• No results found

Challenging CAPM: Including Imported Political Risk into the Equation

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Challenging CAPM: Including Imported Political Risk into the Equation"

Copied!
44
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

Challenging CAPM: Including Imported Political Risk

into the Equation

Author: W.G. Tigranyan 1829378

Supervisor: J.O. Mierau

University of Groningen, Faculty of Economics and Business

Date: April 22th, 2013

ABSTRACT:

The recent developments in the financial world raised questions about the practicality and

reliability of the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM). This paper investigates the reliability of

CAPM in context of 54 countries around the world. In addition, a variable is included to measure

Political Risk exposure of a country to measure its effect on CAPM. The results indicate that the

market risk premium is indeed one and the Imported Political Risk (IPR) has significant quadratic

effect on country index returns. Furthermore, market portfolio and IPR together do not explain all

(2)

Page | 1

The recent developments in the financial world, such as credit crunch in 2007, resulted in a boom

of academic articles concerning the causes and the effects of the credit crunch (Attinasi II,

Checherita-Westpal and Nickel, 2009; Goodhart, 2008; Hall, 2008). In addition, European

Central Bank implemented BASEL III in order to limit the risk taking behavior of the banks and

other financial institutions. To elaborate the intuition behind the regulation, one should keep in

mind that financial institutions work with valuation models, from which Capital Asset Pricing

Model (CAPM) is the backbone underlying all models. CAPM is developed gradually by Treynor

(1961) and Sharpe (1964) and extended by Lintner (1965a; 1965b), Mossin (1966), Fama (1968a;

1968b) and Long (1972). One of the assumptions of CAPM is the information symmetry which

results in correct valuation of securities. However, a crisis in any form indicates correction of the

market prices and if one believes in efficient financial markets with symmetric information

availability, than there should be no market corrections or crises in the long run, as the

information symmetry forces the security prices to correct gradually.

As the market mechanism indicates market inefficiencies, the question is raised why in the recent

financial credit crunch of 2007 large institutional investors would believe that for example

CDO’s offered higher risk adjusted returns than what market would indicate. This is against CAPM, which states that risk adjusted returns for all securities are constant.

Because the scholars dedicated much of their time to investigate the dynamics of market

inefficiencies, this paper will concentrate on more fundamental issue. This paper will investigate

the efficiency of CAPM in the context of information flow. The advances in telecommunication

resulted in better accessibility of relevant information by investors, resulting in faster market

reaction on news. When considering that the news regarding the political developments is

(3)

Page | 2

in the security prices in short amount of time. Changes in political risk should therefore have no

significant influence on security return in the long run. In order to test this, an index of PR is

designed such that it will capture the exposure of a country towards the political risk of its trade

partners. The Imported Political Risk (IPR) is assumed to be most publically known information,

which should be easily incorporated in the prices of securities1, therefore, when including IPR in

the research, it would not result in significant result. Many researches have investigated the

effect of political event on stock market volatility (Cutler, Poterba and Summers, 1989;

Bittlingmayer, 1988; Chan and Wei, 1996; Kim and Mei, 2001) and stock market performance

(Erb, Harvey and Viskanta, 1995, 1996a, 1996b; Cosset and Suret, 1995; Bekaert, 1995, Bekaert

and Harvey, 1997), however, those researches were based on single event and single country. For

example, Beaulieu, Cosset and Essaddam (2006) investigate the short run effect of 1995 Quebec

referendum on the stock return of Quebec companies. Therefore, to my knowledge, there are no

cross country security pricing studies investigating the information efficiencies of markets in

context of IPR. Accordingly, this research will investigate whether the information symmetry

prevails in context of IPR. In addition, test will be conducted to see whether the risk is rewarded

linearly.

This paper is structured as follows: Section A will describe the literature and define the

hypotheses, thereafter the methodology will be justified in Section B, which will be followed by

the data definition in Section C, the results of the research will be summarized in Section D and

then the conclusion and discussion in Section E.

(4)

Page | 3

A. Literature Review

A concept of equity valuation is developed in the 60’s. Initially, Treynor (1961) and Sharpe

(1964) introduced the basics of valuation model, which has been extended and improved futher

by Lintner (1965a; 1965b), Mossin (1966), Fama (1968a; 1968b) and Long (1972). The model,

nowadays known as Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), states that the return on risky assets

depend only on equity specific risk; where the return is linearly related to market portfolio. In

order to be able of valuing equities CAPM adopted strong assumptions. CAPM assumes that (i)

there are no transaction costs or taxes, (ii) all important information concerning the equity is

publically available to all investors at no costs, (iii) the investors care only about the return and

the volatility of securities, and (iv) all investors can borrow and lend at risk free rate at all time

(Fama, 1970). The assumption that investors care only about the return and the risk of a security,

also known as homogenous beliefs assumption, is based on three pillars: (i) investors are assumed

to be rational and value securities rationally, (ii) when the investors are not acting rationally, their

investments are random and cancel each other out, and as last (iii) when the randomness does not

result in cancelation of mispricing, the professional arbitrageurs will cancel out the mispricing

(Fama, 1970).

The CAPM provides a simple and easily implementable framework for security pricing.

Elaborating more in detail, one can see that the first assumption is always violated as all investors

have transaction costs, and although some countries have no taxes on capital gains and dividends,

such as United Arab Emirates, considerable part of the countries have taxes. In addition, Shleifer

and Vishny (1997) prove the inability of arbitrageurs to bring the prices of securities back to their

fundamentals. In addition, Errunza and Losq (1985) and King (1993) prove the existence of

(5)

Page | 4

work of Blitz and van Vliet (2007) prove that securities with historically low volatility have

considerably higher risk adjusted return than high volatility securities in terms of Sharpe ratio and

CAPM alpha.

More importantly, the disagreements about the assumptions of information availability and

homogeneous beliefs of investors have created the field of behavioral finance where these

assumptions are discussed and tested intensively. In his book “Inefficient markets” Andrei

Shleifer (2000) provides an extensive summary of the literature concerning efficient market

theory and empirics.

CAPM predicts all efficient securities to lie on Security Market Line (SML), as described below.

( ) ( ) (1)

where ( ) is the expected return of security i, is the risk free rate, is the return on market portfolio and is the idiosyncratic risk of security i. Hence the expected return depends only on as the firm specific factor. The SML is illustrated in Figure 1 where market portfolio has beta equaling one. Any mispricing will trigger actions from arbitrageurs, thereby forcing the

prices to fall back to their fundamental values, balancing the correct pricing of securities. In the

short run, there might be inconsistencies with the CAPM, as the market needs time to recognize

the mispricing and react on it; however, when taking long perspective, all mispricing should have

been eliminated when the correction mechanism functions properly. Therefore, when the markets

are efficient, the individual securities represent together the market; hence have on average beta

of one. In order to test whether the securities are priced according to CAPM, the first hypothesis

is developed as:

(6)

Page | 5

Figure 1: The relation between expected return of a security against Beta of the security with market portfolio return of 15% and risk free return of 3%. The black dot represents the market portfolio.

Arguably, the most debated assumption of CAPM is the information availability to all investors.

It is difficult to belief that all investors have the same information always. The fact that almost all

countries imposed legislative restrictions for trade with insider information suggests information

asymmetry or at least different costs to gain the information. The availability of information

assumption is divided into three separate hypotheses: weak, semi-strong and strong forms (Fama,

1970). The weak form of efficiency states that the investors have only access to the information

of past performance and risk for certain security and attach the price based on that information.

The semi-strong information efficiency states that all publically known information is

incorporated in the price of the security; therefore no risk-adjusted excess returns can be obtained

in the long run. The strong form of information efficiency states that even insider information

will be incorporated in the security prices, as the information always leaks to the public.

