• No results found

State capitalism and state owned enterprises : a case study of the Chinese energy sector

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "State capitalism and state owned enterprises : a case study of the Chinese energy sector"

Copied!
65
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

 

State  Capitalism  and  State  Owned  Enterprises.  A  

Case  Study  of  the  Chinese  Energy  Sector  

        Author:  M.W.  Vos   Student  Number:  6056679    

Supervisor:  Prof.  J.W.J.  Harrod   Second  Reader:  P.W.H.  Aarts    

Master  Thesis  Political  Science   International  Relations  

Seminar:  The  Political  Economy  of  Trade  and  Investment:  The  Global  Politic  of   Corporate  Sectors  

 

(2)

Table  of  Contents  

 

1. Introduction                 p.  4  

2. Theoretical  Framework               p.  8  

2.1. State  Capitalism               p.  8  

2.1.1. A  New  Type  of  State  Capitalism         p.  10  

2.2. Surplus  Maximization             p.  14  

2.3. Summary                 p.  17  

3. Research  Methods               p.  19  

4. The  Evolution  of  the  Chinese  Petro  Sector:  ‘Going  Out’     p.  22  

4.1. Summary                 p.  26  

5. Foreign  Investments  by  Chinese  NOC’s           p.  27  

5.1. Energy  Backed  Loans             p.  33  

5.2. The  Middle  East               p.  37  

5.2.1. Iran                 p.  38  

5.2.2. Iraq                 p.  40  

5.2.3. Saudi  Arabia               p.  42  

5.3. North  America               p.  43  

5.4. Summary                 p.  46    

6. Who  Runs  Chinese  SOE’s             p.  48  

7. Conclusion                 p.  52  

8. Bibliography                 p.  55  

(3)

List  of  Abbreviations  

 

AEIA:  American  Energy  Information  Agency   BP:  British  Petroleum  

CDB:  China  Development  Bank   CEB:  China  Exim  Bank  

 CCP:  Chinese  Communist  Party  

CNPC:  China’s  National  Petroleum  Company   CNOOC:  China’s  National  Offshore  Oil  Company   EBL:  Energy  Backed  Loan  

IEA:  International  Energy  Agency  

MFO:  Chinese  Ministry  of  Foreign  Affairs   MOFCOM:  Chinese  Ministry  of  Commerce   MPI:  Ministry  of  Petroleum  Industry   NOC:  National  Oil  Company  

PLA:  People’s  Liberation  Army   PRC:  People’s  Republic  of  China   SOE:  State-­‐Owned  Enterprise   SPZ:  Special  Economic  Zone  

TPAO:  Türkiye  Petrolleri  Anonim  Ortaklığı   SWF:  Sovereign  Wealth  Fund  

WEC:  World  Energy  Council  

(4)

1.0  Introduction  

 

The  rise  of  China  as  an  economic  super  power  has  been  a  hot  topic  for   international  scholars  over  the  past  three  decades.  The  reforms  that  Deng  

Xiaoping  started  in  the  1980s  have  brought  the  People’s  Republic  of  China  (PRC)   unprecedented  growth  figures  and  reestablished  China  as  a  global  power  and   goes  hand  in  hand  with  China’s  relentless  appetite  for  natural  resources.   Especially  the  hunt  for  energy  resources  is  important  here,  as  many  scholars   have  already  argued  that  it  could  be  driving  China’s  foreign  policy  (Zweig  and  Bi,   2005;  Leverett  and  Bader,  2005;  Dorraj  and  English,  2012).    China’s  energy   resource  security  is  not  only  important  to  continue  its  economic  growth,  but  is   also  key  too  the  survival  of  the  Chinese  Communist  Party  (CCP).  This  is  due  to   the  fact  that  the  economic  growth  of  the  last  decades  has  become  the  

cornerstone  of  China’s  social  stability  (Zweig  and  Bi,  2005).  Taking  this  into   account  it  can  be  argued  that  most  of  the  policies  that  are  implemented  by  the   CCP  are  driven  by  the  strategic  economic  interest  of  the  state.  

