• No results found

The financial position of Dutch households : a "minskian" perspective.

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "The financial position of Dutch households : a "minskian" perspective."

Copied!
85
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

 

 

 

The  Financial  Position  of  Dutch  Households  

A  “Minskian”  Perspective  

 

 

 

 

 

Abstract:  

After  the  financial  crisis  of  2007-­‐2008,  the  global  economy  experienced  a  major   recession.  The  Dutch  economy  was  not  spared,  and  especially  the  household   sector  was  hit  hard.  This  study  analyses  the  developments  in  the  Dutch   household  sector  over  the  past  20  years,  using  a  framework  based  on  the   Financial  Instability  Hypothesis  (FIH).  The  FIH  is  a  heterodox  economic  theory,   which  provides  a  coherent  insight  into  the  internal  dynamics  of  the  modern-­‐day   economy.  Data  on  over  1,500  households  over  the  past  20  years,  obtained  from   the  DNB  Household  survey,  are  used  to  analyse  if  the  Dutch  household  sector   overleveraged  in  the  period  prior  to  the  recession,  as  the  FIH  predicted.  The   results  suggest  that  this  is  not  the  case.  Other  possible  causes  of  the  crisis  in  the   household  sector,  such  as  contagion  from  the  financial  sector,  inadequate   government  policy  and  a  decline  in  disposable  income,  seem  more  likely.    

 

 

 

 

    Master  Thesis     Date:               16-­‐07-­‐2014  

Institution:             University  of  Amsterdam   Student:               Lars  Kroese  

Student  number:             6042554  

(2)

Table  of  Contents       Introduction  ...    3     1. Theoretical  framework    ...  6  

1.1. Interpretation  of  Keynes    ...  6  

1.2. Assumptions  of  the  FIH    ...  8  

1.3. The  dynamics  of  finance    ...  12  

1.4. The  FIH;  from  a  stable  to  an  unstable  system    ...  15  

1.5. Extensions  of  and  contributions  to  the  FIH    ...  17  

1.6. Similarities  between  the  FIH  and  mainstream  economics  ...    20  

1.7. Household  finance  ...  22  

  2. Methodology  and  data    ...  26  

2.1. Research,  hypothesis  and  expected  results    ...  26  

2.2. DNB  household  survey    ...  27  

2.3. Data  and  variables  ...  29  

2.4. Methodology    ...  34  

2.5. Overview  of  the  variables    ...  36  

  3. Results    ...  37  

3.1. Hedge,  speculative,  ponzi    ...  37  

3.1.1. Case  I:  𝑋 = 0.2      𝑌 = 0.6        ℎℎ𝑖𝑛𝑐 > 𝑚𝑖𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑐  ...  38   3.1.2. Case  II:  𝑋 = 0.25        𝑌 = 0.65        ℎℎ𝑖𝑛𝑐 > 𝑚𝑖𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑐  ...  41   3.1.3. Case  III:  𝑋 = 0.3        𝑌 = 0.7        ℎℎ𝑖𝑛𝑐 > 𝑚𝑖𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑐  ...…...…...  43   3.1.4. Case  IV:  𝑋 = 0.25        𝑌 = 0.65        ℎℎ𝑖𝑛𝑐 > 0  …...  44   3.2. Additional  analysis    ...  46   3.3. Interest  payments  ...    46   3.4. Mortgage  debt  ...    48   3.5. Household  income    ...  49     4. Discussion    ...  50     5. Conclusion    ...  61     References    ...  65     Appendix  I    ...  69   Appendix  II    ...  70   Appendix  III    ...  82   Appendix  IV    ...  83   Appendix  V    ...  84   Appendix  VI    ...  85              

(3)

Introduction  

In  late  2007,  a  global  financial  crisis  erupted,  triggered  by  a  collapse  of  the  value   of  assets  and  securities  due  to  a  crisis  in  the  American  subprime  mortgage   market.  As  a  result  several  major  global  financial  institutions  failed,  stock   markets  worldwide  crashed  and  governments  had  to  bailout  systemically   important  banks.  The  housing  market  was  also  affected  heavily,  at  first  only  in   the  USA,  where  house  prices  plummeted  and  many  households  were  no  longer   able  to  service  their  mortgage,  resulting  in  foreclosures.  Soon  the  crisis  spread,   Europe  was  affected  by  the  sovereign  debt  crisis  and  the  whole  (western)  world   was  affected  by  a  global  economic  recession.  The  Dutch  economy  was  not  

spared;  Dutch  banks  required  government  support,  house  prices  and  sales   collapsed  and  GDP  growth  stagnated,  and  even  became  negative  in  2009,  2012   and  2013  (CBS,  2014).  Especially  the  housing  market  was  hit  hard,  house  prices   declined  by  approximately  20%  in  the  period  2008-­‐2013  and  the  number  of   houses  sold  declined  from  about  210,000  in  2006  to  only  about  110,000  in  2013   (CBS,  2014).  At  the  same  time  as  the  value  of  the  assets  of  households  declined,   the  disposable  income  of  households  dropped  due  to  the  recession.    

  The  developments  in  the  Dutch  economy,  and  particular  the  Dutch   household  sector,  are  interesting  to  analyse,  as  there  are  not  many  academic   studies  into  the  events  and  causes  of  the  crisis  in  the  Dutch  household  sector.   What  makes  the  Dutch  housing  market  and  household  sector  even  more   interesting,  is  that  Dutch  households  have  a  notoriously  high  mortgage  debt   (Mattich,  2013),  which  is  compensated  by  high  pension  savings,  but  these  are  not   available  to  be  withdrawn  at  request  and  can  thus  not  be  used  for  debt  relief.   These  high  debts  might  suggest  that  Dutch  households  have  been  overleveraged   prior  to  the  crisis,  and  that  this  high  ratio  of  debts  compared  to  income  available   to  fulfil  the  payment  obligations  due  to  debt,  might  be  a  cause  of  the  crisis  in  the   Dutch  household  sector.    

  Mainstream  economic  theories  do  not  suffice  in  providing  an  appropriate   explanation  for  the  crisis.  They  don’t  account  for  several  important  concepts  in   our  modern  economy  that  cannot  be  neglected  when  analysing  the  economic   crisis.  One  obvious  aspect  the  mainstream  economic  theories  mostly  ignore,  is   the  importance  of  finance  and  the  interrelatedness  of  finance  with  the  real  

(4)

economy,  which  cannot  be  neglected  after  the  immense  impact  of  the  2007   financial  crisis  on  the  global  economy.  Another  important  conception  that  is  not   accounted  for  in  most  mainstream  economic  theories  is  fundamental  

uncertainty.  The  economy  is  a  complex  system  with  many  interconnections  and   unknowns,  and  not  all  possible  outcomes  can  be  predicted  using  a  model  and  a   probability  distribution;  some  results  are  fundamentally  incalculable.  

