• No results found

The choice between private banks and state-owned banks

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "The choice between private banks and state-owned banks"

Copied!
31
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

University  of  Amsterdam  -­‐  Amsterdam  Business    

Bachelor  in  Economics  and  Business,  Economics  and  Finance  track

 

 

 

 

 

 

The  Choice  Between  Private  Banks  and  State-­Owned  Banks  

 

 

 

 

 

       Bachelor  Thesis  

 

 

 

 

 

July  2015  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Max  Kranendijk  (101251200)  

 

 

 

 

 

 

Thesis  Supervisor:  C.  van  der  Kwaak    

 

                   

 

(2)

Abstract  

 

The  nationalization  processes  in  recent  years  as  a  consequence  of  the  financial  crisis   have  reignited  the  debate  on  which  ownership  structure  should  be  preferred,  private  or   state-­‐owned  banks.  In  this  literature  review,  the  differences  between  state-­‐owned  banks   and  private  banks  are  examined  based  on  empirical  and  theoretical  studies.  In  general,   most  studies  find  that  private  banks  should  be  preferred  over  state-­‐owned  banks.   Firstly,  countries  with  a  relatively  higher  degree  of  private  banks  than  state-­‐owned   banks  are  associated  with  more  economic  growth.  Secondly,  in  most  countries  private   banks  perform  better  than  state-­‐owned  banks  in  terms  of  profitability,  riskiness  and   efficiency.  Thirdly,  private  banks  are  not  influenced  as  much  as  state-­‐owned  banks  by   political  incentives.  However,  an  advantage  of  state-­‐owned  banks  over  private  banks  is   their  stabilizing  effect  during  a  crisis.  During  a  crisis  state-­‐owned  banks  often  have  a   positive  impact  on  the  economy,  because  state-­‐owned  banks    then  tend  to  keep  lending   out  money  to  firms,  so  that  projects  are  continued.    In  addition,  an  example  of  the   German  banking  system  shows  that  in  a  country  with  “good  governance”  state-­‐owned   banks  could  possibly  perform  better  in  terms  of  profitability  than  private  banks.                                      

(3)

Contents  

 

I. Introduction……….4  

  II. Chapter  1:  How  Does  the  Financial  System  WORK?...5  

1.1-­‐ How  do  banks  work?  ……….5  

1.2-­‐ How  do  banks  reduce  information  asymmetry?...6  

1.3-­‐ What  causes  banks  to  be  in  danger?...7  

  III. Chapter  2:  Bank  Ownership  and  the  Reasons  for  Nationalizing  or  Privatizing…….8  

2.1-­‐   What  are  the  reasons  for  privatizing  banks?...8  

2.2-­‐   What  are  the  reasons  for  nationalizing  banks?...10  

  IV. Chapter  3:  Differences  in  Results  Between  Privatized  and  Nationalized  Banks…11     3.1-­‐     Comparing  Nationalized  and  Private  banks………..12  

  3.2-­‐   Bank  Performance  based  on  economic  growth,  profits  and  efficiency…….12  

    3.2.1-­‐   Effect  on  economic  growth  and  the  financial  system………..12  

    3.2.2-­‐   Effects  on  profits,  efficiency  and  risks  of  the  banks  themselves…...13  

3.3-­‐   Difference  in  Lending  Behaviour,  due  to  elections  or  political  incentives.17   3.4-­‐     Change  in  behaviour  and  performance  between  state-­‐owned  and     private  banks  during  a  crisis………...………21  

  V. Analysis  and  Conclusion……….………...25  

  VI. References………28                  

(4)

 

I.   Introduction:    

During  the  recent  financial  crisis  many  countries  were  forced  to  nationalize  private   banks  to  prevent  these  banks  from  falling  into  bankruptcy.  The  consequences  of  private   banks  in  bankruptcy  for  clients  of  private  banks  and  for  the  general  economy  of  a  

country  would  be  so  severe,  that  governments  had  no  choice,  but  to  nationalize  these   banks.  This  happened  especially  in  developed  countries  (examples  are  Northern  Rock  in   the  UK,  Kaupting  and  Landsbanki  in  Iceland,  Anglo  Irish  bank  in  Ireland,  and  ABN  AMRO   in  the  Netherlands),  where  in  general  the  amount  of  private  banks  relative  to  state-­‐ owned  banks  is  higher.  Criticizers  of  the  banking  system  in  developed  countries,  with  its   high  degree  of  private  banks,  claim  that  in  this  situation  profits  of  banks  are  privatized,   while  the  losses  are  nationalised.    Proponents  of  private  banks  point  out  that  countries   with  high  economic  growth,  are  in  general  countries  with  a  high  degree  of  private  banks   (La  Porta  2002,  Barth,  Caprio  and  Levine  1999,  Cole  2009).    The  nationalization  

processes  in  recent  years  have  reignited  the  debate  on  which  ownership  structure   should  be  preferred,  private  or  state-­‐owned  banks  (Bertay,  2014.,  Cull  2013).     This  resulted  in  the  following  research  question;  “should  state-­owned  banks  be   preferred  over  private  banks?”    

In  this  paper  I  try  to  give  a  well-­‐considered  answer  to  this  general  question,  by   executing  a  diverse  literature  review.  To  give  some  background  information,  I  will  give  a   short  overview  in  chapter  1  on  how  the  financial  system  works.  This  will  be  done  by   giving  a  simplified  description  on  how  banks  work,  how  banks  reduce  information   asymmetry  and  what  causes  banks  to  be  in  danger.  In  chapter  2,  theoretical  arguments   in  favour  of  private  banks  are  discussed,  followed  by  theoretical  arguments  in  favour  of   state-­‐owned  banks.  In  chapter  3,  the  two  ownership  forms  of  banking  are  judged  in   three  different  ways.  First,  bank  performance  will  be  considered  based  on  economic   growth,  profits  and  efficiency.  Second,  the  difference  in  lending  behaviour  between   state-­‐owned  and  private  banks  will  be  examined.  Third,  the  effects  of  bank  ownership   on  the  economy  during  a  crisis  will  be  evaluated.    

