• No results found

The Single Resolution Board Promoting Market Discipline in the European Banking Sector

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "The Single Resolution Board Promoting Market Discipline in the European Banking Sector"

Copied!
29
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

 

 

 

 

 

The  Single  Resolution  Board  Promoting  Market    

Discipline  in  the  European  Banking  Sector  

 

 

Author  

Kirsten  van  de  Grift  

10371915  

 

Supervisor  

Prof.  Dr.  A.C.J.F.  Houben  

 

University  of  Amsterdam  

Msc  Economics  

Monetary  Policy  and  Banking  

July  2018  

            Keywords  

(2)

 

 

 

Abstract  

In   light   of   the   debate   on   ‘too   big   to   fail’   in   the   European   banking   sector,   this   thesis   explores   the   effect   of   the   ‘too   big   to   fail’   concept   on   market   discipline   in   the   bond   market.  Analysis  of  bonds  of  nineteen  banks  shows  weakened  market  discipline  when  a   bank   is   considered   systemically   important   or   ‘too   big   to   fail’.   The   Single   Resolution   Board   has   been   established   to   strengthen   market   discipline,   but   results   show   no   significant  success  in  strengthening  market  discipline.  First,  the  legal  framework  and  the   credibility  of  the  resolution  process  have  to  be  improved.    

   

   

Statement  of  originality  

This  document  is  written  by  Kirsten  van  de  Grift  who  declares  to  take  full  responsibility   for  the  contents  of  this  document.    

I  declare  that  the  text  and  the  work  presented  in  this  document  are  original  and  that  no   sources   other   than   those   mentioned   in   the   text   and   its   references   have   been   used   in   creating   it.   The   Faculty   of   Economics   and   Business   is   responsible   solely   for   the   supervision  of  completion  of  the  work,  not  for  the  contents.    

(3)

Table  of  Contents  

                       

1. Introduction                   4  

2. Literature  Review                 5  

2.1 Market  Discipline  in  the  Banking  Sector         5  

2.2 Too  Big  to  Fail                 7  

2.3 The  Single  Resolution  Board             10  

2.4 Resolution  Cases               12  

2.5 Quantification  of  Implicit  Subsidies           13  

3. Methodology                   16  

3.1 Model  1:  Too  Big  to  Fail             16  

3.2 Model  2:  Too  Big  to  Fail  and  the  Bank-­‐Sovereign  Nexus       17  

3.3 Sample                   18  

3.4 Preparation  of  the  Dataset             18  

4. Results                   19  

4.1 Descriptive  Statistics               19  

4.2 Too  Big  to  Fail  and  Market  Discipline           19  

4.3 The  Single  Resolution  Board  and  Market  Discipline       21  

4.4 The  Bank-­‐Sovereign  Nexus  and  Market  Discipline       22  

5. Conclusion                   25   References                   27   Appendix                     29                                            

(4)

1. Introduction    

“The  public  will  not,  and  should  not,  accept  more  bailouts.  Addressing  the  problem  of   ‘too  big  to  fail’  is  therefore  the  next  central  step  in  the  reform  programme,”  declared   Mario  Draghi  in  September  2010,  at  that  time  chairman  of  the  Financial  Stability  Board.   Two  years  after  the  onset  of  the  Global  Financial  Crisis,  many  large  European  banks   failed  and  were  saved  by  governments.  Financial  markets  anticipated  on  the  

government  guarantees  and  came  to  believe  that  major  financial  institutions,  labelled  as   systemically  important,  would  be  bailed  out  in  case  of  default.  The  ‘too  big  to  fail’  belief   subsequently  reduced  the  urge  of  markets  to  monitor  and  discipline  banks  by  charging   risk  in  their  credit  prices.  In  other  words,  banks  received  an  implicit  subsidy  and  market   discipline  in  the  banking  sector  weakened.  A  key  question  is  whether  large  banks  still   receive  a  funding  advantage,  not  because  they  are  safer,  but  because  they  are  bigger.  In   this  thesis,  the  ‘too  big  to  fail’  problem  is  examined  by  testing  the  following  hypothesis:  

   

Market  discipline  in  the  European  banking  sector  is  lower  for  systemically  important   banks.  

 

Market  discipline  is  a  key  objective  to  the  Basel  Committee  on  Banking  Supervision;   Pillar  3  of  the  Basel  requirements  explicitly  aims  at  strengthening  market  discipline.  In   response  to  the  many  bailouts  of  banks  in  the  Global  Financial  Crisis,  the  European   Commission  established  the  Single  Resolution  Board  (SRB).  The  aim  of  the  SRB  is  to   reduce  the  number  of  bank  bailouts  in  the  European  Union  and  thereby  strengthen   market  discipline  in  the  European  banking  sector.  To  see  if  the  establishment  of  the  SRB   helped  to  reach  the  objective  of  more  market  discipline,  the  following  hypothesis  is  also   tested:    

 

Market  discipline  in  the  European  banking  sector  has  increased  since  the  establishment  of   the  Single  Resolution  Board.    

   

In  this  thesis,  the  hypotheses  are  empirically  tested  supported  by  an  overview  of  the   related  theoretical  and  empirical  literature.  Two  models  are  constructed  to  empirically   test  for  the  effect  of  systemic  importance  of  banks  on  their  bond  spreads.  The  first   model  includes  bond,  bank  and  macroeconomic  control  variables,  the  second  also   accounts  for  the  bank-­‐sovereign  nexus.  For  both  models,  the  effect  of  systemic  

(5)

importance  on  bond  spreads  before  and  after  July  2014  is  compared  to  see  if  the   establishment  of  the  SRB  improved  market  discipline.      

  Results  suggest  market  discipline  in  the  European  banking  sector  is  indeed  

lower  for  systemically  important  banks  as  they  enjoy  lower  bond  spreads  compared  to   other  banks.  The  establishment  of  the  Single  Resolution  Board  did  not  convincingly   improve  market  discipline.  Only  for  very  systemically  important  banks,  market  

discipline  strengthened.  For  less  systemically  important  banks,  no  significant  difference   is  found.  To  further  strengthen  market  discipline,  the  legal  framework  and  credibility  of   the  resolution  process  have  to  be  improved.    

  In  this  thesis,  the  existing  literature  on  market  discipline  will  first  be  discussed.  