  The  reforms  that  Deng  Xiaoping  started  in  the  1980s  have  opened-­‐up  the   Peoples  Republic  to  the  rest  of  the  world.  The  Foreign  Direct  Investments  

flowing  into  the  country  skyrocketed  from  USD  430  million  in  1982  to  253,5   billion  in  2012,  while  the  US  did  not  even  passed  the  200  billion  mark  in  2012   (World  Bank,  2014).  With  the  investments  of  foreign  businesses  in  China  it   became  clear  that  for  China’s  state-­‐owned  enterprises  (SOE’s)  to  be  compatible   on  the  international  market,  entire  economic  sectors  and  business  structures  of   the  SOE’s  had  to  be  reformed  (Zhang,  2004).  The  market  reforms  that  where   started  in  the  1980s  accelerated  with  the  implementation  of  the  Zǒuchūqū  

Zhànlüè  policy  or  ‘going  out’  policy  by  the  Ministry  of  Foreign  (MFA)  in  1999.  

  The  arrival  of  foreign  companies  in  China  presented  the  CCP  with  the   opportunity  to  experiment  with  different  strategies  in  different  sectors  (Zhang,   2004).  These  pressures  from  international  markets  and  the  development  policy   of  the  CCP  put  a  heavy  burden  on  the  SOE’s,  but  also  provided  new  opportunities.   It  provided  them  with  access  to  new  technology  and  management  techniques,   but  also  access  to  the  much-­‐needed  capital  to  modernize  the  Chinese  economy   and  especially  modernize  the  organization  of  the  different  economic  sectors.  For  

(5)

example,  until  the  end  of  the  1980s  the  Chinese  petrol  sector  was  basically  acting   like  a  ministry.  It  was  the  China  National  Petroleum  Company  (CNPC)  who  

determined  the  production  quotas  and  set  the  price  for  every  product  that  was   produced  within  the  Chinese  petroleum  sector  (Nolan,  2002).  In  short  the   companies  within  the  Chinese  petro  sector  did  not  show  any  resemblance  with   the  western  businesses  on  the  international  oil  and  gas  markets.  This  changed  in   1990s  when  the  CCP  started  to  reform  its  three  major  national  oil  companies   (NOC’s)  CNPC,  China  National  Offshore  Oil  Company  (CNOOC)  and  Sinopec  with   the  large  international  petro  companies  of  that  time,  like  Royal  Dutch  Shell,   Exxon,  British  Petroleum  (BP)  and  Mobil  set  as  examples.  As  the  reforms  were   rolled  out  the  Chinese  NOC’s  started  to  show  some  resemblance  with  the  private   international  petro  companies,  but  it  was  only  in  1997  that  the  CNPC  was  

completely  cut  loose  from  its  ministerial  responsibilities  (Zhang,  2004).     Even  after  the  reforms  of  the  1980s  and  1990s  all  petro  companies  in   China  are  still  state-­‐owned.  This  is  part  of  a  strategic  long-­‐term  policy  choice  by   the  CCP,  that  Ian  Bremmer  calls  state  capitalism  (2010:  50).  With  state  capitalism   markets  are  used  as  a  tool  that  serve  national  interest,  or  the  interests  of  the   ruling  elites,  and  not  as  an  engine  of  opportunity  for  the  individual  (ibed).  In   short,  the  state  uses  markets  to  extend  political  and  economic  leverage,  both  on   the  domestic  and  the  international  stage.    

  Although  Bremmer  sees  China  as  the  best  example  of  state  capitalism  on   the  international  stage,  there  are  some  problems  with  his  assumption.  This  is   where  the  state-­‐led  market  reforms  come  in  to  play,  because  it  seems  that  these   reforms  have  led  to  more  freedom  for  SOEs  within  the  domestic  and  on  the   international  stage  than  the  CCP  can  control  (Downs,  2011;  Song  et  al,  2011).    As   the  market  reforms  within  China  go  hand  in  hand  with  sectorial  and  corporative   reforms,  Chinese  SOEs  are  starting  to  behave  more  like  other  (i.e.  western)   enterprises.  This  means  that  surplus  maximization  has  become  a  vital  part  to  the   goals  of  the  SOEs  (Downs,  2011;  Zhang,  2004).    

