• No results found

Balancing the EMU : the imbalances created by the euro : how could the implementation of Eurobonds contribute to the stabilization of the EMU?

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Balancing the EMU : the imbalances created by the euro : how could the implementation of Eurobonds contribute to the stabilization of the EMU?"

Copied!
42
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

 

 

 

UNIVERSITY  OF  AMSTERDAM  

Balancing  the  EMU  

The  imbalances  created  by  the  euro:  ‘How  could  the  implementation  of  Eurobonds  

contribute  to  the  stabilization  of  the  EMU?’

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Eveline  van  ’t  Spijker  

10400982  

BSc  Economics  and  Business  

Supervisor:  Dr.  C.G.F.  van  der  Kwaak  

04-­‐07-­‐2015  

 

(2)

Balancing  the  EMU  

 

Abstract  

The  purpose  of  this  paper  is  to  provide  insights  in  the  underlying  risk  factors  of  the  EMU  that   eventually  led  to  the  European  Sovereign  debt  crisis,  and  how  its  economic  consequences  incited   the  debate  about  how  Eurobonds  could  play  a  role  in  the  stabilization  of  the  monetary  union.  It   describes  that  neither  the  ESM  nor  the  unconventional  policy  measures  of  the  ECB  provided  the   long-­‐term  solution  to  the  European  debt  crisis.  This  paper  suggests  that  the  analysed  Eurobond   proposals   provide   some   aspects,   such   as   improved   liquidity,   reduced   contagion   between   the   EMU   countries,   and   the   elimination   of   the   feedback   loop   between   banks   and   sovereigns   that   could  contribute  to  the  stabilization  of  the  EMU.  However  Eurobonds  do  not  provide  an  answer   to  the  structural  problems  of  unsustainable  government  debts  and  low  competitiveness.    

Keywords:  Eurobonds,  European  sovereign  debt  crisis,  Economic  Monetary  Union.    

-­‐Eveline  van  ‘t  Spijker  

 

Statement  of  Originality  

This   document   is   written   by   Student   Eveline   van   ’t   Spijker   who   declares   to   take   full   responsibility  for  the  contents  of  this  document.  I  declare  that  the  text  and  the  work  presented   in  this  document  is  original  and  that  no  sources  other  than  those  mentioned  in  the  text  and  its   references  have  been  used  in  creating  it.  The  Faculty  of  Economics  and  Business  is  responsible   solely  for  the  supervision  of  completion  of  the  work,  not  for  the  contents.    

 

Table  of  contents    

 

Introduction                       3  

1.  The  prior  crisis  phase                   5  

1.1  The  developments  towards  a  single  currency             5  

  1.1.1  The  Maastricht  Treaty  and  the  Stability  and  Growth  Pact       5  

  1.1.2  Convergence  in  the  EMU-­‐area               6  

1.2  The  flaws  in  the  design  of  the  Economic  Monetary  Union           10  

  1.2.1  The  Optimal  Currency  Area               10  

  1.2.2  The  weaknesses  of  the  Stability  and  Growth  Pact           11  

2

.  The  European  Sovereign  Debt  Crisis  

 

 

 

 

 

 

13  

2.1  Start  of  the  Global  Financial  Crisis                 13  

(3)

2.2.1  Deterioration  in  government  accounts,  banks             14                    balance  sheets  and  Target  balances  

  2.2.2  Determinants  of  interest  rate  differentials  in  EMU         16  

2.3  Policy  responses  to  the  European  debt  crisis             17  

  2.3.1  The  EFSF  and  ESM                 17  

  2.3.2  The  SMP,  LTRO  and  OMT                 17  

  2.3.3  The  Fiscal  Compact                 19  

3.  Eurobonds

   

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

19  

3.1  Introduction  to  Eurobonds                 20  

  3.12  Arguments  in  favour  of  Eurobonds             20  

  3.1.3  Arguments  against  Eurobonds               21  

3.2  Eurobond  Proposals                   22  

  3.4.1  The  Blue-­‐red  bond                 22

  3.4.2  The  Euro  T-­‐bills                   23  

3.4.3  European  investment  bank               25  

  3.4.4  European  Safe  Bonds  (ESBies)               26  

3.4.5  Euro-­‐insurance  bonds                 28  

3.5  Implementing  Eurobonds                   29  

  3.5.1  Political  resistance                 29  

  3.5.2  Legal  barriers                   30  

  3.5.3  Practical  matters  and  criticism  on  the  proposals           31  

4.  Risk  premium  on  Eurobonds                 33  

4.1  The  model                       33   4.2  Results                       34   5.  Conclusion

   

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

36   Appendix  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

38   Reference  list

   

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

39  

 

List  of  figures  and  tables  

Figure  1.  10  year  government  bond  spreads  EMU-­‐countries  to  German  Bunds        7  

Figure  2.  Government  Debt  in  1997  and  2013                8  

Table      1.  Current  Account  Balances                  9  

Figure  3.  Real  effective  Exchange  Rate  (unit  labour  costs)             10   Table      2.  Violations  of  fiscal  rules                   13  

Figure  4.  Target  Balances  in  the  EMU                 16  

(4)

Figure  6.  Country  Weights  for  EIB  and  ESBies               27   Table      3.  Overview  and  common  factors  of  Eurobonds             29  

Table      4.  Overview  of  Eurobond  features                 31  

Figure  7.  Risk  premium  on  Eurobonds  in  percentage  points  (2001-­‐2014)         35   Table      5.  Borrowing  costs  for  EMU-­‐countries  (2001-­‐2014)             36  

 

 

Introduction  

   

The  burst  of  the  housing  bubble  in  the  USA  in  2007  triggered  a  subprime  mortgage  crisis  that   became  a  global  crisis  due  to  the  interdependence  of  the  banking  system  and  the  contagion  of   the   financial   system.   During   2008   and   2009   the   financial   markets   remained   relatively   calm   in   Europe.  Only  at  the  end  of  2009  the  global  crisis  spread  to  the  eurozone  causing  the  European   Sovereign   Debt   crisis.   The   shock   of   the   financial   crisis   hit   the   euro   countries   asymmetrically.   Especially  the  countries  that  had  established  weak  fiscal  positions  and  current  account  deficits   in  the  years  before  2007  faced  liquidity  problems  when  the  international  money  markets  dried   up.   The   yields   on   the   southern   European   government   bonds   rose   rapidly   because   investors   recognized   the   liquidity   problem   that   later   became   a   solvency   problem,   especially   for   Greece.   Many  European  banks  had  a  great  exposure  to  governments  bonds  leading  to  a  more  aggravate  

problem.                      