-60.00% -40.00% -20.00% 0.00% 20.00% 40.00% 60.00% -4 -3.5 -3 -2.5 -2 -1.5 -1 -0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 R et u rn o f se cu ri ti es w it h gi ve n b et a Beta of securities

(7)

Page | 6

Nowadays, the improvements in information and communication sector have led to fast

distribution of information worldwide. Even the political event in foreign countries is becoming

known by the public in very short amount of time. The ease of obtaining information regarding

political changes should have direct impact on security prices. Therefore, including the change in

the foreign political risk into CAPM framework should not influence the security prices in the

long run.

Companies having operations in foreign countries are faced with the foreign political risk2 on

everyday basis (Kobrin, 1979), which will eventually influence the firms performance when not

managed properly (Erb, Harvey and Viskanta, 1996a). A clear example of foreign political risk

influence on a company’s performance is the case of Royal Dutch Shell in Sakhalin, Russia in 2006, when, off the records, Russian government imposed a two billion affine to Shell for

violating environmental standard, which resulted in withdrawal of Shell from the region. In this

case, Shell did not anticipate the influence of the government in large commercial projects in

Russia which might give some strategic benefits to the political power of Russian Federation.

This major event is in line with Clark and Tunaru (2005) and Simon (1973), who find that

political events have significant negative economic and financial consequences.

Many researches have investigated the effect of political event on stock market volatility (Cutler,

Poterba and Summers, 1989; Bittlingmayer, 1988; Chan and Wei, 1996; Kim and Mei, 2001) and

stock market performance (Erb, Harvey and Viskanta, 1995, 1996a and 1996b; Cosset and Suret,

1995; Bekaert, 1995, Bekaert and Harvey, 1997), however, those researches were based on short

run, single event, domestic political risk or one country events. For example, Beaulieu, Cosset

(8)

Page | 7

and Essaddam (2006) investigate the short run effect of 1995 Quebec referendum on the stock

return of Quebec companies. To sum up, the political risk itself might not have as much impact

on a firm’s performance as the change in the foreign political risk or the exposure towards it. Related to the assumptions of CAPM regarding to the information availability, the political risk is

categorized in the semi-strong assumption of information. The political events are always

highlighted in the media, which might take less than half hour in order to recognize and broadcast

to the investors, hence in the long run, the change in the Imported Political Risk (IPR) should not

have significant explanatory power for the firm’s or country’s performance. Moreover, political

risk is country specific; therefore, it can be diversified when investing internationally; meaning

that the international investor will not price the IPR as idiosyncratic risk, whereas the national

investor will.

Although the political risk is converging over time (Diamonte, Liew and Stevens, 1996),

Pukthuanthong-Le and Visaltanachoti (2009) found significant pricing of idiosyncratic risk on

firm level, leading to significant pricing of political risk on country’s largest index. In the long

run IPR should have no effect on country index return. When IPR explains the variations of the

index returns, it violates the semi-strong assumption of information availability, thereby proving

the limited use of CAPM by practitioners. Formally, hypothesis 2 is formed as:

When considering different risk adjusted returns for securities (Errunza and Losq, 1985), one can

expect that the same nonlinear relation also holds also for IPR. To explain more in detail with

(9)

Page | 8

amount3, it is less likely that Shell would react double as fierce. Most probably Shell would leave

the country and stop all its operation in Russian Federation for long time. In accordance with this

logic, the third and last hypothesis is formed as:

(10)

Page | 9

B. Methodology

Within CAPM, the expected returns of any securities are described by the SML, formula (1). In

the setting of this research, the world is the market with individual securities on SML. Country

indices represent efficient portfolios consisting of securities listed in that country. When taking

into account the risk free rate requirement of SML, Formula (1), it becomes impossible to find

risk free rate applicable to every country (Solnik, 1974). Therefore, this research will employ the

methodology used by Jorion (1990), which does not require the specification of universal risk

free rate. The regression model to be estimated can be written as:

̃ ̃ (2)

where ̃ is the index return of country i at time t, is the regression intercept for country i, is the world equity market beta, which should equal one, ̃ is the return of market portfolio at time t, and is the disturbance term for country i at time t. In order to understand what measures, formula (1) is rearranged, as illustrated by formulae 3 – 6. ̃ ̃ (3)

̃ ( ) ̃ (4)

formula (2) – formula (4) => ̃ ̃ ( ) ̃ ̃ (5)

( ) (6) In context of CAPM, should equal one. Regardless of what the value of risk free rate is,

should always equal to zero when market beta equals one. In case that the intercept is anything

(11)

Page | 10

problem, disproving automatically the CAPM. For example, Ross (1976) proposed using

Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) as a substitute for CAPM. APT is a multifactor model where

also macroeconomic factors are included for asset pricing.

For investigation of IPR impact on the return of country index and the nonlinear relation of IPR,

the regression models become:

̃ ̃ (7)

̃ ̃ (8)

(12)

Page | 11

C. Data

The data of this research is limited to the availability of country bilateral trade weights and

political risk measures. While Bank of International Settlements (BIS) provides country level

bilateral trade weight for 61 countries4 from 1993 until 2010, the Political Risk Service Group

(PRS Group) provides data for political risk measures for 146 countries from 1984 until 2008 in

its International Country Risk Guide (ICRG). Therefore, when excluding Euro Area as a separate

country, the combined dataset includes 60 countries with data from 1993 until 2008. However,

not all countries have equity markets indices starting 1993; therefore, the countries which

introduced indices after 2000 are excluded from this research. The year 2000 is chosen in order to

have at least 50% of the observations included in the time series; hence the dataset includes at

least eight years observations. When deleting the countries with missing country index values, 54

countries remain in the dataset with a total of 847 observations. When accounting for one year

loss when calculating the return and maintaining the 50% criteria, 777 country – year

observations remain. The summary of countries and their indices with corresponding available

observations is illustrated in Appendix A.

C.1. Country Performance

Country performance is measured by a country’s dominant large cap index, as illustrated in

Appendix A. The large cap index prices are obtained on annual basis from Thomson Datastream

database. Ideally, one should include the total return indices. However, the total return indices are

introduced quite recently, resulting in many missing variables for the years 1993 – 2008. As a

result, only price indices are employed.

(13)

Page | 12

Using only price indices may lead to biased results, as it automatically assumes that the capital

gains are the most important measures for performance, thereby neglecting the dividend yield.

However, when comparing the price indices with the corresponding total return indices for

available countries, the correlations are very high5. More thorough investigation indicates that the

variation between the total return and price indices are also very similar. As Thomson Datastream

provides index prices instead of the returns, the index return for country i at time t is calculated

using formula (9).

(

) (9)

When investigating individual indices, some very interesting developments are observed. Figure

2 illustrates the developments in the two fastest growing equity indices; namely MSCI Brazil and

Istanbul SE National 100. When comparing with Figure 3, MSCI World had average

continuously compounded return of 7.48% while MSCI Brazil had average return of 45.11% and

Istanbul SE National 100 50.93%. The highest increase yielded in Brazil in 1993, accounting for

386.22%. The worst performing country in the dataset is Thailand which had on average negative

annual return of 3.23%. It is interesting to mention that after the financial crisis in 2007, without

exception all indices declined sharply. The minimum decline was the Venezuelan market by

7.06% and maximum decline was astonishing 194.19%6. In comparison, MSCI World had a

return of -67.87% and DJGL World -69.67%. This suggests the existence of outliers. In order to

prevent distortion in analysis results, the outliers are excluded from the analysis by using dummy

variable. Section C.4. will explain the construction of the dummy variable.