  When  examining  the  effects  of  bank  ownership  on  economic  growth  we  can   assume  that  the  prevalence  of  relatively  many  private  banks  in  a  country  seems  to  go   along  with  more  economic  growth  and  a  more  efficient  financial  system  in  the  long  run  

(5)

(La  Porta,  2002.,  Barth,  Caprio  and  Levine  1999.,  Cole  2009).    When  looking  at  the   individual  performances  of  banks  based  on  profit,  riskiness  and  efficiency,  the  results   are  more  mixed.  Most  studies  that  evaluate  the  performance  differences  between  state-­‐ owned  banks  and  private  banks  across  countries  (both  empirical  and  theoretical)  find   that  state-­‐owned  banks  are  less  profitable  and  take  more  risk  in  particular  in  times  of   economic  downturn  (Ianotta,  2007.,  Cornett  2010,  Boyd  2005).  The  results  of  Figueira   (2009)  are  an  exception,  which  show  that  in  Latin  America  private  banks  did  not   outperform  state-­‐owned  banks.  However,  when  we  look  at  the  differences  in  

performance  of  state-­‐owned  banks  and  private  banks  on  a  per  country  basis,  we  find   mixed  results.  In  India  (Bhattacharyya,  1997)  state-­‐owned  banks  were  more  efficient   but  less  profitable,  while  in  Germany  (Altunbas,  2001)  state-­‐owned  banks  had  slight  cost   advantages  and  were  more  profitable.  

  Looking  at  the  differences  in  lending  behaviour  between  private  and  state-­‐owned   banks,  the  findings  of  Dinc  (2005)  and  Sapienza  (2001)  give  a  clear  preference  for   private  banks.  They  show  that  in  most  countries  state-­‐owned  banks  are  politically  

biased,  by  charging  lower  interest  rates  and  increase  lending  behaviour  during  elections.   However,  in  most  developed  countries  an  increase  in  lending  behaviour  cannot  be  

detected  during  elections.    

  However,  in  times  of  a  crisis  state-­‐owned  banks  seem  to  have  a  positive   impact  on  the  economy  of  a  country.  Brei  (2014),  Betray  (2014)  and  Coleman  (2014)  et   al  showed  that  contrary  to  private  banks,  state-­‐owned  banks  keep  lending  out  money  to   firms  during  a  crisis,  so  that  firms  can  continue  their  projects.  These  articles  proved  that   in  times  of  a  crisis,  countries  or  local  areas  with  a  relatively  high  degree  of  state-­‐owned   banks  generated  higher  economic  growth  than  countries  or  local  areas  with  a  relatively   low  degree  of  state-­‐owned  banks.  The  drawback  of  this  outperformance  during  crisis   periods  is  that  in  times  when  there  are  no  recessions  countries  with  relatively  many   private  banks  seem  to  generate  more  economic  growth  (Brei,  2014.,  Betray,  2014.,   Coleman,  2014.))  

 

II.   Chapter  1  

How  does  the  Financial  System  work?      

(6)

 

According  to  Megginson  (2001)  banks  have  three  main  functions.  Banks  are  responsible   for  the  transfer  of  money,  act  as  financial  intermediaries  and  banks  are  able  to  evaluate   and  monitor  credit  allocation.  Banks  generate  money  by  accepting  money  as  deposits,  or   by  borrowing  from  money  markets.  Deposits  come  from  individuals,  businesses,  

financial  institutions  and  governments  with  surpluses.  Banks  use  their  deposits  and   borrowed  money  (liabilities)  to  make  loans  or  buy  securities  (assets).  Loans  are  made  to   individuals,  businesses,  financial  institutions  and  governments  with  deficits.  

(www.frbsf.org/education/publications/doctor-­‐econ/2001/july/bank-­‐economic-­‐

function.,  05-­‐06-­‐2015)  

Banks  are  originally  created  so  that  people  and  businesses  can  put  their  money  at   a  safe  place,  in  which  it  also  gets  interest  for.  At  the  same  time  people  and  businesses,   which  are  in  need  of  money  for  their  investments  can  borrow  at  banks.  Generally  banks   make  money  by  lending  money  at  higher  interest  rates,  than  the  interest  they  pay  on   deposits.  So  banks  make  money  by  collecting  interest  on  loans  and  interest  payments   from  the  securities  they  own,  while  interest  rates  on  deposits  cost  banks  money.  The   difference  between  the  interest  banks  receive  on  loans  and  the  interest  banks  pay  on   deposits  is  known  as  the  “spread”,  which  is  the  net  interest  income  for  banks.  

(www.investopedia.com/university/banking-­‐system/banking-­‐system3.asp.,  05-­‐06-­‐ 2015)  

 

1.2-­  How  do  banks  reduce  information  asymmetry?      

Banks  act  as  intermediaries  in  the  financial  system  and  reduce  the  asymmetric  problem   in  contracts  between  borrowers  and  lenders.  Information  asymmetry  implies  a  

situation,  in  which  one  party  in  a  transaction  has  more  or  superior  information  than  the   other  party.  The  asymmetric  information  problem  arises  in  the  situation  of  money   lending/borrowing,  because  borrowers  know  more  about  the  risk  of  their  investments   than  lenders  do.  Also  lenders  cannot  observe  if  borrowers  will  act  in  the  best  interest  of   the  lenders.    This  moral  hazard  is  known  as  the  principal-­‐agent  problem  (principal  is  the   lender  and  agent  is  the  borrower).  (Berk  and  De  Marzo,  2011).  When  borrowers  are   monitored,  lenders  can  more  easily  know  which  borrowers  will  have  a  higher  chance  of   default.  Banks  reduce  the  information  problem,  as  they  provide  both  credit  and  liquidity  

(7)

and  so  are  able  to  collect  far  more  information  than  other  lenders  (Berk  and  De  Marzo,   2011).    

 

1.3-­  What  causes  banks  to  be  in  danger?    

 

According  to  Cippolini    and  Fiordelisi  (2012)  credit  risk,  liquidity  risk  and  bank  market   power  are  the  main  factors  of  banks  getting  into  danger.  Credit  risk  refers  to  the  risk  of   default  by  the  issuer  of  any  bond  or  loan.  It  is  a  measure  to  indicate  to  which  degree  the   bond’s  or  loan’s  cash  flows  are  not  known  with  certainty.  Liquidity  risk  refers  to  the  risk   of  not  being  able  to  buy  or  sell  an  investment  quickly  enough  to  prevent  a  loss.  In  case  of   illiquidity,  the  party  is  forced  to  liquidate  an  investment  at  a  loss,  because  cash  is  

required  to  pay  for  another  obligation.  Bank  market  power  refers  to  the  ability  of  a  bank   to  manipulate  prices  (in  this  case  interest  rates)  by  influencing  supply  and  or  demand  of   money  (Berk  and  DeMarzo,  2011).  