  When  entering  the  Economic  Monetary  Union  (EMU),  most  of  the  member  states  did  not   satisfy  the  criteria  of  the  Maastricht  Treaty.  With  the  introduction  of  the  euro,  the  government   spreads   against   the   German   bund   fell   to   almost   zero   leading   to   an   increase   in   borrowing   by   households   and   governments   in   the   southern   EMU   countries.   The   low   interest   rates   further   triggered   capital   flows   from   northern   Europe   to   Southern   Europe   leading   to   current   account  

imbalances  in  the  EMU.                  

  In   the   aftermath   of   the   Global   financial   crisis,   policymakers   responded   with   several   measures  to  tackle  the  liquidity  problems  and  dramatic  increase  in  the  government  spreads  over   the  German  bunds  in  the  periphery  countries.  Several  funds  as  the  EFSF  and  later  on  the  ESM   were  established.  The  ECB  conducted  its  monetary  policy  using  unconventional  tools  and  open   market   operations   by   the   means   of   the   SMP   and   OMT   programmes.   Although   these   measures   could  partially  solve  the  problems  in  the  short  run,  there  is  still  not  a  real  long-­‐term  solution  to  

safeguard  the  future  of  the  euro.                

   This  thesis  studies  how  Eurobonds  might  be  able  to  fulfil  this  function.  On  the  one  side,   Eurobonds  can  increase  liquidity  and  reduce  the  debt  servicing  costs  of  the  weaker  countries;  on   the  other  side  it  increases  moral  hazard,  fiscal  indiscipline  and  the  borrowing  costs  for  the  core  

(5)

economies.  The  research  question  will  therefore  be:  ‘How  could  the  implementation  of  Eurobonds   contribute  to  the  stabilization  of  the  EMU,  is  it  enough  or  would  more  be  needed?’  

  To   be   able   to   answer   this   research   question,   we   will   discuss   the   Eurobond   concept,   analyse   several   proposals   in   literature   of   implementing   Eurobonds   and   discuss   the   potential   advantages  and  disadvantages.  The  thesis  is  structured  in  the  following  way.  The  first  section  of   the   thesis   will   discuss   the   institutional   set-­‐up   of   the   Economic   and   Monetary   Union   from   the   Maastricht   Treaty   towards   the   Euro,   the   development   of   the   underlying   pre-­‐crisis   risk   factors   and   the   flaws   in   the   design   of   the   EMU.   The   next   section   covers   the   beginning   of   the   global   financial  crisis  with  the  burst  of  the  housing  bubble  and  the  run  up  to  the  European  sovereign   debt   crisis.   In   addition,   this   section   considers   the   policy   measures   and   the   unconventional   measures   taken   by   the   ECB   to   address   the   problems   in   the   euro   area.   Furthermore,   section   3   contains  the  discussion  of  the  different  aspects  of  Eurobonds,  several  Eurobond  proposals  and   what   should   be   taken   into   account   before   implementing   Eurobonds.   In   section   4,   the   actual   borrowing   costs   of   11   EMU   countries   are   compared   to   the   costs   when   we   would   have   had   Eurobonds   from   the   start   of   the   euro.   The   calculations   will   be   based   on   Boonstra   ‘s   (2012)   model  for  the  risk  premium  on  Eurobonds.  With  the  information  of  those  four  sections,  we  will   in   section   5   conclude   whether   Eurobonds   could   help   in   balancing   the   EMU   and   reducing   the   problems  created  by  the  euro  and  the  European  debt  crisis.  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(6)

1.  The  prior  crisis  phase  

 

This  section  discusses  the  possible  causes  of  the  Sovereign  debt  crisis  that  were  created  by  the   institutional  design  of  the  EMU.  It  examines  how  the  Maastricht  treaty  and  Stability  Pact  were   brought   into   practice,   in   how   far   there   was   convergence   between   the   countries   in   the   run-­‐up   towards  the  euro,  and  how  imbalances  had  the  chance  to  grow  over  the  years.  In  this  section  we   will   also   apply   the   Optimum   Currency   Area   (OCA)   theory   to   the   EMU   by   analysing   how   asymmetric  shocks  could  be  absorbed  in  a  monetary  union.    

 

1.1 The  developments  towards  a  single  currency  

 

 

1.1.1  The  Maastricht  Treaty  and  Stability  and  Growth  Pact  

To  secure  a  sound  monetary  union  and  to  converge  and  coordinate  the  participating  economies,   in  1992  the  Maastricht  Treaty  took  effect.  With  the  Maastricht  Treaty,  the  EU  members  agreed  to   introduce  the  euro  upon  several  convergence  criteria  that  must  be  fulfilled  for  membership  to   the  currency  union.  The  convergence  criteria  emphasize  the  need  for  price  stability,  sustainable   fiscal  situations,  the  stability  of  the  exchange  rate  and  low  interest  rates.  In  total,  the  Maastricht   Treaty  outlines  four  criteria:  1)  to  secure  price  stability,  the  average  inflation  rate  could  not  be   higher  than  1.5  percentage  points  compared  to  the  three  best  performing  members;  2)  The  fiscal   convergence  criterion  requires  that  the  EMU-­‐countries’  net  deficit  cannot  exceed  3  per  cent  of  its   GDP.   Moreover,   the   government   debt   must   not   exceed   60   per   cent   of   the   country’s   GDP   (De   Haan,   Gilbert,   Hessel   &   Verkaart   2013);   3)   The   currency   of   the   member   states   could   only   fluctuate   ‘normally’   within   in   the   defined   margins   of   the   Exchange   Rate   Mechanism   (ERM)   to   ensure   exchange   rate   stability;   4)   The   last   criterion   regarding   the   interest   rates   states   that   countries’  average  long-­‐term  interest  rate  could  not  exceed  the  rate  of  the  three  best  performing   member  states  by  more  than  2  percentage  points  (Eijffinger  &  De  Haan  2000).    

