• No results found

Flawed Economic Planning in Sub-Saharan Africa and its Consequences. A Political-Economic History of World Bank Policies in Malawi.

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Flawed Economic Planning in Sub-Saharan Africa and its Consequences. A Political-Economic History of World Bank Policies in Malawi."

Copied!
57
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

Flawed Economic Planning in Sub-Saharan

Africa and its Consequences

A Political-Economic History of World Bank

Policies in Malawi

(2)

2

Flawed Economic Planning in Sub-Saharan Africa and its

Consequences

A Political-Economic History of World Bank Policies in Malawi

Stijn Kuipers

A thesis submitted for the degree of

Master of Arts

in International Relations

2019

(3)

3

Contents

Maps, Graphs and Tables ... 4

1. Introduction... 5

2. Literature Review ... 8

2.1 The World Bank’s Paradigm: From the Washington to the (New) Post-Washington Consensus. ... 8

2.2 The Political-Economic Alternative ... 11

3. Methodology and Relevance ... 14

3.1 Research Question ... 14

3.2 Political-Economic Approach ... 14

3.3 Why the World Bank in Malawi? ... 16

4. Malawi’s Economic History, 1891-1979 ... 19

4.1 Building the Estates, 1891-1961 ... 19

4.2 Independence and State-led Capitalism, 1961-1979 ... 23

5. Economic Adjustment without Structural Change, 1979-1991 ... 30

5.1 Agricultural Liberalization ... 32

5.2 The Big 3 ... 35

6. Political Reforms without Structural Change, 1991-2018 ... 39

6.1 A Critique of the “Good Governance” Agenda ... 39

6.2 The Costs of Political Competition ... 40

6.3 Continued Constraints ... 44

7. Concluding Remarks ... 48

(4)

4

Maps, Graphs and Tables

Malawi and Madagascar ... 30

Foreign and local resources as part of budget expenditure ... 17

Malawi Tobacco Production, 1923-1943 ... 21

Malawi Average Rate of Growth of Real GDP, 1960-1994 ... 26

Malawi GDP Per Capita, 1960-2017 ... 34

Malawi’s Pace of Poverty Reduction, 1998-2013... 43

Respective Growth and Decline of Consumption per Population Percentile, 2004-2010 ... 43

Estate Sector Data, 1955-1984 ... 24

MDC and its Subsidiary Companies ... 28

ADMARC’s Commercial Investments ... 29

Other MDC-Press-ADMARC Investments ... 29

(5)

5

1. Introduction

The prominent role of the World Bank (WB) in designing and implementing development policies in Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) has been heavily discussed within development economics for the last 30 years. Because the Bank’s policies largely failed to produce economic growth in the region till the mid-1990s, SSA became an important case study in the debate on what went wrong. This came close to an existential crisis in the profession.1

Continued WB involvement, the unstable and unequal nature of economic growth in SSA since the early 2000s and the sustained precariousness of debt levels (despite large scale debt relief in 2005) have made the debate all the more relevant in recent years.2

The policy failures of ‘market-fundamentalism’ in the 1980s and 1990s seemed to shift the WB towards a more contextualized development approach throughout the 2000s. This included a larger possible role for the state and more attention to national peculiarities in development, in contrast to the earlier ‘one-size-fits-all’ approach for which the WB had come to be known. This development has been taken as cause for celebration.3 However, from a critical point of view, this optimism seems unfounded.

While the WB has slowly acknowledged the importance of institutions and the state for economic development, much of this has merely been discursive and the fact that politics lie behind these institutions hasn’t been readily recognized. Despite a prolific debate, little has truly changed considering the actual implementation of development policies because of the continued improper attention to the inherent political nature of development.4

1 Jayati Ghosh, “A Brief Note on the Decline and Rise of Developments Economics”, Rethinking Development

Economics Draft Paper (Cape Town, 2001),

http://www.unrisd.org/unrisd/website/document.nsf/(httpPublications)/2DA5AEC5C09E51E7C1256BC900459 735?OpenDocument [last consulted 11-12-2019].

2 William Battaile et al., “Debt Sustainability in Sub-Saharan Africa: Unravelling Country-Specific Risks”, World

Bank Policy Research Working Paper 7523 (Washington, 2015); Keith Palmer, “Why are sub-Saharan Economies

Not Growing Sustainably?”, Enterprise for Development Discussion Paper (2017).

3 Joseph Stiglitz, “Is there a Post-Washington Consensus Consensus?”, in: Narcís Serra and Joseph Stiglitz (ed.),

The Washington Consensus Reconsidered: Towards a New Global Governance (Oxford, 2008); Carlos Lopes,

“Economic Growth and Inequality: The New Post-Washington Consensus”, Revista Criticia de Ciências Sociais 4 (2012).

4 Thomas Carothers and Diane de Gramont, Development Aid Confronts Politics: The Almost Revolution

(Washington, 2013); K. Sarwar Lateef, Evolution of the World Bank’s Thinking on Governance (2016),

http://pubdocs.worldbank.org/en/433301485539630301/WDR17-BP-Evolution-of-WB-Thinking-on-Governance.pdf [last consulted 11-12-2019].

(6)

6 The problem is that much scepticism still exists among practitioners on how useful more politically aware approaches can be.5 The idea that development requires relatively

straightforward technical solutions seems deeply engrained within the development community.6 This has fostered a stubborn adherence to ‘best practice’ approaches that

continues to ignore the inherently historical and political rooted nature of countries’ socio-economic problems, which decisively influence the implementation and consequences of economic policies in practice.7

This thesis seeks to engage with this scepticism by asking why the World Bank’s

stated goals have not matched the actual consequences of its policies in Malawi since 1981. The hypothesis is that many economic policies have been ineffective or had

unforeseen adverse effects because they were implemented without proper attention to historically rooted socio-economic and political structures. This lack of attentiveness to local political economy has meant that little real improvements have been made to Malawi’s society and economy, despite years of WB involvement. This hypothesis is tested through an historical analysis of the implementation and consequences of WB development policies in Malawi. The analysis will also look at the political-economic legacy of Malawi’s colonial era as it is underlies the country’s contemporary development problems.

If the hypothesis is correct, it will mean that historical experience contradicts the existing scepticism towards the possible benefits of more politically aware development approaches. This would mean that elite interests, historical socio-economic structures and (in)formal institutions intersect to have a defining impact on the way development policies play out, therefore requiring proper attention in future policy design. These insights would be applicable beyond Malawi as many SSA countries seem to suffer from context-specific impediments to equitable, sustainable growth, as they have been subject to comparable ‘best practice’ WB policies with differing, but often detrimental effects.8 In

5 Alina Rocha Menocal, Getting real about politics. From thinking politically to working differently (ODI London,

2014).

6 Ibid.; Carothers and Gramont, The Almost Revolution; Kate Bridges and Michael Woolcock, “How (Not) to Fix

Problems That Matter. Assessing and Responding to Malawi’s History of Institutional Reform”, World Bank

Policy Research Working Paper 8289 (December 2017, Washington).