Banks  are  in  danger  when  they  are  in  financial  distress.  Cippolini  and  Fiordelisi   (2012)  measure  this  by  looking  at  the  effect  of  credit  risk,  liquidity  risk  and  market   power  on  Shareholder  Value  Ratio.  The  shareholder  value  ratio  (SHVR)  is  the  ratio   between  economic  value  added  and  the  shareholder  capital  invested  in  the  previous   period.  Economic  value  added,  or  EVA,  is  calculated  by  computing  the  difference   between  the  bank  net  operating  profits  minus  the  cost  of  capital  (expressed  as  a   percentage)  times  the  capital  invested  in  the  previous  period.    

Cippolini  and  Fiordelisi  (2012)  measure  credit  risk  by  focusing  on  the  ratio  of   loan  loss  provisions  to  total  loans.  They  find  in  all  their  models  an  increase  in  the   probability  of  a  distressed  shareholder  value  ratio,  when  the  ratio  of  loan-­‐loss  

provisions  to  total  loans  increase.  Liquidity  risk  is  measured  by  focusing  on  the  ratio  of   liquid  assets  to  total  assets.  When  accounting  for  country  fixed  effects  there  is  a  negative   relationship  between  liquid  assets  and  observing  a  distressed  shareholder  value  ratio.    

Bank  market  power  is  estimated  by  using  the  Lerner  index,  which  indicates  the   degree  to  which  market  power  allows  to  fix  a  price  above  marginal  cost.  Chippolini  and   Fiordelisi  (2012)  find  that  a  distressed  shareholder  value  ratio  has  a  negative  significant   link  with  the  Lerner  index,  suggesting  that  an  increase  in  market  power  lowers  chances   of  financial  distress.  So  an  increase  in  credit  risk  and  liquidity  risk  lead  to  a  higher  

(8)

chance  of  banks  getting  in  financial  distress.  Berger  et  al  (2009)  state  that  there  is  a   negative  link  between  bank  market  power  and  financial  distress.    

 

III.   Chapter  2:    

Bank  Ownership  and  the  Reasons  for  Nationalizing  or  Privatizing.    

2.1-­  What  are  the  reasons  for  privatizing  banks?    

Privately  owned  banks  are  commercial  and  generally  aim  at  generating  maximum   profits.  Government-­‐owned  banks  are  in  the  hands  of  the  public  and  would  ideally  aim   at  generating  a  maximum  social  welfare.  Private  ownership  should  in  general  be   preferred  over  public  ownership,  when  the  incentives  to  innovate  and  to  contain  costs   are  strong  (Shleiffer,  1998).    

As  biggest  evidence  Shleifer  (1998)  points  out  the  difference  in  success  of   capitalism  over  socialism.  During  the  first  decades  after  the  Second  World  War  

economists  almost  all  favoured  government  ownership  of  firms  as  soon  as  any  market   imperfections  were  suspected.  This  was  especially  the  case  for  “strategic”  sectors,  as   mines,  hospitals,  schools  and  banks.  However,  the  last  30  years  the  desire  to  privatise   grew  enormously  in  market  economies  and  communism  collapsed  almost  everywhere  in   the  world.  Governments  proved  to  be  imperfect,  by  preferring  political  goals,  such  as   patronage  or  simply  maximizing  the  income  of  politicians  (Shleiffer,  1998).  More   interestingly  Shleifer  and  Vishny,  (1994,  1998)  conclude  that  state  firms  are  inefficient,   due  to  the  fact  that  governments  deliberately  transfer  resources  to  supporters.  

    Cornet  (2010)  states  that  state-­‐owned  companies  disregard  social  objectives  and   are  extremely  inefficient.  The  reason  for  this  is  that  politicians  often  have  goals  that  are   in  conflict  with  social  welfare  improvements,  while  having  as  main  purpose  political   interests.  This  is  also  the  case  for  government-­‐owned  banks.  Shleifer  and  Vishny  (1994)   explain  this  by  the  fact  that  government-­‐owned  banks  are  run  by  political  bureaucrats,   who  have  a  total  power  on  the  control  rights,  but  not  on  the  cash  flow  rights,  as  these   need  to  go  to  tax-­‐payers.  The  profits  are  distributed  in  the  form  of  dividends  to  the  state   and  do  not  accrue  to  the  bureaucrats.  Therefore  maximizing  profits  are  not  extremely   important  for  the  bureaucrats,  who  own  the  state-­‐owned  banks.  A  bigger  concern  for   them  is  to  fund  special  interest  groups,  such  as  trade  unions,  who  help  the  bureaucrats  

(9)

win  elections.  This  political  interest  of  state-­‐owned  banks  cause  that  their  goals  are  in   conflict  with  social  welfare  and  maximization  of  profits.  In  this  case  the  performance  of   state-­‐owned  banks  would  in  general  be  inferior  to  privately  owned  banks  (Shleifer  and   Vishny,  1994).    

La  Porta  (2002)  defines  this  as  the  “political  view”  of  government  participation  in   financial  firms.  Politicians  who  control  banks  would  use  their  power  over  banks  to  win   votes,  instead  of  focusing  on  efficiency  and  maximizing  profit.  State-­‐owned  banks  would   give  jobs  or  financial  resources  to  friends  and  political  supporters.  So  politicians  would   run  state-­‐owned  banks  not  to  finance  resources  to  economically  efficient  users,  but  to   maximize  their  own  personal  objectives  (Sapienza  2004).    According  to  Kane  (2000)   politicians  try  to  preserve  cheap  subsidized  loans  for  their  parties  and  befriended   sectors.  These  subsidized  loans  occur  much  more  often  at  state-­‐owned  banks.  This   creates  un-­‐booked  losses,  which  become  visible  only  in  the  case  of  a  banking  crisis.  As   privatized  banks  main  goal  is  to  maximize  profits,  there  is  no  incentive  to  give  away   these  cheap  loans.    

