5.6020) COS_(ln)FDI_1 --- --- -0.4247*** (0.1503) --- --- COS_(ln)Lab --- --- --- -3.1971*** (0.9617) --- COS_(ln)Hum --- --- --- --- -0.3434 (0.4752) Constant -31.4886*** (6.3190) -14.2405 (7.9760) -20.3305** (8.3058) -29.5946*** (9.1762) -16.3717 (8.4273) Number of Obs. 353 353 353 353 353 R2 0.2066 0.2398 0.2542 0.2581 0.2414 Wald-Statistics 101.18*** 117.36*** 128.11*** 132.16*** 118.04***

(27)

Analysis II: Coastal to Non-coastal

Diagnostic Tests II

We are also interested in whether the economic development in the coastal region can

actually affect that in the central and western regions. However, lacking of important

data is a major problem to this research. The amount of FDI which directly comes to

the coastal region that eventually indirectly goes to the other two regions is a number

cannot be exactly calculated at the moment. We are not able to find any this kind of

data from China Statistical Yearbook or the websites of provincial statistics bureaus.

Thus, the already collected data used in Analysis I is also applied to this analysis.

Descriptive Statistics

N Minimum Maximum Mean Std. Deviation

Growth 2 234 -9.9554 28.8233 12.363184 5.2142398 Growth 1 156 2.4191 48.9926 12.546046 4.8723460

FDI 1 156 384160000 4.E12 6.11E11 1.009E12

Labor Costs 2 233 4564 30983 12176.49 6243.254 Human Capital 2 234 6029 729119 156960.45 147220.509

CEN 234 0 1 0.50 0.501

Valid N (listwise) 155

Multicollinearity, normality, and heteroskedasticity are also tested, as shown below.

Those variables present little collinearity and all pairs of correlations are relatively

low, with the highest is 0.650. While the histogram of residuals is reasonably

bell-shape, the Jarque-Bera test result of 115.8803 with a p-value of 6.869e-26 (> 0.05)

also suggests a normal distribution. Q-Q plots of all variables have been drawn to

show whether each variable has a normal distribution. Growth 1 and 2 still are

normally distributed separately as when they are together, whereas FDI 1 as well as

Lab 2 and Hum 2 are transformed to normal distributions by natural logarithm. Graphs of Q-Q plots are not attached here. Besides, the results of LM test show that

(28)

robustness check is no longer required. A Wooldridge test is also conducted to check

whether there is autocorrelation. The answer is no. And the Hausman test suggests

random effects estimation is feasible. Both tests results are shown in appendices.

Correlations

Growth 2 Growth 1 FDI 1 Labor

Costs 2 Human Capital 2 CEN Growth 2 1 Growth 1 0.174* 1 FDI 1 0.392** 0.137 1 Labor Costs 2 0.490** 0.239** 0.650** 1 Human Capital 2 0.002 0.097 -0.176* 0.194** 1 CEN -0.025 0.032 -0.080 -0.113 -0.055 1

*. Correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed). **. Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).

Histogram of Residuals

Heteroskedasticity Results

Variable LM value p-value

(29)

Empirical Results II

The results are pleasant. Model (1) represents whether the economic growth and FDI

inflows in the coastal region has any effects on that in the central and western regions.

Before adding Labor Costs and Human Capital of non-coastal region as control

variables, we can get from Model (1) that both Growth 1 and FDI 1 with a one-year

lag is positively and significantly related to Growth 2. It suggests inward FDI to the

coastal region after one year indeed promotes the economic growth in the central and

western regions, whereas by what means does this take place is out of the scope of

this paper. In the first two models, Growth 1_1 are both positively and significant

related to Growth 2 at a 5% level, meaning the economic development in the central

and western regions can be driven by that of the coastal region. This result confirms

one of the effects of Reform and Open Policy launched in 1970s: Let parts of our

country and parts of our people get prosperous first, and thus bring along the

development of the rest in times to come.