7 Ibid.; OECD-DAC, Lessons Learned on the Use of Power and Drivers of Change Analyses in Development

Co-operation (Paris, 2005);

8 Thandika Mkandawire, “Maladjusted African Economies and Globalisation”, Africa Development 30:1&2

(2005), 1-33; Jeffrey Sachs et al., “Ending Africa’s Poverty Trap”, Brookings Paper on Economic Activity 1 (2004); David Williams, “Managing Sovereignty: The World Bank And Development in Sub-Saharan Africa”, Mondes en

(7)

7 the end, this would strengthen the recent demand for more contextualized socio-economic development, increasing pressure on the WB and other practitioners to change their ways.

(8)

8

2. Literature Review

The proposal that the lack of attention to political economy in WB programmes harms development raises two questions. Firstly, is it true that the WB pays inadequate attention to non-economic factors in policy design, despite its own rhetoric? Secondly, if that is the case, why is that a problem and what’s the alternative? A review of the evolution of the WB’s paradigm helps to illuminate the lack of actual change in relation to the criticism expressed in the wider debate. Meanwhile, political-economic analyses which have explicated this issue also offer an alternative.

2.1 The World Bank’s Paradigm: From the Washington to the (New) Post-Washington Consensus.

The rise of neoclassical economics in the late 1970s presented a sharp turn away from the WB’s earlier state-focused development approaches. Neoclassical economists argued that SSA economies were performing poorly because their markets were over-regulated and over-taxed due to extensive state interference. On the basis of econometric models and free trade theory did they point to the benefits of comparative advantage in the production of economic growth. The awesome powers of the market just needed to be unleashed to lift Africa out of poverty. The Structural Adjustment Programs (SAPs) which aimed to do so were generally designed to be as apolitical as possible. This was caused by a sincere belief in economics as an objective science and distrust of state interference, but was also instrumental in pushing through unpopular reforms as policies were presented as unavoidable.9 When the SAPs failed to produce growth, neoclassical economists argued

that this was because liberalizing policies had not been correctly implemented.10

Adherents of adjustment pointed at the widespread neo-patrimonial nature of SSA states – informal patron-client relations in which state resources are used to secure the loyalty of clients – as an obstacle to economic transformation. While price liberalization, deregulation and monetary reform were commonly implemented, few regimes indeed were willing to risk their own position by privatizing significant state enterprises or

9 James Ferguson, The Anti-Politics Machine. “Development”, Depoliticization and Bureaucratic Power in

Lesotho (Cambridge, 1990);

10 Paul Collier and Jan Willem Gunning, “Why Has Africa Grown Slowly?”, The Journal of Economic Perspectives

13:3 (1999), 3-22; David Dollar and Aart Kraay, “Trade, Growth and Poverty”, The Economic Journal 114:493 (2004), 22-49; World Bank, Adjustment in Africa (Oxford, 1994).

(9)

9 reorganizing the civil sector.11 Resultingly, a small shift occurred within what was then

called the Washington Consensus from ‘purely’ economic measures to institutional economics in the early 1990s.12 Apart from opening up to the global economy, loans were

now also made conditional on political reforms, such as the implementation of a multi-party system. This stemmed from the belief that development will occur through the combined growth of economic and political freedom.13

The shift to institutional economics presented a first look at the potential role of politics in development. However, it remained limited to the attempted imposition of a prefabricated Western democratic model, instead of an analysis of local politics.14 This

was problematic, because the implementation of such ‘best practice’-policies led to an almost exclusive focus on the institutional determinants of economic performance. As the policies were assumed to be sound, a lack of growth had to be caused by incorrect implementation or corruption. As a result, the lack of growth in SSA was largely blamed on African governments.15 The continuingly unequal and unstable nature of economic

growth in the 1990s and early 2000s however made these arguments increasingly inadequate, which generated extensive criticism of the dominant development paradigm.16

New analyses showed that the Bretton Wood institutions were accomplices in the implementation failure of policies, for which they had blamed governments. Many development projects had payed inadequate attention to existing economic and political structures within countries, leading to ineffective or even counterproductive measures.17

The WB, driven by its own internal ideological and bureaucratic logic, had kept allocating funds to programs clearly failing.18 As such, regimes dragging their feet had been kept in

the saddle. They simply implemented neoliberal demands for e.g. budget cuts by lessening their development ambitions, making African citizens bear the costs of these policies. Sam

11 Pierre Englebert and Kevin Dunn, Inside African Politics (Boulder/London, 2013), 238-239.

12 A typical recent example is: Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson, Why Nations Fail. The Origins of Power,

Prosperity and Poverty (London, 2012).

13 Exemplified by Amartya Sen, Development as Freedom (New York, 1999).

14 Ha-Joon Chang, “Institutions and economic development: theory, policy and history”, Journal of Institutional

Economics 7:4 (2011), 473-498.

15 Jomo Kwame Sundaram et al., “Globalization and development in sub-Saharan Africa”, DESA Working Paper

102 (2011), 2.

16 See: Alfredo Saad-Filho, “Growth, Poverty and Inequality: From Washington Consensus to Inclusive Growth”,

DESA Working Paper 100 (2010), 5-6.

17 Margaret McMillan et al., “When Economic Reform Goes Wrong: Cashews in Mozambique”, NBER Working

Paper 9117 (2002).

(10)

10 Hickey has even argued that the WB ignored Uganda’s opposition to multi-party politics as they wanted a success story for their ‘new institutional approach’, in the process encouraging cronyism and rentier forms of capitalism undermining the productive basis of the economy.19

Critics therefore argued that the Bank’s policies themselves were to blame for Africa’s lack of growth. The great divergence between South-East Asia and Africa since the 1970s stressed the potential power of a dirigist state to encourage growth, in contrast to the state-minimalism of WB programs.20 Likewise, the case studies of Asian economies

presented a strong charge against the democratic bias of the new institutional economics mentioned above, as most of these countries did not have a lot of democratic freedoms yet arguably developed successfully.21 The impressive economic growth in countries

which didn’t follow WB guidelines called the universal applicability of the Bank’s theories into question. In contrast, the inability of many African countries to respond to most economic incentives, as they lacked the infrastructure and bureaucratic means following enforced liberalization, seemed to stress the need for a more embedded form of development.22

The WB slowly picked up on this criticism and started to stress the need for a more contextualized approach throughout the 2000s. Developing from the basic ideas Joseph Stiglitz had proposed in the late 1990s, it publicly declared that one-size-fits-all market-oriented policies are doomed to fail.23 In contrast, the WB stated that policies should

indeed be designed on a per-country basis. This would allow room for experimentation, the possibility of bringing the state back in and paying attention to social, cultural and political factors in development as to create ‘inclusive growth’.24 The unravelling of

inconsistencies within neoliberalism during the global economic crisis of 2008 seemed to

19 Sam Hickey, “Beyond the Poverty Agenda? Insights from the New Politics of Development in Uganda”, World

Development 43 (2013), 194-206, 195.

20 Joseph Stiglitz, “Rethinking Development Economics”, The World Bank Research Observer 26:2 (2011),

230-236; Ha-Joon Chang, Kicking Away the Ladder. Development Strategy in Historical Perspective (London, 2003).

21 Kenichi Ohno, “The East Asian growth regime and political development” in: Kenichi Ohno and Izumi Ohno

(ed.), Eastern and Western Ideas for African Growth (London, 2013), 37-61.