  In   1997   the   Stability   and   Growth   Pact   (SGP)   came   into   force   to   strengthen   the   surveillance  of  the  fiscal  positions  and  rules  –  the  preventive  arm,  and  to  outline  the  details  of   the   excessive   deficit   procedure   –   the   corrective   arm   (Buti,   Franco   &   Ongena   1998).   When   the   deficits  and  government  debt  ratios  do  not  satisfy  the  convergence  criteria,  a  country  enters  the   excessive  deficit  procedure  (EDP)  and  is  obliged  to  correct  for  the  fiscal  situation.  When  a  state   does  not  comply  with  the  correction,  the  European  Council  can  impose  sanctions  such  as  non-­‐ interest   bearing   deposits   that   amount   0.2%   of   GDP   and   must   be   placed   within   the   European   Commission  (EC).  When  the  member  state  made  not  enough  effort  to  adjust  its  excessive  deficit,   the  deposit  will  be  converted  into  a  fine  (Regulation  EU  No  1173/2011).  There  could  be  made  an   exception  to  the  EDP  when  the  ratios  have  declined  significantly  towards  the  target  ratio  or  a  

(7)

country  is  hit  by  a  severe  economic  downturn  (De  Haan  et  al.  2013).  Besides  the  EDP  the  pact   contains  a  no-­‐bail  out  clause.  When  forming  a  monetary  union,  there  arises  a  free-­‐rider  problem.   Countries  might  have  the  incentive  to  borrow  substantially  since  they  know  they  are  likely  to  be   bailed   out   by   other   countries   that   fear   contagion   to   the   rest   of   the   union,   due   to   the   interdependence   of   the   financial   system   and   the   issuance   of   debt   in   the   same   currency.   So   to   ensure  the  credibility  of  the  monetary  union,  and  to  cope  with  the  potential  free-­‐rider  problem,   the   pact   includes   a   no-­‐bail   out   clause,   meaning   that   a   sovereign   default   takes   place   when   a   member   does   not   hold   on   to   the   fiscal   rules   (Lane   2012).   This   rule   was   to   ensure   the   risk   premiums  would  price  in  the  sovereign  risk  (De  Grauwe  2012b).  

 

1.1.2  Convergence  in  the  EMU-­‐area    

As  becomes  clear  from  the  graph  in  figure  1,  in  the  period  prior  to  the  introduction  of  the  euro,   the  government  spreads  over  the  German  bunds  of  countries  like  Greece,  Ireland,  Italy,  Portugal   and  Spain  (GIIPS)  were  high  but  decreasing  from  significant  values.  De  Grauwe  (2012b)  argues   that  this  is  due  to  the  decline  in  devaluation  risk  when  approaching  the  introduction  of  the  euro,   which  has  previously  been  a  major  source  of  the  risk  premium.  In  addition,  Hans-­‐Werner  Sinn   (1997)  argues  that  the  spread  on  the  left-­‐hand  side  of  the  graph  was  also  due  to  inflation  risk.     Before  the  introduction  of  the  euro,  the  national  central  banks  (NCB)  had  autonomous  monetary   policy,   meaning   they   could   print   money,   causing   inflation   and   a   devaluation   of   their   currency.   With  the  euro,  printing  money  by  one  NCB  was  cancelled  out  by  the  reduction  in  money  by  other   NCBs.  When  a  NCB  creates  seigniorage  wealth  it  has  to  place  equity  in  the  ECB,  to  distribute  the   profits   among   the   other   member   states   based   on   equity   shares   (Sinn   &   Feist   1997).     Additionally,   the   anti-­‐inflationary   policy   of   the   ECB   also   eliminated   the   fear   of   inflation   (Feldstein  2011).  In  2001,  when  the  devaluation  risk  was  entirely  eliminated,  the  spreads  were   almost  zero.  The  EMU  established  a  common  market  for  government  bonds.  The  fixed-­‐income   government  securities  denominated  in  the  same  currency  were  seen  as  substitutes,  although  not   perfect  substitutes  (Favero,  Ambrogio  &  Missale  2012).      

(8)

Figure  1.    10-­‐year  government  bond  spreads  EMU-­‐countries  to  German  Bunds  

Source:  Fred  Economic  Data.  St.  Louis  FED  (Long-­‐Term  Government  Bond  Yields:  10  year).  

   

While  the  EMU  countries  had  reduced  their  fiscal  budgets  in  the  convergence  phase  before  the   launching  of  the  euro,  most  of  the  countries  did  not  meet  the  planned  goal  of  60  per  cent  debt  to   GDP   from   the   Maastricht   Criteria   (De   Haan   et   al   2013).   It   appears   from   figure   2   and   Sinn   (2014b)   that   only   about   five   of   the   eleven   participating   countries   met   the   criteria   in   1997.   However,  all  countries  that  exceeded  the  60  per  cent  limit  could  join  the  euro  since  their  deficit   was  moving  towards  the  3  per  cent  requirement.  In  2002,  with  the  introduction  of  the  euro  bills   and   coins,   Greece   had   a   debt/GDP   ratio   of   101.7   per   cent   and   Italy   a   ratio   of   105.7   per   cent   (Eurostat).   Despite   the   structural   economic   differences   in   the   euro   countries,   the   financial   markets  did  not  anticipate  a  default  risk  for  almost  10  years,  leading  to  lower  interest  rates  on   the   government   debts   (De   Grauwe   2012b).   In   countries   such   as   Greece   and   Portugal,   the   governments   used   the   low   interest   rates   to   increase   their   borrowing.   Those   countries   did   not   use  the  advantage  of  lower  debt  servicing  cost  to  repay  more  debt;  instead  a  major  motivation  to   join  the  currency  union  was  to  get  access  to  lower  interest  rate  on  their  sovereign  debt.  In  Spain   and  Ireland  there  was  no  such  excessive  public  borrowing  when  joining  the  euro  (Sinn  2014b).               0   5   10   15   20   25   Greece   France   Portugal   Spain   Ireland   Italy   Netherlands   France   Finland   Austria  

(9)

Figure  2.  Government  Debt  in  1997  and  2013  

Source:  IMF  database,  World  economic  outlook  (general  government  debt).  

 

In  addition,  in  most  of  the  periphery  countries,  a  private  credit  boom  occurred.  With  the  cheap   credit,   Greece   and   Portugal   increased   the   wages   and   hired   more   workers   in   the   public   sector,   however  it  did  not  lead  to  productivity  gains.  In  Ireland  and  Spain  the  cheap  credit  was  used  in   the   construction   sector   and   to   buy   real   estate.   In   Spain   for   example,   the   banks   became   more   relaxed   in   terms   of   providing   loans.   The   banks   required   less   collateral   and   financed   bigger   proportions   of   the   property   prices   than   would   be   common   in   for   instance   Germany   (Sinn   2014b).  Hence,  the  boom  drove  up  wages,  goods  prices  and  property  prices  (Sinn  2014a).  