When we add Labor Costs 2 and Human Capital 2, FDI_1 turns to insignificantly and

negatively related to Growth 2, while Labor Costs 2 of the non-coastal regions are

positively and significantly related to their economic growth at a 1% level. This result

confirms what we get in Model (4) of Empirical Results I. The insignificant Human

Capital 2 also confirms last analysis. In the third model, a central region dummy CEN is added to see whether the impacts within the non-coastal regions, between the

central and the western region, are different. However, this variable is positive but

insignificant. It means that although the central region may have a higher growth rate

than the western region do, this difference is not prominent. Growth 1_1 and Labor

(30)

Table 7 Empirical Results II

Variable (1)General (2)Controls (3)CEN

Growth1_1 0.1852** (0.0802) 0.1614** (0.0777) 0.1556** (0.0781) (ln)FDI1_1 0.7535*** (0.1293) -0.0508 (0.2201) -0.0694 (0.2217) (ln)Labor Costs2 --- 9.6999*** (2.1459) 10.0053*** (2.1837) (ln)Human Capital2 --- -0.3317 (0.3735) -0.3222 (0.3742) CEN --- --- 0.5658 (0.7198) Constant -9.2802*** (2.9539) -73.4704*** (16.0544) -76.0978*** (16.4203) Number of Obs. 144 144 144 R2 0.2768 0.3704 0.3732 Wald-Statistics 53.98*** 81.78*** 82.17***

(31)

Conclusions

Using a panel data study from 1997 to 2009, this paper investigates the relationship

between inward FDI and regional economic growth in China. Two analyses are

performed in this study. The first analysis, regarding the different impacts of inward

FDI to coastal and non-coastal regions, shows a negative result for the coastal region.

It also suggests FDI inflows insignificantly affect the economic growth in non-coastal

regions. A possible reason for this can be that, studies which found positively

significant results for the coastal region actually used relatively earlier data of China.

On the contrary, we use very recent data from 1997 to 2009.

While inward FDI may contributes the most to the fast economic growth in the east

China and even to the whole country‟s development at the beginning of Reform and

Open Policy, in recent years, as the coastal region economy increasingly approaches

saturation, more FDI inflows may actually slow down its economic growth rate.

Along with the rapid economic growth, land and labor costs also rise faster in the

coastal region than in the other two regions. The increase in production factor prices

will not discourage FDI inflows at the moment, however inward FDI in the coastal

region may not have as big power as it has before. Besides, the surplus labor and

natural resources in the non-coastal regions will be more sufficiently utilized in the

future. To sum up, inward FDI accelerates the economic growth in the central and

western regions is an inevitable trend, regarding China‟s economic development.

In respect that the entry into WTO can be considered as a landmark event contributing to China‟s economic growth, the impact of WTO accession is another focus of this paper. WTO accession shows a significant positive relationship with the economic

growth in China at a national level. After the entry into WTO, FDI remarkably promotes China‟s economic growth. However, we have to mention that this result does not necessary mean WTO is the major factor inducing China‟s growth after 2001.

(32)

may also contribute to this result during that period. Moreover, we find a negative

relationship between coastal region‟s labor costs and its economic growth, as well as a

positive relationship between those of the central and western regions. These results

coincide with our theory and hypotheses. However, we could not find any significant

results for the importance of human capital to China during 1997-2009. As we

discussed before, this is mainly because the measurement issue.

The second analysis is to find out whether the economic development in the central

and western regions can actually be driven by that of the coastal region. The answer is

yes. Not only the economic growth in the coastal region will promote that in the

non-coastal regions, but also FDI inflows to the coastal region contribute to the

economic growth in central and western regions. However, the central region dummy

shows an insignificant result, which thus indicates the economic growth in the central

region is not significantly different from that of the western region.