Dinc  (2010)  gives  reasons  why  the  problems  of  political  influence  will  be  greater   at  government-­‐owned  banks  than  other  government-­‐owned  firms.  “First,  the  

asymmetric  information  between  lending  banks  and  outsiders  about  the  quality  of  a   specific  loan  makes  it  easy  to  disguise  political  motivation  behind  a  loan.  Second,   revealing  the  costs  of  any  politically  motivated  loan  can  be  deferred  until  the  loan   maturity.  Third,  while  a  non-­‐bank  government-­‐owned  enterprise  operates  in  a  defined   industry,  which  can  limit  the  politicians’’  ability  to  transfer  resources,  banks  operate   across  the  whole  economy,  providing  politicians  with  more  opportunity  to  channel   funds”.  Funds  can  be  channelled  by  providing  loans  more  easily  to  large  companies  who   are  aligned  with  trade  unions,  so  that  these  unions  will  support  the  political  party  of  the   bureaucrats  (Dinc,2010).    

Privatization  is  also  supported  by  the  ‘competition-­‐stability’  view,  which  states   that  a  high  degree  of  competition  creates  a  more  stable  financial  system  (Boyd  and  De   Nicolo,  2005).  In  an  economy  with  a  high  degree  of  state-­‐owned  banks,  there  is  often  a   lower  degree  of  competition.  Too  much  market  power  of  only  a  few  banks  will  cause   these  banks  to  raise  interest  on  loans,  which  will  adversely  select  investors  and  firms   with  risky  investments.  This  will  have  a  negative  impact  on  the  stability  of  the  banking   system  (Cipollini,  2012.  Boyd  and  De  Nicolo  (2005)  call  this  a  moral  hazard  problem,  as  

(10)

borrowers  confronted  with  higher  interest  costs,  optimally  choose  a  higher  risk  

portfolio.  More  competition  would  increase  chances  of  solving  the  optimal  contracting   problem,  which  states  that  the  actions  of  borrowers  are  unobservable,  or  observable  at  a   cost.  As  privatization  goes  along  with  more  competition,  risks  of  financial  distress  will   decrease.    

Moreover,  Figueira  (2009)  states  that  under  the  principal-­‐agent  theory  managers   in  the  private  sector  have  greater  incentives  to  aim  at  maximizing  profit  than  managers   under  state-­‐ownership.  He  states  that  this  is  due  to  the  fact  that  the  private  capital   market  is  far  better  in  monitoring  management  behaviour  than  government   departments.  

O’Hara  states  that  in  the  case  of  state-­‐owned  banks  there  is  a  lack  of  capital   market  discipline,  which  indicates  that  management  in  these  banks  experience  a  lower   intensity  of  political  pressure  and  may  therefore  operate  less  efficiently  than  privately   owned  banks.  For  example,  when  a  bank  is  in  a  less  competitive  local  market  the  bank   may  choose  to  take  the  gains  of  market  power  to  spend  more  on  staff  or  purposes,   instead  of  aiming  at  higher  profits.  State-­‐owned  banks  are  typically  more  concentrated   and  face  less  competition  (O’Hara,  1981).  So  did  Berger  and  Hannan  (1998)  find  that   during  the  1980s  U.S.  banks  which  operated  in  more  concentrated  markets  faced  lower   cost  efficiency.    

   

2.2-­  What  are  the  reasons  for  nationalizing  banks?    

 

Privately  owned  firms  might  underperform  in  terms  of  quality  or  neglect  the  interests  of   certain  stakeholders,  because  their  single-­‐minded  focus  on  profits.  A  politician,  who   should  stand  for  social  efficiency,  could  then  improve  efficiency,  by  controlling  decisions   of  firms  (Sappington  &  Stiglitz  (1987).  Sapienza  (2005)  expands  this  to  the  social  view,   based  on  the  economic  theory  of  institutions.  State-­‐owned  firms  are  created  to  

overcome  market  failures,  whenever  the  social  benefits  of  state-­‐owned  firms  exceed  the   costs.  The  social  view  implies  that  state-­‐owned  banks  improve  economic  development   and  improve  general  welfare  (Cole  2009).    Moreover,  La  Porta  (2002)  argues  that  state-­‐ owned  banks  ensure  complete  control  of  the  government  for  the  choice  which  projects   should  be  financed,  while  regulation  of  private  banks  could  only  influence  the  financing   of  projects  partly.    

(11)

According  to  Dinc  (2005)  it  is  a  common  view  that  government  ownership  of   banks  facilitates  financing  of  certain  investments  that  private  banks  would  not  finance.   This  is  especially  important  for  projects  that  could  help  economic  development.  La  Porta   (2002)  even  introduces  the  development  view,  which  states  that  especially  in  emerging   markets  due  to  bank  ownership  the  government  can  more  easily  finance  investments   which  create  financial  and  economic  development.    

There  is  also  a  “light”  version  of  the  social  view,  which  is  called  the  agency  view.   The  agency  view  also  shares  the  idea  that  state-­‐owned  banks  in  essence  try  to  create   maximum  social  welfare.  Conversely,  bank  ownership  of  the  state  increases  the  chances   of  corruption  and  misallocation.  Sapienza  (2004)  compares  the  choice  between  state-­‐ owned  and  privately  owned  firms  as  “  a  trade-­‐off  between  internal  and  allocative  

efficiency”.  State-­‐owned  banks  would  allocate  resources  more  efficiently,  as  state-­‐owned   banks  move  resources  to  socially  profitable  activities.  Conversely,  state-­‐owned  banks   would  internally  be  less  efficient  than  private  banks,  as  public  managers  would  exert   less  effort  or  use  resources  for  personal  benefits,  which  could  lead  to  corruption   (Sapienza,  2004).    

In  the  1930s  the  main  view  was  that  to  preserve  stability,  competition  needed  to   be  restrained.  The  basic  idea  was  that  when  banks  earn  monopoly  rents,  banks  become   conservative.  The  reason  for  this  is  that  they  see  their  monopoly  position  as  a  valuable   asset,  so  they  want  to  lower  their  risks  of  bankruptcy  (Boyd,  2005).  This  theory  is   supported  by  Hellmal  et  al  (2000),  who  find  that  an  implementation  of  deposit  interest   rate  ceilings  decreases  risks  of  bank  failure.  Allen  and  Gale  (2004)  describe  the  

“competition-­‐fragility  view”,  which  argues  that  bank  competition  causes  banks  to   finance  risky  projects  to  increase  their  profit  margins.  This  results  in  a  higher   probability  of  financial  distress.  In  the  case  of  government-­‐ownership  of  banks   competition  will  be  much  lower,  so  these  problems  are  less  likely  to  arise.    

Lastly,  the  assumption  that  managers  in  privately  owned  banks  are  monitored   better  by  their  shareholders  than  managers  in  state-­‐owned  banks  is  rejected  by  

Altunbas  (2001).  He  states  that  effective  monitoring  is  not  dependent  on  an  ownership   form  and  not  weakened  in  a  market,  where  it  is  not  possible  to  trade  ownership  rights.      