Furthermore  the  large  fluctuations  observed  in  the  business  cycle  of  our  modern   economy  are  hardly  compatible  with  the  mainstream  general  equilibrium  view,   which  is  the  view  that  the  economy  is  a  fundamentally  stable  system,  only   subject  to  (minor)  random  shocks.    

  A  theory  that  does  take  into  account  the  concepts  mentioned  above,  and   many  more  ideas  that  are  missing  in  mainstream  theories,  is  the  Financial   Instability  Hypothesis  (FIH)  by  Hyman  Minsky  (1919-­‐1996),  an  American  post   Keynesian  economist.  He  developed  a  coherent  economic  theory  that  is  able  to   explain  instability  and  show  how  it  is  generated.  Minsky  (1982b)  regards   instability  as  an  important  recurring  characteristic  of  the  modern  economy.       This  study  investigates  if  the  FIH  is  an  appropriate  theory  to  explain  the   developments  in  the  Dutch  business  cycle  and  in  particular  the  Dutch  household   sector.  The  research  question  is  formulated  as  follows:  Can  the  Financial  

Instability  Hypothesis  explain  the  developments  in  the  Dutch  economy,  in   particular  the  Dutch  household  sector,  over  the  past  20  years?  This  question  is   answered  in  the  discussion  section  after  a  careful  analysis  of  data  on  Dutch   households  over  the  past  20  years,  which  are  obtained  from  the  DNB  Household   survey  (CentERdata,  2014b.).    

  The  paper  is  structured  as  follows:  the  first  section  describes  the  

theoretical  framework,  in  which  an  outline  of  the  FIH  is  given.  The  FIH  is  built-­‐up   from  scratch,  starting  at  Keynes  (1936)  and  working  towards  the  coherent   theory  of  Minsky  (1992)  and  further  complemented  with  extentions  by  other   authors.  Furthermore  the  similarities  between  certain  other  economic  theories   and  the  FIH  are  discussed.  At  the  end  of  the  theoretical  framework  an  overview   of  the  relevant  literature  regarding  household  finance  is  given.  The  second   chapter  of  this  paper  discusses  the  methodology  of  the  research  and  the  data   used,  including  a  section  with  the  hypothesis  and  the  expected  results.  The  DNB  

(5)

Household  survey  is  also  covered  in  this  chapter.  Furthermore  a  table  with  an   overview  of  all  variables  that  are  used  in  the  analysis  is  included.  The  third   chapter  consists  of  two  parts:  the  main  analysis  and  an  analysis  with  additional   evidence  that  does  not  directly  follow  from  the  narrative  of  the  FIH.  The  fourth   chapter  is  a  discussion  of  the  results.  The  last  chapter  is  a  conclusion,  in  which   the  whole  paper  is  briefly  summarized  and  the  research  question  is  answered.  At   the  end  of  this  paper  the  reference  list  and  the  appendices  can  be  found.    

(6)

1.  Theoretical  framework  

This  chapter  contains  an  outline  of  the  Financial  Instability  Hypothesis  as   originally  developed  by  Hyman  Minsky  and  summarizes  the  main  concepts  and   underlying  assumptions.  Furthermore  the  developments  in  the  relevant  

literature  on  the  FIH  and  related  subjects  are  described  and  a  brief  overview  of   the  literature  on  household  finance  is  given.  

 

1.1  Interpretation  of  Keynes  

Hyman  Minsky  regarded  his  Financial  Instability  Hypothesis  as  an  interpretation   of  the  theories  of  John  Maynard  Keynes,  which  were  laid  out  in  “The  General   Theory”  (1936).  Furthermore  Minsky  builds  upon  the  views  of  Joseph   Schumpeter  (1934)  regarding  money  and  finance  and  Charles  Kindleberger   (1978)  and  Martin  Wolfson  (1986)  regarding  disequilibrating  processes  and   financial  instability.  Minsky  also  uses  the  concept  of  debt  deflation  as  described   by  Irving  Fisher  (1933).    

  It  is  important  to  know  that  since  the  FIH  is  an  interpretation  of  the   original  ideas  of  Keynes,  it  is  fundamentally  different  from  the  dominant  post-­‐ WWII  economic  theories.  The  neoclassical  synthesis,  monetarism,  new  

Keynesian  economics  and  new  classical  economics  can  be  seen  as  the  dominant   schools  of  thought  after  WWII.  All  these  schools  can  be  captured  under  the   common  denominator  that  is  neoclassical  economics.  For  convenience  I  will,   from  now  on,  refer  to  these  dominant  schools  as  neoclassical  or  mainstream   economics.  Economic  schools  of  thought  that  are  not  considered  part  of  the   mainstream  are  commonly  referred  to  as  heterodox  economics,  a  term  that  I  will   also  use  when  referring  to  the  non-­‐dominant  economic  schools  of  thought.      

In  1975,  John  Maynard  Keynes,  a  book  by  Minsky  was  published.  In  this  book   Minsky  argues  that  the  common  interpretation  of  Keynes’  magnum  opus,  The   General  Theory  (1936),  was  incorrect.  The  common  interpretation  in  mainstream   economics  was  an  interpretation  that  regarded  the  theories  of  Keynes  as  an   extension,  or  at  most  an  evolution,  of  the  neoclassical  ideas  of  the  time.  The   dominant  interpretation  of  The  General  Theory  (1936)  is  what  Minsky  (1977,   p.20)  calls  “the  Hicks-­‐Hansen  formulation  of  Keynesian  theory  and  the  

(7)

neoclassical  synthesis.”  John  Hicks  published  the  article  Mr.  Keynes  and  the   Classics,  A  Suggested  Interpretation  (1937)  in  which  he  presents,  for  the  first   time,  the  famous  IS-­‐LM  model.  The  model  was  extended  and  popularized  by   Alvin  Hansen  (1941).  The  neoclassical  interpretation  of  Keynes  is  known  as  the   neoclassical  synthesis.  Paul  Samuelson  (1948)  was  one  of  the  first  who  

incorporated  the  neoclassical  synthesis  theories  in  an  economics  textbook.  The   book  later  became  one  of  the  all-­‐time  bestselling  economics  textbooks.  Other   important  contributions  to  the  neoclassical  interpretation  of  Keynes  were  made   by  (later)  famous  economists  as,  Franco  Modigliani,  James  Tobin,  Robert  Solow   and  many  more.  The  neoclassical  interpretation  of  Keynes  was  basically  an   incorporation  of  some  of  Keynes’  ideas  into  neoclassical  economics.  Minsky   (1977,  p.20-­‐21)  argues  that  this  interpretation  is  not  correct,  as  Keynes   presented  ideas  in  The  General  Theory  (1936)  that  should  be  considered  as  a   revolution  rather  than  an  evolution  of  the  existing  neoclassical  school  of  thought.   Minsky  (1977)  points  out  that  Keynes  himself  did  not  agree  with  the  