When  considering  the  international  investment  of  Chinese  SOEs  the   strategy  of  state  capitalism,  on  the  one  hand,  and  the  goal  of  surplus  

maximization,  on  the  other,  raises  multiple  questions.  Are  foreign  investments   maid  by  Chinese  SOEs  driven  by  the  foreign  policy  of  the  CCP?  If  so,  what  kind  of  

(6)

control  does  the  CCP  has  over  its  SOEs?  If  not,  are  Chinese  SOEs  becoming  more   independent?  And  therefore,  do  these  SOEs  operate  more  and  more  like  private   enterprises?  Or,  and  this  would  be  even  more  interesting,  are  SOEs  using  the   state  capitalism  that  the  CCP  promotes  to  their  own  advantage?  As  of  yet  the   available  literature  on  this  topic  supports  rather  one  ore  the  other.  Bremmer   states  that  it  is  state  capitalism  all  the  way,  while  others  like  Downs  and  Zhang   state  that  normal  (i.e.  western)  business  strategies  are  now  central  to  Chinese   SOEs  to  achieve  their  goals  (surplus  maximization).  Energy  security  is  one  of  the   major  concerns  of  the  CCP  to  continue  the  economic  development  of  China  and   the  fact  that  the  foreign  investments  portfolio’s  of  the  CNPC,  CNOOC  and  Sinopec   are  among  the  biggest  in  China,  it  seems  that  the  energy  sector  and  especially  the   petroleum  and  natural  gas  sector  are  most  suited  to  answer  the  questions  

mentioned  above.  The  research  question  for  this  thesis  is  therefore  as  follows:    

What  drives  foreign  direct  investment  of  SOEs  in  the  energy  sector?      

This  question  becomes  even  more  interesting  if  current  developments  on  the   international  petro  market  are  taken  into  account.  In  1993  China  became  a  net   importer  of  petroleum  and  by  November  2013  China  surpassed  the  U.S.  as  the   largest  net  importer  of  petroleum  (EIA,  24-­‐03-­‐2014).  This  rapid  development  is   especially  remarkable  if  it  is  taken  into  account  that  the  first  foreign  investments   made  by  a  Chinese  NOC’s  occurred  in  2002(IEA,  2011).  Most  of  the  investments   by  the  NOC’s  since  then  were  made  in  resource  rich  developing  countries,  but   since  2010  Chinese  NOC’s  started  to  successfully  invest  in  American  and   Canadian  companies.  At  the  same  time  the  China  Development  Bank  (CDB)   started  to  provide  so  called  energy  backed  loans  (EBL’s)  to  developing  countries   in  Africa,  Asia  and  Latin  America.  Due  to  the  economic  crisis  of  2008  China  was   one  of  the  few  actors  on  the  international  market  that  could  provide  countries   with  long-­‐term  loans  (Dorraj  and  English,  2012).  The  EBL’s  provided  the  

receiving  countries  with  the  much  needed  capital,  while  China  secured  the  inflow   of  energy  resources  as  these  loans  are  paid  back  by  supplying  these  resources  to   China.  This  gave  the  Chinese  NOC’s  a  competitive  advantage  over  other  

(7)

investments  made  by  the  CNPC,  CNOOC  and  Sinopec.  With  these  developments  in   mind  the  2008  economic  crisis  was  the  start  of  a  tremendous  increase  of  foreign   investments  made  by  the  Chinese  NOC’s  (IEA,  2011).  

  Another  major  development  within  the  international  petro  market  over   the  past  ten  years  is  the  retreat  of  the  US  out  of  the  Middle  East  (Dorraj  and   English,  2012).  The  Americans  did  not  only  pulled  out  of  Iraq  in  2009,  the   American  government  also  decided  to  explore  shale  oil/gas  and  oil  sands  and   therefore  become  less  dependent  on  oil  imports  (Swint,  2014).  British  Petroleum   (BP)  stated  that  ‘the  US  will be  able  to  provide  for  all  its  own  energy  needs  by   2035  as  output  of  shale  oil  and  gas  accelerates  and  demand  growth  slows’  (Ibed).   With  the  diminishing  role  of  the  US  in  the  Middle  East,  China  has  started  a  new   strategy  that  has  been  called  the  New  Silk  Road  (Shah  and  Reed,  2012;  Tiezzi,   2014).  For  the  states  in  the  Middle  East  the  New  Silk  Road  comes  as  a  blessing,   because  the  governments  feared  that  the  shift  of  the  strategic  interest  in  the  US   could  be  harmful  to  the  region  as  U.S.  investment  in  the  region  would  decline   (Shah  and  Reed,  2012).      