This  includes  literature  on  market  discipline  in  the  banking  sector,  the  ‘too  big  to  fail’   concept,  the  Single  Resolution  Board,  resolution  cases  and  the  quantification  of  implicit   subsidies.  Second,  in  the  methodology  the  two  models  used  to  test  the  hypotheses,  the   sample  features  and  the  preparation  of  the  dataset  will  be  described.  The  third  

paragraph  will  cover  descriptive  statistics,  the  results  and  the  analysis.  The  last   paragraph  will  present  the  conclusion  including  a  summary  of  the  results,  policy   implications  and  suggestions  for  further  research.  

 

2. Literature  Review    

2.1  Market  Discipline  in  the  Banking  Sector  

Market  discipline  in  the  banking  sector  is  described  as  a  situation  in  which  agents  face   costs  that  increase  with  banks’  exposure  to  risks  (Berger,  1991).  Bank  risk  can  arise  in   several  ways,  alongside  each  other  or  reinforcing  each  other,  being  (1)  credit  risk,  when   a  bank’s  creditors  do  not  meet  their  obligations;  (2)  operational  risk,  the  risk  of  losses   resulting  from  failed  processes,  people  and  systems,  either  internal  or  from  external   events;  (3)  market  risk,  the  risk  of  losses  due  to  movement  in  market  prices;  (4)   liquidity  risk,  the  risk  of  a  bank’s  inability  to  meet  its  cash  flow  obligations;  (5)  

reputational  risk,  the  risk  of  a  loss  in  a  bank’s  reputation,  which  may  be  triggered  by  a   bank’s  activities  or  by  rumours  and  (6)  systemic  risk,  which  will  be  explained  in   paragraph  2.2.  Also,  management  may  take  on  more  risk  because  the  bank  lacks  good   internal  risk  controls  or  because  they  know  someone  else  will  have  to  face  the  burden,   commonly  known  as  moral  hazard.  When  costs  increase  due  to  an  increase  in  risk,   agents  take  action.  Agents  can  be  equity  holders,  depositors  and  debt  holders.  For   example,  an  uninsured  depositor  may  withdraw  her  deposits  in  response  to  excessive  

(6)

risk  taking.  This  can  lead  to  a  loss  in  customers  and  business,  forcing  the  bank  to  change   its  strategy.  

  According  to  the  Basel  Committee  on  Banking  Supervision  “market  discipline  

imposes  strong  incentives  on  banks  to  conduct  business  in  a  safe,  sound  and  efficient   manner”.  The  Committee  underlines  several  benefits  to  effective  market  discipline  in  the   banking  sector  (Pillar  3  (Market  Discipline),  2001).  First,  it  can  reduce  moral  hazard  as  a   bank  is  punished  when  taking  on  too  much  risk,  which  creates  an  incentive  to  limit  risk   taking.  Second,  it  can  make  the  banking  sector  more  efficient  when  agents  force  an   inefficient  bank  to  become  more  efficient  or  to  leave  the  market  (Soledad,  Peria  &   Schmukler,  2001).    

  For  market  discipline  to  be  effective,  agents  should  be  able  to  monitor  and  

influence  the  market  (Bliss  &  Flannery,  2002).    To  be  able  to  monitor,  market  prices   should  be  a  reflection  of  the  bank’s  exposures  to  risks  (Gorton  &  Santomero,  1990).  To   be  able  to  influence  the  market,  agents  should  have  either  direct  or  indirect  influence   (Flannery,  2001).  Agents  can  directly  discipline  banks  when  causing  changes  in  market   prices  that  increase  funding  costs  to  banks.  Agents  can  indirectly  discipline  banks  when   influenced  market  prices  have  a  signalling  function  to  regulators,  investors  and  policy   makers  regarding  the  condition  of  a  bank.  

Different  agents  can  discipline  banks.  The  most  commonly  mentioned  are   depositors.  With  the  introduction  of  deposit  guarantee  schemes,  the  incentive  to   discipline  is  limited  for  depositors.  In  the  European  Union,  deposits  up  to  €100.000  are   guaranteed.  However,  small  depositors  exerting  market  discipline  is  not  necessarily   desirable.  Often,  depositors  do  not  consider  all  information  available  when  choosing  a   bank,  for  instance  because  they  care  more  about  services  offered  by  a  bank  than  its   solvency  (Garten,  1995).  Market  discipline  by  depositors  also  implies  high,  inefficient,   search  costs.  Moreover,  depositor  discipline  can  be  destabilizing  as  depositors  can   create  bank  runs  with  large  negative  externalities,  even  when  a  bank  is  solvent.   Therefore,  depositors  are  not  the  preferred  discipliners  of  banks.    

The  second  group  of  discipliners,  equity  holders,  are  important  discipliners  as   they  have  a  stake  in  the  bank  and  have  the  residual  claim  in  case  of  default.  They  have   the  power  to  influence  management,  for  example  in  the  likelihood  of  managerial   turnover  (De  Ceuster  &  Masschelein,  2003).  On  the  other  hand,  they  are  also  

incentivized  to  take  on  more  risk,  as  they  benefit  the  most  from  upside  gains  (Gropp,   Vesala  &  Vulpes,  2006).  For  this  reason,  equity  holders  are  not  the  preferred  group  of   discipliners  either.    

(7)

Debt  holders  represent  the  third  group  of  discipliners.  Debt  holders  are  focused   on  the  downside  risks  of  banks  and  are  therefore  much  more  aligned  with  the  interests   of  bank  supervisors  and  appropriate  discipliners  (Morgan  &  Stiroh,  2001)  .  Debt  holders   require  different  bond  spreads  when  risk  changes,  thereby  influencing  borrowing  costs   and  disciplining  the  banks.      

Morgan  and  Stiroh  (1999)  argued  that  the  bond  market  prices  bank  risk   efficiently.  They  found  evidence  that  suggests  that  investors  even  look  beyond  public   measures  of  risk,  such  as  the  underlying  portfolio  of  loans,  in  pricing  a  bank’s  risk   exposure.  The  research  conclusions  of  Flannery  (2000)  and  Evanoff  and  Wall  (2001)  on   the  effectiveness  of  the  bond  market  are  aligned.  According  to  them,  the  bond  market   indicators  are  usually  more  accurate  than  supervisory  assessments.  However,  Bliss   (2001)  showed  that  bond  yield  spreads  are  noisy  measures  of  risk,  even  though  the   noise  is  not  random.  Moreover,  Gropp  et  al.  (2006)  stressed  that  the  debt  market  is  hard   to  measure  consistently  due  to  varying  maturities  and  tax  treatments.  When  controlling   for  these  measurement  difficulties,  the  bond  market  is  a  good  market  to  measure  market   discipline  and  is  therefore  the  focus  of  this  thesis.    