At  the  introduction  of  the  Euro,  there  was  a  common  thought  about  the  economic  growth   and  prosperity  the  single  currency  would  stimulate.  The  southern  countries  could  get  access  to   cheap   credit,   leading   to   capital   flows   from   the   core   member   states   to   the   periphery   countries   (Sinn   2014b).   This   transfer   was   largely   funded   by   private   savings   from   the   northern   to   the   southern  states  leading  to  current  account  deficits  of  the  latter.  In  fact,  the  current  account  is  the   difference   between   domestic   saving   and   investment   (Sinn   2012).   Lane   (2012)   and   Feldstein   (2011)  also  address  the  variances  in  the  current  account  and  trade  imbalances  among  the  euro   members.  As  can  be  seen  in  table  1,  in  countries  such  as  Greece,  Portugal  and  Spain,  the  current   account  deficits  increased  strongly  since  the  introduction  of  the  euro.  Saving  fell  in  the  southern   countries   while   investment   increased.   In   the   contrary,   Germany   established   a   current   account   surplus.    

 

      63   123   53   59   59   97   63   117   7   68   54   66   74   101   58   93   80   176   123   132   23   74   124   94   0   20   40   60   80   100   120   140   160   180   200   P er ce n ta ge  o f  G D P   1997   2013  

(10)

Table  1.  Current  Account  Balances   (Percent  of  GDP)   1993-­‐1997   1997-­‐2002   2003-­‐2007   2008-­‐2011   France   1.1   2.0   -­‐0.2   -­‐1.5   6.1   -­‐11.5   Germany   -­‐0.9   -­‐0.4   5.1   Greece   -­‐2.4   -­‐6.3   -­‐9.2   Ireland   3.6   -­‐0.2   -­‐2.8   -­‐1.4   Italy   2.1   0.5   -­‐1.0   -­‐2.9   Portugal   -­‐2.4   -­‐9.0   -­‐9.2   -­‐10.3   Spain   -­‐0.6   -­‐3.1   -­‐7.0   -­‐5.7  

Source:  IMF  database,  World  Economy  Outlook  (Current  Account  Balances).    

However,  the  capital  transfers  from  the  northern  states  towards  the  periphery  countries  did  not   fuel  the  productivity  growth  of  tradables  but  rather  those  of  non-­‐tradables  such  as  real  estate.   This  poses  risk  to  the  countries  running  a  current  account  deficit,  since  this  indirectly  drives  up   the  wages  and  constrains  resources  from  sectors  that  have  possible  productivity  growth  (Lane   2012).  Since  the  introduction  of  the  euro,  the  real  effective  exchange  rates  of  the  GIIPS  countries   in  terms  of  labour  costs  (see  figure  3)  and  consumer  goods  increased  significantly  relative  to  the   other   euro   countries.   The   relative   price   level   of   Greece   increased   by   67   per   cent,   the   Spanish   relative   prices   by   56   per   cent,   followed   by   53   and   47   per   cent   for   respectively   Ireland   and   Portugal   (Sinn   2014a).   This   is   especially   risky   in   the   case   of   a   currency   area.   When   those   periphery  countries  would  not  join  the  EMU,  their  exchange  rates  could  devalue  over  time.  This   adjustment  of  the  exchange  rate  would  lead  in  the  periphery  countries  to  lower  exports  prices   and  higher  import  prices.  In  those  countries,  export  will  start  to  rise  and  imports  will  start  to   fall,   which   improves   the   competitiveness   and   prevents   a   growing   current   account   deficit.   This   adjustment  mechanism  is  absent  in  a  monetary  union  and  must  now  be  achieved  by  cutting  the   real   labour   costs   relative   to   the   rest   of   Europe   (Feldstein   2011).   According   to   calculations   of   Goldman   Sachs,   Greece   would   need   a   painful   price   cut   of   approximately   20   to   30   per   cent,   compared  to  third  quarter  of  2008,  in  order  to  achieve  a  path  of  sustainable  debt  in  the  long  run   and  restore  its  competitiveness  relative  to  the  rest  of  Europe  (Sinn  2015).    

             

(11)

Figure  3.  Real  Effective  Exchange  Rate  (unit  labour  costs)  

  Source:  Fred  Economic  Data.  St.  Louis  FED  (Real  Effective  Exchange  Rate  Based  on  Unit  Labour  Costs).    

The   decline   in   government   spreads   triggered   thus   capital   flows   form   north   to   south   Europe,   leading  to  the  current  account  imbalances.  However,  as  becomes  clear  from  figure  1  and  table  1,   the   government   spreads   over   the   German   bunds   had   already   declined   while   table   1   does   not   show   big   imbalances   in   the   EMU   in   the   period   before   1997.   Sinn   (2014b)   recognizes   the   existence  of  a  timing  problem.  The  investment  boom  in  southern  countries  (e.g.  real  estate)  can   increase  work  opportunities  and  wages,  which  lead  to  an  increase  in  import  in  those  countries.   The  relative  prices  in  the  periphery  countries  increase  when  the  wages  increase  relative  to  north   Europe,   thus   reducing   the   export   to   north   Europe.   However,   the   change   in   relative   prices   and   wages  has  a  time  lag  and  the  reflections  in  the  current  account  balances  are  therefore  delayed.    