As  the  purpose  of  this  thesis  is  to  find  the  strategies  that  are  behind  the   foreign  investments  of  Chinese  SOEs  it  will  contribute  to  a  broader  explanation   of  the  behavior  of  SOEs  and  the  CCP  in  other  economic  sectors  that  are  

strategically  vital  for  the  further  development  of  China.  This  is  true  for  sectors   that  involve  natural  resources,  other  than  energy  resources,  and  maybe  even  for   sectors  with  heavy  involvement  of  People’s  Liberation  Army  (PLA)  the  MFA.   However,  this  is  probably  not  the  case  for  sectors  that  are  involved  in  assembling   final  products,  clothing  and  other  sectors,  as  these  are  strategically  less  

important  to  the  CCP.  

  This  thesis  is  organized  as  follows.  The  second  chapter  will  outline  the   theoretical  framework.  The  third  chapter  will  explain  the  research  methods  that   have  been  used  to  construct  this  paper  and  will  operationalize  the  concepts  of   state  capitalism  and  surplus  maximization.  The  fourth  chapter  presents  the   research  findings  concerning  the  foreign  investments  of  Chinese  NOC’s.  The  fifth   chapter  compares  the  findings  presented  in  this  thesis  with  findings  made  by   other  authors  concerning  the  foreign  investments  of  Chinese  SOE’s.  The  sixth   chapter  concludes  this  thesis.  

(8)

2.0  Theoretical  framework  

 

This  thesis  will  make  use  of  two  different  theories  to  help  explain  the  strategies   of  the  CCP  and  the  NOC’s:  state  capitalism  and  surplus  maximization.  The   concept  of  state  capitalism  helps  explaining  how  the  CCP  would  likely  be  using   SOEs  and  their  investments  abroad  to  reach  their  foreign  policy  and  economic   goals.  However,  as  has  been  already  described  above  the  strategies  of  SOEs  could   also  be  driven  by  normal  (i.e.  Western)  corporate  strategies.  To  help  explain   findings  other  than  related  to  state  capitalism  surplus  maximization  will  be  used   in  this  thesis.    

2.1  State  Capitalism    

The  concept  of  state  capitalism  is  definitely  not  new;  it  has  been  used  throughout   the  history  of  Marxism,  socialism  and  anarchism.  The  term  can  be  traced  back  to   Jan  Waclav  Machajski,  he  claimed  in  1905  that  socialism  was  a  movement  of  the   ruling  elite(s)  that  would  result  in  a  new  type  of  society,  which  he  called  state   capitalism  (The  Economist,  2012:  3).  The  concept  is  mainly  focused  on  state   activity  within  a  capitalist  framework  and  by  this  standard  has  been  around   since  the  dawn  of  capitalism,  although  not  specifically  by  this  name.  On  a  

scientific  level  Marxists,  anarchists,  liberals,  realists  and  many  others  have  used   the  concept  and  as  there  are  many  scholars  there  are  many  definitions  of  state   capitalism.    

  Anton  Pannekoek  stated  that  the  term  state  capitalism,  before  the  Second   World  War,  was  frequently  used  in  two  different  ways.  On  the  one  hand,  it  was   used  to  describe  ‘an  economic  form  in  which  the  state  performs  the  role  of  the   capitalist  employer,  exploiting  the  workers  in  the  interest  of  the  state’,  on  the   other  hand  it  was  used  to  describe  a  system  ‘under  which  capitalist  enterprises   are  controlled  by  the  state’  (Pannekoek,  1937:  1).  Pannekoek’s  definition  of  state   capitalism  is  very  basic  and  is  still  completely  based  on  Marxist  literature.  After   the  Second  World  War  scholars  started  using  state  capitalism  to  understand  and  

(9)

describe  the  economies  of  the  third  world  (Petras,  1977,  Dupuy  and  Truchil,   1979;  Frieden,  1981).    