interpretation  of  his  work  in  the  spirit  of  traditional  mainstream  economics.  In  a   rebuttal  (Keynes,  1937)  to  professor  Jacob  Viner  of  the  University  of  Chicago,   Keynes  disagrees  that  his  General  Theory  (1936)  does  not  make  a  sharp  break   with  the,  at  that  time,  dominant  economic  school  of  thought.  Minsky  (1977)   notes  that  the  interpretation  following  from  the  rebuttal  to  Viner  (Keynes,  1937)   is  not  consistent  with  the  interpretation  suggested  by  Hicks  (1937)  and  

subsequent  mainstream  interpretations.  Minsky  (1977,  p.20-­‐21)  continues:    

 “Furthermore  the  interpretation  of  the  General  Theory  that  is  consistent   with  Keynes’  rebuttal  to  Viner  leads  to  a  theory  of  the  capitalist  economic   process  that  is  more  relevant  and  useful  for  understanding  our  economy   than  the  standard  neoclassical  theory:  this  theory,  which  builds  upon  an   interpretation  of  Keynes,  is  the  “financial  instability  hypothesis.”  

 

The  starting  point  of  the  analysis  of  Keynes  and  Minsky  on  one  side,  and   neoclassical  economists  on  the  other  side,  is  the  crucial  difference  from  which   almost  all  differences  in  assumptions,  methods,  results,  etc.  can  be  explained.     Neoclassical  economists  use  a  simple  barter-­‐based  market  economy  as  

(8)

the  starting  point  of  their  economic  models  and  theories.  Minsky  (1977)  calls   this  the  “village  fair  paradigm”.  It  starts  with  the  most  simple  basic  form  of  an   economy,  where  rational  agents  trade  on  a  decentralized  market,  leading  to   cohesive  and  consistent  results,  which  in  some  occasions  are  efficient.  Most   conclusions  however  only  hold  when  strong  assumptions  are  made  (Minsky,   1982a).  The  theories  based  on  this  can  be  extended  with  contingent  concepts   and/or  processes  such  as  a  production  process,  capital  and  investment,  money   and  much  more,  but  the  basic  assumptions  and  subsequently  most  of  the  results   remain  the  same.  Accordingly,  neoclassical  theory  is  unable  to  explain  some   anomalies  as  the  periodical  occurrence  of  busts  and  booms.  Minsky  (1982a)   considers  it  important  that  a  coherent  economic  theory  is  able  to  explain   instability  and  show  how  it  is  generated,  as  it  is  an  ever-­‐recurring  observed   characteristic  of  the  modern  economy.    

  Keynes,  and  Minsky  follows  him  in  this,  takes  another  point  of  view,  a   point  of  view  that  Minsky  (1977,  p.21)  calls  the  “city  or  Wall  Street  paradigm.”   The  economy  is  viewed  as  a  complex  monetary  economy  with  an  ever-­‐evolving   system  of  financial  interconnections  between  agents,  firms  and  institutions.   Minsky  (1977)  calls  this  the  “city  or  Wall  Street  view”  because  this  is  how   bankers,  investors  and  managers  from  their  skyscrapers  in  financial  districts   look  at  the  economy.  In  this  view  finance  is  important  and  money  is  not  just  a   tool  used  to  smoothen  the  exchange  of  goods  and  services.  The  Keynesian  “Wall   Street  paradigm”,  which  sees  our  modern  economy  as  a  “money  manager   capitalist  economy”  (Wray,  2011),  where  finance  and  money  play  a  crucial  role,   is  the  starting  point  of  the  construction  of  Minsky’s  financial  instability  

hypothesis  (1977,  1992).      

1.2  Assumptions  of  the  FIH  

As  noted  earlier,  Minsky  himself  considered  the  FIH  an  interpretation  and   continuation  of  the  ideas  of  Keynes,  and  thus  many  concepts  used  in  the  FIH   directly  follow  from  The  General  Theory  (Keynes,  1936).  This  section  goes  into   more  detail  regarding  the  concepts  that  Minsky  borrows  from  Keynes  (1936)  to   construct  his  FIH  and  explain  the  assumptions  underlying  the  FIH.    

(9)

  One  of  the  crucial  deviations  from  the  mainstream  economic  theory   Minsky  makes,  is  his  view  on  money.  Neoclassical  theories  consider  money  as   exogenous,  at  least  in  the  long  run.  If  money  is  exogenous,  it  plays  no  role  in  the   economy  in  the  sense  that  it  has  no  effect  on  real  economic  variables.  Minsky   thought  money  could  not  be  neutral,  neither  in  the  long  or  short  run,  in  these   times  where  complex  and  expensive  capital  assets  are  commonly  traded  and  are   an  important  part  of  the  economy.  (Tymoigne  and  Wray,  2008).    Keynes  (1936)   considered  money  as  an  endogenous  variable  in  the  economy,  a  special  type  of   bond,  the  most  liquid  type  of  asset.  The  demand  for  money  is  determined  by  the   liquidity  preference  of  agents,  a  concept  Keynes  introduced  in  his  General  Theory   (1936),  which  is  a  subjective  value  given  to  holding  liquidity.  If  the  value  agents   assign  to  holding  liquidity  increases,  money  demand  will  increase,  while  the   demand  for  less  liquid  assets,  such  as  machines  and  long-­‐term  bonds,  will  go   down.  Furthermore  money  connects  the  owners  of  assets,  the  producers,  with   the  owners  of  wealth,  the  investors.  In  the  modern  economy  producers  often   need  to  borrow  money  to  acquire  capital,  and  they  do  this  through  banks,  or   other  financial  institutions.  Owners  of  wealth  on  the  other  hand  seek  a  way  to  get   return  on  their  money.  Via  the  financial  sector  they  lend  out  their  money  to  the   producers.  These  investors  have  claims  on  money,  not  on  real  assets,  and  thus   money  is  the  connection  between  the  investors  and  the  producers.  Keynes  calls   money  a  “veil  between  the  real  assets  and  the  wealth  owner”  (Minsky,  1977).   This  veil  is  the  connection  between  money  and  the  financing  process  taking   place  in  the  economy  through  time.  Time  is  important  in  this  respect,  as  the   process  is  dynamic.  Financial  contracts  entered  at  one  point  in  time  lead  to   payment  obligations  in  the  future.  This  is  another  important  difference  with   neoclassical  theory,  which  mostly  abstracts  from  time  (Minsky,  1982a).  