IV.   Chapter  3    

(12)

   

3.1-­  Comparing  Nationalized  and  Private  banks  

 

Government  ownership  of  banks  for  many  years  has  been  a  frequently  investigated  topic   in  economics.  In  general,  there  are  three  different  ways,  in  which  papers  judge  

government  ownership  of  banks.  The  first  and  most  investigated  way  is  to  consider  bank   performance,  based  on  economic  growth,  profits  and  efficiency.  The  second  group  

examines  the  difference  in  lending  behaviour  between  private  and  government-­‐owned   banks,  due  to  elections  or  other  political  incentives.  The  third  group  investigates  what   the  effect  is  of  bank  ownership  during  a  crisis  (Cornett,  2010).  In  this  chapter  the  results   of  all  these  three  different  judgements  on  the  effect  of  bank  ownership  will  be  discussed.      

3.2-­  Bank  Performance  based  on  economic  growth,  profits  and  efficiency  

 

3.2.1  Effect  on  economic  growth  and  the  financial  system  

 

There  are  a  lot  of  articles  about  the  difference  in  performance  between  private  and   government-­‐owned  banks.  In  general  most  articles  found  that  economies  with  a  lot  of   private  banks  come  with  more  economic  growth,  profits  and  efficiency  (La  Porta  et  al,   2002.,  Cole,  2009.,  Boyd  and  De  Nicolo,  2005.).  Government  ownership  of  banks  today  is   still  common  around  the  world,  though  it  did  decrease  the  last  40  years.  The  percentage   of  state-­‐owned  banks  is  especially  high  in  countries,  which  are  poor,  have  lots  of  

government  interventions  and  underdeveloped  financial  systems.  Government   ownership  is  also  higher  in  countries  that  have  less  political  rights,  or  are  less   democratic.  However,  this  does  not  implicitly  mean  that  state-­‐owned  banks  

underperform  relative  to  private  banks  (La  Porta,  2002).  A  lot  of  studies  were  done  to   try  to  find  if  there  is  a  difference  in  performance.  

    La  Porta  (2002)  did  a  big  investigation  by  analyzing  government  ownership  of   large  banks,  measured  in  terms  of  assets,  in  92  countries  and  compares  them  with  the   private  banks  in  these  countries.  For  each  country,  the  then  largest  commercial  and  the   then  largest  development  banks  (state-­‐owned)  are  included.  The  countries  are  

(13)

investigated  by  running  a  regression  over  the  92  countries  over  a  period  from  1970  to   1995.    

La  Porta  (2002)  finds  that  the  higher  the  degree  of  government  ownership  of   banks,  the  slower  the  development  of  the  financial  system,  the  lower  the  economic   growth  and  especially,  the  lower  the  growth  of  productivity.  These  negative  effects  are   not  weaker  in  less  developed  countries.  This  supports  the  political  view  of  the  effects  of   government  ownership  of  banks.  So  government  ownership  of  banks  go  along  with   slower  financial  and  economic  development,  also  in  poorer  countries.  These  results  are   consistent  with  Barth,  Caprio  and  Levine  (1999),  who  find  that  government  ownership   of  banks  is  higher  in  countries  with  less  developed  financial  systems.  Still,  these  results   do  not  prove  causality  between  performance  and  ownership,  as  also  other  reasons  can   be  given  for  the  higher  economic  growth  of  developed  countries.  Cross-­‐country  

regressions  suggest  plausible  relationship,  but  it  does  not  provide  evidence.  

  Cole  (2009)  uses  a  policy  experiment  of  India  in  1980  to  evaluate  the  effect  of   bank  ownership  on  financial  and  economic  development.  In  1980  the  government  of   India  nationalized  all  private  banks  with  a  deposit  base  above  Rs.  2  billion.  Comparable   and  smaller  banks  were  kept  private.  The  nationalization  of  the  banks  came  along  with   strict  policy  rules,  which  were  identical  for  public  and  private  banks.  In  this  way  

differences  in  performances  between  banks  can  be  accounted  on  bank  ownership,   instead  of  characteristics  of  the  banks,  or  different  stages  of  regulation.  The  

nationalization  induced  variation  in  the  share  of  credit  issued  by  public  banks  and   therefore  causal  effects  of  bank  nationalization  on  the  economy  could  be  interpreted.      

Cole’s  (2009)  results  showed  that  the  nationalization  first  increased  the  quantity,   but  substantially  lowered  the  quality  of  financial  intermediation.  Though  more  money   was  lent  to  agricultural  borrowers,  agricultural  outcome  did  not  improve.  The  bank   nationalization  may  have  even  slowed  the  growth  of  employment  in  more  developed   sectors  of  trade  and  services.  No  effect  on  financial  development  was  found  nor  

mentioned.  Cole  (2009)  concludes  that  one  shortcoming  of  his  paper  is  that  due  to  the   fact  that  banks  were  nationalized  according  to  their  deposit  base,  the  nationalized  banks   are  significantly  larger  than  the  private  (control)  banks.  As  only  the  effects  of  

government  ownership  of  banks  on  the  larger  banks  could  be  evaluated,  it  is  not  sure  if   similar  results  would  be  generated  if  also  smaller  banks  would  be  nationalized.    

(14)

3.2.2  Effects  on  profits,  efficiency  and  risks  of  the  banks  themselves    

 

Ianotta  (2007)  investigated  the  effect  of  ownership  structure  on  performance  and  risk   in  the  European  banking  industry  during  a  period  from  1999  to  2004.  In  this  article  the   effect  of  three  types  of  bank  ownership  are  measured,  namely  privately  owned  banks,   government-­‐owned  banks  and  mutual  banks.  I  will  only  elaborate  on  the  results  of  the   differences  between  the  first  two  ownership  types.  The  performance  and  risk  of  a   sample  of  181  large  banks  from  15  European  countries  are  evaluated.  A  bank  is  

classified  as  large  if  it  has  total  assets  of  at  least  €  10  billion.  This  information  is  based   on  the  income  statements,  balance  sheets  and  ownership  information  data  from  the   investigated  banks.  When  testing  for  systematic  performance  differences  in  ownership,   Ianotta  (2007)  controls  for  bank  characteristics,  country  and  year  effects,  and  specific   macroeconomic  growth  differentials.  The  results  show  that  private  banks  are  more   profitable  than  government-­‐owned  banks.  These  higher  profits  come  from  higher  net   returns  on  the  assets,  and  not  from  a  superior  cost  efficiency.  In  addition,  government-­‐ owned  banks  turn  out  to  be  riskier,  as  these  banks  have  a  poorer  loan  quality  and  higher   insolvency  risks  than  private  banks.    The  paper  came  with  curious  results  for  the  

banking  activity  of  government-­‐owned  banks,  as  a  larger  share  of  their  funding  comes   from  the  wholesale  interbank  and  capital  markets,  their  liquidity  is  higher  and  their   investments  in  loans  is  lower  compared  to  private  banks  (Ianotta  2007).    