Petras  used  state  capitalism  to  describe  a  process,  which  was  set  in   motion  by  states  to  transform  an  agricultural  export  society  through  national   industrialization.  State  capitalism  allowed  the  governments  of  these  states  to   create  an  internal  market  for  agricultural  products,  reduce  the  power  of  the   landlords,  and  to  mobilize  natural  resources  in  a  way  that  they  could  harness  the   created  surpluses  for  national  development  projects  (1977:  4).  Keeping  the   process  of  national  industrialization  in  mind,  Petras  claims  that  the  import-­‐ substitution  strategy  originate  from  a  state  capitalist  perspective,  which  was   used  in  Latin  America  during  the  1950s  and  1960s  (ibid:  5).  State  capitalism,  in   the  way  that  Petras  understands  it,  is  a  product  of  a  specific  historical  

conjuncture:  the  intensification  of  inter-­‐imperialist  rivalries  coupled  with  the   relative  decline  of  the  United  States  hegemony  at  that  time  and  the  increase  of   anti-­‐imperialists  struggles  resulting  form  intensified  class  struggles  within  third   world  societies  (Fernandez  and  Ocampo,  1975;  Petras,  1977;  Bamat,  1977).     However,  in  the  way  that  Petras,  Bamat  and  Fernandez  and  Ocampo   present  state  capitalism  as  a  new  concept  is  problematic.  The  essence  of  the  state   in  a  capitalist  society  is  that  it  functions  to  reproduce  the  conditions  for  capitalist   accumulation  (Dupuy  and  Truchil,  1979:  9).  In  underdeveloped  countries  self-­‐ sustained  capitalist  growth  is  still  absent,  this  means  that  foreign  capital  is   needed  to  keep  capitalist  growth  going.  This  provides  states  with  a  problem  as   ‘[t]he  consequences  are  the  relative  weakness  of  domestic  capital  vis-­‐fi-­‐vis   foreign  capital,  and  the  failure  of  …  domestic  classes  to  develop  independently  of   and  to  compete  with  foreign  capital’  (ibid:  10).  As  states  try  to  to  counter  the   dominant  position  of  foreign  capital  within  their  economies,  while  keeping  the   economic  growth  rates  on  the  same  level  at  the  same  time,  states  need  to  create   strong  and  centralized  bureaucracies  to  sustain  capitalist  accumulation  (Evans,   1976:  139).  It  is  for  this  reason  that  an  underdeveloped  capitalist  state  is  more   involved  in  the  economic  process  than  in  advanced  capitalist  states.  According  to   Dupuy  and  Truchil  (1977)  authors  like  Petras  and  Bamat  did  not  create  a  new   concept,  but  simply  put  a  new  label  on  a  process  that  can  be  perfectly  explained   by  the  logic  of  capitalism  itself.    

(10)

Dupuy  and  Truchil  recognized  that  the  states  in  Latin  America  had  become  more   active  in  these  respective  economies,  but  during  this  time  the  state  did  not   become  an  autonomous  accumulating  unit  and  the  bureaucracies  did  not  replace   the  already  existing  capitalist  classes  (1977:  14).  Even  the  nationalization  of   different  enterprises,  which  according  to  Petras  and  Batam  is  essential  for  state   capitalism,  did  only  occur  to  decrease  investments  risks  and  increase  the  inward   flow  of  foreign  investments  (Frieden,  1981:  407).    

2.1.1  A  New  Type  of  State  Capitalism    

With  the  rise  of  China  since  the  beginning  of  the  1980s  it  seems  that  a  more   advanced  type  of  state  capitalism  has  been  rising  as  well.  The  CCP  had  learned   from  the  failures  in  Latin  America  and  began  experimenting  with  capitalism  on  a   smaller  scale  with  the  first  special  economic  zones  (SPZ)  in  Shenzhen,  Zuhai,   Shantou,  Xiamen  and  Hainan  at  the  beginning  of  the  1980s.  But  the  experiment   in  China  with  capitalism  seems  to  have  its  limits  (Rickards,  2011).  Instead  of   implementing  a  form  of  market  capitalism  over  night,  China  was  one  of  the  first   states  to  choose  a  path  of  more  gradual  reforms.  Along  with  establishing  SPZs   the  CCP  also  started  to  reform  the  business  structures  of  SOEs  and  used  different   economic  sectors  to  experiment  with  different  kinds  of  corporate  reforms  