  Furthermore,  Keynes  (1936,  1937),  and  Minsky  (1977)  agrees  with  him,   thought  that  there  are  always  disequilibrating  forces  affecting  the  economy.  The   view  of  Keynes  (1936,  p.108)  and  Minsky  was  that  the  economy  is  fundamentally   unstable,  which  contrasts  with  the  mainstream  Walrasian  general  equilibrium   view  that  the  economy  is  fundamentally  stable  and  it  is  occasionally  hit  by   disequilibrating  shocks,  after  which  the  economy  automatically  returns  to   equilibrium.  This  is  more  or  less  the  opposite  of  Minsky’s  point  of  view.  Minsky  

(10)

(1992)  argues  that  over  prolonged  periods  of  prosperity,  the  economy  departs   from  stability  and  inevitably  becomes  unstable.  Thus,  the  perceived  stability   associated  with  a  prolonged  period  of  economic  growth  actually  conceals  the   development  of  the  economy  becoming  increasingly  unstable.  This  is  essence  of   Minsky’s  FIH  and  can  be  captured  in  the  famous  statement:  “stability  is  

destabilizing”.    

  Especially  the  investment  decision  process  is  subject  to  these  

disequilibrating  forces.  According  to  Minsky  (1977),  the  investment  decision   plays  an  essential  role  in  the  economy,  as  investments  are  the  main  determinant   of  the  volatility  of  aggregate  activity.  Whether  or  not  firms  decide  to  invest,   depends  on  the  price  of  a  capital  asset  relative  to  its  output  price  and  financial   conditions  (Minsky,  1977).  Expected  returns  on  a  capital  asset  are  composed  of   the  asset’s  expected  yield,  the  carrying  cost,  liquidity  and  the  expected  price   change.  All  assets  have  a  different  expected  return,  and  a  different  composition   of  the  expected  return.  Some  assets  provide  more  return  in  the  form  of  liquidity   (e.g.  money),  while  others  have  high-­‐expected  yields  (e.g.  machines).  The  

demand  for  liquidity  is  determined  by  the  liquidity  preference  of  agents.  As   expectations  change,  so  do  the  liquidity  preference  of  agents  and  the  expected   yields  of  capital  assets.  The  result  is  that  the  expected  return  on  capital  assets   changes,  but  the  change  is  not  equal  for  all  assets,  the  relative  return  on  one   asset  compared  to  others  also  changes.  It  is  clear,  that  in  this  process,   expectations  about  the  future  are  essential  in  determining  the  level  of   investments  and  thus  output  and  employment  (Tymoigne  and  Wray,  2008).   Expectations  are  however  not  determined  by  rational  agents  with  selfish   motives,  who  make  no  systematic  errors  in  predicting  the  future,  as  in  

neoclassical  theory,  but  in  an  expectation  formation  process  where  people  have   to  deal  with  the  absence  of  information  and  fundamental  uncertainty.    

  Keynes  (1936)  distinguished  two  shorts  of  “uncertainty”.  The  first  is  the   concept  of  risk,  similar  to  the  mainstream  conception  of  risk.  It  can  be  calculated   as  it  has  a  probability  distribution,  an  expected  value  and  mean,  standard  

deviation,  etc.  In  combination  with  rational  expectations  and  perfect  information   this  will  enable  agents  to  make  perfectly  rational  decisions.  The  second  type  of   “uncertainty”  Keynes  distinguished  is  fundamental  uncertainty,  which  is  

(11)

unknown  and  cannot  be  calculated,  similar  to  Knightian  uncertainty  (Knight,   1921).  This  uncertainty  is  not  taken  into  account  in  neoclassical  models  since  it   is  by  definition  impossible  to  formalize  or  model  fundamental  uncertainty.   Keynes  however  was  convinced  this  concept  of  fundamental  uncertainty  was   important  and  he  was  critical  about  theories  that  only  took  calculable  risk  into   account  since  they  did  not  capture  the  real  world  situation.  As  Keynes  explained:      

 “human  decisions  affecting  the  future,  whether  personal  or  political  or   economic,  cannot  depend  on  strict  mathematical  expectation,  since  the   basis  for  making  such  calculations  does  not  exist;”  (Keynes,  1936;  p.162-­‐ 163).      

 

In  a  world  with  Knightian  uncertainty,  agents  are  not  able  to  calculate  outcomes   regarding  the  future  with  certain  probabilities  and  thus  cannot  fully  know  the   consequences  of  actions  beforehand.  So  even  if  agents  would  be  rational,  it   would  not  help  people  to  reach  optimal  outcomes.    

Keynes,  Minsky  and  in  fact  many  heterodox  economists,  however  reject  the   concept  of  rational  agents.  Keynes  (1936)  thought  people  tried  to  reduce  the   fundamental  uncertainty  by  forming  a  vision  about  the  future  through  social   interactions.    In  this  social  process  the  average  opinion  about  the  appropriate   prices  is  determined.  This  has  two  main  implications;  first,  a  self-­‐fulfilling   process  will  start  in  which  the  socially  created  expectations  will  tend  towards   the  existing  prices.  Secondly,  the  social  conventions  created  will  lead  people  to   behave  in  a  manner  such  that  the  expectations  come  true  (Tymoigne  and  Wray,   2008).  

  The  General  Theory  (Keynes,  1936)  connects  some  important  concepts,   forming  the  basis  of  a  business  cycle  theory.  A  business  bases  its  decision   whether  to  invest  or  not,  on  the  expected  return  on  capital  assets.  The  expected   return  on  capital  assets  is  influenced  by  subjective  expectations  about  the  future,   which  are  determined  in  a  social  process.  Furthermore,  investments  are  the   main  determinant  of  the  volatility  of  aggregate  activity.  This  implies  that  there  is   a  causal  relation  between  expectations  and  aggregate  activity.  Since  expectations   are  subjective  and  confidence  about  the  future  plays  a  major  role  in  the  process  

(12)

that  establishes  these  subjective  expectations,  it  is  possible  for  self-­‐fulfilling   speculative  booms  to  develop  during  periods  of  economic  prosperity.        