1.2  Flaws  in  the  institutional  design  of  the  EMU    

1.1.2  The  Optimal  Currency  Area    

We   have   to   address   the   economic   consequences   when   having   a   single   interest   rate   set   by   the   ECB   and   a   fixed   exchange   rate   in   countries   facing   asymmetric   shocks   and   national   fiscal   tax   systems.  This  can  be  done  by  analysing  the  Optimal  Curency  Area  theory.  The  OCA  theory  was   first   introduced   by   Robert   Mundell   (1961).   ‘The   theory   of   monetary   unions   is   a   trade-­‐off   between   the   reduced   costs   of   trade   and   the   adverse   macroeconomic   effects   of   precluding   interest  rate  and  exchange  rate  variation’  (Mundell  1961).  According  to  Feldstein  (1997),  when   designing   the   EMU   the   policy-­‐makers   were   especially   driven   by   political   motivations   and   the   implementation  of  a  single  currency  and  less  so  by  the  economic  consequences  of  a  monetary   union  or  whether  the  EMU  would  be  an  Optimum  Currency  Area.  The  reason  being  that  at  that  

60,0   65,0   70,0   75,0   80,0   85,0   90,0   95,0   100,0   105,0   110,0   Ind ex 2 0 0 7 = 1 0 0   Greece   Portugal   Italy   France   Ireland   Spain   Italy   Germany  

(12)

time,   the   OCA   theory   was   complex   and   not   yet   fully   developed,   leading   to   doubts   about   its   meaning.  Only  in  the  years  after  1992,  a  debate  arose  about  the  effect  asymmetric  shocks  could   have  on  Europe  and  about  the  issue  whether  the  EMU  would  be  an  OCA  when  having  a  common   currency  or  not.  Feldstein  (1997)  outlines  four  factors  identified  by  Mundell,  that  are  important   in   the   absence   of   flexible   exchange   rates   and   interest   rates:   homogeneity,   wage   and   price   flexibility,   labour   mobility   and   fiscal   transfers.   When   countries   in   a   monetary   union   are   very   different   in   economic   structure   due   to   differences   in   GDP   structure   and   trading   partners,   a   demand  shock  will  have  asymmetric  effects  in  the  union,  which  causes  for  example  inflation  in   one   country   and   unemployment   in   the   other   country.   This   requires   expansionary   monetary   policy  in  the  first  country  and  contractionary  policy  in  the  second,  which  could  not  be  achieved   simultaneously   with   one   monetary   policy   for   the   union   thus   making   homogeneity   between   countries   important   (Mundell   61).   In   the   EMU,   countries   also   have   different   structures.   The   northern  members  have  more  capital  and  skilled  labour  endowments  compared  to  the  southern   countries  (Krugman,  Obstfeld  &  Melitz  2012).          

  Flexible   wages   and   prices   could   also   smooth   the   shocks   when   adjusting   to   a   level   that   maintains  the  full  level  of  employment.  Then  the  absence  of  national  interest  rates  and  exchange   rates  won’t  be  critical,  since  adjusting  those  variables  is  not  necessary  to  restore  employment.   Nevertheless,  it  becomes  clear  from  the  structural  employment  level  in  the  EMU  that  this  is  not   the  case  in  the  Eurozone.  In  the  short  run,  prices  and  wages  are  sticky,  especially  a  downward   stickiness   applies   for   wages   (Krugman   et   al.   2012).   Another   way   that   could   keep   the   level   of   unemployment   unchanged,   is   the   existence   of   labour   mobility.   If   employees   are   prepared   to   move   to   areas   where   there   is   demand   of   labour,   unemployment   could   be   reduced.   Although   there   is   free   movement   of   labour   in   the   EMU,   labour   migration   is   limited.   The   language   and   cultural   barriers   prevent   mostly   the   cross-­‐border   movements.   Also   government   regulations   limit   the   mobility.   Some   European   countries   only   provide   unemployment   benefits   if   the   employees  found  residence,  which  make  it  harder  to  work  elsewhere  (Krugman  et  al.  2012).     Finally,   the   existence   of   fiscal   transfers   could   also   offset   a   negative   demand   shock.   Wyplosz  (2006)  argues  that  in  order  to  attenuate  asymmetric  shocks,  a  fiscal  transfer  from  the   strong  country  to  the  weaker  country  is  needed.  These  automatic  transfers  could  be  assured  by   tax  systems.  Since  the  EMU  has  only  small  fiscal  federalism,  it  does  not  fulfil  this  criterion  very   well.    In  section  2  we  will  see  how  the  shock  of  the  global  financial  crisis  hit  the  EMU  countries,   with  structural  economic  differences,  asymmetrically.    

 

1.2.2  The  weaknesses  of  the  Stability  and  Growth  Pact  

At  first  the  SGP  was  invented  to  ensure  sound  fiscal  balances  and  sustainable  government  debt,   however  it  suffered  from  critics  about  its  weak  enforcement  and  other  flaws,  such  as  the  voting  

(13)

and   decision   making   process   (Irlenbush   &   Sutter   2006).   De   Haan,   Berger   and   Jansen   (2003)   address  the  weak  enforcement  of  the  pact  with  a  distinction  between  soft  law  and  hard  law.  The   first   one   refers   to   general   rules   not   included   in   the   legal   force   but   which   may   have   legal   and   practical  effects.  The  latter  one  refers  to  legal  rules  that  are  binding,  precise  and  assign  authority   to  an  independent  entity  for  interpreting  the  law.  The  preventive  arm  of  the  pact  relies  mostly   on   soft   law.   For   instance   the   ECOFIN   Council   (Economic   and   Financial   affairs   Council)   cannot   automatically   impose   sanctions,   for   the   reason   that   the   council   needs   to   vote   about   the   sanctions.  Moreover,  the  ECOFIN  council  can  never  obtain  control  over  the  government  budgets   since   there   is   fiscal   sovereignty.   The   council   can   only   exercise   pressure   on   the   countries   to  

reduce  their  deficits.                      

  This   pressure   will   be   stronger   in   two   cases.   First,   a   country   will   experience   more   pressure  the  bigger  the  negative  externalities  of  the  excessive  deficits.  Unsustainable  debt  in  one   country   can   push   up   the   interest   rate   in   the   union   because   of   the   anti-­‐inflationary   monetary   policy,  causing  higher  debt  servicing  costs  for  all  the  members  (De  Grauwe  2012b).  However  the   main  refinancing  rate  of  the  ECB  remained  fixed  from  1999  to  2008  (ECB  key  interest  rates).  The   second   factor   that   could   lead   to   pushing   the   weaker   countries   to   tighten   their   budgets   is   the   deterioration   of   its   reputation   by   higher   bond   rates   or   lower   credit   ratings,   however   the   countries   were   not   severely   punished   by   the   financial   markets   and   the   interest   rates   on   the   countries  with  high  debt  burdens  stayed  relatively  low  (De  Haan  et  al.  2003).  The  paper  further   argues   that   the   corrective   arm,   the   EDP,   mainly   relies   on   hard   law.   However,   it   also   suffered   from  weak  enforcement,  for  the  reason  being  that  the  bigger  EMU  countries  felt  less  obliged  to   bring  down  their  deficits  to  the  balanced  budget  than  the  smaller  countries.  The  small  countries   had  an  average  surplus  of  1%  between  1997-­‐2002,  while  the  bigger  countries  had  on  average  a   deficit  of  1.5%.  The  medium-­‐sized  members  were  on  average  in  balance  in  the  same  timeframe.   This   is   related   to   the   fact   that   bigger   countries   are   less   likely   to   loose   their   influence   on   European  policies.  So  both  the  soft  and  the  hard  law  mechanism  didn’t  work  properly.    