5

The correlation coefficient between the price indices and the corresponding total return indices are well above 0.9.

(14)

Page | 13

Figure 2: Equity market developments in Brazil for MSCI Brazil and Turkey for Istanbul SE National 100 in logarithmic scale. MSCI Brazil grew on average by 45.11% from 1993 until 2007 to fall by 51.25% in 2008. Istanbul SE National 100 grew on average by 50.93% from 1993 until 2007 to fall with 58.03% in 2008.

Figure 3: Equity market developments in MSCI World, Thailand for Bangkok S.E.T. and Philippine for Philippine SE I in logarithmic scale. MSCI World grew on average by 7.48% from 1993 until 2007 to fall with 50.18% in 2008. Bangkok S.E.T. decreased on average by 3.23% from 1993 until 2007 to fall with 51.77% in 2008 and Philippine SE I grew on average by 2.75% from 1993 until 2007 to fall by 49.47% in 2008.

1 10 100 1000 10000 100000 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008

Index developments for Brazil and Turkey

Brazil Turkey 1 10 100 1000 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008

Index developments for the world, Thailand and

Philippine

(15)

Page | 14

C.2. Imported Political Risk

Imported Political Risk (IPR) is the average of political risk exposure of a country towards its

trade partner, weighted with bilateral trade weights. The political risk measures are obtained from

ICRG provided by PRS Group, while the trade weights are obtained from BIS.

The PRS Group publishes ICRG on annual basis, which includes measures for political risk7

through 12 components. By employing the ICRG data, this research follows the steps of

Diamonte, Liew and Stevens (1996), who studied the political risk in emerging and developed

countries. In addition, Erb, Harvey and Viskanta (1996b) summarize various measures for

country risk with their reciprocal differences (Exhibit 7) between January 1984 and September

1995. The major advantage of ICRG political risk indicator is that it encompasses almost all

aspects of country risk; therefore, it is a proxy for country’s total risk index.

The ICRG country political risk includes 146 countries from 1984 until 2008. The PRS Group

attaches different values to different components, depending on the importance of the component.

The weight of risk components and the meaning of the indices are summarized in Table 1.

Realizing the maximum score of 12 points, the total Political Risk (PR) is calculated as the

average of 12 components of PR weighted against the maximum points the component can

receive. The calculation is summarized by formula (10).

(∑ ) (10)

where is the index score for risk component for country i at time t, Point is the maximum point the component can score, and is the total political risk of country i at time t.

(16)

Page | 15

Table 1: The weights used for calculation of total political risk index (left) and the relative meaning of the index (right)

Risk Components Weight Political Risk Assessment Government Stability 12 Very High <49.9%

Socioeconomic Conditions 12 High 50%-59.9%

Investment Profile 12 Moderate 60%-69.9%

Internal Conflict 12 Low 70%-79.9%

External Conflict 12 Very Low 80%-100%

Corruption 6

Military in Politics 6

Religious Tensions 6

Law and Order 6

Ethnic Tensions 6

Democratic Accountability 6

Bureaucracy Quality 4

Note 1: The highest weight in the components is 12, indicating the high importance of the component for the total political risk. Some components are constructed by summing other sub-components. For

example, Government Stability is the sum of three different sub-components: Government Unity, Legislative Strength and Popular Support. Every subcomponent receives at maximum a value of 4, resulting in a maximum of 12 points for Government Stability. Compared to Bureaucracy Quality, Government Stability is more important for political measure, because unstable governments result in regime change while Bureaucracy Quality results in inefficiencies in the government. Poor Bureaucracy Quality results rarely in political uncertainty.

Note 2: Political Risk Assessment illustrates the relative meaning of the total Political Risk. Lower index value corresponds with higher risk, while higher indicates lower risk.

In order to calculate IPR, data is needed to describe a country’s exposure towards other partner

countries. Jorion’s work (1990) is used as guideline in this context, where the revenues of the

multinationals from foreign countries were used as the weight of exchange rate exposure.

Although being a solid measure of foreign exposure, this methodology is only applicable at firm

level and in countries where the revenues from foreign operations are obliged to be reported. This

research uses country level data, which makes Jorion’s (1990) application impossible.

More detailed investigation suggests that countries import risk from their foreign partner relative

(17)

Page | 16

countries from 1993 until 2010. The weighting matrix is composed such that the weights between

the years 93-95, 96-98, 99-01, 02-04, 05-07, and 08-10 are constant. In order to be able of

constructing the total IPR, assumption is made that the trade is roughly constant over relatively

short period of time; therefore the values of bilateral trade can be used as yearly inputs. For

example, Figure 4 illustrates the development of trade with Euro Area for several important trade

partners8. One can observe that the trade with China is increasing rapidly, resulting in higher

exposure of Euro Area towards the developments in China. The increasing share of China seems

to be at the expense of other countries, as their relative share in Euro Area is declining.

Figure 4: Trade development of selected countries with Euro Area

The downside of BIS dataset is that the bilateral trade of Euro Area member countries with total

Euro Area is not provided; therefore, it is impossible to construct political risk for Euro Area

based only on BIS dataset. However, when realizing that the political risk is directly linked to the

8 Total share of the six countries to world GDP (current USD) fluctuates around 50%. 0.0 5.0 10.0 15.0 20.0 25.0 1993_1995 1996_1998 1999_2001 2002_2004 2005_2007 2008_2010

Trade with Euro Area

(18)

Page | 17

governing body of a country, it can be stated that the political risk of Euro Area is transferred

trough a common governing structure. The Euro Area countries are unified in European

Parliament as the main governing body where from the local political risk is being transferred to

the whole European Union. Therefore, the total political risk of Euro Area can be calculated by

taking the weighted average political risk of Euro Area countries with the weight being the share

of representatives of Euro Area countries in the European Parliament. Appendix B summarizes

the representatives of Euro Area countries in the European Parliament with their corresponding

weights. For example, Germany’s contribution to the total political risk of Euro Area can be calculated as follows: Germany has 20.63% of total representatives from the Euro Area and its

political risk in 1994 was 83.80, which results in 20.63%*83.80=17.28 as Germany’s

contribution of the political risk in the Euro Area. Hence the calculation can be summarized by

the formula:

∑(

), (11)

where is the total political risk of Euro Area at time t and

is the weight of risk exposure

based on political representation in the EU for country i at time t.

Once the political risk of the Euro Area is constructed, the Imported Political Risk (IPR) can be

calculated by using the formula:

∑( ), (12)

(19)

Page | 18

As IPR is publicly known information, a constant IPR will not influence the return. However,

when there is a change in IPR, market are expected to react on the change. The yearly change in

IPR is obtained by employing formula (9).

The calculation of IPR for USA will illustrate in detail the steps of IPR index construction.

Assume world consists of five countries: China, France, Germany, Greece and USA. The first

step is to calculate the political risk of the countries. The steps and results are summarized in

Table 2. The rows for score are the raw data received from ICRG. The weighted scores are

obtained by dividing the scored by the maximum points per component. After summing the

weighted scores, unscaled political risk is received; this is rescaled by multiplying with 100/12 in

order to receive the total political risk, as explained by formula (10).