The  general  view  in  economic  literature  is,  according  to  Boyd  (2005),  that,  in  case   of  increased  competition,  banks  rationally  choose  more  risky  portfolios.  Private  banks,   which  are  subject  to  more  competition,  would  in  this  view  be  riskier.  Boyd  (2005)   doubts  this  view  and  shows  with  his  paper  the  opposite,  namely  that  banks  become   more  risky  as  the  markets  become  more  concentrated.  This  study  focuses  on  the  asset   side  of  the  balance  sheet,  which  was  not  done  before.  As  competition  decreases,  banks   charge  higher  loan  rates  in  the  loan  market,  which  led  to  higher  bankruptcy  risks  for   bank  borrowers.  So  banks  would  use  their  increased  market  power  to  raise  loan  rates   and  borrowers,  who  are  confronted  with  increased  funding  costs,  would  optimally   choose  riskier  projects.  There  is  assumed  that  borrowers  totally  determine  project  risk,   conditional  on  the  loan  set  by  banks.  In  general  the  study  suggests  that  government-­‐ owned  banks,  which  are  subject  to  more  market  power  and  less  competition,  are  riskier   than  private  banks  (Boyd,  2005).    

(15)

Cornett  (2010)  investigated  performance  differences  between  state-­‐owned  and   privately  owned  banks  before,  during  and  after  the  Asian  financial  crisis.  The  study   examined  year-­‐end  financial  statement  data  from  1989  until  2004  for  16  Far  East   countries.  This  period  includes  the  Asian  financial  crisis,  which  started  in  July  1997.  The   drop  of  the  Thai  baht  relative  to  the  U.S.  dollar,  was  followed  by  devaluation  of  al  lot  of   Asian  currencies.    A  bank  is  accounted  as  state-­‐owned  if  the  government  holds  at  least   20%  of  the  shares.    

    Cornet’s  (2010)  results  show  that  on  average  state-­‐owned  banks  were  less   profitable,  held  less  core  capital  and  had  greater  credit  risk  than  private  banks  during   the  period  of  1989-­‐2000.  The  reason  for  this  was  that  state-­‐owned  banks  had  un-­‐booked   losses,  which  could  no  longer  be  kept  secret  during  the  crisis.  Another  result  was  also   found,  namely  that  during  the  years  after  the  Asian  crisis,  the  period  of  2001-­‐2004,   state-­‐owned  banks  recovered  relatively  quicker  than  private  banks.  This  resulted  that  in   the  year  2004,  cash  flow  returns,  core  capital  and  nonperforming  loans  were  not  

significantly  different  anymore  from  private  banks.  According  to  Cornett  (2010)  state-­‐ owned  banks  could  catch  up  due  to  the  increase  in  globalization,  which  created  an   increase  in  financial  competition.  This  has  lead  to  a  more  sustainable  banking  policy  that   disciplines  inefficient  regulators.      

 

Examples  of  countries  with  mixed  results    

Complementary  to  the  last  finding  of  Cornet  (2010),  there  are  also  examples  of   individual  countries  where  government-­‐owned  banks  performed  on  average  equally   well,  or  even  performed  better  in  total  than  private  banks.    

Bhattacharyya  (1997)  tried  to  measure  the  variation  in  performance  of  Indian   commercial  banks,  during  the  early  years  of  financial  liberalization  in  India  from  1986  to   1991.  Before  this  period  most  of  the  banking  sector  was  under  government  protection   and  ownership  since  1980.    In  1969  already  14  major  banks  were  nationalized  and  in   1980  a  further  6  major  banks  were  nationalized.  This  was  due  to  the  decision  of  the   Indian  government  to  nationalize  all  private  banks  with  a  deposit  base  above  Rs.  2   billion  .  From  1986  to  1991,  in  response  to  changing  international  financial  markets  and   as  an  effort  to  make  the  Indian  banking  system  internationally  more  competitive  

(16)

privatization  took  place  and  private  banks  were  allowed  to  expand  without  the  fear  of   nationalization.  Efficiency  of  70  Indian  commercial  banks  was  measured  during  this   liberalization  process,  which  revealed  the  differences  in  performance  between  privately   owned  and  government-­‐owned  banks.  Performance  was  associated  with  technical   efficiency;  which  is  the  ability  to  transform  multiple  resources  into  multiple  financial   services.  A  bank  is  technical  efficient  when  it  is  generating  maximum  output  from  the   minimal  amount  of  capital.  Bhattacharyya  (1997)  calculates  technical  efficiencies  by   using  data  envelop  analysis  (DEA),  a  method  often  used  when  performance  differences   in  relation  to  bank  ownership  are  calculated.  Variation  in  efficiency  of  banks  is  explained   by  decomposing  variation  into  a  systematic  and  a  random  component.  From  the  

systematic  component  differences  in  efficiency  are  attributed  to  differences  of  bank   ownership.    

The  results  showed  that  government-­‐owned  banks  were  more  efficient  than   privately  owned  banks.  Government-­‐owned  banks  utilized  their  resources  better  to   deliver  financial  services  to  their  customers.  However,  government-­‐owned  banks   underperformed  privately  owned  banks,  when  looking  at  profitability.  So  the  

investigation  of  the  Indian  banking  sector  gave  mixed  results  on  the  effect  of  ownership   of  banks  on  performance  (Bhattacharyya,  1997).    

Figueira  (2009)  investigated  the  difference  in  performance  between  state-­‐owned   and  private-­‐owned  banks  in  Latin  America  in  2001.  During  the  decade  before  2001  in   the  Latin  banking  industry  liberalization  was  common  to  most  countries,  which  included   privatization  of  banks.  Private  and  government-­‐owned  banks  were  compared  using   cross-­‐sectional  data  on  financial  and  economic  performance  ratios,  which  provide   insights  into  the  results  of  reforms  of  ownership  during  the  1990s.  The  results  showed   that  there  was  no  evidence  that  private  banks  in  Latin  America  in  2001  performed   better  than  government-­‐owned  banks.  The  study  even  showed  that  differences  in   performance  were  more  related  to  the  national  regulations  and  economic  environment   in  which  banks  operate,  instead  of  ownership.    