  The   second   weakness   of   the   pact,   the   voting   process,   is   described   by   Irlenbush   and   Sutter  (2006).  They  question  the  usefulness  of  the  pact  since  it  has  a  voting  system  that  takes   considerable  time  and  is  very  complex.  They  studied  the  effectiveness  of  the  institutional  set-­‐up   of  the  SGP  in  relation  to  the  sanctions  of  EMU-­‐members  in  the  excessive  deficit  procedure.  Their   results   show   the   existence   of   two   major   shortcomings.   First,   it   becomes   clear   that   the   bigger   countries   can   more   easily   block   sanctions   relative   to   the   smaller   member   states.   The   bigger   economies  have  more  voting  rights  and  according  to  De  Haan  et  al  (2013)  are  less  likely  to  loose   influence   on   EU   decisions.   An   example   of   the   difference   between   the   bigger   and   smaller   countries  is  provided  in  2002.  When  Portugal  in  August  2002,  had  a  deficit  of  4.1%  of  GDP,  the   European   Council   imposed   the   first   excessive   deficit   procedure.  However,  when  Germany   was  

(14)

likely  to  exceed  the  3  per  cent  deficit  rule  in  October  2002,  the  European  Commission  argued  for   a  looser  interpretation,  preventing  Germany  from  entering  the  EDP  (Irlenbush  &  Sutter  2006).   At  the  time  Germany  and  France  exceeded  their  budget  deficit/GDP  ratio  in  2003  and  2004,  they   successfully   blocked   sanctions   that   were   imposed   (Pilbeam   2013).   Second,   the   decision   mechanism   allows   that   countries   in   the   excessive   deficit   procedure   can   also   vote   about   the   sanctions   of   the   other   countries   (Irlenbush   &   Sutter).   The   ECOFIN   council   consists   of   the   ministers  of  economics  and  finance,  including  the  ministers  of  the  countries  that  broke  the  rules   themselves.  The  table  below  illustrates  how  often  the  rules  were  not  obeyed  since  1995.  Since   1995,   not   a   single   time   a   sanction   was   imposed   although   in   97   cases   they   should   have   been   imposed  (Sinn  2014b).    

             

Table  2.  Violations  of  fiscal  rules  

Deficit  above  3%  ceiling   Due  to  severe  recession   Sanctions  should  be  levied  

148   51   97  

 

Further,  De  Grauwe  (2012b)  argues  that  the  no-­‐bailout  clause  lacked  credibility.  The  spreads  on   the  government  bonds  in  the  eurozone  over  the  bunds  where  almost  zero  since  the  start  of  the   euro.  Although  a  country  could  default  since  a  bailout  was  forbidden,  default  risk  was  not  priced   in  and  ignored  by  the  market.  

 

2.  The  European  Sovereign  Debt  Crisis  

 

This  section  describes  the  onset  of  the  housing  crisis  in  the  US  and  how  it  spilled  over  to  the  rest   of  the  world.  We  will  see  how  the  imbalances  and  weak  structural  fundamentals  created  by  the   EMU  in  the  periphery  countries  led  to  the  Sovereign  debt  crisis  in  the  euro-­‐area  and  what  the   impact  was  on  the  government’s  account,  bank’s  balance  sheets  and  Target  balances.  In  addition,   the  measures  taken  by  the  ECB  and  IMF  in  reaction  to  the  crises  will  be  covered.  

 

2.1  Start  of  the  Global  Financial  crisis    

The  first  phase  of  the  global  financial  crisis  started  with  the  shock  to  the  house  prices  in  in  the   US   in   2007,   significantly   affecting   subprime   mortgages.   The   asset-­‐backed   securities   related   to   those   subprime   mortgages   declined   sharply   in   value.   The   markets   dried   up   and   confidence   decreased.  As  a  consequence  a  bank  run  on  short-­‐term  debt  emerged.  Because  entities  that  were   based  on  short-­‐term  debt  could  not  roll  over  the  debt,  or  were  subject  to  withdrawals,  this  shock   to  housing  prices  spread  rapidly  to  other  asset  classes.  European  banks  were  highly  reliant  on   the  US  money  markets  with  a  high  exposure  to  US  asset-­‐backed  securities,  leading  to  the  global  

(15)

financial  crisis.                      

  The  crisis  got  more  severe  with  the  collapse  of  Lehman  Brothers  in  September  2008.  In   many   European   countries,   announcements   of   bank   bailouts   were   made.   The   most   dramatic   example  of  such  a  bailout  in  the  eurozone  was  the  bailout  by  the  Irish  government  in  September   2008.   Almost   all   major   banks,   for   instance   the   Anglo   Irish   bank,   were   nationalized   (Pilbeam   2013).   The   bank   bailouts   included   injections   of   equity,   asset-­‐purchase   programs   and   debt   guarantees,  or  sometimes  a  combination  of  those  (Hoque  2013).          

  The   financial   crisis   had   as   a   consequence   that   the   capital   transfers   between   the   euro   countries   changed.   Investors   were   withdrawing   their   funds   from   the   periphery   countries   and   reinvested   it   back   into   the   core   countries.   The   current   account   surpluses   of   the   stronger   countries  no  longer  increased,  and  the  deficits  in  the  periphery  countries  reduced,  although  the   deficits  were  not  entirely  evaporated  (Sinn  2012).    

During  2008  and  2009,  the  main  emphasis  lied  on  the  stabilization  of  the  financial  and   banking  system.  The  bond  spreads  on  ten-­‐year  sovereign  bond  yields  of  member  states  such  as   Portugal,  Ireland,  Italy,  Greece  and  Spain  were  still  only  slightly  higher  than  on  German  bunds   (Lane  2012).      