 

1.3  The  dynamics  of  finance  

The  crucial  observation  Minsky  (1982b)  makes,  and  which  forms  the  focus  of  the   FIH,  is  that  the  “structure  of  finance”  matters  a  lot.  The  finance  structure  of  firms,   households  and  governments,  more  specifically  their  liability  structure,  commits   the  future  cash  flows  of  these  agents  and  institutions.  Minsky  (1982a)  notes  that   cash  flows  always  have  three  functions.  The  first  function  is  to  signal  the  quality   of  past  investment  decisions.  The  second  function  is  providing  funds  to  meet   payment  commitments.  And  the  last  function  of  cash  flows  is  determining  the   conditions  for  present  and  future  investment  and  the  possibilities  to  finance   investment  (Minsky,  1982a,  p.9).  Thus,  cash  flows  play  an  important  role  in  the   investment  decision  process.  Keynes  (1936)  already  observed  that  (subjective)   expectations  are  an  important  determinant  of  investments.  Minsky  (1982a)  adds   to  this  that  investments  are  determined  by  borrowing,  lending  and  interest  rates.   Financial  commitments  also  enter  the  investment  decision  process,  as  past   financial  arrangements  have  an  influence  on  the  prices  of  capital  and  financial   assets,  and  new  financial  arrangements  are  needed  to  finance  present  and  future   investment.  Furthermore  investment  is  an  important  and  volatile  component  of   aggregate  demand  and  thus  a  determinant  of  employment,  output  and  profits.  To   summarize  Minsky  (1982a):  both  cash  flows  from  operations  and  payment   commitments  due  to  the  structure  of  the  financing  of  liabilities  determine   investments,  which  in  turn  determine  economic  activity  and  the  course  of  the   economy.  The  process  described  is  a  dynamic  process;  over  time  both  cash  flows   and  the  structure  of  finance  change  and  evolve.  As  Minsky  (1992,  p.4)  puts  it:    

“In  a  capitalist  economy  the  past,  the  present,  and  the  future  are  linked   not  only  by  capital  assets  and  labour  force  characteristics  but  also  by   financial  relations”    

(13)

As  noted  earlier,  money  is  the  link  between  all  the  components  in  the  investment   decision  process;  it  connects  investors  with  producers,  the  past  with  the  present   and  cash  flows  with  payment  commitments.  Key  in  this  process  is  the  financial   system.  Financial  institutions,  which  are  just  as  other  businesses  profit-­‐seeking   firms,  channel  money  flows  and  create  financial  contracts,  which  constitute  the   future  payment  commitments  of  households  and  businesses.  The  financial   system  can  be(come)  institutionally  complex,  with  several  layers  of  

intermediation  and  various  interconnections  between  financial  institutions,   resulting  in  a  large  distance  between  the  agents  who  are  the  owners  of  wealth   and  the  agents  who  are  the  operators  of  wealth.  Our  current  financial  system  is   arguably  a  good  example  of  how  complex  and  extensive  a  financial  system  can   become.  In  the  financial  system,  the  flow  and  market  price  of  finance  are   determined  by  expectations  of  business  profits  and  returns  (Minsky,  1992).   Current  cash  flows  and  profits  determine  whether  it  is  possible  for  businesses  to   fulfil  the  payment  commitments  due  to  debt.  Current  profits  and  cash  flows  in   turn  are  dependent  upon  past  investments,  while  future  profits  and  cash  flows,   or  the  expectations  thereof  are  dependent  on  current  investment  (Minsky,  

1992).  Therefore,  the  ability  of  businesses  to  fulfil  their  payment  commitments  is   dependent  on  past  investment  and  the  ability  to  engage  in  new  financial  

contracts  is  dependent  on  current  investment,  which  is  dependent  on  past  

investment.  This  process  continues  over  time  and  forms  a  recurring  cycle.  Figure   1  shows  a  schematic  representation  of  the  connections  between  profit  and  cash   flow,  investment,  and  the  ability  to  meet  and  engage  in  new  financial  

commitments,  as  they  influence  each  other  over  time.      

(14)

Investment  

Cash  jlow  and   projit  

Ability  to  meet   jinancial   commitments   Ablity  to  engage  

in  new  jinancial   commitments  

 

Figure  1.  Schematic  representation  of  the  relation  between  interest,  cash   flow  and  profit  and  financial  commitments  

 

It  is  evident,  as  explained  above,  that  finance,  and  in  particular  debt  and  the   structure  of  debt  plays  a  crucial  role  in  the  FIH.  Minsky  (1992)  calls  the  FIH  a   “theory  of  the  impact  of  debt  on  system  behaviour.”    

  The  FIH  revolves  around  the  three  “ways”  of  financing,  or  income-­‐debt   relations  as  Minsky  calls  them.  Minsky  thought  that  the  analysis  of  how  

investment  is  financed  was  missing  in  the  work  of  Keynes,  as  Keynes  seemed  to   assume  that  funds  for  the  financing  of  investment  are  simply  always  available   (Tymoigne  and  Wray,  2008).  Minsky  (1992),  however  thought  the  way  a  firm  or   household  finances  it’s  investments  is  crucial.  He  distinguishes  three  sorts  of   finance  profiles:  

1. Hedge  finance:  the  cash  flow  from  operations  of  a  hedge-­‐financed  

economic  unit  is  larger  than  all  payment  commitments  due  to  debt  of  that   economic  unit  at  a  particular  date.  

2. Speculative  finance:  a  speculative-­‐financed  economic  unit  can  meet  its   interest  payment  commitments  due  to  debt,  but  is  not  able  to  meet  all   principle-­‐payment  commitments  due  to  debt  out  of  its  cash  flows  from   operations  at  a  certain  point  in  time.  Hence  it  needs  to  “roll  over”  debt.    

(15)

3. Ponzi  finance:  a  ponzi-­‐financed  economic  unit  cannot  meet  any  payment   commitment  due  to  debt  from  its  cash  flows  from  operations  at  a  

particular  date.  Ponzi  units  can  only  sustain  in  an  environment  of  rising   asset  prices.  Its  needs  to  refinance  principle  payments  as  well  as  interest   payments  by  issuing  new  debt,  or  by  selling  assets.    

 

1.4  The  FIH;  from  a  stable  to  an  unstable  system  

The  first  Theorem  of  the  FIH  states  that  there  are  financing  systems  for  which   the  economy  is  stable  and  financing  systems  for  which  the  economy  is  unstable.   The  second  theorem  of  the  FIH  states  that  during  periods  of  economic  growth   the  economy  evolves  from  a  system  with  stable  financial  relations  to  a  system   with  unstable  relations  (Minsky,  1992,  p.8).  The  shares  of  the  different  

categories  of  finance  in  the  economy  determine  the  stability  of  the  economy.   Minsky  (1992)  observed  that  over  prolonged  periods  of  economic  growth,  the   system  of  finance  in  the  economy  as  a  whole  tends  to  shift  from  dominated  by   hedge-­‐financed  units  to  speculative  financed  and  even  ponzi-­‐financed  units.  As   one  can  probably  imagine,  an  economy  is  less  stable  if  the  share  of  speculative   and  especially  ponzi  units  is  large  compared  to  the  share  of  hedge-­‐financed  units.   Minsky  (1982b)  emphasized  that  hedge-­‐financed  units  have  a  “cushion  of  