 

An  interesting  exception    

As  followed  from  the  results  of  the  different  articles  above,  most  empirical  

(17)

less  efficiently.  According  to  Altunbas  (2001)  this  empirical  evidence  was  especially   found  in  non-­‐financial  firms  and  non-­‐competitive  markets.  However  Altunbas  (2001)   criticizes  this  view  when  applying  it  to  financial  firms  and  tries  to  show  that  public   financial  banks  in  a  competitive  market  do  not  necessarily  need  to  underperform  in   comparison  with  private  financial  firms.  He  investigated  separate  cost  and  alternative   profit  frontiers  (stochastic  frontier  analysis)  for  three  different  owner  types  in  the   German  banking  period  between  1989-­‐1996:  privately  owned  banks,  state-­‐owned  banks   and  mutual  cooperative  banks.  The  sample  consists  of  1195  private  banks  observations,   2858  public  bank  observations  and  3486  mutual  cooperative  bank  observations.  The   breakdown  of  these  banks  is  helped  by  the  detailed  classification  by  the  Deutsche   Bundesbank.  We  focus  only  on  the  differences  between  public  and  state-­‐owned  banks.   Inefficiency  differences  are  measured  using  the  stochastic-­‐frontier  approach  and  the   distribution-­‐free  approach.  The  stochastic-­‐frontier  approach  classifies  a  bank  as   inefficient  if  its  costs  are  higher,  or  profits  lower,  than  predicted  by  an  efficient  bank   producing  the  same  input/output  combination  and  where  the  difference  cannot  be   explained  by  statistical  noise.  The  cost  or  alternative  profit  frontier  is  derived  by  

estimating  a  cost  or  alternative  profit  function  with  a  composite  error  term,  the  sum  of  a   two-­‐sided  error  term  representing  random  fluctuations  in  cost  and  profit  and  a  one-­‐ sided  positive  error  term  representing  efficiency  (Altunbas,  2001).    

Altunbas’  results  show  that  there  is  little  to  suggest  that  privately  owned  banks   are  more  efficient  than  state-­‐owned  banks  in  the  German  banking  world.  Both  

ownership  forms  benefit  from  economies  of  scale  and  it  seems  that  larger  banks  seem  to   realize  greater  economies  of  scale  than  smaller  banks.  The  inefficiency  measures  show   that  public  banks  tend  to  have  slight  cost  and  profit  advantages  compared  to  the  private   banking  counterparts.  This  may  be  explained  by  lower  cost  of  funds.  The  findings  show   that  there  are  no  agency  problems  for  public  banks  operating  in  the  German  banking   market.  This  German  example  shows  that  public  banks  in  a  market  economy  with  a   stable  and  democratic  government  and  a  good  governance  system  can  be  more   profitable.  

 

3.3-­  Difference  in  Lending  Behaviour,  due  to  elections  or  political  invectives  

(18)

Some  articles  have  found  evidence  that  state-­‐owned  banks  have  different  lending   behaviours  than  private  banks.  As  politicians  choose  managers  of  state-­‐owned  banks,   differences  in  lending  behaviour  may  be  due  to  elections  or  other  political  incentives   (Sapienza  2002  and  Dinc  2005).    

 

Bank  ownership  and  lending  behaviour  in  Italy    

According  to  Sapienza  (2002)  looking  at  bank  performance  is  not  the  appropriate  way   to  value  the  differences  between  state-­‐owned  and  privately  owned  banks.  As  most   empirical  evidence  shows  that  government  ownership  is  less  profitable,  it  is  not  clear  if   this  is  because  state-­‐owned  banks  maximize  broader  social  objectives,  or  that  they  have   lower  incentives  to  maximize  profit  or  because  they  inefficiently  give  in  to  political   wishes.  Instead  of  focusing  on  bank  performance,  Sapienza  (2002)  focuses  on  the   lending  behaviour  of  banks  in  correlation  with  ownership  structure.  The  data  used  to   determine  differences  in  lending  behaviour  include  information  on  the  balance  sheets   and  income  statements  of  more  than  37  000  companies  in  Italy.  This  data  comes  from   “Centrale  der  Bilanci”,  an  institution  created  to  provide  its  members,  which  are  mainly   banks,  with  economic  and  financial  information  for  screening  Italian  companies.  The   information  in  this  database  has  proven  to  be  very  precise  in  predicting  the  chances  of   success  for  a  company.  As  both  state-­‐owned  and  privately  owned  banks  use  this   information,  any  difference  in  credit  policy  is  more  likely  to  reflect  differences  in  the   objectives  of  the  banks,  instead  of  differences  in  the  evaluation  skills.  

  Sapienza  (2002)  looks  at  the  individual  loan  contracts  of  the  two  types  of  banks   and  compares  the  interest  rates  charged  to  two  different  companies  with  the  same   score,  where  one  borrows  from  an  state-­‐owned  bank  and  the  other  from  a  privately   owned  bank.  The  main  result  is  that  when  controlled  for  firm  and  bank  characteristics,   state-­‐owned  banks  charge  interest  rates  that  are  44  basic  points  lower  than  interest   rates  charged  by  comparable  privately  owned  banks.  First  is  tested  whether  these   results  can  be  explained  by  the  social  view.  As  earlier  mentioned  Sapienza  (2002)   explains  that  according  to  the  social  view  state-­‐owned  firms  are  created  to  overcome   market  failures,  whenever  the  social  benefits  of  state-­‐owned  firms  exceed  the  costs.  In   this  view  state-­‐owned  banks  improve  economic  development  and  improve  general   welfare.  The  hypothesis,  that  state-­‐owned  banks  lend  to  firms  for  which  borrowing  from  

(19)

private  banks  is  too  difficult  or  too  expensive,  is  rejected.  When  the  sample  is  restricted   to  firms  that  borrow  both  from  state-­‐owned  and  privately  owned  banks  still  a  lower   interest  rate  of  44  basic  points  is  found  at  state-­‐owned  banks.  Second,  companies   located  in  the  south  of  Italy  benefit  more  from  state-­‐owned  companies  than  companies   located  in  the  north,  which  can  be  due  to  the  fact  that  political  patronage  is  more   common  in  the  south  (supporting  the  political  view),  or  because  of  the  fact  that  the   south  is  poorer  and  the  government  wants  to  channel  funds  to  this  depressed  area   (supporting  the  social  view).  As  earlier  mentioned  according  to  the  political  view,  

politicians  who  control  banks  would  use  their  power  over  banks  to  win  votes,  instead  of   focusing  on  efficiency  and  maximizing  profit.  State-­‐owned  banks  would  give  jobs  or   financial  resources  to  friends  and  political  supporters.  As  state-­‐owned  banks  tend  to   favour  especially  large  firms,  the  social  view  is  rejected.    