 

2.2 Too  Big  to  Fail  

In  the  last  two  decades,  the  process  of  technological  innovation  and  consolidation  in  the   banking  industry  lead  to  larger  banks.  In  Figure  2.1,  asset  growth  of  the  top  global   systemically  important  banks  as  of  November  2013  is  shown  (IMF,  2014).  The  banks  all   grew  exponentially  after  1997,  even  after  the  Global  Financial  Crisis.  Only  Citigroup  did   not  grow  larger  after  2007.  They  suffered  substantial  losses  in  the  crisis  and  received   state  support  in  2008.  Large  banks  can  be  ‘too  big  to  fail’  because  the  damaging  effects  of   failure  are  larger  than  that  of  other  corporates  or  smaller  banks;  it  brings  along  systemic   risk.  Systemic  risk  is  the  risk  of  financial  instability  caused  by  the  collapse  of  a  major   part,  or  all  of  the  financial  system  with  potentially  negative  consequences  for  the  real   economy.    

Systemic  risk  can  arise  in  several  ways.  First,  banks  are  subject  to  contagion   risks.  Contagion  risk  is  the  risk  of  many  banks  failing  in  response  to  one  large  bank   failing,  even  if  the  other  banks  were  solvent  before.  Banks  are  subject  to  this  risk   because  they  operate  based  on  public  trust  (European  Commission,  2014).  If  trust  in  a   large  bank  is  lost,  this  can  result  in  the  loss  of  confidence  in  other  banks  too.  Moreover,   banks  are  often  highly  interconnected.  Cross-­‐border  banking  claims  have  increased   substantially,  reaching  more  than  50%  of  global  GDP  in  2007  (Figure  2.2).  This   phenomenon  was  driven  by  worldwide  deregulation  and  innovation  of  the  banking  

(8)

sector.  Linkages  have  decreased  to  around  30%  of  global  GDP  in  the  process  of  bank   deleveraging  and  restructuring  since  the  crisis.  Due  to  these  linkages,  a  failing  bank  can   financially  harm  other  banks  if  they  are  exposed  to  each  other.  Second,  systemic  risk  can   arise  because  banks  perform  a  critical  function  in  the  economy.  They  allocate  savings  to   investments  for  both  households  and  firms  and  they  manage  payment  systems  to   various  sectors  in  the  economy  and  society.  When  a  large  bank  fails,  these  functions  are   lost  to  the  customers.    

 

Figure 2.1 Total Assets of Large Banks Figure 2.2 Cross-Border Banking Linkages

(in billions of US Dollars) (as a Percentage of Global GDP)

Source: IMF Global Financial Stability Report (2014) Source: IMF Global Financial Stability Report (2014)  

There  are  multiple  indicators  of  systemic  importance.  The  most  significant   indicator  of  systemic  importance  is  size  (Adrian  &  Brunnermeier,  2011).  When  a  bank   has  a  large  amount  of  assets  on  its  balance  sheet,  the  bank  is  most  likely  systemically   important.  Deutsche  Bank  AG,  a  very  systemically  important  bank,  had  2.164,1  billion  in   assets  at  the  beginning  of  2012,  relative  to  Banca  Carige  Italia  SpA  with  44,86  billion  in   assets  at  the  beginning  of  2012.  Another  measure  of  systemic  importance  is  based  on  a   list  of  systemically  important  banks  developed  by  the  Financial  Stability  Board  (2017).   The  FSB  determined  systemic  importance  based  on  five  indicators,  all  given  an  equal   weight  of  20%.  The  indicators  are  size,  global  (cross-­‐jurisdictional)  activity,  

interconnectedness,  substitutability  and  complexity.  Systemically  important  banks  were   allocated  to  different  buckets  corresponding  to  the  required  level  of  additional  capital   buffers,  ranging  from  no  additional  capital  buffer  (Caixabank  SA)  to  3,5%  additional   capital  buffer  (bucket  5).  Deutsche  Bank  AG  is  the  European  bank  with  the  highest  

(9)

required  additional  capital  buffer,  namely  2%  (bucket  3).  The  Financial  Stability  Board   assigned  only  very  large  and  systemically  important  banks  to  one  of  the  buckets  and   thereby  set  a  clear  threshold.  The  European  Central  Bank  (ECB)  for  instance  set  a  much   lower  threshold.  The  ECB  conducted  a  list  with  significant  entities  that  are  under  the   direct  supervision  of  the  ECB.  This  list  is  based  on  a  bank’s  size,  economic  importance,  

cross-­‐border  activities  and  direct  public  financial  assistance  (Criteria  for  determining  

significance  section,  para.  1).  Whereas  the  list  by  the  Financial  Stability  Board  only   consists  of  seven  EU  banks  (excluding  British  banks),  the  list  by  the  European  Central   Bank  consists  of  119  significant  entities.  To  illustrate  the  difference,  the  European   Central  Bank  did  label  Caixabank  SA  as  a  significant  entity.  The  focus  of  this  thesis  is  on   ‘too  big  to  fail’  in  terms  of  size  and  the  buckets  of  the  FSB.  The  banks  on  the  list  of  the   ECB  are  not  all  ‘too  big  to  fail’,  as  some  of  these  banks  were  (supposed  to  be)  wound  up   in  the  past  under  the  supervision  of  national  authorities.  For  this  reason,  the  focus  of   this  thesis  is  not  on  the  list  of  the  ECB.    

The  origins  of  the  ‘too  big  to  fail’  problem  date  back  to  1972,  when  the  Bank  of   the  Commonwealth  was  bailed  out  for  1,2  billion  dollars  by  the  Federal  Reserve   (Nurisso  &  Prescott,  2017).  The  bailout  finally  lead  to  the  belief  that  large  banks  were   ‘too  big  to  fail’  and  governments  would  bail  out  these  banks  in  case  of  insolvency.  Prior   to  the  Global  Financial  Crisis,  policy  makers  tried  to  address  this  problem  by  acting   ambiguous  about  the  willingness  to  save  failing  banks  (IMF,  2014).  However,  little   uncertainty  was  left  about  the  willingness  to  save  failing  banks  when  many  large  banks   like  ABN-­‐Amro  and  Commerzbank  were  bailed  out  during  the  Global  Financial  Crisis.   Even  though  the  bailouts  may  have  been  necessary,  they  were  costly  for  several  reasons   too.    