22 Mkandawire, “Maladjusted African Economies”.

23 Charles Gore, “The Rise and Fall of the Washington Consensus as a Paradigm for Developing Countries”,

World Development 28:5 (2000), 789-804.

24 World Bank, Economic Growth in the 1990s: Learning from a Decade of Reform (Washington, 2005); Stiglitz,

(11)

11 accelerate this policy shift, leading some to cheerfully declare that a ‘(New) Post-Washington Consensus’ had been achieved.25

2.2 The Political-Economic Alternative

However, from a critical perspective, this enthusiasm seems ill-founded. While the WB has paid more attention to the role of institutions and politics in economic development, much of this has been merely discursive.26 The Bank has failed to meaningfully include

social, political and cultural factors in project design, as the alterations to its actual approach have been severely limited.27 This can be seen in the continuingly detailed

prescriptions of ‘correct’ economic policies in its documents, despite claims from the WB that it no longer wishes to present strict blueprints. These policies still stress the need for market access, integration into the world economy and economic growth, while largely ignoring the nature of such growth and questions of equity and distribution. Policy failure is still explained through an ignorance of ‘correct’ policies or through deviousness of governance (such as corruption). This disregards other possible causes of policy failures (such as bad implementation design) and the WB’s own role in sustaining political-economic impediments to development.28

In contrast, Paul Cammack’s criticism that the WB’s increased attention to the role of the state in economic development has focused on creating a more deeply embedded form of neoliberalism still seems to apply today.29 While the proponents of the

Post-Washington Consensus have presented it as a distinct break with the Post-Washington Consensus, it is fair to point out that the WB has remained fundamentally pro-market. Instead of truly diversifying its methods, the Bank has merely brought the state back in as a complementary factor to the market. Any government’s main goal is to create market-friendly institutional frameworks, such as stability, infrastructure and a sound judicial system, to allow the market to produce economic growth. Toby Caroll likewise pointed

25 Ibid.; Lopes, “The New Post-Washington Consensus”. 26 Saad-Filho, “Growth, Poverty and Inequality”.

27 Richard Peet, Unholy Trinity. The IMF, World Bank and WTO (London/New York, 2009); Kate Bayliss et al., The

Political Economy of Development: The World Bank, Neoliberalism and Development Research (London, 2011);

Ali Burak Güven, “Whither the post-Washington Consensus? International financial institutions and

development policy before and after the crisis”, Review of International Political Economy 25:3 (2018), 392-417.

28 See: Saad-Filho, “Growth, Poverty and Inequality”, 14-15; World Bank, What is Inclusive Growth?

(Washington, 2009), 7-11, http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTDEBTDEPT/Resources/468980-1218567884549/WhatIsInclusiveGrowth20081230.pdf.

29 Paul Cammack, “What the World Bank means by poverty reduction, and why it matters”, New Political

(12)

12 out that the WB’s understanding of ‘social factors’ has been limited to the utilization of social capital in establishing capitalist citizens. By providing debt-based funding through village councils, groups and individuals were stimulated to both think and work as market participants.30 Economic and political ties among countries’ elite, the ownership of the

means of production or culture-dependent forms of social behaviour are still largely seen as redundant in project design and treated superficially.31 Instead, the task of poverty

reduction is conflated with a technical process designed to foster market forces.

Although one could take issue with the sustenance of a neoclassical capitalist system, the WB’s policies could also be taken as sound if they achieved their own goals of inclusive, sustainable socio-economic growth. The problem is that they don’t. Despite the discursive acceptance that politics matter, the de facto continuance of neoclassical economics has meant that markets have retained ontological priority as the “natural means of creating economic order”.32 This has likewise meant that political power

relations continue to be regarded as somewhat of an externality, implying a separation between economics and politics. As a result, WB analyses of institutions have remained overtly simplistic and its policies therefore shallow.33 They address the outcomes of

political-economic structures with technocratic means, failing to engage with the underlying concentration of power and resources in the hands of political and economic elites. This has hindered socio-economic development by misunderstanding the causes of developmental problems, inadvertently fostering predatory rent-creation and overlooking how technocratic reforms fail due to political-economic structures.34

Critical authors have doubted whether (WB) development can help SSA at all.35 I

however belief this goes too far, as they criticize the current approach without really considering how development could be made to work. The reason why the shift towards a more politically and historically aware development approach has stunted lies in what Carothers and Gramant have called the ‘Almost Revolution’. While there has been a

30 Toby Carroll, “’Social Development’ as Neoliberal Trojan Horse: The World Bank and the Kecamatan

Development Program in Indonesia”, Development and Change 40:3 (2009), 447-466.

31 Consider for example: Richard Record et al., From Falling Behind to Catching Up. A Country Economic

Memorandum for Malawi (Washington, 2018), 1-11, 47-60.

32 Frank Stilwell, “From Economics to Political Economy: Contradictions, Challenge and Change”, American

Journal of Economics and Sociology 78:1 (2019), 35-62.

33 Chang, “Institutions and economic development”. 34 Carothers and Gramont, The Almost Revolution, 4-5.

35 William Easterly, The Tyranny of Experts: Economists, Dictators and the Forgotten Rights of the Poor (New

(13)

13 growing discursive acceptance that non-economic factors play a role in socio-economic development, development agencies in general have proven to be hesitant to alter their policies. While there are numerous factors at play (see Bridges and Woolcock in detail), the biggest issue seems to be that practitioners are not convinced about the benefits of a more contextualized, less technocratic approach due to a lack of analytical proof.36

Malawi, as a clear example of best approach failure, can provide part of this analytical proof and help to alter the status quo. We will now first take a look at the used methodology, before analysing the history of Malawi’s political economy in detail.

36 Carothers and Gramont, The Almost Revolution; Bridges and Woolcock, “How (Not) to Fix Problems That

(14)

14

3. Methodology and Relevance

3.1 Research Question

As has likely become clear from the literature review, criticism of the WB’s lack of attention to historical local circumstances and politics is not new. However, both the debate and the WB’s attention to other perspectives have developed significantly over the last twenty years. As the problems associated with the dominant best-practice approach are slowly becoming apparent within the mainstream, it seems fair to suggest that this offers an opportunity to finally produce a fundamental shift in the way the WB practices development by strengthening the political-economic criticism entering the mainstream. The history of economic development in Malawi clearly shows the effects of technocratic development and as such substantiates the thesis that the lack of attention to political-economic specifics has severely hampered development efforts in Malawi (and elsewhere, as many SSA countries have been subject to comparable ‘best practice’-policies).37 The

historical analysis of WB policies in Malawi (more on case selection below) is therefore helpful in problematizing contemporary development in SSA by explicitly relating policy failure to political-economic factors, in the process contributing to a better approach.