Table 2: Calculation of total Political Risk for China, France, Germany and Greece

Components 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Max points 12 12 12 12 12 6 6 6 6 6 6 4 S cor e China 10.7 7.8 7.0 9.6 10.0 2.5 3.0 5.0 4.5 4.5 1.5 2.0 France 8.8 7.5 11.8 9.7 10.0 5.0 5.5 4.0 5.0 2.5 6.0 3.0 Germany 10.0 8.0 11.9 11.1 10.5 5.0 6.0 5.0 5.0 4.0 6.0 4.0 Greece 6.9 7.7 10.5 8.8 10.2 2.0 5.0 5.0 4.5 5.0 6.0 3.0 W eight ed S cor e China 0.89 0.65 0.58 0.80 0.83 0.42 0.50 0.83 0.75 0.75 0.25 0.50 France 0.73 0.63 0.98 0.81 0.83 0.83 0.92 0.67 0.83 0.42 1.00 0.75 Germany 0.83 0.67 0.99 0.93 0.88 0.83 1.00 0.83 0.83 0.67 1.00 1.00 Greece 0.58 0.64 0.88 0.73 0.85 0.33 0.83 0.83 0.75 0.83 1.00 0.75 Unscaled PR (sum weighted score) Total PR (x100/12) T otal P R China 7.76 64.65 France 9.40 78.33 Germany 10.46 87.15 Greece 9.01 75.07

Note 1: Max points refer to the maximum point a country can score per component.

(20)

Page | 19

At this stage, the total PR is known, however, according to BIS dataset9, USA trades for 40%

with Euro Area and 60% with China. As the PR of Euro Area is not known, the IPR cannot be

calculated. Assuming Euro Area consists only of Germany, France and Greece, who are

represented in the European Parliament by respectively 50%, 30% and 20% of the seats, the PR

can be approximated using formula (11).

In this case, USA imports 40% of 82.09 from Euro Area and 60% of 64.65 from China, resulting

in IPR of 77.88. The calculation is similar for all other countries in the dataset.

C.3. Market Performance

Market performance reflects the world equity market performance. This research employs two

measures for world performance: MSCI World and DJGL World. Both of them are denominated

in US dollar. Both of the indices will be used in simultaneously in order to cross check the

robustness of the results. The return on market portfolio is calculated by employing formula (9).

The proxies for world benchmarks are somewhat different regarding the exposure of index

towards several countries and industries, as illustrated by Appendix C. Although the benchmarks

are somewhat different, one cannot predict which one approximates the world market better,

however, it is not excluded that the regression results will yield slightly different results.

C.4. Outliers

As discussed before, this research will control for outliers by using dummy variable. The

criterion of outlier used in this research is:

(21)

Page | 20

̅ (13)

where, ̅ is the mean of country index returns and is the standard deviation of index returns. Three time positive and three time negative deviation from the mean will cover 99.7% of the

dataset, when assuming that the returns follow normal distribution. When the observations are

identified as outlier, the dummy variable receives value of one, otherwise zero. As a result, 43

outliers are identified from a total of 777 observations.

C.5. Domestic Political Risk

This research will also control for domestic Political Risk (PR). How the domestic PR is

influencing valuation practices is described by Agmon and Findlay (1982). The main argument

how domestic political risk will affect stock valuation is by increasing inflation. The mechanism

described by Agmon and Findlay (1982) is that weak governments, which are characterized by

high political risk, will grant subsidies to certain domestic companies, which will increase the

governmental spending. The government tries to close the gap in budget deficit, caused by large

subsidies. As the tax income is the main source of income for government, and the tax rates are

sticky in the short run, the government will use inflation as the tax mechanism of last resort. The

increase in inflation will force the discount rate for stock valuation to increase, resulting in

decrease of stock prices.

Table 2 illustrates the construction of total political risk, which is converted to domestic PR by

(22)

Page | 21

D. Results

Initially there were 60 countries involved in the research. However, because of lacking data 54

countries remained in the dataset with 15 yearly (1994 – 2008) observations, accounting for 777

country-year observations. Table 3 summarizes the correlation matrix and descriptive statistics of

the data employed in this research. Frankly, none of the variables seem to follow normal

distribution. Interesting is to mention the difference between the minimum and the maximum of

the returns between 1994 and 2008. MSCI Brazil faces an incredible return of 288% in 1994

whereas OMX Iceland all share face devastating decrease of 194%10. These large differences

indicate the existence of outliers which will influence the regression results. The influences of

these outliers are eliminated by using a dummy variable. As can be seen, the correlation between

the Return and IPR is very low at 0.14. Further, the correlation between world and country

indices are fairly high, indicating that the world indices explain a large part of the movements in

the country indices.

In order to analyze the relation and magnitude of IPR on country’s index, stepwise regressions is conducted using formulae (2), (7) and (8). Using two different world index proxies and three

models will result in six regressions. The regressions are summarized in Table 4.

10 Based on continuous compounding ( (

(23)

Page | 22

Table 3: Correlation matrix and descriptive statistics

Variable 1 2 3 4 5 6 1 Return 1.000 2 IPR 0.140 1.000 3 IPR2 0.043 -0.344 1.000 4 MSCI World 0.623 0.188 -0.084 1.000 5 DJGL World 0.640 0.176 -0.085 0.996 1.000 6 Domestic PR -0.061 0.245 -0.094 -0.001 -0.002 1.000 Mean 0.060 -0.001 -0.000 0.021 0.021 0.001 Standard Deviation 0.374 0.014 0.000 0.223 0.225 0.037 Minimum -1.942 -0.064 0.000 -0.678 -0.697 -0.367 Maximum 2.881 0.053 0.004 0.178 0.203 0.148 Skewness -0.402 -0.553 5.535 -2.050 -2.126 -1.435 Kurtosis 9.749 4.712 43.016 6.638 7.025 17.429 Note 1: N=777

Note 2: 9 countries provided index data later than 1993, which resulted in incomplete return data from 1993 until 2008. Missing countries are: Bulgaria until 2001, Croatia until 1998, Czech Republic until 1995, Estonia until 1997, Latvia until 1997,

Luxembourg until 2000, Malta until 1997, Romania until 1998, and Russian Federation until 1996.

Table 4: Regression model specification Model Specification 1 ̃ ̃ 2 ̃ ̃ 3 ̃ ̃ 4 ̃ ̃ 5 ̃ ̃ 6 ̃ ̃ Note 1: ̃ is the return on MSCI World in year t

Note 2: ̃ is the return on DJGL World in year t

Note 3: is the dummy variable of outliers with the value of one if ̃ exceeds the mean with more than three times the standard error and zero otherwise

(24)

Page | 23

The initial results of pooled OLS are summarized in Appendix D.1. The pooled OLS model show

very significant effects of IPR and IPR2 in the CAPM setting. Furthermore, the constant is as

predicted zero with slightly significant, negative coefficient for Domestic PR, indicating that a

country’s risk free rate is determined by the country risk characteristics. Even the test of coefficients proves the beta of the market is one. In order to see whether the results are BLUE,

diagnostic tests are conducted. The results of Breusch – Pegan / Cook – Weisberg test of

heteroscedasticity shows homoscedastic disturbance terms in Models 1 – 3 and 6. It is surprising

how the P-values of heteroscedasticity test change when including the variables for IPR and IPR2.

In Models 1, 2, 4 and 5 in Appendix D.1 the P-values of heteroscedasticity are very low until the

inclusion of political risk variables. Even when looking the differences between Models 5 and 6,

initially inclusion of IPR in Model 5 seems to have limited effect on the regression output;

however, when introducing IPR2 to correct for nonlinear relation between IPR and Return, the

P-value for heteroscedasticity increases dramatically from 0.085 to 0.999, almost perfect

homoscedastic. Further, the tests for autocorrelations indicate absence of autocorrelation. As last,

when investigating multicollinearity in Appendix D.2, the correlations between the disturbance

terms with its one year lagged values are very low.