First,  the  level  of  state  support  given  to  save  the  banks  was  extremely  high  in   some  countries  and  paid  with  taxpayers’  money  at  the  expense  of  other  possible  public   expenditures  (European  Commission,  2014).  Second,  the  bailouts  partially  instigated   the  bank-­‐sovereign  nexus  in  some  European  countries.  Large  guarantees  given  to  failing   banks  contributed  to  the  build  up  of  sovereign  debt  problems,  in  Europe  eventually   leading  to  the  Sovereign  Debt  Crisis.  High  indebtedness  of  sovereigns  creates  

uncertainty  if  governments  will  be  able  to  save  banks  in  case  of  failure.  The  uncertainty   jeopardizes  bank  stability  and  magnifies  the  anticipated  need  for  and  the  cost  of  public   intervention  in  the  banking  sector.  This  in  turn  further  deteriorates  the  sovereign’s  debt   position,  setting  in  motion  a  feedback  loop  between  sovereign  and  bank  stability  (the   bank-­‐sovereign  nexus).  The  Irish  crisis  of  2008  is  a  strong  example  of  the  mechanism  of   a  bank-­‐sovereign  nexus  (European  Central  Bank,  2017).    

(10)

A  more  indirect  cost  of  a  bailout  is  related  to  market  discipline.  When  banks  are   considered  ‘too  big  to  fail’  and  a  bailout  is  very  likely,  market  discipline  weakens  

(Cubillas,  Fernández  &  González,  2017;  Gropp  et  al.,  2006;  Morgan  &  Stiroh,  1999).  First,   the  expectations  of  state  support  are  incorporated  in  the  credit  spreads  of  these  banks   (Acharya,  Anginer  &  Warburton,  2013).  Second,  the  costs  of  monitoring  and  taking   action  against  a  bank  rise  relative  to  the  benefits,  as  creditors  don’t  lose  (all)  their   money  in  case  the  bank  fails.    Subsequently,  systemically  important  banks  pay  a  lower   price  for  risk  than  other  banks  or  financial  institutions  and  are  not  monitored  as  much.   The  perception  of  ‘too  big  to  fail’  provides  the  banks  with  an  implicit  subsidy  and   encourages  risk-­‐taking,  not  because  they  are  safer,  but  because  they  are  bigger.    

   

2.3 The  Single  Resolution  Board  

In  response  to  the  many  bailouts  during  the  Global  Financial  Crisis  and  the  negative   externalities  that  followed,  policymakers  brought  about  financial  reforms.  Amongst  the   reforms  are  higher  capital  requirements  and  strengthened  supervision  of  banks  to  limit   the  probability  and  cost  of  failure  and  contagion,  but  also  a  stronger  resolution  

framework  (IMF,  2014).  In  the  European  Union,  the  Bank  Recovery  and  Resolution  

Directive  (BRRD)  and  the  Single  Resolution  Mechanism  Regulation  (SRMR)  were   adopted  in  2014.  The  BRRD  provides  authorities  with  arrangements  to  deal  with  failing   banks  at  national  level  and  to  tackle  cross-­‐border  banking  failures.  Also  it  requires   banks  to  prepare  recovery  plans  to  deal  with  financial  distress  (Bank  recovery  and   resolution  section,  para.  2).  The  SRMR  constitutes  the  resolution  framework  of  banks  in   EU  countries  participating  in  the  banking  union  (Single  Resolution  Mechanism  section,   para.  1).  The  Single  Resolution  Board  (SRB)  has  responsibility  for  the  enforcement  of  the   SRMR  and  has  been  operational  as  an  independent  European  Union  Agency  since  

January  2015.    

Bank  resolution  is  a  controlled  approach  to  bank  failure  and  promotes  market   functioning.  Instead  of  managing  resolution  by  national  authorities,  the  higher  

integration  and  interconnectedness  of  banks  in  the  European  Union  called  for  a  common   framework  in  the  EU  (European  Commission,  2014).  In  this  framework,  the  SRB  gets  full   responsibility  for  the  resolution  of  a  bank  when  the  European  Central  Bank  decides  a   bank  is  “failing  or  likely  to  fail”.  The  aim  of  the  SRB  is  to  avoid  future  bailouts  and  to   place  the  costs  of  a  bank  resolution  on  the  shareholders  and  debt  holders  and  thereby   limit  the  costs  to  taxpayers  and  the  real  economy  (Single  Resolution  Mechanism  section,   para.  2).  When  resolution  is  effective,  both  shareholders  and  debt  holders  will  suffer   losses  in  case  of  default  (European  Commission,  2014).  Losses  strengthen  the  incentive  

(11)

to  discipline  banks  and  reduce  moral  hazard.  Subsequently,  risk  should  be  priced   correctly  in  the  markets.  

  If  a  bank  is  placed  under  resolution,  the  SRB  has  four  resolution  tools.  The  tools   are  intended  to  secure  public  interests,  including  the  continuity  of  a  bank’s  critical   functions  and  financial  stability,  all  at  minimal  cost  to  taxpayers.  Before  any  resolution   tool  is  set  into  motion,  a  bank’s  capital  has  to  be  written  down  or  converted.  The  first   resolution  tool  is  the  sale  of  business.  This  entails  the  total  or  partial  sale  of  the  bank  to   another  entity.  Assets  stay  in  the  banking  system  so  this  causes  little  disruption.  The   second  resolution  tool  is  the  bridge  institution.  Part  of  a  bank  is  then  transferred  to  a   temporary  (completely  or  partially)  publicly  owned  entity.  ‘Bad  assets’  are  separately   liquidated.  Third,  the  SRB  can  use  the  asset  separation  tool.  Assets,  rights  and  liabilities   are  transferred  to  an  asset  management  vehicle,  also  completely  or  partially  publicly   owned.  The  last  and  most  important  tool  is  the  bail-­‐in  tool,  which  is  provided  for  in  the   Bank  Recovery  and  Resolution  Directive.  Equity  and  debt  are  then  written  down  or   converted,  placing  the  costs  on  shareholders  and  debt  holders.  The  BRRD  clearly  states   which  liabilities  are  eligible  for  bail-­‐in  and  in  what  order.  However,  the  BRRD  also  states   that  ‘exceptional  circumstances’  exist  for  instruments.  The  resolution  authority  then  has   the  discretion  to  decide  if  an  instrument  is  eligible  for  bail-­‐in.  Which  instruments  are   exceptional  is  not  defined  however,  creating  uncertainty  and  room  for  different  bail-­‐in   procedures  among  member  states.  Huertas  (2016)  discussed  the  different  