3.2 Political-Economic Approach

The above mentioned lack of historical awareness has partly resulted from a preoccupation with technical solutions and quantitative analysis within mainstream (development) economics. While very useful in its own right, econometric analysis is somewhat ill-equipped to take into account the diverse and numerous social, economic and political variables which are relevant to the implementation of development policies and the nature of poverty if taking a general country view.38 This has generated an

excessive reduction of the complexity of reality, which by extension has led to the treatment of Malawi and other SSA countries as cases merely needing comparable economic and democratic fine tuning. This has been reflected in the lack of attention to

37 Williams, “Managing Sovereignty”.

38 Martha Starr, “Qualitative and Mixed-Methods Research in Economics: Surprising Growth, Promising

Future”, Journal of Economic Surveys 28:2 (2012), 238-264; Michael Bamberger (ed.), Integrating Quantitative

(15)

15 the nature of African growth since the early 2000s, as an overt focus on statistical data and GDP diverted attention from its unequal and unsustainable characteristics.39

In this regard, political-economic analysis is a powerful tool for improving the effectiveness of development economics, as it explicitly focuses on the distribution and contestation of power and resources over the years.40 As such, it lays bare the economic

and political structures which have for an important part determined Malawi’s socio-economic development, revealing the underlying interests, incentives and institutions that have enabled or frustrated development. This helps illuminate the context into which WB policies were implemented, allowing for their fair assessment. This thesis therefore uses a political-economic macro-level country analysis, aimed at engaging with said structures underpinning Malawian society and economy. While mostly qualitatively driven, this approach is augmented by datasets on GDP growth, agricultural production, government budgeting and fiscal deficits, among others, as to present a comprehensive picture of the concurrent socio-economic and political development of Malawi since 1964. This data has been drawn from the statistical office of Malawi, the WB databank and a range of earlier works on the subject.41

To give a representable assessment of the WB policies which have been implemented in Malawi over the span of almost 40 years, I have chosen to take the main projects of the two dominant WB development paradigms as objects of analysis. The first one concerns the SAPs of the 1980s and early 1990s, which focused on industrial and especially agricultural liberalization and macro-economic stabilization as to foster socio-economic development. The second one is the mentioned shift to institutional socio-economics with the good governance agenda from the early 1990s onwards, for which we will focus on the consequences of the shift to a multi-party democracy till the present day. The effect of WB policies will be measured against the goal of shared/inclusive socio-economic growth as stated by the WB itself.42

39 Palmer, “Not Growing Sustainably”; Morten Jerven, Africa. Why economists get it wrong (London, 2015),

74-102.

40 OECD-DAC, Lessons Learned.

41 Such as: Frederic Pryor, “Income Distribution and Economic Development in Malawi. Some Historical

Statistics”, World Bank Discussion Papers 36 (Washington, 1988).

42 World Bank, Report and Recommendation for a Third Structural Adjustment Operation to Malawi No.

P-4172MAI (25-11-1985),

http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/911651468046778153/text/multi0page.txt [last consulted 11-12-2019], 17-19; World Bank, Report and Recommendation for an Industrial and Trade Policy Adjustment Program to Malawi No. P-4778-MAI (25-05-1988),

(16)

11-12-16 By focusing on these two broad programmes, I do leave out some variables on development in Malawi. The first one is AIDS, a disease widely spread and with adverse socio-economic consequences. However, as pointed out by Conroy et al., AIDS does not really cause economic downturn, but simply exacerbates the poverty trap Malawi finds itself in.43 Also considering that there already has been extensive work on that subject by

Conroy, I deem it fair to ignore this factor considering the political-economic focus of this inquiry. The other one is ethnicity, which at times has been discussed as a potential impediment to broad development in Malawi since the onset of a multi-party system.44

However, although electoral results indeed often follow ethnic and regional lines, the extent of collective elite capture of politics and economics in Malawi arguably diminishes the importance of ethnicity as a factor in this regard.45 Furthermore, as there have also

been electoral results to the contrary (such as in 2009), I do not deem ethnicity a fundamental variable for development in Malawi at this time.

3.3 Why the World Bank in Malawi?

The choice to focus on the impact of WB policies is based on the central role the bank has fulfilled in development in Malawi since the country made its first loan request in 1981. The extensiveness of this influence is not to be underestimated. Donors on average provide between ⅓ and ½ of the government’s funds (consider figure 1), and 80% of the development budget. Around the beginning of the 2000s, aid formed a quarter of annual GDP.46

While the WB provides a decent amount of these funds, this is not the primary reason for analysis, as we could have taken any large donor in that case. Instead, both the influence and leverage of the WB is greater than the funds it provides, as it largely works in tandem with other bilateral and multilateral donors.47 Without WB involvement or

2019], 24-26; Luis Lopez-Calva and Carlos Rodriguez-Castelán, “Pro-Growth Equity: A Policy Framework for the Twin Goals”, Policy Research Working Paper No. 7897 (Washington, 2016).

43 Anne C. Conroy et al., Poverty, AIDS and Hunger. Breaking the Poverty Trap in Malawi (New York, 2006),

81-82.

44 Eunice Sahle, Democratisation in Malawi: State, Economic Structure and Neo-Liberal Hegemony (PHD Thesis,

Kingston, 2001); Arne Tostensen, Malawi: A Political Economy Analysis (Oslo, 2017).

45 Diana Cammack, “Malawi’s Political Settlement: Crafting Poverty and Peace, 1994-2014”, Journal of

International Development 29:5 (2017), 661-677.

46 Diana Cammack, “Poorly Performing Countries: Malawi, 1980-2002”, ODI Background Paper 3 (London,

2004), 15-16.

47 See: Michael Hodd, “Africa, the IMF and the World Bank”, African Affairs 86:344 (1987), 331-342, also for

(17)

17 approval, other donors are likely to abstain from funds provision. This happened for example in 1992, when the World Bank Consultative Group, as the leading representative of the transnational lending community, decided to withhold non-humanitarian aid until the Malawian government showed signs of moving towards the establishment of a multi-party democracy.48

The importance of the WB as an object of analysis is further strengthened by the fact that it has largely coordinated development in Malawi since 1981. In contrast to the IMF, the WB has dedicated itself to long-term development projects. It coordinates these with the IMF, but primarily for the latter to be involved in shorter term loans to prop up budget deficits in cases of emergency. The WB’s influence is further enhanced by its decisive impact on which ideas in development become dominant, as the Bank employs the largest group of development economists in the world and has strong ties with many governments.49 As such, the WB is beyond doubt one of the most important actors in

influencing Malawi’s development since the early 1980s and its policies are therefore the primary object of analysis for this thesis.

48 Sahle, Democratisation in Malawi, 237.

49 Hodd, “Africa, the IMF and the World Bank”, 340-341; Susan Park and Antje Vetterlein (ed.), Owning

Development. Creating Policy Norms in the IMF and the World Bank (Cambridge, 2010).

Source: Cammack, “Malawi, 1980-2002”, 16.

(18)

18 Finally, Malawi is an interesting case study, as it adopted a form of ‘managed capitalism’ with a strong primary commodity export-orientation at independence. The WB spoke very enthusiastically about these ‘realistic’ liberal economic policies when it got involved in 1981, and since then Malawi has ranked first in WB documents when it comes to the implementation of their policy recommendations and forms of economic liberalization.50

However, Malawi also still ranks as one of the poorest countries in the world, with very unstable economic growth. This conundrum of ostensibly successful policy implementation and sustained underdevelopment offers a clear opportunity to scrutinize the consequences of WB policies in practice as they were successfully implemented according to the Bank’s own statements.51

50 Mkandawire, “Maladjusted African Economies”, 12; Jane Harrigan, “Book Reviews”, Journal of African

Economies 1:1 (1992), 151-163.