safety”,  to  absorb  financial  setbacks,  namely  their  equity.  Speculative  and  ponzi   units  do  not  have  these  “cushions”  and  the  risk  of  bankruptcy  for  those  units  is   much  greater  when  confronted  with  economic  crises,  (financial)  misfortune,  etc.   Especially  ponzi-­‐financed  units  are  continuously  on  the  brink  of  the  abyss,  as   they  are  totally  dependent  on  refinancing  for  their  payment  commitments.       Minsky  (1992)  explains  that  in  the  particular  situation  where  an  economy   that  contains  a  sizeable  share  of  speculative-­‐financed  units  and  is  experiencing   inflation,  which  the  monetary  authorities  try  to  mitigate  by  constraining  money   growth  or  other  contractionary  monetary  policies,  then  speculative-­‐financed   units  will  become  ponzi-­‐financed  units  easily  and  units  who  were  previously   ponzi  will  have  a  large  chance  of  going  bankrupt.  This  process  works  via  rising   interest  rates,  either  because  of  tighter  monetary  policy  by  the  central  bank,  or   via  increased  demand  for  loans,  or  through  any  other  channel  that  can  influence   the  interest  rate.  The  increased  interest  rate  raises  the  cost  of  the  production  of  

(16)

investment  output,  since  production  is  frequently  financed  by  (short-­‐term)  debt,   and  it  will  also  create  a  downward  pressure  on  the  value  of  capital  assets  

(Minsky,  1982a).  As  a  result,  investments  decrease.  Decreasing  investments  have   a  deteriorating  effect  on  the  expectations  of  future  profits.  The  result  will  be  that   the  economic  outlook  will  be  less  bright.  Because  of  the  declining  economic   situation,  financial  institutions  will  be  less  inclined  to  provide  finance  for  new   projects  or  refinancing  of  debt  to  businesses.  Moreover  the  finance  still  provided   will  be  more  expensive  and  the  conditions  for  receiving  loans  will  be  more   stringent.  For  hedge-­‐financed  businesses  and  households  this  will  result  in  more   financing  costs,  less  investments  and  less  equity,  and  there  will  be  a  chance  that   hedge-­‐financed  units  will  become  speculative-­‐financed.  For  speculative  and   ponzi  financed  units  however,  it  will  have  more  drastic  implications.  For  

speculative  units  it  will  mean  that  the  refinancing,  which  is  necessary  to  meet  the   principle-­‐payment  commitments,  is  getting  more  and  more  expensive,  creating   the  possibility  that  such  a  unit  will  become  a  ponzi-­‐financed  unit.  For  ponzi  units   the  deteriorating  economic  outlook  is  destructive.  They  will  not  be  able  to  

refinance  maturing  debt  and  they  will  not  be  able  to  meet  payment  

commitments.  Ponzi  units  will  be  forced  to  sell  assets  to  compensate  for  the   shortfall  of  cash  flow.  The  paradox  is  however  that,  when  a  large  enough  share  of   the  businesses  and/or  households  will  be  in  trouble  and  will  be  forced  to  sell   assets,  asset  prices  will  plunge,  leading  to  a  collapse  in  asset  values  (Minsky,   1992).  This  will  have  devastating  effects  for  the  economy  as  a  whole,  triggering  a   debt-­‐deflation  process  a  la  Irving  Fisher  (Minsky,  1977).  The  result  of  higher   interest  rates  is  that,  via  decreasing  asset  prices,  rising  cost  of  holding  assets  and   decreasing  profits,  the  solvency  and  liquidity  of  businesses  and  households  and   the  stability  of  the  financial  system  and  the  economy  is  jeopardized  (Minsky,   1982b).  Therefore,  the  investment  decision,  influenced  by  several  factors  that   were  outlined  earlier,  affects  the  profitability,  solvency  and  liquidity  of  all   economic  units  in  the  system.  The  logical  conclusion  of  the  FIH  is  that  the   internal  dynamics  of  capitalist  economies  and  interventions  and  regulations  by   the  monetary  authorities  are  the  drivers  of  the  business  cycle  (Minsky,  1992).       The  business  cycle  consists  of  six  stages  according  to  Minsky  (1982b).  The   first  stage  is  one  of  accelerating  inflation,  caused  by  a  booming  economy.  The  

(17)

second  stage  is  a  financial  crisis.  This  crisis  is  caused  by  the  dynamics  of  finance   as  explained  earlier.  A  significant  blow  to  the  real  economy  characterizes  the   third  stage.  At  this  point  the  financial  crisis  developes  into  a  full-­‐blown  economic   crisis  via  a  debt-­‐deflation  process.  The  fourth  stage  is  reached  when  the  

government  or  monetary  authorities  intervene  in  the  economy,  trying  to  counter   the  recession  by  monetary  and  fiscal  stimulation.  This  intervention  causes  a   breaking  of  the  downturn  of  the  economy,  which  is  the  fifth  stage.  Finally  the   sixth  state  is  one  of  renewed  expansion,  fuelled  by  bright  prospects  and  positive   expectations  about  the  future.    

 

1.5  Extensions  of  and  contributions  to  the  FIH  

The  FIH  is  an  intuitive  and  comprehensive  but  coherent  theory  of  how  the   internal  dynamics  in  a  capitalist  system,  characterized  by  extensive  and  complex   financial  relations,  can  cause  business  cycles  of  booms  and  busts.  Although   Minsky  was  clear  about  the  structure  of  his  theory  and  the  elements  it  should   contain,  he  did  not  elaborate  on  how  to  model  it  mathematically,  neither  was  he   explicit  on  the  sizes  of  the  shares  of  speculative  or  ponzi  units  an  economy  must   contain  to  become  unstable.  Although  Minsky  himself  was  a  skilled  

mathematician,  he  thought  it  was  more  appropriate  to  use  a  narrative  approach   rather  than  a  formal  approach  when  doing  economics.  However,  economists   influenced  by  the  work  of  Minsky  not  only  maintained  his  legacy  and  continued   research  on  and  in  the  tradition  of  the  FIH,  but  also  made  the  first  steps  

regarding  the  formalization  and  modelling  of  the  FIH.    Subsequent  work,  by   economists  who  built  upon  Minsky’s  ideas,  staying  in  the  (post)  Keynesian   tradition,  was  done  in  several  areas.  The  most  important  contributions  to  the   literature  related  to  the  FIH  are  summarized  in  this  section.    