implementations  of  the  BRRD  among  member  states  and  suggested  the  convergence   towards  one  creditor  hierarchy  for  banks  across  the  EU  or  at  least  EU-­‐wide  standards   for  what  circumstances  an  instrument  can  be  ‘exceptional’.    Phillipon  and  Salord  (2017)   recognized  the  same  problem  and  proposed  reduced  discretion  in  the  application  of  the   bail-­‐in  exceptions.  Another  problem  that  Huertas  mentioned  is  the  legal  enforceability  of   the  bail-­‐in  tool.  Systemically  important  banks  often  operate  globally.  When  instruments   are  issued  in  third  countries  (not  under  the  BRRD),  investors  may  seek  protection  from   a  court  in  the  third  country  to  prevent  the  bank  from  bailing  in  the  investor’s  liability.   The  BRRD  tackles  the  problem  by  requiring  banks  to  give  all  new  liabilities  eligible  for   bail-­‐in  the  right  contractual  terms  that  indicate  if  the  instrument  is  subject  to  write-­‐ down  or  conversion.  In  the  future,  this  requirement  will  give  the  resolution  authorities   the  rights  to  bail  in  every  eligible  liability.    

  In  the  EU  resolution  framework,  state  is  still  possible  if  it  qualifies  as  a   precautionary  measure.  Although  the  Single  Resolution  Board  is  not  involved  in   precautionary  recapitalizations,  Philippon  and  Salord  (2017)  argued  that  this  can   undermine  the  credibility  of  the  SRM.  They  suggested  reduced  discretion  as  the  

(12)

condition  of  granting  is  too  broadly  defined.  The  current  condition  of  granting  public   funds  is  “in  order  to  remedy  a  serious  disturbance  in  the  economy  of  a  Member  State   and  preserve  financial  stability”.  They  proposed  stricter  conditions,  including  

quantitative  and  qualitative  requirements.    

Several  event  studies  were  done  to  see  if  the  implementation  of  the  resolution   framework  alone  had  effect  on  market  discipline.  The  IMF  found  that  the  European   Commission’s  proposal  for  (not  the  adoption  of)  the  Single  Resolution  Mechanism  did   not  have  any  significant  effect  on  the  markets,  whereas  the  proposal  for  the  Bank  

Recovery  and  Resolution  Directive  did.

 

Schäfer,  Schnabel  and  Weder  di  Mauro  (2016)  

did  find  significant  differences  in  stock  prices  after  the  formal  agreement  of  the  Single   Resolution  Mechanism.  They  analyzed  stock  returns  and  CDS  spreads  of  EU  banks  after   bail-­‐in  events  and  the  implementation  of  the  Single  Resolution  Mechanism.  They  found   widespread  negative  effects  on  stock  returns  after  the  agreement  of  the  SRM,  with  a   stronger  effect  on  systemically  important  banks.  However,  the  market  response  was   much  smaller  than  for  the  response  to  actual  bank  failures.  They  concluded  that  the   success  of  the  Single  Resolution  Board  crucially  depends  on  the  handling  of  next   resolution  cases.  From  these  findings,  no  conclusions  can  be  drawn  upon  the  expected   effect  of  the  establishment  of  the  Single  Resolution  Board  on  market  discipline.      

2.4 Resolution  Cases  

In  the  United  States,  the  ‘too  big  to  fail’  problem  was  and  is  present  as  well.  Acharya  et   al.  (2013)  found  that  bondholders  of  major  financial  institutions  in  the  United  States  did   not  accurately  price  risk  because  they  expected  government  support  in  case  of  default.   The  United  States  government  acted  on  the  expectation  of  public  support  in  the  market   and  passed  the  Dodd-­‐Frank  Wall  Street  Reform  and  Consumer  Protection  Act  (‘The   Dodd-­‐Frank  Act’)  in  2010,  of  which  avoiding  future  bailouts  is  one  of  the  main   objectives.  Acharya  et  al.  (2013)  did  an  event  study  on  the  Dodd-­‐Frank  Act  to  see  if  it   strengthened  market  discipline.  They  found  that  the  passing  of  the  Act  did  not  eliminate   expectations  of  government  support  and  did  not  strengthen  market  discipline.  However,   Acharya  et  al.  (2013)  also  found  that  following  the  rescue  of  Bear  Stearns  in  March   2008,  before  the  Dodd-­‐Frank  Act  was  introduced,  larger  financial  institutions   experienced  a  greater  decrease  in  their  credit  spreads  than  smaller  institutions.  By   contrast,  after  the  collapse  of  Lehman  Brothers  in  September  2008,  larger  financial   institutions  experienced  a  greater  increase  in  their  credit  spreads  than  smaller  

institutions.  These  market  responses  show  that  the  expectation  of  government  support   in  the  United  States  influenced  market  discipline  for  large  institutions.  This  could  

(13)

indicate  that  the  passing  of  the  Dodd-­‐Frank  Act  did  not  in  itself  strengthen  market   discipline  because  credible  commitment  is  critical,  which  was  possibly  missing.  In  figure   2.3,  level  of  implicit  subsidies  to  systemically  important  banks  in  the  US  is  shown.  The   findings  of  Acharya  et  al.  (2013)  do  not  rule  out  the  second  hypothesis  of  this  thesis,   providing  that  the  Single  Resolution  Board  credibly  commits  to  its  objective.    

So  far,  the  Single  Resolution  Board  has  been  involved  in  three  resolution  cases.  