51 World Bank, Third Structural Adjustment Operation No. P-4172-MAI (25-11-1985); World Bank, Industrial and

(19)

19

4. Malawi’s Economic History, 1891-1979

This section explores the long-term implications of the economic and political structures relevant to socio-economic development which were established in Malawi under British rule between 1891 and 1964. While Malawi indeed achieved political independence in 1964, its political economy remained inherently colonial. As such, this chapter sketches the context in which WB policies were implemented and the assessment which was made of these circumstances. What I consider to be the continued colonial economy consists of 3 main elements. Firstly, the country became incorporated into the international economy with a narrow estate-based export sector, making the country dependent on external revenue and setting the basis for Malawi’s continued vulnerability to price shifts on the world market. Secondly, post-1964 ownership of these estates simply shifted from a European to an African elite. As the preferential economic treatment that these plantations received continued, revenues accrued mainly within this elite. Thirdly, the undemocratic centralized state which had dominated the colony continued post-independence, with a large amount of power concentration in the figure of the president (replacing the governor) and the mentioned elite. As such, the colony’s political economy came to define Malawi’s ‘postcolonial’ state and economy with little structural alterations.

4.1 Building the Estates, 1891-1961

Nyasaland, which would later be named Malawi, became a British ‘protectorate’ in 1891, marking the onset of 73 years of British rule. The colonialization of the region followed a standard pattern. Ambiguous treaties were made, troops were used to make resistors ‘come to their senses’ and the creation of the colonial administrative structure transferred political power to the British, marginalizing Africans in economic and political decision making.52

The colony’s first governor, Harry Johnston, saw himself faced with a large financial challenge as the British foreign office had informed him that the treasury would not provide revenue to support the protectorate, except for the salaries of civil servants. A lack of available mineral resources led the administration to pursue an

52 Consider for a detailed (and biased) first-person description by the colony’s first governor: Harry Johnston,

British Central Africa (London, 1897), 80-151, https://archive.org/details/britishafrica00johnuoft/page/n17 [last consulted 11-12-2019].

(20)

20 based export economy to generate revenues. Most indigenous agriculture in the region at the time however consisted of subsistence farming, with limited trade and exports. A capitalist export culture thus had to be created, which was done by introducing the notion of private (instead of communal) land and a habit of land alienation. This process had already started prior to the establishment of colonial rule, with small numbers of Europeans (57 in 1891, 300 by 1896) acquiring land through trade, warfare and treaties with chiefs (which promised them protection from Portuguese colonists and explorers).53

This process was accelerated by the Johnston administration, which introduced a new land ownership structure between 1892 and 1894.54 Land was classified in two ways,

either as ‘freehold’ (which basically meant that it was held by Europeans) or as ‘crown land’, which meant that it belonged to the British state. In practice, this meant that European estates could fairly easily accrue the most fertile land through the support of the colonial administration, leading to a clear-cut division of the country’s agriculture in two sub-sectors: the European estate sector, producing export crops, and an African peasant or ‘smallholder’ sector, mainly producing foodstuffs. At the end of 1894, 15% of cultivated land was already held by a small number of Europeans, with 72% of these acres belonging to a mere 11 estate holders.55

The plantations enjoyed benefits beyond owning the best land. In contrast to the smallholders, they faced no restrictions on the crops they could grow. The most lucrative ones, such as flue-cured tobacco and tea, were even the exclusive domain of the estates as to maximize their possibilities of generating revenue.56 Furthermore, estate owners had

access to cheap labour, which was commonly drawn from the African population whose villages and farms happened to be on the bought properties. The indigenous notion of thangata, which in pre-colonial times had meant as much as reciprocal agricultural help between members of the same community, was basically reinterpreted as a form of forced labour. Colonial commissions argued that ‘…what first brought the native and the European together was a contract of labour in exchange for ground on which the native could make his garden and build his hut … this system is purely native life and its

53 Sahle, Democratisation in Malawi, 60. 54 Johnston, British Central Africa, 112-113.

55 Pachai Bridglai, “Land Policies in Malawi: An Examination of the Colonial Legacy”, The Journal of African

History 14:4 (Cambridge, 1973), 681-698, here 683.

(21)

21 continued existence … shows that it has practical convenience for both sides”.57 The

African population logically did not agree, but despite various uprisings such as the Chilembwe riot of 1915, the regime’s labour policy saw little true alterations.58

While the smallholder sector was not completely neglected, it remained vitally subdued to the primacy of the estates and the financial needs of the colonial administration. For example, following a severe cotton shortage in 1902 (due to unstable prices caused by speculative trading in the USA), Britain sought to reduce its dependence on US grown cotton and started encouraging its production in the colonies.59 The colonial

state in Malawi therefore stimulated peasant cotton production through e.g. tax rebates. Such policies however lasted only two growing seasons, because it led to a reduction in the labour supply for the estate sub-sector as most African farmers preferred growing their own cotton.60 Despite such unreliable and often restricting state intervention, cotton

and especially tobacco production (low-earning types such as dark-fired western leaf, as

57 1921 Land Commission of Nyasaland, as quoted in: J.A.K. Kandawire, “Thangata in Pre-Colonial and Colonial

Systems of Land Tenure in Southern Malawi”, Africa 47:2 (1977), 185-191.

58 See for a discussion: Jenny de Nobel, A right to land? Population density and land rights in Malawi, Zambia

and Zimbabwe, 1923-2013 (MA thesis, Leiden, 2016), 53-54.

59 See: Allen Isaacman and Richard Roberts (eds.), Cotton, Colonialism and Social History in Sub-Saharan Africa

(Portsmouth, 1995).

60 Leroy Vail, “The State and the Creation of Colonial Malawi’s Agricultural Economy”, in: Robert Rotberg (ed.),

Imperialism, Colonialism and Hunger: East and Central Africa (Lexington, 1983), 39-87, here 61.

Source: Vail, “Malawi’s Agricultural Economy”, 63; Martin Prowse, “A history of tobacco production and marketing in Malawi, 1890-2010”, Journal of Eastern

African Studies 7:4 (2013), 691-712, here 697.

0 2000 4000 6000 8000

MALAWI TOBACCO PRODUCTION

1923-1943

Smallholder Tobacco Production (in tons) Estate Tobacco Production (in tons)

(22)

22 prime tobacco was reserved for the estates) within the smallholder sector grew rapidly (see figure 2).

In response, the marketing of peasant produce was monopolised by state marketing boards, a practice which would be continued after independence. The ‘Native Tobacco Board’ was first established in 1926, while cotton was regulated through state sanctioned traders until 1951, when a cotton board was created. In the following year, a marketing board for foodstuffs was also set up. These boards would be merged in 1956 to create the Agricultural Production and Marketing Board, which formed the basis for the post-independence Agricultural Development and Marketing Corporation (ADMARC). All of this is important, because the boards were used by the colonial and postcolonial regime to siphon revenues from the smallholders to the government and the estates, basically constituting a bottom-to-top income redistribution. The given rationale of the colonial state was that this kind of agricultural marketing would be more efficient and stabilise prices for peasant producers. However, by determining ‘reasonable prices’ for peasants and paying them well below true market profits, the board put great limits on the possibilities for smallholders to develop their farms, while once again favouring the estates.61

Underlying this approach to smallholder farming were racist and paternalistic attitudes, which both favoured the idea of Africans working for the European elite and considered African agriculture too underdeveloped to be enabled to develop on its own (despite the clear growth in production).62 The tensions this system logically created

between the African and European population grew markedly after the Second World War. In response, the colonial state sought to expand its political base among rural producers by creating a class of so called ‘yeoman’ or ‘master farmers’. The idea was that the best individuals among the smallholders would be encouraged to develop their plots through cash bonuses and the availability of free seeds, fertiliser and advice.63 However,

as Sahle has pointed out, “little success was achieved in the long run since these policies did not address the fundamental issues … such as the monopolisation of peasant production and availability of land”.64

61 R.W. Kettlewell, “Agricultural Change in Nyasaland: 1945-1960”, Studies in Tropical Development 5:3

(Stanford, 1965), 229-285, here 248.