  The  first  area  where  authors,  inspired  by  the  FIH,  have  done  a  lot  of  work   is  the  original  interpretation  and  extension  of  the  narrative  theories  of  Minsky.   Authors  like  Tymoigne  and  Wray  (2008),  elaborated  on  the  interpretation  of   Keynes  and  Minsky  and  extended  the  FIH  with  a  more  sophisticated  analysis  of   asset  pricing  and  the  evolution  of  the  financial  system.  They  emphasize  that  asset   prices  in  the  theories  of  Keynes  and  Minsky  are  not  based  on  the  theories  of   rational  or  adaptive  expectations,  but  more  on  a  Keynesian  theory  of  

(18)

“conventional  expectations.”  People  are  ignorant  and  their  expectations  are  not   based  on  fundamentals  of  the  economy,  not  because  they  are  not  able  to  think   rationally  but  rather  because  the  future  is  fundamentally  unknown  (Tymoigne   and  Wray,  2008).  The  implication  is  that  there  is  room  for  several  self-­‐fulfilling   processes  to  occur.  Asset  prices  might  be  considered  as  the  right  price,  because   the  socially  accepted  value  converts  to  whatever  this  price  will  be.  People  might   behave  in  a  way  that  will  confirm  their  expectations  about  the  future.  If  

expectations  are  not  controlled  and/or  managed  by  for  example,  regulations  or   (government)  institutions,  speculative  bubbles  can  develop  due  to  this  process.         Another  author  who  developed  the  narrative  approach  of  Minsky  is  for   example  Kregel  who  uses  the  FIH  to  examine  the  events  during  the  subprime   mortgage  crisis  in  the  USA  (Kregel,  2008).  Whalen  did  something  similar,  also   applying  Minsky  to  the  recent  credit  crunch  (Whalen,  2009).  Another  analysis  of   the  recent  financial  and  economic  crisis  is  by  Wray  (2011).  He  notes  that  the   crisis  was  inevitable  as  just  as  Minsky  pointed  out,  endogenous  processes  

pushed  the  economy  towards  being  a  fragile  unstable  system,  and  sooner  or  later   the  bubble  had  to  burst.  Wray  (2011)  concludes  with  the  statement  that  the   impact  of  fundamental  uncertainty  on  the  economy  needs  to  be  reduced  by   creating  new  economic  institutions  that  will  constrain  this  uncertainty.       A  pioneer  in  modelling  and  formalizing  the  FIH  is  Steven  Keen.  Keen  is   one  of  the  few  economists  concerned  with  creating  consistent  models,  which   both  capture  the  real  economic  events  and  are  based  upon  the  theories  of  

Keynes,  Minsky  and  other  (post)  Keynesian  economists.  The  starting  point  of  his   models  is  post  Keynesian  theory  rather  than  neoclassical  theory.  The  models   Keen  (1995,  2011)  created  could  be  categorized  as  complexity  models,  showing   similarities  with  complex  models  in  other  fields  of  science.  Keen  thinks  that  non-­‐ linear  complexity  models  are  much  more  appropriate  to  capture  the  essential   features  of  the  economy  than  neoclassical  stochastic  models  (Keen,  1995).  Ryoo   is  another  economist  who  is  concerned  with  modelling  Minsky’s  and  other  (post)   Keynesian  theories  in  a  more  formal  way.  In  his  paper  Ryoo  (2013)  uses  a  

Minsky-­‐Harrod  approach.  The  “Harrodian”  element  is  in  the  accumulation   behaviour  of  firms.  Firms  desire  to  accumulate  capital  at  a  certain  rate,  in  the   short  run  however,  this  desired  rate  of  accumulation  (utilisation)  is  not  always  

(19)

met,  because  the  capital  stock  adjusts  slowly  and  actual  demand  is  not  always   equal  to  expected  demand  (Ryoo,  2013).  The  result  is  that  the  actual  rate  of   utilisation  fluctuates  around  the  desired  rate.  Ryoo  (2013)  combines  the  FIH  of   Minsky  with  the  accumulation  concept  of  Harrod.  In  his  model,  Minsky’s  theories   provide  the  basis  for  the  long  run  cycle,  while  Harrod’s  theory  explains  the  short   run  fluctuations.  The  model  he  constructs  is  a  stock-­‐flow  consistent  model,  a   special  type  of  model  that  is  incompatible  with  mainstream  economics.  Ryoo   (2013)  uses  his  model  to  discuss  the  implications  of  Minsky’s  ideas  about  how  to   stabilize  the  economy.  Ryoo  (2013)  finds  that  a  rise  in  the  debt  ratio  of  firms,   which  he  defines  as  debt  divided  by  capital,  leads  towards  a  self-­‐reinforcing   dynamic.  Key  mechanisms  in  this  dynamic  system  are  bank  leverage  and  the   profit-­‐seeking  behaviour  of  banks.  Eventually  unsustainable  expansion  of  credit   will  lead  to  a  financial  contraction  (Ryoo,  2013).  Chiarella  and  Di  Guilmi  (2011)   constructed  a  model  that  tries  to  capture  the  elements  of  the  FIH.  Their  model  is   a  micro-­‐founded  model,  which  is  also  common  practice  in  the  mainstream  of   economics,  but  lays  special  emphasis  on  financial  variables  and  incorporates  a   lot  of  new  elements.  Examples  of  concepts  used  by  Minsky  in  the  FIH  that  are   also  used  by  Chiarella  and  Di  Guilmi  (2011)  are  endogenous  money,  

heterogeneous  agents  and  firms  and  heterogeneous  and  complex  financial   conditions.  They  use  the  model  to  do  computer  simulations  and  provide  some   insights  on  financial  fragility  and  possible  stabilization  policies.  Chiarella  and  Di   Guilmi  (2011)  find  results  similar  to  Minsky’s  intuition  presented  in  the  FIH;  in   boom  periods,  firms  take  on  more  debt,  eventually  the  units  in  the  worst  

condition  regarding  their  financial  position  start  to  fail,  the  process  is  reversed,   causing  an  economic  slump.  Chiarella  and  Di  Guilmi  (2011)  recommend  

stabilizing  the  economy  by  reducing  the  capacity  to  create  endogenous  money   and  regulating  debt  levels.    