(Zhang,  2004).  Over  time  many  SOEs  were  given  the  opportunity  to  become   privately  owned  companies.  However,  there  is  still  a  large  portion  of  SOEs  that  is   not  allowed  to  follow  the  same  path.  SOEs  that  operate  in  economic  sectors  that   the  CCP  deems  vital  to  the  development  of  China  as  a  modern  state  are  still   under  firm  state  control  (Bremmer,  2009).  

  The  concept  of  state  capitalism  is  useful  in  explaining  this  process  of  the   limited  implementation  of  capitalism,  as  it  is  known  in  Western  countries.  The   concept  it  self  seems  to  stem  from  classical  mercantilism  (Luttwak,  1993;  1999).   Mercantilism  was  used  by  European  states  between  the  16th  and  18th  century  to   establish  government  control  over  a  state’s  economy  for  the  purpose  of  

increasing  state  power  at  the  cost  of  rival  nations  (Johnson,  1974).  As  state   capitalism  originates  form  mercantilism  it  clashes  with  modern  day  capitalism.   State  capitalism  is  therefore  seen  as  a  threat  to  the  free  market  (Bremmer,  2009).  

(11)

The  way  in  which,  for  example,  Brazil,  China  and  Russia  have  used  state  led   development  have  made  Bremmer  to  believe  that  ‘[t]he  free-­‐market  tide  has  now   receded.  In  its  place  has  come  state  capitalism...  This  trend  has  stoked  a  new   global  competition,  not  between  rival  political  ideologies  but  between  competing   economic  models.  And  with  the  injection  of  politics  into  economic  decision-­‐ making,  an  entirely  different  set  of  winners  and  losers  is  emerging’  (Bremmer,   2009:  40-­‐41).  Bremmer  is  not  alone;  Rickards  for  example  states  that  this  new   development,  where  corporations  are  extensions  of  state  power  gravely  

endangers  the  world  economy  today  (2011,  149).  The  2008  economic  crisis  has   strengthened  this  view  as  ‘the  crisis  of  liberal  capitalism  has  been  more  rendered   more  serious  by  the  rise  of  a  potent  alternative:  state  capitalism,  which  tries  to   meld  the  powers  of  the  state  with  the  power  of  capitalism.  It  depends  on   governments  to  pick  winners  and  promote  economic  growth.  But  it  also  uses   capitalist  tools  such  listing  state  owned  companies  on  the  stock  market  an   embracing  globalization  (The  Economist,  2012).    

  The  most  important  difference  between  state  capitalism  and  

mercantilism  is  its  focus  on  present  day  phenomena.  State  capitalism  embraces   globalization,  to  a  certain  extent  the  free  market  and  other  economic  tools  that   were  less  important  or  non-­‐existent  in  the  17th  century  (Bremmer,  2009;  

Rickards,  2011).  Also  the  way  scholars  used  state  capitalism  during  the  Cold  War   to  describe  the  economies  of  developing  countries  is  not  useful  for  the  purpose   of  this  thesis.  The  way  in  which  Bremmer  uses  the  concept  is  a  good  start:    

‘governments  use  various  kinds  of  state-­‐owned  companies  to  manage  the   exploitation  of  resources  that  they  consider  the  state’s  crown  jewels  and  the   create  and  maintain  large  numbers  of  jobs  …..  the  state  is  using  markets  to  create   wealth  that  can  be  directed  as  political  officials  see  fit  ….  [and]  the  ultimate   motive  is  not  economic  (profit  maximization),  but  political  (maximizing  the   state’s  power  and  the  leaderships  chances  of  survival)’  (Bremmer,  2010:  11)    

Bremmer  uses  three  different  types  of  companies  to  explain  the  functions  of   state  capitalism:  national  oil  (and  gas)  companies,  privately  owned  national   champions,  and  sovereign  wealth  funds  (SWF).  As  the  Chinese  oil  sector  consists  

(12)

only  of  SOEs  the  privately  owned  national  champions  will  be  disregarded  in  this   thesis.  Also  the  SWF  will  be  kept  on  the  sideline  because  investments  of  the   NOC’s  are  not  backed  by  these  funds  but  by  national  banks  like  the  China   Development  Bank.    