At first glance, the pooled OLS is BLUE, however, when investigating the autocorrelation for

separate countries, in Appendix D.3, and years, Appendix D.4, the regional and periodical

autocorrelations are obvious. For example, Thailand has correlation coefficient of 0.559. For the

total market, the correlation coefficient of the disturbance term between the years 2006 and 2007

is 0.486. The model seems to suffer from positive and negative autocorrelation, depending on the

country and year. In addition, when looking to the scatter plot of disturbance term of Model 3

(25)

Page | 24

probable heteroscedasticity in the long run. To correct for the autocorrelation and

heteroscedasticity, General Least Squared (GLS) regression analysis will be conducted taking

into account Durbin Watson d-statistic and ARCH(1) effect (Brooks, 2008). However, before

proceeding to the GLS regression, decision needs to be made concerning the use of fixed or

random effects by using regional and income dummy variables.

The definitions of regional dummy variables are summarized in Appendix E. The dummy

variable of North America is not included in the analysis in order to avoid the dummy trap. The

dummy variable of income level is based on current GNI per capita, using World Bank Atlas

method11. The dummy variable receives a value of one when the GNI per capital exceeds 12.476

USD, which is the level at which World Bank classifies the countries as high income country.

Hence, the dummy variable can take different values within the time span and country, making it

dynamic dummy variable, representing the state of a country for a specific year.

The results of robust OLS regression with the dummy variables are illustrated in Appendix F. The

results of the regressions indicate the presence of regional effects, as the dummy variable of Asia

is significantly positive and the joint hypothesis test of regional coefficients prove the existence

of regional effects on country returns. In addition, the income level also has significant effect on

a country’s return. Based on Appendix F, conclusion can be drawn that there are fixed effects in the dataset, therefore, the final GLS regression analyses are conducted taking into account fixed

effects.

(26)

Page | 25

Table 5: GLS panel data regression with control for ARCH effect, Durbin Watson d-statistic and Fixed Effects

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6

IPR 0.590 2.829** 0.567 2.779** (0.791) (0.933) (0.775) (0.913) IPR2 126.5*** 127.1*** (29.89) (29.25) MSCI World 1.019*** 1.014*** 1.022*** (0.0442) (0.0450) (0.0447) DJGL World 1.026*** 1.021*** 1.029*** (0.0425) (0.0432) (0.0429) Outliers -0.540*** -0.534*** -0.507*** -0.517*** -0.512*** -0.487*** (0.0954) (0.0955) (0.0944) (0.0935) (0.0936) (0.0925) Domestic PR -0.270 -0.321 -0.286 -0.284 -0.334 -0.299 (0.286) (0.295) (0.293) (0.280) (0.289) (0.287) Intercept 0.0456*** 0.0473*** 0.0306** 0.0445*** 0.0462*** 0.0294** (0.0101) (0.0104) (0.0108) (0.00994) (0.0102) (0.0106) R2 Within 0.411 0.413 0.428 0.432 0.435 0.451 R2 Between 0.000 0.000 0.013 0.000 0.000 0.022 R2 Overall 0.392 0.394 0.410 0.413 0.416 0.433 Note 1: N=723

Note 2: Standard errors in parentheses Note 3: * p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001

Table 6: P-values of hypotheses tests

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6

(27)

Page | 26

Table 5 illustrates the final outcome of the analysis, whereas Table 6 summarizes the results of

hypotheses tests. For Models 1 and 4, the CAPM seems to hold for world market beta, as the

hypothesis tests fail to prove that the beta is other than one, the intercept is significant which

indicates that the risk free return is not dependent on domestic political risk. When introducing

IPR, the results do not change much in terms of significance. However, this is caused by

misspecification of functional form of IPR. When including IPR and IPR2 in Models 3 and 6, the

results change dramatically. The measure for IPR becomes very significant. When IPR increases,

the imported political environment becomes more risky, the return of country’s index also

increases, which is in line with higher risk higher reward perception. However, the risk adjusted

return is not constant, as IPR2 is significantly positive. Furthermore, proxies for market

performances do have a beta of one, as theory suggests. However, the intercept is significantly

positive and the domestic political risk is not. This indicates that the risk free return is not

explained only by domestic political risk. In addition, the R2 is always somewhat higher than

40%, which leaves almost 60% of the variation unexplained. When taking into account that the

dataset contains yearly observations, the noise or inefficiencies in the dataset are brought to

minimum. This means that the 60% unexplained variance is impossible to attribute to noise or

inefficiencies in the market. Therefore, it is safe to conclude that extending CAPM with IPR fails

to explain the market dynamics fully; hence there are other important factors which are not

included in this paper. The inclusion of IPR and IPR2 improves the explanatory power of the

model by only 2%. To sum up, the market has a beta of one; however, country index returns do

also depend on IPR which is not rewarded linearly.

In order to ensure the consistency of the results, this research employs two proxies for world

(28)

Page | 27

different method is also used to crosscheck the results. Appendix G.1 shows the final regression

results, based on the methodology of Fama and MacBeth (1978), whereas Appendix G.2 shows

the hypotheses tests of the models. The difference between the main methodology and Fama and

MacBeth (1978) is that they use excess returns of equities and markets, whereas Jorion (1990)

uses the returns directly as inputs for the model. The different approach yields in the same results

with somewhat better R2. Hence the results are robust across different methodologies and

(29)

Page | 28

E. Conclusion and Discussion

Current financial and political developments, such as credit crunch in 2007 and sovereign debt

crisis of Greece in 2010, indicate market inefficiencies with respect to information flow. CAPM

predicts correct market pricing under the assumption of information symmetry. Furthermore, the

excess return of a security should depend only on the risk of security. When considering the

correct security pricing under the assumption of symmetric information flow, the market should

correct the security prices gradually over time. When this is true, the mispricing should not

accumulate to create crises.

This paper has investigated the risk characteristics of country indices’ returns and the influences of political changes on index returns. Initially, the CAPM seemed to hold ground when the

measure of IPR was introduced, with exception of constant risk adjusted return of indices.

However, when including IPR2, the results changed significantly. The results of regression

analyses accept Hypothesis 1, that the market has indeed a beta of one, whereas Hypotheses 2

and 3 are also proven to be true, stating that the IPR is not initially priced and the pricing is not

constant in terms of risk adjusted return. In addition, there seems to be some regional influences.

For example, Asian indices yielded on average lower returns than elsewhere. Also the high

income countries had lower returns on their country indices.

When looking at researches investigating pricing theories with firm level data, price to book ratio

and price to earnings ratio seem to have significant influence on firm return (Danielson and

Dowdell, 2001). Even more fundamental, Fama and French (1992) show that the firm’s beta fails

to predict the returns in the year 1963 – 1990. In this setting, this research does not deviate from

prior research as different regions have different risk rewards (Errunza and Losq, 1985; Garcia

(30)

Page | 29

more appropriate to test security pricing theory, as the intercept is significantly positive, thereby

supporting Arbitrage Pricing Theory (Ross, 1976). In order to see what causes the significant

intercept, more research should be done using macroeconomic variables. One of the

macroeconomic factors could be the measures of international investments (Ferson and Harvey,

1993), which can be related to the semi-strong assumption of information flow and transaction

costs of CAPM.

To sum up, the CAPM is a good estimation of the security prices; however it is not the complete

picture. The R2 of the CAPM is nearly 40%, indicating that the largest amount of the security

price variation is not explained by CAPM. The assumption of CAPM for information symmetry

is also overruled, as the political risk has significant influence on security return. Moreover,

increasing IPR12 results in higher return, which is contra intuitive to what CAPM predicts. In

addition, the exposure to foreign country risk does not have linear influence on the country index

return. These results are robust when testing with two different measures of world market

performance and two different methodologies.