Discussion

Generally, this paper has several contributions to FDI research. First of all, it

contributes to the FDI-growth nexus literature by using very recent data and empirical

results from China. Secondly, an understanding of how FDI affects different regions

in China is also important to the local policy makers and foreign investors. Last but

not least, as far as I am concerned, this is the first academic paper ever investigates

into whether the economic development in the coastal region can actually affects that

in the central and western regions, and even gets pleasant empirical results.

However, this paper also has its limitations. We find that regional FDI inflows to

China does not promote but weaken the economic growth in the coastal region. Due

to this main distinctness of the results between other similar researches and our study,

we consider a dataset of the whole period from 1978 to 2009 can be divided to several

five-year intervals, and it will be better to analyze the real situation in China. The only

(33)

variable, Human Capital. We have not found any significant results for the impacts of human capital on China‟s regional economic growth. We argue that it is probably because we use the number of higher education and specialized secondary graduates

as a measure of this variable. Future researches may use measures with lower

education level for the special case of China. Finally, also due to data limitation, the

second analysis uses already collected data for Analysis I. We cannot define by what

means and how the coastal region affects its non-coastal counterparts. If indirect FDI

data from the coastal region to the other two regions can be obtained, it will be a very

(34)

Acknowledgement

I would like to express the sincerest gratitude to my thesis supervisor, Dr. Dirk

Akkermans for guiding me during every stage of writing this thesis. He has inspired

me with invaluable ideas and offered me several suggestions with his profound

knowledge in his expertise. His kindness and patience are greatly appreciated. I am also grateful to my methodology supervisor, Prof. Dr. Erik Dietzenbacher, for his

valuable advices and comments on the methodology part as well as throughout this

thesis. Last but not least, I want to thank my family and friends for their unconditional

(35)

References

Alfaro, Laura, Chanda, A., Kalemli-Ozcan, S. and Sayek, S. 2000. FDI and Economic Growth: The Role of Local Financial Markets. Harvard Business School Working

Paper, pp. 01-083.

Alfaro, Laura, Kalemli-Ozcan, S. and Volosovych, V. 2008. Why Doesn‟t Capital Flow from Rich to Poor Countries? An Empirical Investigation. The Review of

Economics and Statistics, 90:347-368.

Ali, S. and Guo, W. 2005. Determinants of FDI in China. Journal of Global

Business and Technology, 1(2).

Baltagi, B.H. and Wu, P.X. 1999. Unequally Spaced Panel Data Regression with AR(1) Disturbances. Econometric Theory, 15(6):814-823.

Bellak, C., Leibrecht, M. and Riedl, A. 2008. Labour Costs and FDI Flows into Central and Eastern European Countries: A survey of the literature and empirical evidence. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 19:17-37.

Boermans, M., Roelfsema, H. and Zhang, Y. 2009. Regional determinants of FDI in China: A new approach with recent data. Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Institute, Utrecht School of Economics, Utrecht University, Discussion Paper Series nr:

09-23.

Borensztein, E., De Gregorio, J. and J.W. Lee. 1998. How does foreign investment affect growth? Journal of International Economics, 45.

Brambor, T., Clark, W.R. and Golder, M. 2006. Understanding Interaction Models: Improving Empirical Analyses. Political Analysis, 14:63-82.

Broadman, H.G. and Sun, X. 1997. The distribution of foreign direct investment in China. Blackwell Publishers Ltd, Oxford, UK.

Buckley, P.J., Clegg, J., Wang, C. and Cross, A.R. 2002. FDI, regional differences and economic growth: panel data and evidence from China. Transnational

Corporations, 11(1), UNCTAD.

Buthe, T. and Milner, H.V. 2008. The Politics of Foreign Direct Investment into Developing Countries: Increasing FDI through International Trade Agreements?

(36)

Carkovic, M. and Levine, R. 2005. Does Foreign Direct Investment Accelerate Economic Growth? Does Foreign Direct Investment Promote Development? T. Moran, E. Graham and M. Blomstrom, Washington, DC, pp. 195-220.