The  European  Central  Bank  decided  on  June  6th  2017  that  Banco  Popular  Español  S.A.  

was  failing  or  likely  to  fail  (Resolution  Cases  section,  para.  2).  The  next  day,  the  SRB  first   wrote  down  the  shares  of  Banco  Popular  Español  S.A.  and  converted  junior  debt  to   shares.  Thereafter,  the  SRB  transferred  all  shares  to  Banco  Santander  S.A..  Because  of   this,  Banco  Popular  Español  S.A.  could  continue  to  operate  under  normal  business   conditions.  The  second  resolution  case  concerned  Banca  Popolare  di  Vicenza  SpA  and   Veneto  Banca  SpA  in  June  2017.  The  SRB  decided  that  resolution  could  take  place  under   Italian  authority  (Resolution  Cases  section,  para.  3).  Under  their  authority  the  banks   were  supposed  to  be  wound  up.  However,  Italian  authorities  decided  that  the  winding   up  of  the  banks  would  have  a  serious  impact  on  the  real  economy  and  asked  the   European  Commission  for  approval  to  use  national  funds  to  facilitate  the  liquidation.   The  Commission  approved,  partially  because  shareholders  and  subordinated  debt   holders  contributed  to  the  costs.  The  approval  resulted  in  cash  injections  of  about   €4.785  billion  and  state  guarantees  of  about  €12  billion  (European  Commission,  2017).   Even  though  the  SRB  did  not  decide  on  state  aid,  the  fact  that  the  banks  received  state   aid  does  not  contribute  to  the  resolution  objectives  of  the  SRB.  Third,  the  European   Central  Bank  decided  on  February  23rd  2018  that  ABLV  Bank,  AS  and  its  subsidiary  

ABLV  Bank  Luxembourg  S.A  were  failing  or  likely  to  fail  (Resolution  Cases  section,  para.   5).  The  SRB  decided  that  ABLV  Bank,  AS  and  its  subsidiary  should  be  wound  up  under   national  authority.  The  bank  is  currently  in  the  process  of  liquidation.  Moreover,  in  July   2017,  Banca  Monte  dei  Paschi  di  Siena  was  precautionary  recapitalized  by  the  Italian   government.  Philippon  and  Salord  (2017)  argued  that  this  can  undermine  the  credibility   of  the  SRB  too,  even  though  the  SRB  is  not  directly  involved.    

 

2.5 Quantifications  of  Implicit  Subsidies  

Different  models  have  been  tested  and  used  to  quantify  the  effects  of  ‘too  big  to  fail’.  The   International  Monetary  Fund  (IMF)  approached  three  of  them  (IMF,  2014).  The  IMF   used  the  same  sample  for  all  three  approaches,  consisting  of  the  list  of  G-­‐SIBs  identified   by  the  Financial  Stability  Board  and  the  three  largest  banks  (by  asset  size)  in  each   country  (if  not  already  in  the  list  of  G-­‐SIBs).  The  first  approach  is  measurement  of  the  

(14)

bond  spread  differential  between  systemically  important  banks  and  other  banks.    The   IMF  used  this  method  and  found  the  results  shown  in  figure  2.3.  Since  the  Global   Financial  Crisis,  the  implicit  subsidies  have  fallen  significantly  for  the  United  States  and   to  a  lesser  extent  in  Japan  as  well.  For  Europe,  the  implicit  subsidy  has  been  positive  and   rising  since  the  Global  Financial  Crisis  until  around  2013,  reaching  a  peak  of  over  500   basis  points.  From  then  on,  it  has  been  falling  again.  According  to  the  IMF,  the  high   subsidies  in  the  Euro  Area  largely  reflect  the  Sovereign  Debt  Crisis.  The  shortcoming  of   the  bond  spread  differential  approach  is  that  it  does  not  consider  risk  characteristics  of   a  bank.  When  controlling  for  these  characteristics  of  banks  in  the  United  States,  results   prove  that  systemically  important  banks  did  enjoy  funding  advantages  after  the  crisis   (IMF,  2014).      

 

Figure 2.3 Bond Spread Differential between Systemically Important Banks and Other Banks (in basis points)

  Source: IMF Global Financial Stability Report (2014)

 

The  second  approach  is  the  contingent  claims  analysis  approach,  for  which   Credit  Default  Swap  Prices  are  used  to  measure  implicit  subsidies.  The  advantage  of  this   approach  is  that  it  controls  for  bank  characteristics.  However,  there  is  only  limited  CDS   data  available  and  it  may  not  be  reliable  in  case  of  a  market  turmoil.  Figure  2.4  shows  a   positive  trend  for  the  Euro  Area  too,  but  the  implicit  subsidy  estimations  are  

substantially  lower.  Since  2012,  implicit  subsidies  in  the  Euro  Area  have  averaged   around  90  basis  points,  whereas  the  results  of  the  first  approach  show  a  substantially   higher  average  subsidy.  The  results  of  the  second  approach  even  show  negative  implicit   subsidies  between  2011  and  2012.    

(15)

Figure 2.4 Mean Implicit Subsidy for Systemically Important Banks in the Euro Area Estimated with the Contingent Claims Analysis Approach (in basis points)

Source: IMF Global Financial Stability Report (2014)

The  ratings-­‐based  approach  is  the  third  approach.  In  this  approach,  the  IMF   made  use  of  the  fact  that  credit  rating  agencies  generally  take  a  government’s  implicit   guarantee  into  account  and  translated  the  rating  uplift  to  bond  spreads.  Like  the  second   approach,  this  approach  includes  bank  characteristics.  A  shortcoming  is  the  dependency   on  credit  rating  agencies  and  views  among  credit  rating  agencies  are  not  always  similar.   Also,  credit  ratings  adjust  very  slowly.  Figure  2.5  shows  the  results  for  the  Euro  Area.   The  results  again  show  positive  but  declining  implicit  subsidies  for  systemically   important  banks  since  the  peak  of  the  Global  Financial  Crisis.    This  applies  to  both   solvent  systemically  important  banks  and  systemically  important  banks  that  are  already   in  distress  (banks  with  positive  support).  Implicit  subsidies  never  turn  negative.  

   

Figure 2.5 Mean Implicit Subsidies in the Euro Area Derived from Credit Ratings (in basis points)

 

Source: IMF Global Financial Stability Report (2014)  

Even  though  the  results  of  the  IMF  show  different  values  for  the  different   approaches,  the  results  of  the  three  approaches  suggest  positive  average  subsidies  from  

(16)

2005  to  2014  for  systemically  important  banks  in  the  Euro  Area.  The  results  therefore   support  the  first  hypothesis  of  this  thesis.    

 

3.  Methodology

 

   

3.1 Model  1:  Too  Big  to  Fail    

In  this  thesis,  market  discipline  in  the  banking  sector  is  measured  by  examining  how   systemic  importance  (‘too  big  to  fail’)  affects  the  spread  of  a  bank’s  bonds.  Ordinary   Least  Squares  regressions  are  done  using  two  different  models,  following  the  first   quantification  approach  discussed  in  paragraph  2.4.  The  first  model  is  based  on  the   empirical  model  by  Acharya  et  al.  (2013):  

 

𝑆𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑!,!,! = 𝛼 + 𝛽!𝑇𝐵𝑇𝐹!,!+   𝛽!𝐵𝑜𝑛𝑑  𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠!,!,!+ 𝛽!𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘  𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠!,!