  Another  area  where  Minsky  himself  did  not  do  much  work  is  in  empirical   research.  As  noted  earlier,  Minsky  used  a  narrative  approach,  which  he  used  to   explain  events  and  elaborate  on  his  view  of  the  business  cycle,  but  he  did  not  do   empirical  research  supported  by  economic  data.  Other  economists  however  have   done  empirical  research  on  the  FIH.  Mulligan  (2013a)  for  example  used  data  on   over  8500  firms  in  North  America  to  analyse  how  big  the  shares  of  hedge,  

(20)

speculative  and  ponzi  firms  in  the  economy  are,  and  furthermore  analysed  the   development  of  these  shares  over  time.  In  another  study  he  also  used  empirical   data  on  firms  in  North  America  to  examine  the  similarities  of  the  FIH  and   Austrian  business  cycle  theory  (Mulligan,  2013b).  Tymoigne  (2011)  tried  to   capture  the  “ponziness”  of  the  economy  by  creating  a  fragility  index  consisting  of   several  indicators  that  could  signal  the  share  of  ponzi-­‐financed  units  in  an  

economy.  His  conclusion  is  that  indeed  the  share  of  ponzi-­‐financed  units  was   increasing  in  the  economy  prior  to  the  recent  financial  crash.  However,  the  share   of  ponzi  units  was  already  large  from  the  beginning.  Furthermore  he  also  

observes  that  there  is  no  convincing  evidence  of  a  real  debt-­‐deflation  process,   which  could  indicate  that  there  is  no  such  a  cycle  as  Minsky  (1992)  suggested.   Tymoigne  (2011)  is  however  sceptic  about  his  own  results,  as  he  acknowledges   that  a  fragility  index  might  not  be  able  to  capture  the  process  described  in  the   FIH.    

   

1.6  Similarities  between  the  FIH  and  mainstream  economics  

Apart  from  several  authors  who  interpreted  and  extended  the  FIH  in  the  

“Keynes-­‐Minsky”  tradition,  predominantly  post  Keynesian  economists,  there  are   also  economists  from  other  traditions,  mainstream  and  heterodox  economics,   who  developed  and  worked  on  theories  that  show  remarkable  parallels  with  the   FIH.  Maybe  most  remarkable  are  the  similarities  of  the  FIH  with  Austrian  

business  cycle  theory  (ABCT).  Although  not  considered  mainstream  economics,   Austrian  economics  did  have  a  great  influence  on  a  lot  of  mainstream  

economists.  Probably  the  most  famous  Austrian  economist,  and  also  one  of  the   founders  of  the  Austrian  tradition,  is  Nobel  Prize  winner  Friedrich  von  Hayek.  He   was  in  Keynes’  time  one  of  the  main  opponents  of  Keynes’  theories,  which  makes   the  similarities  between  the  FIH  and  ABCT  all  the  more  interesting.  The  

resemblances  between  the  FIH  and  ABCT  mostly  lay  in  the  emphasis  on  credit,   capital,  investments  and  debt  in  the  economic  system.  Both  in  the  ABCT  and  the   FIH  credit  and  credit  growth  in  particular  are  the  drivers  of  the  business  cycle.   There  is  a  similar  dynamic  of  credit  growth  leading  to  asset  price  bubbles.  In   ABCT  bubbles  are  caused  by  malinvestments  rather  than  because  of  the   speculative  nature  of  financing  during  an  economic  boom  as  in  the  FIH  is  the  

(21)

case.  In  both  theories  an  unsustainable  build-­‐up  of  debt  will  eventually  lead  to  a   bust  and  a  credit  crunch.  An  important  difference  is  however  that  ABCT  stresses   that  this  is  the  result  of  (bad)  monetary  policy,  an  exogenous  process,  while  the   FIH  sees  this  as  a  result  of  endogenous  dynamics  in  the  financial  system  

(Mulligan,  2013b).  Furthermore  debt  commitments  are  an  important  concept  in   both  theories.    Mulligan  (2013b)  compares  real  business  cycle  theory  (RBCT),   Austrian  business  cycle  theory  and  the  financial  instability  hypothesis  and   concludes  that  ABCT  and  FIH  are  to  a  certain  extent  complementary  theories,   while  the  mainstream  RBCT  is  a  competing  theory  and  is  not  compatible  with   either  the  FIH  or  ABCT.  

  Another  theory  that  seems  to  be  remarkably  similar  to  the  FIH  is  the   theory  on  leverage  cycles.  Leverage  is  a  measure  of  the  amount  of  debt  compared   to  the  amount  of  equity  of  an  economic  unit.  If  debt  is  high  compared  to  equity,  a   unit  uses  a  lot  of  external  finance;  the  leverage  (ratio)  is  high.  If  debt  is  low   compared  to  equity,  the  unit’s  main  source  of  finance  is  internal;  the  leverage   (ratio)  is  low.    Leverage  cycle  theory  revolves  around  the  observation  that   leverage  ratios  fluctuate  and  seem  to  move  together  with  or  even  cause  business   cycles  (Geanakoplos,  2010).  Fostel  and  Geanakoplos  (2008)  present  one  of  the   first  mainstream  economic  theories  in  which  finance  matters,  and  in  that  respect   already  connects  with  the  FIH.  Leverage  cycles  are  caused  by  a  process  that  is   similar  to  the  financial  cycle  Minsky  (1992)  described.  Geanakoplos  (2010)   explains  that  some  buyers  might  be  willing  to  pay  more  for  certain  assets  than   other  people.  This  can  be  due  to  various  reasons,  these  people  can  for  example   have  a  more  positive  view  of  the  future,  or  they  can  be  less  risk  averse  or  the   product  is  just  more  preferred  by  some.  These  people  are  willing  to  pay  more,   and  if  they  have  access  to  credit,  are  willing  to  take  on  more  leverage  to  finance   the  purchase  of  the  product.  This  drives  up  the  price  of  the  asset  and  can  give   rise  to  asset  price  bubbles.  Geanakoplos  (2010)  notes  that,  without  interference,   leverage  becomes  too  high  in  good  times  and  too  low  in  bad  times.  This  results  in   asset  prices  that  also  are  too  high  in  good  times  and  too  low  in  bad  times.  The   most  important  conclusion  is  that  financial  variables  have  a  huge  impact  on  the   economy.  Geanakoplos  (2010,  p.6)  recognizes  the  efforts  of  Minsky,  who  already   stated  that  high  leverage  ratios  were  dangerous  for  the  economy  decades  ago.    

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

(2001), Hen- ley (2004) on hours worked); however, subjective expectations on bequests can also act as a possible engine driving labour market and savings intentions; along this

These models contribute to the investigation of the effects of the recession on both difficulties in making ends meet and the ability to face unexpected expenses for

Different industries will be examined and compared to get more insight into the effect of the salient stakeholder demands and sustainable competitive position on the CSR-CFP

Therefore Table 8 is constructed, which provides the financial literacy index based on the amount of correct answers for 2008 and 2011 for individuals, responsible for the

This table reports the share of liquid financial wealth invested in stocks and bonds for different levels of total debt, mortgage debt and consumer credit in two distinct

In an attempt to change a students’ time perspective by the manipulation, this research explored if informing students of the negative consequences of borrowing right before they

We focus on the wealth (financial distress, making ends meet, financial situation and economic situation), saving behavior and beliefs (income uncertainty,

The results in the previous sections suggest that parents increase their saving because they face a higher probability of financing a part of their children’s college expenses