Cheng, L.K. and Kwan, Y.K. 2000. What are the determinants of the location of foreign direct investment? The Chinese experience. Journal of International

Economics, 51:379-400.

Cheung, K. and Lin, P. 2004. Spillover effects of FDI on innovation in China: Evidence from the provincial data. China Economic Review, 15:25-44.

Choe, J. 2003. Do Foreign Direct Investment and Gross Domestic Investment Promote Economic Growth? Review of Development Economics, 7:44-57.

Ciruelos, A. and Wang, M. 2005. International Technology Diffusion: Effects of Trade and FDI. Atlantic Economic Journal, 33:437-449.

Daniel III, C. 2004. The impact on China of its ascension into the WTO. The Social

Science Journal, 41:363-374.

Ding, X., Yue, C. and Sun, Y. 2009. The Influence of China‟s Entry into the WTO on its Education System. European Journal of Education, 44(1).

Fleisher, B., Li, H. and Zhao M.Q. 2005. Regional inequality and productivity growth in China: The role of foreign direct investment, infrastructure, and human capital.

Frank, A.G. 1960. Human Capital and Economic Growth. Economic Development

and Cultural Change, 8(2):170-173.

Fujita, M. and Hu, D. 2001. Regional disparity in China 1985-1994: The effects of globalization and economic liberalization. The Annals of Regional Science, 35:3-37.

Fung, K.C., Iizaka, H. and Tong, S. 2002. Foreign Direct Investment in China: Policy, Trend and Impact. International Conference on “China’s Economy in the 21st

Century”.

Galor, O. and Moav, O. 2004. From physical to human capital accumulation: Inequality and the process of development. The Review of Economic Studies, 4(71):1001–1026.

(37)

Graham, E.M., and Wada, E. 2001. Foreign Direct Investment in China: Effects on Growth and Economic Performance. Achieving High Growth: Experience of

Transitional Economics in East Asia, Oxford University Press.

Hill, R.C., Griffiths, W.E. and Lim, G.C. 2007. Principles of Econometrics, 3rd Edition, New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

Huang, S. 2009. Foreign Direct Investment and Regional Growth in China. Brunel

University.

IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2002. What will WTO membership mean for China and its trading partners? Finance & Development, 39(3).

Lee, D.W. and Lee, T.H. 1995. Human capital and economic growth. Tests based on the international evaluation of educational achievement. Economics Letters, 47:219-225.

Lheem, H.G., and Guo, S. 2004. Political Economy of FDI and Economic Growth in China: A Longitudinal Test at Provincial Level. Journal of Chinese Political Science, 9(1).

Liu, Y. and Pearson, G. 2010. An Empirical Study of the Determinants of Foreign Investment in China: A Western Australian Perspective. Journal of Asia-Pacific

Business, 11:99-120.

Long, G. 2005. China‟s Policies on FDI: Review and Evaluation. Does foreign direct

investment promote development? Institute for International Economics, and Center

for Global Development.

Mankiw, N.G., Romer, D. and Weil, D.N. 1992. A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107:407-437.

Markusen, J. and Anthony, V. 1999. Foreign direct investment as a catalyst for industrial development. European Economic Review, 43(2):335-356.

Mencinger, J. 2003. Does Foreign Direct Investment Always Enhance Economic Growth? Kyklos, 56:491-508.

Mullen, J.K. and Williams, M. 2005. Foreign Direct Investment and Regional Economic Performance. Kyklos, 58:265-282.

Noorbakhsh, F., Paloni, A. and Youssef, A. 2001. Human Capital and FDI Inflows to Developing Countries: New Empirical Evidence. World Development,

(38)

Seguino, S. 2000. Accounting for Gender in Asian Economic Growth. Feminist

Economics, 6(3):27-58.