+ 𝛽!𝑀𝑎𝑐𝑟𝑜  𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠!,!+ 𝜖!,!,!  

 

The  subscripts  i,  b  and  t  denote  banks,  bonds  and  time  (in  months)  respectively.  Spread   is  a  specific  bond  spread,  which  is  the  difference  between  the  yield  on  the  bond  and  the   yield  on  the  corresponding  maturity-­‐matched  and  country-­‐specific  Treasury  bond.     When  there  is  no  Treasury  bond  exactly  matching  in  maturity,  the  closest  match  is  used.  

TBTF  stands  for  ‘too  big  to  fail’  and  represents  the  systemic  importance  of  a  bank.  As  

explained  in  the  literature  review,  there  are  several  ways  to  estimate  systemic  

importance.  In  this  thesis,  assets  (measured  in  logarithms)  and  the  buckets  developed   by  the  Financial  Stability  Board  are  used  to  measure  the  effect  of  systemic  importance   on  bond  spreads.  The  TBTF  measure  in  terms  of  assets  shows  a  continuous  range  in   systemic  importance  and  does  not  include  a  certain  threshold  separating  systemic  and   non-­‐systemic  banks.  The  Financial  Stability  Board  assigned  only  very  large  and  

systemically  important  banks  to  one  of  the  buckets  and  thereby  set  a  clear  threshold.   The  list  by  the  Financial  Stability  Board  only  consists  of  seven  banks  in  the  European   Union  (excluding  British  banks).  Both  measures  of  ‘too  big  to  fail’  are  tested  to  ensure   the  final  conclusions  are  robust.      

Bond  Controls  are  bond  specific  control  variables,  including  the  time  to  maturity  

in  years  and  the  seniority  of  the  issue.  The  time  to  maturity  and  the  seniority  of  a  bond   determine  the  risk  of  a  bond  and  thereby  the  bond  spread.  Therefore,  these  bond   controls  are  taken  into  account.  Contrary  to  the  approach  of  the  International  Monetary   Fund,  risk  characteristics  of  a  bank  are  included  in  this  model.  The  Bank  Controls  are  the   following  bank  specific  control  variables:  debt-­‐to-­‐equity  ratio,  return  on  assets,  price-­‐to-­‐ book  ratio  of  equity  and  the  maturity  mismatch.  The  bank  characteristics  influence  the  

(17)

likelihood  of  distress  and  therefore  the  risk  to  bondholders.  Macro  Controls  include  the   market  risk  premium,  which  is  the  difference  between  the  expected  return  on  a  risky   market  portfolio  and  the  risk-­‐free  rate.  The  other  two  macro  controls  are  the  yield   spread  between  long-­‐term  (10  year)  treasury  bonds  and  the  short-­‐term  (three-­‐month)   treasuries  as  a  measure  for  the  term  structure,  and  the  BAA-­‐AAA  corporate  bond  spread   as  a  proxy  for  default  risk.  Finally,  𝛼  represents  a  constant  and  𝜖!,!,!  the  error  term.  More   details  on  the  variables  are  given  in  Appendix  A.      

To  measure  if  the  establishment  of  the  Single  Resolution  Board  improved   market  discipline,  a  second  test  is  done.  In  this  test,  regression  results  of  the  first  model   are  compared,  one  with  data  from  before  July  2014  and  the  other  with  data  from  July   2014  onwards.  The  adoption  of  the  Single  Resolution  Mechanism  Regulation  is  used  as   the  establishment  date  instead  of  the  actual  establishment  of  the  Single  Resolution   Board  in  2015.  The  adoption  of  the  SRMR  meant  the  Single  Resolution  Board  was  going   to  come  with  certainty  and  it  gave  clarification  on  the  tools  of  the  Single  Resolution   Board.  It  is  expected  that  agents  anticipated  on  the  effect  of  an  operational  Single   Resolution  Board  once  the  Single  Resolution  Mechanism  Regulation  was  adopted.  In  the   regressions,  the  coefficients  of  the  two  measures  of  TBTF  are  compared  to  see  if  the   effect  of  systemic  importance  on  market  discipline  has  decreased  since  the  

establishment  of  the  SRB.    

   

3.2 Model  2:  Too  Big  to  Fail  and  the  Bank-­‐Sovereign  nexus  

In  case  of  a  highly  indebted  sovereign,  a  bank  guarantee  is  less  credible  and  effective.   Bondholders  may  see  their  position  as  more  risky  and  subsequently  might  ask  for  a   higher  return  on  their  bonds.  The  European  bank-­‐sovereign  nexus  may  therefore  have   strengthened  market  discipline  regardless  of  the  Single  Resolution  Mechanism  

Regulation.  Including  sovereign  debt  positions  into  a  second  model  can  possibly   improve  the  first  model,  especially  considering  the  countries  in  the  dataset,  ranging   from  Italy  with  a  weak  fiscal  position  to  the  Netherlands  with  a  strong  fiscal  position.   The  regressions  of  the  second  model  test  for  these  effects  and  at  the  same  time  test  for   the  validity  of  the  conclusions  that  are  drawn  from  the  regressions  based  on  the  first   model.    

  The  second  model  including  sovereign  debt  positions  is  constructed  as  follows:  

 

𝑆𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑!,!,! = 𝛼 + 𝛽!𝑇𝐵𝑇𝐹!,!+   𝛽!𝐵𝑜𝑛𝑑  𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠!,!,!+ 𝛽!𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘  𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠!,!

+ 𝛽!𝑆𝑜𝑣𝑒𝑟𝑒𝑖𝑔𝑛  𝑑𝑒𝑏𝑡  𝑝𝑜𝑠𝑖𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛!,!+ 𝑀𝑎𝑐𝑟𝑜  𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠!,!+ 𝜖!,!,!  