                     

2.2  From  Global  Financial  Crisis  to  Sovereign  Debt  crisis    

2.2.1  Deterioration  in  government  accounts,  banks  balance  sheets  and  Target  balances  

At   the   end   of   2009,   the   European   sovereign   debt   crisis   entered   a   new   phase   when   some   countries  announced  a  higher  deficit  as  percentage  of  GDP  than  was  anticipated.  Especially  the   revelation  in  October  2009  of  the  Greece  budget  deficit  of  12.7  per  cent  of  GDP,  which  was  more   than   twice   the   estimated   deficit   of   6   per   cent   GDP,   deteriorated   the   market   sentiment   in   the   euro-­‐area   (Gilbert,   Hessel   &   Verkaart   2013).   Moreover,   the   structural   borrowing   problem   of   Greece  was  totally  revealed  during  the  financial  crisis.  In  addition,  it  became  evident  that  French   and  German  banks  possessed  70  per  cent  of  the  Greek  debt  (Pilbeam  2013).  The  fear  of  default   and  contagion  to  other  countries  led  to  two  rescue  packages  for  Greece  under  supervision  of  the   Troika,  which  consists  of  representatives  of  the  European  Commision,  the  ECB  and  the  IMF  (De   Bruyckere,  Gerhardt,  Schepens  &  Vennet  2013).  In  2010,  the  Irish  deficit  reached  30.6%  of  GDP.   The  bailout  of  the  Anglo  Irish  Bank  contributed  16  per  cent  of  the  deficit  in  this  fiscal  year.  The   Spanish  Government  made  several  capital  injections  into  commercial  banks  as  Banco  Financiero   y   de   Ahorros,   consequently   resulting   in   an   increase   of   the   sovereign   debt   level   (Eurostat   Government  and  Finance  Statistics,  Supplementary  tables  for  The  Financial  crisis).      

  The  increase  in  the  Sovereign  debt  burden  and  the  ongoing  stress  in  the  banking  system   further   intensified   the   interdependence   between   the   banks   and   the   countries.   Through   four  

(16)

channels   the   high   sovereign   debt   level   spilled   over   to   banks   that   had   great   exposure   to   this   sovereign  debt.  First  of  all,  the  losses  on  sovereign  debt  led  to  a  deterioration  of  the  asset  side  of   the  balance  sheet  through  the  asset  holdings  channel.  Many  European  banks  had  highly  invested   in  Government  bonds  that  were  now  decreasing  in  value  (Feldstein  2011).  The  second  channel  is   the   collateral   channel,   since   the   value   of   collateral   in   the   form   of   sovereign   debt   decreased.   Third,  the  rating  channel  may  cause  a  reduction  in  access  to  the  money  markets  for  the  banks,   because  a  downgrade  in  a  countries  credit  rating  may  affect  the  rating  of  national  banks.  The  last   channel  is  called  the  guarantee  channel.  The  governments  became  more  vulnerable,  reducing  the   value  of  government  guarantees  for  the  national  banks  (De  Bruyckere  et  al.  2013).      

  As  described  in  paragraph  2.1,  the  current  account  imbalances  were  reduced  since  the   start  of  the  crisis  in  2007.  However,  to  eliminate  the  current  account  deficits,  a  large  cut  in  the   real   wages   is   needed   that   could   lower   the   prices   (Feldstein   2011).   In   2011,   in   most   of   the   southern  EMU  countries,  the  current  account  deficits  were  still  the  same  as  the  average  of  the   first   five   years   of   the   single   currency.   Since   the   markets   no   longer   provided   funding   for   the   current   account   deficits,   the   question   is   how   these   deficits   were   funded.   Sinn   and   Wollmershäuser   (2012b)   describe   this   development   with   Target   balances.   Target   (Trans-­‐ European   Automated   Real-­‐time   Gross   settlement   Express   Transfer   system)   is   an   acronym   for   the   payment   system   of   the   ECB   and   the   NCBs.   These   balances   measure   the   intra-­‐euro   area   claims   and   liabilities   or   the   financial   transfers   between   the   NCBs   in   the   EMU   that   arise   when   public  or  private  financial  entities  make  payment  orders  to  the  commercial  banks.  It  shows  how   the  net  refinancing  credit  of  the  ECB  is  allocated  trough  the  Eurosystem.  To  be  able  to  finance   the   current   account   deficits,   the   periphery   NCBs   were   lending   at   expense   of   the   NCBs   in   Northern   Europe.   The   first   ones   became   net   creditors   of   the   Euro   system,   the   latter   ones   net   debtors.  Those  transfers  included  goods  and  assets,  as  well  as  financial  transactions.    

  In  figure  4  we  see  that  up  until  the  start  of  the  crisis,  the  Target  balances  had  been  almost   zero   (Sinn   &   Wollmershäuser   2012b).   In   2007,   with   the   start   of   the   financial   crisis   the   imbalances   grew,   but   started   to   increase   dramatically   by   2010   when   the   interbank   lending   declined   substantially.   Some   countries   needed   credit   to   pay   back   their   outstanding   debt.   This   shortage   was   funded   by   the   additional   refinancing   funds   provided   by   the   NCBs,   by   printing   money,  to  the  commercial  banks  and  led  to  the  Target  imbalances.  After  2012,  the  imbalances   declined  due  to  the  guarantees  of  the  OMT  and  the  ESM,  which  will  be  discussed  in  paragraph   2.3.    In  case  of  a  default  and  a  country  exit  the  euro,  the  claim  against  the  negative  balances  of   this  country’s  NCB  remains.  However,  we  could  not  be  sure  that  when  a  country  defaults,  its  NCB   can   service   the   losses.   The   losses   are   then   imposed   on   the   other   NCBs,   based   on   their   capital   share  in  the  ECB,  which  could  therefore  be  a  threat  to  the  persistence  of  the  Eurosystem  (Sinn  &   Wollmershäuser  2012a).  

(17)

Figure  4.  Target  Balances  in  the  EMU  

  Source:  CESifo,  Target  balances.  Notes:  Core  countries:  Germany,  Netherlands,  Luxembourg  and  Finland.      