(31)

Page | 30

F. References

Agmon, Tamir, and Findlay, M. Chapman, 1982, Domestic political risk and stock valuation,

Financial Analysts Journal 38(6), 74-77.

Attinasi II, Maria Grazia, Checherita-Westpal, Cristina D., and Nickel, Christiane, 2009, What

explains the surge in Euro Area sovereign spread during the financial crisis of 2007-2009? ECB

Workin Paper No. 1131.

Beaulieu, Marie-Claude, Cosset, Jean-Claude, and Essaddam, Naceur, 2006, Political uncertainty

and stock market returns: evidence from the 1995 Quebec referendum, Conadian Journal of

Economics 39(2), 621-642.

Bekaert, Geert, 1995, Market integration and investment barriers in emerging equity markets,

World Bank Economic Review 9(1), 75-107.

Bekaert, Geert, and Harvey, Campbell R., 1997, Emerging equity market volatility, Journal of

Financial Economics 43, 29-77.

Bittlingmayer, George, 1998, Output, stock volatility, and political uncertainty in a natural

experiment: Germany, 1880-1940, The Journal of Finance 53(6), 2243-2257.

Blitz, David C., and van Vliet, Pim, 2007, The volatility effect: low risk without lower return,

The Journal of Portfolio Management Fall, 102-113.

Brewer, Thomas L., 1981, Political risk assessment for foreign direct investment decisions: better

(32)

Page | 31

Brooks, Chris, 2008, Introductory Econometrics for Finance, (Cambridge University Press, New

York, NY)

Cambel, John Y., and Taksler, Glen B., 2002, Equity volatility and corporate bond yields,

Working Paper No: 8961, Cambridge, MA.

Chan, Yue-cheong, and Wei, Hohn K.C., 1996, Political risk and stock price volatility: the case

of Hong Kong, Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 4(2-3), 259-275).

Clark, Ephraim, and Tunaru Radu, 2003, Quantification of political risk with multiple dependent

sources, Journal of Economics and Finance 27(2), 125-135.

Clark, Ephraim, and Tunaru Radu, 2005, The evolution of international political risk 1956-2001,

http://repec.org/mmfc05/paper37.pdf

Cosset, Jean-Claude, and Suret, Jean-Marc, 1995, Political risk and the benefits of international

portfolio diversification, Journal of International Business Studies 26(2), 301-318.

Culter, David M., Poterba, James M., and Summers, Lawrence H., 1989, What moves stock

prices? The Journal of Portfolio Management 15(3), 4-12.

Danielson, Morris G., and Dowdell, Thomas D., 2001, The return-stages valuation model and the

expectations within a firm’s P/B and P/E ratios, Financial Management 30(2), 93-124.

Diamonte, Robin L., Liew, John M., and Stevens, Ross L., 1996, Political risk in emerging and

developed markets, Financial Analysts Journal 52(3), 71-76.

Erb, Claude B., Harvey, Campbell R., and Viskanta, Tadas E., 1995, Country risk and global

(33)

Page | 32

Erb, Claude B., Harvey, Campbell R., and Viskanta, Tadas E., 1996a, Political risk, economic

risk and financial risk, Financial Analyst Journal 52(6), 29-46.

Erb, Claude B., Harvey, Campbell R., and Viskanta, Tadas E., 1996b, Expected returns and

volatility in 135 countries, The Journal of Portfolio Management Spring, 46-58.

Errunza, Vihang. and Losq, Etienne, 1985, International asset pricing under mild segmentation:

theory and test, The Journal of Finance 40(1), 105-124.

Fama, Eugene F., 1968a, Risk, return, and equilibrium, Chicago: Center for Mathematical Studies

in Business and Economics, No: 6831, University of Chicago.

Fama, Eugene F., 1968b, Risk, return, and equilibrium: some clarifying comments, Journal of

Finance 23, 29-40.

Fama, Eugene F., 1970, Efficient capital markets: a review of theory and empirical work, The

Journal of Finance 25(2), 383-417.

Fama, Eugene F., and French, Kenneth R., 1992, The cross-section of expected stock returns,

Journal of Finance 47, 427-465.

Fama, Eugene F., and MacBeth, James D., 1973, Risk, return and equilibrium: empirical tests,

The Journal of Political Economy 81(3), 607-636.

Ferson, Wayne E., and Harvey, Campbell R., 1993, The risk and predictability of international

equity returns, The Review of Financial Studies 6(3), 527-566.

Garcia, René, and Ghysels, Eric, 1998, Structural change and asset pricing in emerging markets,

(34)

Page | 33

Goodhart, Charles A.E., 2008, The background to the 2007 financial crisis, Internatioanl

Economics and Economic Policy 4, 331-346.

Hall, Maximilian J.B., 2008, The sub-prime crisis, the credit squeeze and Northern Rock: the

lessons to be learned, Journal of Financial Regulation and Compliance 16(1), 19-34.

Jorion, Philippe, 1990, The exchange-rate exposure of U.S. multinationals, The Journal of

Business 63(3), 331-345.

Kim, Harold Y., and Mei, Jianping P., 2001, What makes the stock market jump? An analysis of

political risk on Hong Kong stock returns, Journal of International Money and Finance 20(7),

1003-1016.

King, Alan J., 1993, Asymmetric risk measures and tracking models for portfolio optimization

under uncertainty, Annals of Operations Research 45(1), 165-177.

Kobrin, Stephen J., 1979, Political risk: a review and reconsideration, Journal of International

Business Studies 10(1), 67-80.

Linter, John, 1965a, Security prices, risk, and maximal gain from diversification, Journal of

Finance 20, 587-616.

Linter, John, 1965b, The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock

portfolios and capital budgets, Review of Economics and Statistics 47, 13-37.

Long, John B., Jr., 1972, Consumption-investment decision and equilibrium in security market, in

Michael C. Jensen, ed.: Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets (Preager Publishers).

(35)

Page | 34

Pukthuanthong-Le, Kuntara, and Visaltanachoti, Nuttawat, 2009, Idiosyncratic volatility and

stock returns: a cross country analysis, Applied Financial Economics 19, 1269-1281.

Ross, Stephen A., 1976, The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing, Journal of Economic

Theory 13(3), 341-360.

Sharpe, William F., 1964, Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions

of risk, Journal of Finance 19, 425-442.

Shleifer, Andrei, 2000, Inefficient markets: and introduction to behavioral finance (Oxford

University Press, New York).

Shleifer, Andrei, and Vishny, Robert W., 1997, The limits of arbitrage, The Journal of Finance

52(1), 35-55.

Simon, Jeffrey D., 1982, Political risk assessment: past trends and future prospects, Columbia

Journal of World Business Fall 17(3), 62-70.

Solnik, Bruno H., 1974, The international pricing of risk: an empirical investigation of the world

capital market structure, The Journal of Finance 29(2), 365-378.