62 Sahle, Democratisation in Malawi, 71. 63 Kettlewell, “Agricultural Change”, 274-275. 64 Sahle, 71.

(23)

23

4.2 Independence and State-led Capitalism, 1961-1979

As such, by the late-1950s, Nyasaland had developed into an elite-led undemocratic state with a narrow economic and political basis. Despite the administration’s conviction that the estate sub-sector would be the engine of growth, its development policy had largely benefited the social and economic elite with limited trickle-down effects. This resulted in a poor country with a highly illiterate population and a lack of economic opportunities and arable land for smallholders, which was further exacerbated by a growing population. The skewed socio-economic structure this created provided the anti-colonial movement with its main ammunition to criticise the colonial state.65 It is therefore somewhat

surprising that the emerging elite of the independence movement in practice focused almost exclusively on political independence. Despite a strong socio-economic rhetoric, little actual regard was given to the social and economic structures which made up the country or the question how the country should be run after independence. Instead, the nascent African elite which would take over the country in 1964 mirrored the autocratic tendencies of the colonial state, showcased by an intolerance of dissent and an advocacy of the concentration of power in one national party on the grounds that this was consistent with local cultural norms.66 This put constraints on personal freedom and civic

liberty in the post-independence state, while in the long run also leading to a government once again largely serving an economic and political elite with limited responsiveness to the needs of the broader population.

This is not to say that no attempts at all were made to foster smallholder production in the first years following independence. The government launched four integrated rural development programmes with some WB support as to increase the production of cash crops by smallholders.67 These programmes consisted of considerable

investments in rural infrastructure, land improvement, farmer education and the provision of services and credit. The general logic behind this approach was sound, in the sense that successful agricultural development required a comprehensive approach which tackled not just agricultural projects themselves but also connected issues, such as infrastructural constraints. Yet, despite significant investments and a relative decline in the importance of estate agriculture till 1966 (see figure 3), increase in smallholder

65 See for a more detailed discussion of the anti-colonial struggle; Sahle, “Democratisation in Malawi”, 74-88. 66 John McCracken, A History of Malawi, 1859-1966 (Woolbridge/Rochester, 2012), 374-375.

67 Frederic Pryor, The Political Economy of Poverty, Equity and Growth. Malawi and Madagascar (Oxford, 1990),

(24)

24 production disappointed for a variety of reasons. Firstly, most of the technology and credit packages offered were unsuitable for everyone but the largest smallholders, because of the required investments in capital goods and the need for trained personnel. Secondly, the still enforced requirement to sell export crops to the Farmers Marketing Board for a relatively low price limited growth, as this meant fewer opportunities and incentives for farmers to invest money in their farms. Thirdly, constraints on the availability of land, especially in the southern and central regions of the country, remained unaddressed, hindering effective supply-side response from smallholders. Together, these factors meant that the grand agricultural projects mainly benefited richer farmers, inadvertently contributing to the former colonial ‘wager-on-the-strong’ development policy.

Source: Pryor, Poverty, Equity and Growth, 86.

(25)

25 In response, the regime of president Hastings Banda shifted its developmental focus to the estates once again, continuing the favourable treatment they had received under colonial rule. The official aim was to create a propertied elite, which would take the lead in development and inspire their countrymen to do the same. This however also handily served to consolidate Banda’s political base by creating socio-economic ties and political debt between his regime and wealthy Malawians.68 Estate support took a wide variety of

forms. For starters, legislation which would have allowed smallholder production of burley tobacco and other ‘estate’ cash crops was cancelled in 1965. This meant that the smallholder sub-sector was largely directed to focus on low-profit food production. A whole bunch of Land Acts were introduced between 1965 and 1967, which allowed the Minister of Agriculture to convert customary into private land, inherently transferring smallholder land to the estate sector and allowing its acquisition by people with capital or enough political sway to obtain the necessary credit.69 The credit came from two

sources; firstly, the country’s only two banks were controlled by Banda and his political allies, which instructed the banks to provide credit to the estates.70 Secondly, the Farmer

Marketing Board remained in place, paying smallholders by one estimate as little as 40 to 60% of actual crop value, investing the profits made this way in the estate sector.71 As

such, it should be no surprise that Banda and close allies also bought a bunch of estates for themselves. Together with a boom in crop - especially tobacco - prices on the world market did these economic-political arrangements set the stage for the great expansion of the estate sector from the late 1960s onwards and an impressive record of economic growth.

68 Ibid., 81.

69 See: Sahle, Democratisation in Malawi, 175. 70 Prowse, “A history of tobacco”, 701.

71 J. Kydd, “Malawi in the 1970s: Development Policies and Economic Change”, in: Kings Phiri et al. (eds.),

(26)

26 While estimates differ, GDP grew around 6% per year between 1965 and 1979 (see figure 4), with the estate sector, being its engine, growing at 17% per year.72 Despite these

numbers, which also compared favourably to other SSA countries at the time, growth proved both highly uneven and inherently unstable. On the former, the concentration of investment in and the preferential treatment of the estate sector indeed led to the creation of a small, wealthy elite. However, the predicted trickle-down effects, both in a material sense and the hope of technological and entrepreneurial fertilisation through example, didn’t materialise. This was largely due to the above mentioned constraints on the smallholder sector, which meant that few non-estate farmers could respond to or even received viable economic incentives to increase production. Land alienation for the estate sector was also to blame, as it had meant a reduction of land available to smallholders. This was exacerbated by a rapidly growing population, which led to the accelerating fragmentation and degradation of plots (a process which continues till this very day).73 As

such, due to the government’s focus on an elite-led economic, rather than social development approach, most of the wealth from Malawian exports accrued within an economic-political elite which had “well vested interests in the state control of the economy”.74

72 Jane Harrigan, “U-Turns and Full Circes: Two Decades of Agricultural Reform in Malawi 1981-2000”, World

Development 31:5 (2003), 847-863, here 848.

73 Conroy et al., Poverty, AIDS and Hunger, 18.

74 Guy Mhone (ed.), Malawi at the Crossroads: The Post-Colonial Political Economy (Harare, 1992), 44.

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 9 6 0 - 1 9 6 4 1 9 6 5 - 1 9 6 9 1 9 7 0 - 1 9 7 4 1 9 7 5 - 1 9 7 9 1 9 8 0 - 1 9 8 4 1 9 8 5 - 1 9 8 9 1 9 9 0 - 1 9 9 4

MALAWI AVERAGE RATE OF

GROWTH OF REAL GDP PER HALF

DECADE (%)

Source: C. Chipeata and M. Mkandawire, Explaining African Economic Growth

Performance: A Case of Malawi (Research Paper, Zomba, 2002), 2; Conroy et al.,

Poverty, AIDS and Hunger, 17.