2.2.2  Determinants  of  interest  rate  differentials  in  EMU  

Financial   markets   began   to   anticipate   substantially   the   differentials   in   fundamentals   between   the  EMU  countries.  This  led  to  a  further  negative  impact  on  the  sovereign  bond  values  causing   the  differentials  in  government  spreads,  over  German  bunds,  to  rise  significantly  (see  Figure  1).   Favero,  Carlo  Ambrogio,  and  Alessandro  Missale  (2012)  argue  that  there  are  different  reasons   that  could  explain  the  difference  in  spreads.  The  first  explanation  they  mention  is  the  credit  risk.   Because   investors   require   a   risk   premium   when   sovereign   countries   have   a   higher   risk   of   default.   The   financial   markets   were   concerned   about   a   contagion   between   the   GIIPS.   When   Greece  would  default,  speculative  attacks  could  cause  such  high  yields  on  other  GIIPS  debt  that   they  would  also  default.  The  second  explanation  is  the  liquidity  risk.  This  risk  arises  when  bonds   must  be  sold  or  issued  in  a  small  market,  causing  unfair  pricing  and  increasing  transaction  costs   (Favero  &  Missale).  Due  to  the  panic  that  arose  in  the  financial  markets,  investors  turned  their   risky   debt   into   assets   that   were   considered   safe.   This   panic   resulted   in   a   ‘   flight   to   safety’   to   government  bonds  of  countries  as  Germany  and  the  US  (De  Grauwe  &  Moesen  2009).  

  Bernoth   and   Erdogan   (2012)   also   explain   the   sudden   increase   in   spreads   by   the   time-­‐ varying   risk   premium.   They   found   that   the   influence   of   fiscal   fundamentals   and   the   investors’   risk   aversion   on   the   sovereign   yields   varies   over   time   driven   by   market   sentiment.   When   the   credit  boom  burst  the  market  response  to  the  fiscal  weakening  now  raised  substantially  due  to   the  increase  in  risk  pricing.  This  disciplinary  role  of  the  financial  markets  did  not  prevail  at  the   beginning  of  the  EMU.    

  -­‐1100   -­‐900   -­‐700   -­‐500   -­‐300   -­‐100   100   -­‐100   100   300   500   700   900  

1100   Billion  euros   Billion  euros  

Core   Germany   GIIPS  (right-­‐ hand  scale)  

(18)

2.3  Policy  responses  to  the  European  Debt  Crisis    

In  the  aftermath  of  the  Global  financial  crisis  and  during  the  Euro  crisis,  several  policy  measures   were   taken.   Two   institutions   were   created   by   the   euro   area   members   to   provide   funding   to   distressed   countries,   the   EFSF   and   later   the   ESM.   The   ECB   responded   with   several   unconventional   policy   measures,   like   the   SMP   and   OMT,   to   provide   liquidity   and   reduce   the   increasing  sovereign  spreads  over  Germany.  This  paragraph  discusses  these  measures  in  more   detail.      

 

2.3.1  The  EFSF  and  ESM  

The   European   Financial   Stability   Facility   (EFSF)   was   a   temporary   rescue   fund   that   came   into   force   in   August   2010.   The   EFSF   facilitated   additional   funding   for   the   countries   that   had   very   limited  access  to  the  capital  markets  or  paid  exceedingly  high  interest  rates  on  their  debt.  Since   the  high  exposure  of  German  and  French  banks  to  Greek  debt  and  the  debt  of  the  other  GIIPS   countries,  the  EFSF  was  created  to  prevent  contagion  to  other  euro  countries  in  case  of  a  Greek   default,   and   to   persuade   the   financial   markets   of   the   support   of   the   European   leaders   of   the   common   currency.   The   EFSF   was   able   to   issue   bonds   backed   by   €440   billion,   based   on   the   countries’   capital   placed   in   the   ECB.   The   EFSF   has   provided   loans   to   Ireland,   Portugal   and   Greece.   The   persistent   nature   of   the   Euro   Sovereign   Debt   crisis,   the   contagion   to   other   euro   countries  and  the  danger  of  a  Greek  default  in  the  fall  of  2010  called  for  a  bigger  fund.  The  EFSF   was  only  a  temporary  rescue  fund  and  was  replaced  by  the  permanent  rescue  fund,  European   Stability  Mechanism  (ESM).  The  ESM  took  effect  in  October  2012  (Gocaj  &  Meunier  2013).  The   lending   ability   of   the   ESM   was   raised   to   €500   billion,   guaranteed   by   the   member   states   and   could   purchase   bonds   directly   in   the   primary   markets.   A   total   amount   of   80   billion   of   capital   would  be  placed  in  the  ESM  by  the  member  states.  The  EFSF  could  provide  any  new  loans  until   June   2013.   The   loan   to   Greece,   provided   before   June   2013,   is   extended   until   June   2015.   A   country  that  faces  liquidity  problems  can  request  funding  from  the  ESM  upon  austerity  packages   and  several  conditions  related  to  the  loans  (Pilbeam  2013).    

 

2.3.2  The  SMP  and  the  OMT  

In   May   2010,   the   Securities   Market   Programme   (SMP)   was   called   into   action   by   the   ECB.   The   programme  was  introduced  to  purchase  government  bonds  to  provide  liquidity  in  the  secondary   market  and  reduce  the  government  spreads.  Those  purchases  were  sterilized  in  order  to  keep   the  monetary  base  unchanged.  The  SMP  was  implemented  in  two  phases,  in  the  first  half  of  2010   and  in  the  last  half  of  2011  (Falagiardaa  &  Reitzb  2015).  The  ECB  announced  that  it  would  have  a   senior  status  to  private  lenders.  In  the  months  following  the  statement  the  government  spreads   against   the   German   bund   did   not   decline,   instead   they   increased   (Steinkamp   &   Westermann  

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

For the EMU countries, the cash flow ratio, leverage ratio, net working capital ratio, the volatility of the free cash flows, the financial crisis dummy and the control variable

Size has a more significant negative relation to EMU growth company returns than to EMU value company returns, it supports Bouwer and van der Put(1996). Beta has

Plots of the marginal effects of the Eurozone dummy on inflation volatility for given values of PC/GDP and the government share of GDP will not be shown as no

Five of these criteria (labor market integration, factor market integration, financial market integration, similarity of inflation rates and fiscal integration) were tested

The sea-green histogram is the background comes from µ-pairs, while the red histogram is the signal MC and the black line with error bars represents Υ(3S) 3 % unblinded data sample

[r]

This project aims at developing the knowledge required for the co-design of Building-with-Nature (BwN) type interventions in barrier island - inlet systems.. ‘Co-design’ stands for

Without prejudice to any individual criminal responsibility of natural persons under this Statute, the Court may also have jurisdiction over a juridical person for a crime under