Storper, M. 2010. Why Does a City Grow? Specialisation, Human Capital or Institutions? Urban Studies, 47(10):2027-2050.

Trevino, L.J, Daniels, J.D., Arbelaez, H. and Upadhyaya, K.P. 2002. Market Reform and Foreign Direct Investment in Latin America: Evidence from an Error Correction Model. The International Trade Journal, XVI (4).

Tsai, C.L., Huang, M.C. and Harriott, K. 2010. Human Capital Composition and Economic Growth. Soc Indic Res, 99:41-59.

Tuan, C. and Ng, L.F.Y. 20041. FDI and Industrial Restructuring in Post-WTO Great PRD: Implications on Regional Growth in China. Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Oxford, UK.

Tuan, C. and Ng, L.F.Y. 20042. Manufacturing agglomeration as incentives to Asian FDI in China after WTO. Journal of Asian Economics, 15:673-693.

Van, C.L., Nguyen, T.A., Nguyen, M.H. and Luong, T.B. 2010. New Technology, Human Capital, and Growth in a Developing Country. Mathematical Population

Studies, 17:215-241.

Wang, Y. and Yao, Y. 2003. Sources of China‟s economic growth 1952-1999: incorporating human capital accumulation. China Economic Review, 14:32-52.

Wang, Z. 2003. The impact of China‟s WTO accession on patterns of world trade.

Journal of Policy Modelling, 25:1-41.

Wen, M. 2005. Foreign Direct Investment, Regional Geographical and Market Conditions, and Regional Development: A Panel Study on China.

Wijeweera, A., Villano, R. and Dollery, B. 2010. Economic Growth and FDI Inflows: A Stochastic Frontier Analysis. Journal of Developing Areas, 43:143-158.

Wooldridge, J.M. 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. MIT

(39)

Zhang, K.H. 2006. Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in China: A Panel Data Study for 1992-2004. Conference of “WTO, China and Asian

Economics”, University of International Business and Economics (UIBE), Beijing,

(40)

Appendices

1. Q-Q plot of Growth

2. Histogram of Residuals (1a)

(41)

4. Heteroskedasticity Results (1a)

Variable LM value p-value

(ln)FDI_1 0.0927 0.7608 (ln)Labor Costs 0.6757 0.4111 (ln)Human Capital 1.2799 0.2579 WTO 2.7847 0.0952 COS 0.0645 0.7995 COS_(ln)Lab 0.0908 0.7632 5. Heteroskedasticity Results (1b)

Variable LM value p-value

(ln)FDI_1 0.0301 0.8623 (ln)Labor Costs 0.9564 0.3281 (ln)Human Capital 1.2613 0.2614 WTO 2.7451 0.0976 COS 0.0874 0.7675 COS_(ln)Hum 0.1511 0.6975

6. Wooldridge and Hausman Results

Test (1) (1a) (1b) (2)

Wooldridge 7.652(0.0098) 6.802(0.0142) 6.917(0.0135) 2.461(0.1450)

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

The link between regional competitiveness and the development of human capital is primarily a result of resources gained because of the region’s competitive position vis-à-vis

This significant government balance interaction variable shows that for the CEE10 a higher government balance does lead towards a higher economic growth rate, whereas the effect

The interest rate variable is significant (with the lagged variant causing the original to lose its significance), however the resulting coefficient is not consistent with

Since new countries had the opportunity to join the free trade area within the borders of the union, surprisingly, influence of trade liberalization on the

I use negative binomial regression analysis to examine the relationships between innovation performance and the indicators at firm and country levels, which contains

Absorptive capacity is an ability of a country to identify or exploit knowledge from environment (Cohen & Levinthal, 1989). An environmental capacity restricts or

During recent years, the informational value of sovereign credit rating changes has been questioned and challenged by several academics. Therefore, this thesis analyzes

Additionally, product role was expected to serve as a moderator of this relationship where the utilitarian role of the product bundle would cause the relationship to go more