Finally,  to  give  more  evidence  for  the  political  view,  Sapienza  (2002)  examined   the  relationship  between  interest  rates,  political  affiliation  of  the  bank  and  electoral   results.  The  relationship  between  objectives  of  politicians  and  the  lending  behaviour  of   banks  is  investigated  by  collecting  data  on  the  political  preferences  of  the  top  executives   of  the  state-­‐owned  banks.  The  results  show  that  the  lending  behaviour  is  indeed  affected   by  the  electoral  results  of  the  party  affiliated  with  the  bank.  The  party  affiliation  of  the   top  executives  of  state  owned  banks  come  with  a  lower  interest  rate  given  by  state-­‐ owned  banks  in  the  provinces,  where  this  associated  party  is  stronger.  Overall  these   results  support  the  political  view  of  state-­‐ownership  of  banks  and  so  suggest  that  state-­‐ ownership  goes  along  with  political  arbitrage  (Sapienza,  2002).    

 

Effect  of  bank  ownership  on  lending  behaviour  of  different  countries      

Dinc  (2005)  also  investigated  the  political  influences  on  government-­‐owned   banks  in  lending  behaviour.  In  comparison  with  Sapienza  (2002),  this  article  considers   many  different  countries;  so  that  its  results  have  more  diverse  support.    

Rather  than  looking  at  the  differences  in  interest  rates  charged,  which  followed  from   Sapienza  (2002),  he  looked  at  the  absolute  increases  in  lending  behaviour  due  to  

political  influences.  Dinc  (2005)  wanted  to  know  if  the  actions  of  banks  are  motivated  by   political  concerns,  given  that  politicians  control  state-­‐owned  banks.  During  elections   politicians  especially  might  use  their  power  to  use  state-­‐owned  banks  for  political  

(20)

purposes.  If  so,  these  state-­‐owned  banks  would  increase  their  lending  in  election  years,   so  this  is  investigated.  Actions  of  state-­‐owned  banks  and  private  banks  around  elections   are  compared  in  major  emerging  markets  over  the  period  1994-­‐2000.    

To  isolate  the  effect  of  difference  in  ownership  from  macroeconomic  factors  and   bank  specific  factors,  three  major  issues  need  to  be  considered.  First,  an  event  needed  to   be  identified,  in  which  politicians  may  use  state-­‐owned  banks  for  their  own  political   goals.  General  elections  were  used  as  an  event  that  could  trigger  politicians  to  influence   state-­‐owned  banks  to  increase  their  chances  of  re-­‐election.  Second,  institutional  

differences  across  countries  are  controlled  for  by  taking  a  firm-­‐level,  instead  of  a  

country-­‐level  analysis.  As  banks  are  compared  with  each  other  within  the  same  country,   it  is  possible  to  control  for  many  institutional  differences  across  countries.  Lastly,  

previously  documented  differences  in  efficiency  must  be  accounted  for,  so  that  political   actions  of  state-­‐owned  banks  can  be  distinguished  from  other  differences  between  state-­‐ owned  and  privately  owned  banks.  This  is  done  by  comparing  changes  in  actions  of   state-­‐owned  banks  compared  to  private  banks  around  election  years,  relative  to  other   years.    

The  cross-­‐country  analysis  strengthens  the  results,  as  elections  occur  in  different   years  in  different  countries.  This  prevents  a  correlation  pattern  between  elections  and   some  other  time-­‐events  in  the  world.  The  sample  contains  43  countries,  who  all  have   free  or  partially-­‐  free  elections,  so  therefore  countries  as  China,  Egypt  and  Indonesia   were  left  out  of  the  sample.  The  ten  largest  banks  in  each  country  were  examined,  with   the  requirement  that  the  country  contains  both  state-­‐owned  and  privately  owned  banks   (so  the  U.S.  was  left  out,  Dinc,  2005).  

    The  results  show  that  state-­‐owned  banks  increase  their  lending  in  election  years   relative  to  private  banks.  State-­‐owned  banks  increase  their  lending  with  about  11%   compared  to  their  average  lending  amount  during  the  election-­‐year.    In  this  way   politicians  were  able  to  distribute  rents  to  their  supporters.  Also  the  share  of  

government  securities  on  the  balance  sheet  is  50%  greater  in  government-­‐owned  banks   in  emerging  markets  than  in  private  banks.  These  facts  indicate  that  political  incentives   influence  the  actions  taken  by  state-­‐owned  banks  and  cannot  be  attributed  to  other   differences  between  private  banks  and  state-­‐owned  banks  (Dinc,  2005).  However,  the   results  fail  to  find  an  identical  election-­‐year  increase  in  developed  economies.  According   to  Dinc  (2005)  this  can  be  due  to  several  factors.  State-­‐owned  banks  in  developed  

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

As a contribution to the existing literature, this thesis extensively investigates the impact of the two determinants (regulatory pressure and the business cycle) on the

The real GDP and consumer price index (CPI) data are obtained from the International Monetary Fund (IMF) database, whereas the real broad effective exchange rate

It confirms the results obtained with a constructed synthetic domestic-owned sample of banks by individually verifying the effect of CRD on two groups of (foreign- and

With the following components: total private equity investment activity, total venture capital investment activity, buyout investment activity, and bank lending to

The results confirmed the expected relation between the market value (measured using the market price to book ratio) and the credit rating, as well as relations between the CR

The focus in this thesis is on the potential role of a bank in the matchmaking process; on how banks can have a positive influence on the business angel market by

I am mainly interested in the regressions with the Z-Score and Risk as dependent variable because Intangibles as risk-taking proxy did not provide valuable insights

One possible explanation is that banks that are supported during the crisis and still have to repay the state support, and are busy with restructuring the bank, while