(27)

27 Economic growth was also unstable, due to the deeply interconnected structure of Malawi’s political economy and a lack of sources of income other than tea and especially tobacco exports. Since 1964, the Banda regime had steadily increased its control over the Malawian economy. A mere three companies - namely the Malawian Development Corporation (MDC), Press Holdings (Banda’s personal conglomerate) and ADMARC (the aforementioned marketing board which was created out of the Farmer’s Marketing Board in 1971) – were controlled by the political elite and heavily involved in all sectors of the economy. As both banks were also state-owned, Malawi’s entrepreneurial landscape was effectively dominated by these 3 elite-owned, inherently parastatal companies (consider Sahle’s tables on the next few pages).75 Not only is it likely that this limited private

investment and industrial development, but it also meant that the country was made very vulnerable to recessions. MDC, Press, ADMARC and the banks all had large outstanding investments and debts in one another. When the economy went sour from 1979 onwards, Malawi’s entire economy including the state’s budget was affected in a domino-like fashion.

The country’s conscious dependency on agricultural exports also meant a structural economic risk. Industrialization didn’t really take off in the relatively open Malawian economy, a sector which only grew slightly from 8% of GDP in 1964 to 12% in the early 1980s.76 Industrial growth was also thwarted by low levels of effective consumer

demand in the internal market, which for an important part resulted from the vast social inequalities realised by Malawi’s elitarian economy. As a significant portion of the existing industry was also agriculture-related (e.g. tobacco processing), it didn’t offer an alternative source of revenue when cash crops faltered.

As such, by 1979 a state-backed elite preceded over an inherently colonial and centralised ‘capitalist’ economy, occupying all key positions in the agrarian, commercial and industrial sectors. A range of external shocks would however plummet the narrow basis of the Malawian economy into structural problems in that year, leading to the continued involvement of the WB from 1981 onwards. The assessment made of these circumstances by the WB and the then implemented policies are the subject of the next chapter.

75 Sahle, Democratisation in Malawi, 189-190.

76 Ben Kaluwa, “Malawi Industry: Policies, Performance and Problems”, in: Mhone, Malawi at the Crossroads,

(28)

28

(29)

29

Figure 6 ADMARC’s Commercial Investments

(30)

30

5. Economic Adjustment without Structural Change, 1979-1991

The external shocks which derailed the Malawian economy in the late 1970s were threefold, and came in quick succession. Due to the Second Oil Crisis and the corresponding rise in transport costs, trade declined with 35% as at the same time cash crop prices on the world market contracted. While this would prove to be the onset of the broader SSA debt crisis of the 1980s, Malawi’s

situation was exacerbated by the escalating civil war in Mozambique (partly caused by the Banda regime itself, because it supported Mozambican rebel groups), which disrupted its two main export lines (see map and the rise of freight costs throughout the 1980s in figure 8). The collapse of income was then finished off by a drought in 1980 and 1981,

Source: Ben Kaluwa, The Structural Adjustment Programme in Malawi: A Case of Successful Adjustment? (Harare, 1992), 4. Note: High inflation occurred in Malawi in the late 1980s, which largely explains the ostensible explosion of freight costs from 1987 onwards.

(31)

31 leading to severe food shortages and forcing the government to import maize, prompting budget deficits and increasing debt.77

In response, Banda opened negotiations with the WB for a two-year Structural Adjustment Loan (SAL-1), which was agreed on in June 1981. Eventually, this would lead to a whole range of adjustment programmes (including 5 SAL’s) throughout the 1980s, which all sought to encourage productivity, diversify the export base and further promote exports through agricultural liberalisation and stabilization of Malawi’s macro-economy. They aimed to do so by strengthening government policy making while also reducing government spending.78

The general problem with all these Adjustment Programmes however is the limited assessments on which these policy recommendations were based. Most WB reports from this period spoke highly of the development policies pursued by the Banda regime since independence. The economic downturn was therefore regarded as the unforeseen consequence of external shocks, which could be solved by further removing market impediments. Fostering market forces would boost economic growth by presenting Malawians with more incentives to produce export commodities and diversify their export base. Policy reform mainly focused on agriculture because of its economic dominance. The WB however did not fully understand the structural constraints placed on smallholders by the historic duality between the smallholder and estate sector, nor did it consider the economic-political power structures which kept this duality in place. This generated some fundamental problems for its programme of agricultural liberalization to succeed and actually allowed the estate sector to expand even further.

77 World Bank, Third Structural Adjustment Operation No. P-4172-MAI (25-11-1985), 2.

(32)

32

5.1 Agricultural Liberalization

The WB correctly noticed that relative smallholder export production largely lagged behind the estate sector and saw this as an opportunity for renewed economic growth. The problem is that the WB almost exclusively considered ADMARC price controls as the main market impediment to increased and diversified production. As mentioned, it is very true that ADMARC’s policy of paying smallholders below world market prices had meant a bottom-to-top income redistribution, largely to the benefit of the estate sector. It therefore made sense to reduce such implicit export taxes by decontrolling prices and removing or limiting ADMARC’s monopoly, as the possible increase in income for smallholders could foster production. To make the most out of this policy, maize prices were held down and fertiliser subsidies targeted for removal to further the incentive to increase and diversify export crop production in the smallholder sector.79 However, price

liberalization did not generate the desired effect, as other fundamental constraints remained ignored, presenting a continuation of earlier ‘colonial’ policies and inhibiting most smallholders to respond effectively.

For starters, smallholders strangely remained precluded from the production of prime tobacco, tea and sugar, which were maintained as estate-crops. Instead, they were supposed to increase production of cotton, groundnuts and ‘lesser’ forms of tobacco. WB reports from this time period do not even mention this constraint, merely focusing on price controls.80 Whether completely overlooked or deemed not important enough, the

continued reservation of the most profitable cash crops for the estate sector allowed the elite to keep constraining smallholder production in this area, thus limiting both competition and plausible changes in income.81 The possible benefits which could have

been generated can be illuminated by the early 1990s, when prime tobacco production was finally liberalized. Districts with a concentration of smallholder production saw an economic boom, and the WB even claimed that “…smallholder profits from burley sales have provided the largest ever cash injection of income in rural Malawi”.82

The issue of land shortage and alienation, which had been a topic throughout Malawi’s colonial history, was likewise ignored by the WB. The Land Acts introduced in

79 Conroy et al., Poverty, AIDS and Hunger, 94.

80 E.g. World Bank, Program Performance Audit Report No. 6833 (Washington, 1987), 9, 52. 81 Prowse, “A history of tobacco”, 702.