(36)

Page | 35

Appendix

Appendix A: List of countries and indices

Country Index Code N

Argentina ARGENTINA MERVAL ARGMERV(PI) 16

Australia S&P/ASX 300 ASX300I(PI) 16

Austria ATX - AUSTRIAN TRADED INDEX ATXINDX(PI) 16

Belgium BEL 20 BGBEL20(PI) 16

Brazil MSCI BRAZIL MSBRAZL(PI) 16

Bulgaria BULGARIA SE SOFIX BSSOFIX(PI) 8

Canada S&P/TSX 60 INDEX TTOSP60(PI) 16

Chile CHILE SANTIAGO SE GENERAL (IGPA) IGPAGEN(PI) 16

China SHANGHAI SE A SHARE CHSASHR(PI) 16

Colombia MSCI COLOMBIA MSCOLML(PI) 15

Croatia CROATIA CROBEX CTCROBE(PI) 11

Czech PRAGUE SE PX CZPXIDX(PI) 14

Denmark OMX COPENHAGEN (OMXC20) DKKFXIN(PI) 16

Estonia OMX TALLINN (OMXT) ESTALSE(PI) 12

Finland OMX HELSINKI (OMXH) HEXINDX(PI) 16

France FRANCE CAC 40 FRCAC40(PI) 16

Germany DAX 30 PERFORMANCE DAXINDX(PI) 16

Greece ATHEX COMPOSITE GRAGENL(PI) 16

Hong Kong HANG SENG HNGKNGI(PI) 16

Hungary BUDAPEST (BUX) BUXINDX(PI) 16

Iceland OMX ICELAND ALL SHARE ICEXALL(PI) 15

India INDIA BSE (100) NATIONAL IBOMBSE(PI) 16

Indonesia MSCI INDONESIA MSINDFL(PI) 16

Ireland IRELAND SE OVERALL (ISEQ) ISEQUIT(PI) 16

Israel ISRAEL TA 100 ISTA100(PI) 16

Italy MSCI ITALY MSITALL(PI) 16

Japan TOPIX TOKYOSE(PI) 16

Korea KOREA SE KOSPI 200 KOR200I(PI) 16

Latvia NOMURA LATVIA NMLATVL(PI) 12

Luxembourg LUXEMBOURG SE GENERAL LUXGENI(PI) 9

Malaysia FTSE BURSA MALAYSIA KLCI FBMKLCI(PI) 16

Malta MALTA SE MSE MALTAIX(PI) 12

Mexico MEXICO IPC (BOLSA) MXIPC35(PI) 16

(37)

Page | 36

Appendix A: List of countries and indices (Continued)

Country Index Code N

New Zealand MSCI NEW ZEALAND MSNZEAL(PI) 16

Norway MSCI NORWAY MSNWAYL(PI) 16

Peru LIMA SE GENERAL(IGBL) PEGENRL(PI) 16

Philippine PHILIPPINE SE I(PSEi) PSECOMP(PI) 16

Poland MSCI POLAND MSPLNDL(PI) 15

Portugal PORTUGAL PSI-20 POPSI20(PI) 15

Romania ROMANIA BET (L) RMBETRL(PI) 11

Russia RUSSIA RTS INDEX RSRTSIN(PI) 13

Singapore MSCI SINGAPORE MSSINGL(PI) 16

Slovakia SLOVAKIA SAX 16 SXSAX16(PI) 15

South Africa MSCI SOUTH AFRICA MSSARFL(PI) 15

Spain IBEX 35 IBEX35I(PI) 16

Sweden OMX STOCKHOLM 30 (OMXS30) SWEDOMX(PI) 16

Switzerland SWISS MARKET (SMI) SWISSMI(PI) 16

Taiwan TAIWAN SE WEIGHED TAIEX TAIWGHT(PI) 16

Thailand BANGKOK S.E.T. BNGKSET(PI) 16

Turkey ISTANBUL SE NATIONAL 100 TRKISTB(PI) 16

UK FTSE 100 FTSE100(PI) 16

USA NASDAQ 100 NASA100(PI) 16

Venezuela VENEZUELA SE GENERAL VENGENL(PI) 15

World MSCI WORLD U$ MSWRLD$(PI) 16

World DJGL WORLD $ DJWRLD$(PI) 16

The table reports a summary of countries included in the research with their corresponding indices. Code of index refers to the code employed by Thomson Datastream database. As can be seen, one of the most important emerging markets, Russian Federation, has 13 years of observation for index return. RTS was introduced as early as in 1995. Likewise, most of formal Soviet countries or countries in formal Warsaw pact developed equity indices during late 90’ or beginning of the 21th

(38)

Page | 37

Appendix B: The number of representatives of Euro Area countries in the European Parliament and their share in political influence Euro Area Members Representatives Share of Representatives

Austria 19 3.96% Belgium 21 4.38% Cyprus 6 1.25% Estonia 6 1.25% Finland 13 2.71% France 74 15.42% Germany 99 20.63% Greece 22 4.58% Ireland 12 2.50% Italy 73 15.21% Luxembourg 6 1.25% Malta 6 1.25% Netherlands 26 5.42% Portugal 22 4.58% Slovakia 13 2.71% Slovenia 8 1.67% Spain 54 11.25% Total 480 100.00%

Appendix C: World Index composition

Sector Weights Regional Weights

MSCI DJGL MSCI DJGL

Financials 20.53% 22.06% USA 52.54% 44.48%

Information Technology 11.57% 9.41% UK 9.52% 7.99%

Consumer Discretionary 11.23% 10.23% Japan 8.43% 8.29%

Industrials 10.95% 12.80% Canada 4.73% 4.25%

Health Care 10.71% 8.73% France 4.11% 3.33%

Consumer Staples 10.64% 12.56% Other 20.67% 31.66%

Energy 10.41% 9.83%

Materials 6.79% 7.05%

Telecommunication Services 3.79% 3.79%

Utilities 3.38% 3.55%

(39)

Page | 38

Appendix D.1: Unrestricted pooled OLS

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6

IPR 1.283 2.884*** 1.392 3.048*** (0.784) (0.848) (0.768) (0.829) IPR2 133.1*** 138.0*** (28.86) (28.30) MSCI World 1.023*** 1.009*** 1.014*** (0.0466) (0.0473) (0.0467) DJGL World 1.041*** 1.026*** 1.033*** (0.0452) (0.0459) (0.0452) Outliers -0.0795 -0.0813 -0.0790 -0.0580 -0.0600 -0.0573 (0.0936) (0.0935) (0.0923) (0.0920) (0.0919) (0.0905) Domestic PR -0.592* -0.716* -0.706* -0.588* -0.723* -0.712* (0.282) (0.292) (0.288) (0.277) (0.286) (0.282) Intercept 0.0446*** 0.0470*** 0.0226 0.0435*** 0.0460*** 0.0207 (0.0106) (0.0107) (0.0118) (0.0104) (0.0105) (0.0116) R2 0.392 0.394 0.410 0.413 0.416 0.433 Adj R2 0.389 0.391 0.406 0.411 0.413 0.430 Heteroscedasticity 0.165 0.170 0.705 0.070 0.085 0.999 Autocorrelation 0.086 0.096 0.117 0.085 0.094 0.113 Note 1: N=777

Note 2: Standard errors in parentheses Note 3: * p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001

Note 4: Heteroscedasticity is tested using Breusch-Pegan / Cook-Weisberg test. The values are the P-values of the test with null hypothesis being that the variance of the error term is constant.

Note 5: The value of autocorrelation is measured as correlation between the disturbance term and its one year lagged values.