(18)

The  first  regressions  include  only  government  debt  as  a  percentage  of  GDP.  Debt-­‐to-­‐GDP   reflects  a  government’s  fiscal  position  and  thereby  the  likelihood  a  government  is  able   to  provide  subsidies  to  banks.  In  a  second  regression  series,  the  primary  surplus  as  a   percentage  of  GDP  is  included.  In  2011,  every  government  had  a  budget  deficit,  and  for   each  country  the  budget  deficit  decreased  over  the  years,  some  budget  deficits  even   turning  into  budget  surpluses.  Because  of  the  gradual  improvement  of  government   balances  and  the  differentiation  between  countries,  the  course  of  the  crises  in  Europe  is   reflected  in  the  variable.  This  is  important  as  the  dataset  includes  data  from  2011   onwards,  which  is  in  the  middle  of  the  crisis.  The  third  regression  series  include  both   the  Debt-­‐to-­‐GDP  ratio  and  the  Primary  Surplus.    

 

3.3 Sample  

The  sample  of  banks  used  in  this  thesis  consists  of  banks  under  the  authority  of  the   European  Central  Bank.  In  order  to  gauge  the  effect  of  systemic  importance  on  market   discipline,  the  sample  includes  both  systemically  important  banks  and  other  banks.  A   summary  of  the  banks  in  the  sample  is  shown  in  Appendix  B.  Data  of  the  banks  is   collected  from  Thomson  One,  Datastream  and  Bankfocus.  The  sample  includes  data  of   banks  from  2011  onwards,  as  Bankfocus  is  a  considerably  new  database  only  covering   data  since  2011.      

 

3.4 Preparation  of  the  Dataset  

Before  the  regressions  are  done,  several  modifications  are  made  to  the  data.  First,  to   ensure  the  bond  spreads  are  comparable,  bonds  with  derivative  features,  floating   interest  rates  and  warrants  are  excluded  from  the  sample.  Also,  bonds  with  a  time  to   maturity  of  less  than  one  year  are  excluded.  Second,  Bankfocus  only  provides  annual   accounting  data.  Therefore,  the  end-­‐of-­‐year  accounting  data  is  linearly  interpolated  to   monthly  data.  For  the  price-­‐to-­‐book  ratio,  monthly  market  prices  are  used.  Third,  the   data  on  the  spreads,  bank  controls  and  macro  controls  contain  a  number  of  extreme   observations.  To  ensure  that  outliers  do  not  influence  the  results,  the  data  is  winsorized   to  the  outer  one  percentile.  In  other  words,  all  observations  for  the  spread,  bank  

controls  and  macro  controls  with  values  lower  than  the  1st  percentile  and  higher  than  

the  99th  percentile  of  all  values  are  set  to  the  values  of  the  1st  and  99th  percentile.  Fourth,  

the  dataset  includes  bonds  with  a  perpetual  character.  The  time  to  maturity  for  those   bonds  is  set  to  40  years,  the  highest  value  of  Ttm  in  the  dataset.  Fifth,  standard  errors   are  clustered  on  bank  level.  Last,  a  simple  correlation  test  is  done  to  test  for  linearity   among  pairs  of  variables  and  to  test  for  multi-­‐collinearity,  the  variance  inflation  factors  

(19)

are  estimated.  The  critical  value  for  the  variance  inflation  factor  is  set  at  10  (Hair,  Black,   Babin  &  Anderson,  2010).    

 

4. Results    

4.1 Descriptive  Statistics  

An  overview  of  the  variables  is  found  in  table  4.1.  The  dataset  consists  of  14.246  unique   observations  for  nineteen  different  banks  from  seven  different  countries,  further   specified  in  Appendix  A.    

                                 

Table  4.1:  Descriptive  Statistics  

Mean STD N Min Max

Spread 2,608054 1,85068 14246 0,001 8,554 TBTF in assets 20,13058 1,584658 14246 15,14161 21,46195 TBTF in buckets 1,027657 0,9912606 14246 0 3 Time to maturity 10,87571 10,48534 14246 0 40 Seniority 3,871528 1,346201 14221 1 7 Debt-to-equity ratio 17,98212 7,493638 14246 4,136131 43,49978 Return on assets 0,2747156 0,3904113 14246 -4,155679 8,011952 Price-to-book ratio 0,6728791 0,275852 13511 0,168 1,565 Maturity mismatch 1,188695 2,772 14246 0,0876894 16,15222

Default risk premium 0,9184859 0,2536132 14246 0,55 1,49

Term structure premium 1,835729 0,4909172 14246 1,01 2,97

Market risk premium 6,990429 0,94975 14246 5,19 12,06

 

4.2 Too  Big  to  Fail  and  Market  Discipline  

The  results  of  the  first  OLS  regression  with  cluster  robust  standard  errors  are  shown  in   table  4.2.  The  first  two  regressions  still  include  the  debt-­‐to-­‐equity  ratio.  However,  when   testing  for  correlation  with  the  other  variables,  the  debt-­‐to-­‐equity  ratio  shows  to  have   high  correlation  with  the  other  bank  specific  control  variables.  The  variable  is  

insignificant  for  all  two  regressions  and  it  has  a  negative  sign  for  one  regression,  which   is  not  as  expected.  Furthermore,  the  R2  does  not  improve  when  including  the  debt-­‐to-­‐

equity  ratio.  Therefore,  the  debt-­‐to-­‐equity  ratio  is  not  considered  in  further  regressions   and  the  analysis  is  focused  on  the  last  regressions  that  do  not  include  the  debt-­‐to-­‐ equality  ratio.  No  (multi-­‐)  collinearity  is  detected  in  the  last  two  regressions;  the   variance  inflation  factor  has  a  mean  of  1.32  and  1.31  for  regressions  three  and  four   respectively.    

  For  both  systemic  importance  (TBTF)  measures,  the  coefficient  is  significant  and  

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

The advantage of the interactionist approach is that it deconstructs accountability inter- actions into their constituent parts centred around different types of contestation. The

Understanding the concepts of risk management and patient safety, including effects of their particular characteristics on adult learning and organizational learning, together with

The Enhanced Credit Support (ECS) is a set of comprehensive non-standard measures to support financing conditions and flow of credit beyond what could be achieved through

Book leverage (LEV) and growth opportunities (GROW) are obtain through the DataStream, the stock market development (STD) and bank sector development (BSD) are collected through

To capture the effects of the Single European Market (SEM) Program, two indicators taken from the Cecchini Report (1988) were added for sectors having high non-tariff barriers at

In order to test whether government bailouts induce moral hazard effects in terms of excessive risk taking by banks, this study uses a two-step model to

It is attempted to find a relation between the introduction of the Single Resolution Mechanism and default risk of banks using Credit Default Swap (CDS) spreads, a

Moreover, the moderating effect of country-level investor protection and bank-level corporate governance on the relationship between gender diversity and a bank’s risk taking is