82 Ibid.; World Bank, Accelerating Malawi’s Growth: Long-Term Prospects and Transitional Problems

(33)

33 the 1960s had allowed the Banda regime to provide Malawi’s economic-political elite with leased estates, as ministers could easily convert customary land into private land. Together with the preferential treatment the estates received, the sector had expanded greatly from the mid-1960s onwards (see figure 3, P24), withdrawing land from the customary sector and thus reducing the lands available to smallholders. While this logically caused disruption and unrest in several areas of the country, it was not generally known abroad due to Banda’s tight grip on the media.83 However, when the WB got

involved from 1981 onwards, it allowed the Banda regime and its ‘subsidiaries’ to continue this process of land annexation to the benefit of the estate sector. While the estates had absorbed some 300,000 hectares of customary land during the 1970s, they managed to carve out another 400,000 hectares between 1980 and 1993.84 In contrast to

the 1970s, however, did the further expansion of the estate sector not lead to a recurrence of high economic growth. This was partly because of the slump of cash crop prices on the world market and rising transport costs, but also followed from the mismanagement of the estates themselves. Many members of the elite weren’t particularly concerned with the most efficient or extensive development of their estates as profits still accrued. As such, they lacked incentives to invest or develop all their plots, which lead to inefficient production considering the total amount of estate land.85 The latter explains the large

divergence between the hectares of planted land and the total amount of hectares the estates annexed over the years.86 More problematically, however, did the intensifying

process of land alienation under the not so watchful eye of the WB combine with an ever growing population to increase land shortages for the population at large. Available plots became smaller as they were divided at inheritance and land degraded at an alarming rate (both through inadequate fallows and extensive homogenous crop cultivation), further exacerbated by the necessitated usage of land not suitable for extensive agriculture.

This proved detrimental to the goal of broad development behind agricultural liberalization. In the early 1990s, a mere 25% of all smallholder holdings exceeded 1.5 hectares, the necessary amount to be able to grow cash crops next to food crops. Many smallholders only had enough land to secure their subsistence (0.7 to 1.5), with no acres

83 Pauline Peters and Daimon Kambewa, “Whose Security? Deepening Social Conflict Over ‘Customary’ Land in

the Shadow of Land Tenure Reform in Malawi”, The Journal of Modern African Studies 45:3 (2007), 447-472, here 451.

84 Cammack, “Malawi, 1980-2002”, 48; Nobel, A right to land?, 62. 85 Conroy et al., Poverty, AIDS and Hunger, 93.

(34)

34 available to grow and sell surpluses. 35% of them even held less than 0.7 ha and were as such often incapable of producing enough food to make it around till the next harvest season.87 As a result, when the WB successfully pushed the Malawian government to

increase producer prices and downsize ADMARC, only larger farm owners could respond effectively. WB analyses from this period stand in stark contrast with later assessments. While the WB argued in 1985 that “about 75 percent of the rural population are receiving higher incomes”,88 David Sahn pointed out in 1994 that producers had not really received

a higher income, but that implicit tax decreases at best had served to stabilize real producer prices in the face of falling world prices.89 Pauline Peters stated that market

liberalization did indeed provide some new income opportunities through the sale of tobacco and maize, but that the profits solely went to elite business leaders and larger farmers. Middle- and low-income groups in contrast experienced a deterioration in their income and food security.90 As contemporary WB data bases also show a contraction of

GDP per capita in this period, the WB reports from the 1980s seem strangely inaccurate and overtly optimistic (see figure 9). The benefits some farmers and traders experienced

87 Ben Kaluwa, The Structural Adjustment Programme in Malawi: A Case of Successful Adjustment? (Harare,

1992), 50.

88 World Bank, Third Structural Adjustment Operation No. P-4172-MAI (25-11-1985), 17.

89 David Sahn and Jehan Arulpragasam, “Malawi: Adjustment without Structural Change”, in: David Sahn (ed.),

Adjusting to Policy Failure in African Economies (Ithaca and London, 1994), 196-233.

90 Pauline Peters, “Failed Magic or Social Context? Market Liberalization and the Rural Poor in Malawi”, Harvard

Institute for International Development Report (Cambridge (MA), 1996). 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 1960 1962 1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016

Malawi GDP Per Capita (constant 2010 US$) 1960-2017

Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators,

https://databank.worldbank.org/data/reports.aspx?source=2&country=MWI# [last consulted 11-12-2019].

(35)

35 were also divided unequally across the country; areas with sufficient infrastructure were much better able to sell of surpluses, while the closure of ADMARC depots in less connected areas meant that farmers saw their trade opportunities and therefore income diminishing. Most private traders and smallholders likewise lacked the credit and infrastructure support ADMARC had held, further inhibiting an effective private sector response.

5.2 The Big 3

While the adjustment programmes in Malawi were heavily focused on the agricultural sector, limited attention was also given to the concentration of economic power in the hands of MDC, ADMARC and Press Holdings, Malawi’s 3 biggest conglomerates. However, the steps taken in response to their monopolistic position were once again based on faulty assessments and as such led to detrimental policies.

At the start of the SAPs in 1981, the WB knew that there was an excessive concentration of ownership. However, because of the severe interconnectedness between MDC, ADMARC and Press and their close ties with the financial sector, all 3 companies were deemed ‘too big to fail’ for the Malawian economy. Under SAL-I conditionality, studies were therefore commissioned to develop ‘detailed plans’ for the restructuring of these companies.91 Starting in 1984, major assets that had previously been controlled by

the state through the parastatal sector were sold to ‘private investors’ under a privatisation programme. As Sahle has pointed out, from the WB’s point of view, “the privatisation programme was not only a way of reducing state’s involvement in the economy, thus reducing opportunities for rent-seeking activities, but was also a means of encouraging the growth of entrepreneurs who were not closely tied to the state”.92

However, the WB failed to see that the only people able to buy these assets were members of the state-backed elite. For the strangest of reasons, Banda’s own Press Corporation, at the time officially heavily indebted to the government, was even allowed to become one of the biggest buyers.93 In pushing for the privatisation programme, the WB had naïvely

assumed that the lines between the public and private spheres in Malawi were clearly drawn and that as such private entrepreneurs would pop up and take over companies.

91 World Bank, Third Structural Adjustment Operation No. P-4172-MAI (25-11-1985), 15. 92 Sahle, Democratisation in Malawi, 219.

93 Ibid., 219-222; World Bank, Performance Audit Report Malawi. Industrial and Trade Policy Adjustment

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

In the eight- eenth century, the Lunda Empire became one of the most important suppli- ers of slaves for the long-distance trade, while Kazembe was the strongest power in

Chinese migration to Africa has grown in the wake of increasing trade and investment and it is estimated that between 700,000 and 1 million Chinese are living in Africa today.

‘The crucial event in the earlier history of central Africa has been not the creation of a Luba kingdom by Kongolo and Kalala Ilunga but the introduction of Luba principles

The data of the control and explanatory variables, log GDP per capita of the previous period, population growth, investment, inflation rates, trade, government consumption, inflation,

SACU — with South Africa, Botswana, Lesotho, Namibia, and Swaziland as members - is a well established customs union that currendy operates under the terms of an agreement concluded

Discontent with Gold Coast cocoa price policy stimulated support for Togolese reunification, but the lack of economie Integration between British and French Togo weakened Ewe resolve

To cite this article: Valerie D’Erman , Paul Schure & Amy Verdun (2020) Introduction to “Economic and Financial Governance in the European Union after a decade of Economic

When the owner prefers to over-invest in extraction capacity, a marginal improvement in the strength of property rights may actually reduce the social value of the resource, by