Appendix D.2: Summary Variance Inflation Factor per regression model

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6

IPR 1.11 1.33 1.10 1.33 IPR2 1.23 1.23 MSCI World 1.01 1.05 1.05 DJGL World 1.01 1.04 1.05 Outliers 1.01 1.01 1.01 1.01 1.01 1.01 Domestic PR 1.00 1.07 1.07 1.00 1.07 1.07 Mean 1.01 1.06 1.14 1.01 1.06 1.14

Note: A VIF value above 10 indicates presence of multicollinearity; however the outcome of

(40)

Page | 39

Appendix D.3: Correlation coefficients of regression disturbance with theirs one year lagged value per country for Model 3

Country Correlation N Country Correlation N

Argentina 0.109 14 Korea -0.087 14 Australia 0.455 14 Latvia 0.080 11 Austria 0.584 14 Luxembourg 0.209 8 Belgium -0.058 14 Malaysia 0.199 14 Brazil -0.550 14 Malta -0.045 11 Bulgaria 0.034 7 Mexico -0.176 14 Canada -0.110 14 Netherlands 0.326 14

Chile 0.240 14 New Zealand 0.489 14

China 0.072 14 Norway 0.014 14 Colombia 0.099 14 Peru 0.289 14 Croatia 0.130 10 Philippine 0.145 14 Czech 0.599 13 Poland 0.187 14 Denmark -0.196 14 Portugal 0.134 14 Estonia 0.090 11 Romania 0.250 10 Finland 0.325 14 Russia -0.094 12 France 0.470 14 Singapore 0.069 14 Germany 0.220 14 Slovakia 0.265 14

Greece 0.085 14 South Africa 0.411 14

Hong Kong 0.019 14 Spain 0.202 14

Hungary -0.022 14 Sweden 0.073 14 Iceland 0.276 14 Switzerland -0.408 14 India 0.183 14 Taiwan -0.415 14 Indonesia 0.238 14 Thailand 0.559 14 Ireland 0.175 14 Turkey -0.441 14 Israel -0.261 14 UK -0.249 14 Italy -0.341 14 USA 0.389 14 Japan -0.025 14 Venezuela -0.159 14

Note: Although the total correlation coefficient signifies absence of autocorrelation with the

(41)

Page | 40

Appendix D.4: Correlation coefficients of regression disturbance with theirs one year lagged value per year for Model 3

Year Correlation N Year Correlation N

1995 -0.206 45 2002 0.349 54 1996 0.400 46 2003 0.434 54 1997 0.409 47 2004 0.375 54 1998 -0.067 50 2005 0.459 54 1999 0.108 52 2006 -0.338 54 2000 -0.140 52 2007 0.486 54 2001 0.029 53 2008 -0.218 54

Note: The correlation of the indices seem to follow a specific pattern which is not described by

IPR or world equity benchmark. Typically, in the booming periods, the indices move together. During the dot com crisis, the markets did not behave as much similar as during the crisis of 2006 - 2007.

Appendix D.5: Scatterplot of disturbance term of Model 3 across time

(42)

Page | 41

Appendix E: Definitions of the regional dummy variables

Region Countries in region

Asia China, Hong Kong, India, Indonesia, Japan, Korea, Malaysia, Philippine, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand Europe Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, Croatia, Czech Republic,

Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Latvia,

Luxembourg, Malta, Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Russia, Slovakia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, UK

Latin America Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Peru North America Canada, Mexico, USA

Oceania Australia, New Zealand

(43)

Page | 42

Appendix F: Robust OLS regression with regional and income dummy variables

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6

IPR 1.203 2.689* 1.325 2.868* (1.095) (1.320) (1.078) (1.301) IPR2 122.3*** 127.3*** (36.07) (35.92) MSCI World 1.028*** 1.014*** 1.019*** (0.0518) (0.0514) (0.0512) DJGL World 1.043*** 1.029*** 1.036*** (0.0499) (0.0490) (0.0492) Outliers -0.134 -0.135 -0.133 -0.111 -0.113 -0.110 (0.445) (0.440) (0.432) (0.440) (0.435) (0.426) Domestic PR -0.579 -0.694* -0.688* -0.575* -0.702* -0.695* (0.301) (0.347) (0.332) (0.291) (0.337) (0.322) Asia -0.0902** -0.0895** -0.0747* -0.0900** -0.0892** -0.0738* (0.0290) (0.0295) (0.0310) (0.0283) (0.0288) (0.0304) Europe -0.00508 -0.00750 0.0123 -0.00696 -0.00960 0.0110 (0.0259) (0.0267) (0.0271) (0.0257) (0.0265) (0.0270) Latin America 0.0350 0.0356 0.0392 0.0355 0.0362 0.0399 (0.0527) (0.0528) (0.0518) (0.0518) (0.0518) (0.0509) Oceania -0.0482 -0.0475 -0.0312 -0.0492 -0.0484 -0.0314 (0.0326) (0.0325) (0.0352) (0.0320) (0.0320) (0.0347) High Income -0.0695** -0.0694** -0.0661** -0.0676** -0.0675** -0.0639** (0.0241) (0.0241) (0.0242) (0.0237) (0.0237) (0.0237) Intercept 0.104*** 0.107*** 0.0682* 0.103*** 0.106*** 0.0655* (0.0244) (0.0244) (0.0279) (0.0240) (0.0241) (0.0275) R2 0.421 0.423 0.436 0.441 0.443 0.458 Adj R2 0.415 0.416 0.428 0.435 0.437 0.450 Regional Test 0.001 0.002 0.003 0.001 0.002 0.002 Income Test 0.004 0.004 0.006 0.004 0.005 0.007 Note 1: N=765

Note 2: Standard errors in parentheses Note 3: * p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001

Note 4: Regional test is the joint coefficient test of Asia, Europe, Latin America and Oceania equaling zero.

(44)

Page | 43

Appendix G.1: GLS panel data regression with control for ARCH effect, Durbin Watson d-statistic and Fixed Effects

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6

IPR 0.585 2.828** 0.567 2.781**

(0.789) (0.932) (0.773) (0.911)

IPR2 126.5*** 127.0***

(29.89) (29.25)

Risk Premium MSCI 1.022*** 1.017*** 1.025*** (0.0453) (0.0460) (0.0457) Risk Premium DJGL 1.028*** 1.023*** 1.030*** (0.0435) (0.0441) (0.0438) Outliers -0.540*** -0.534*** -0.506*** -0.517*** -0.512*** -0.487*** (0.0954) (0.0955) (0.0945) (0.0936) (0.0937) (0.0925) Domestic PR -0.271 -0.321 -0.286 -0.284 -0.334 -0.300 (0.286) (0.295) (0.293) (0.280) (0.289) (0.286) Intercept 0.0465*** 0.0480*** 0.0316** 0.0457*** 0.0472*** 0.0307** (0.0102) (0.0104) (0.0108) (0.0100) (0.0102) (0.0106) R2 Within 0.466 0.465 0.477 0.487 0.487 0.499 R2 Between 0.197 0.196 0.111 0.205 0.205 0.110 R2 Overall 0.440 0.440 0.449 0.463 0.463 0.473 Note 1: N=723

Note 2: Standard errors in parentheses Note 3: * p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001

Appendix G.2: P-values of hypotheses tests

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6

IPR 0.459 0.002 0.463 0.002

IPR2 0.000 0.000

Risk Premium MSCI 0.627 0.709 0.583

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

The approach we take in designing POINTER and LOITER, our serious games for interpersonal skills training in the domain of law enforcement, expands the possibilities of

In this study of 203 Dutch workers, a cross-sectional online survey is used to demonstrate that high task interdependency and a preference for segmenting the ‘work’ and

The fact that mezzanine companies show roughly the similar risk and return pattern as do direct private equity companies, is not in line with intuition that would suggest

Thus, while the future expectations of neo-Nazis resemble that of the Nazi Party, present day reality prevents this from taking place; this tension means that both theories

Table 2 gives a more in depth analysis of table 1, it states the average assets, market capitalization, leverage and return per country, based on the averages of those values per

Thus, the results suggest that the public health expenditure, as a % of total health expenditure and as a % of GDP, provide an explanation of the healthcare premium

Since a negative linear relationship is expected in hypothesis 2a, it is also expected that risk-adjusted excess returns in times of high expected volatility are lower than

Based on their analysis, four dimensions are tested, which are the time that a customer can return the product, the monetary costs with regard to the return for the customer,