  For  a  state  that  implements  state  capitalism  a  NOC  is  very  important  to   save  guard  the  future  supply  of  energy  resources.  In  the  Middle  East  every   domestic  oil  and  gas  company  is  owned  by  the  state  and  in  Latin  America  most   states  have  nationalized  the  biggest  former  privately  owned  oil  and  gas  

companies  (Bremmer,  2009;  2010).    In  China  the  situation  is  more  or  less  the   same.  Due  to  its  communist  past  none  of  its  NOCs  were  ever  privately  owned,  but   the  CCP  sees  these  companies  as  vital  to  safeguard  the  development  of  the  state   and  the  economy.  Since  the  1980s  the  economic  growth  in  China  has  become  one   of  the  corner  stones  of  social  stability.  The  energy  supply  towards  China  is  

therefore  not  only  vital  to  keep  its  economy  growing,  it  has  also  become  key  to   maintain  the  power  position  of  the  CCP  (Zweig  and  Bi,  2005).  State  capitalism  is   therefore  a  system  that  states  can  use  to  keep  control  of  their  economy,  to  make   sure  that  it  serves  national  interest  and  to  keep  the  status-­‐quo  (The  Economist,   2012).  This  is  different  compared  to,  for  example,  crony  capitalism,  which  is   driven  by  the  goals  of  the  ruling  elites.  State  capitalism  is  not  solely  driven  by   self-­‐enrichment  of  state  elites,  but  first  and  for  most  of  keeping  the  ruling  elites   in  power  with  as  little  social  turmoil  as  possible  (Alicica  and  Tarko:  359).  This   does  not  mean  that  self-­‐enrichment  is  not  occurring  in  China,  but  it  is  not  the   highest  goal  of  the  CCP  leaders.  This  also  explains  the  fight  of  the  central   government  against  the  heavy  corruption  in  lower  government  levels,  as  the   central  government  clearly  sees  this  self-­‐enrichment  as  a  threat  to  the  political   survival  of  the  party.  

  What  can  be  witnessed  in  China  is  an  interesting  process  were  the  state   implements  an  economic  system  that  is  based  on  the  rules  of  a  free  market,  but   keeps  control  over  the  sectors  that  the  leaders  think  are  key  to  the  further   development  of  the  state  and  are  therefore  vital  for  social  stability.  The  SOEs   operate  under  more  ore  less  normal  corporate  structures,  are  often  listed  at   stock  exchanges  and  are  fairly  open  about  there  yearly  business  results  (Zhang,   2004:  114).  But  these  businesses  often  hold  key  positions  in  domestic  markets  

(13)

and  some  markets,  like  the  petro  market,  are  completely  state-­‐owned.  What  in   fact  happens  is  that  the  state  lets  these  SOEs  operate  under  free  market  

conditions,  which  allows  these  SOEs  to  operate  smoothly  on  the  international   market,  and  reap  the  profits  that  are  then  relocated  as  political  officials  see  fit.     As  the  gas  and  oil  reserves  in  China  are  depleting,  it  has  become  key  to  the   foreign  policy  strategy  of  the  CCP  to  acquire  new  gas  and  oil  reserves  abroad.  As   continuing  large  growth  rates  of  the  Chinese  economy  will  be  accompanied  by   tremendous  growth  rates  in  China’s  demand  for  gas  and  oil.  It  seems  that  the   ultimate  goal  here  is  to  maximize  the  state’s  power  and  secure  the  political   survival  of  the  CCP,  which  depends  on  the  continuing  economic  growth  in  China.    

In  the  way  that  Bremmer  uses  the  concept  of  state  capitalism  it  is  too   much  focused  on  being  an  opposite  force  towards  the  free-­‐market  doctrine.  This   is  not  inline  with  the  purpose  of  this  thesis.  Another  problem  is  that  Bremmer   does  not  give  a  clear  explanation  of  the  international  role  that  SOEs  play  in  the   economic  strategies  of  a  state.  In  this  thesis  state  capitalism  will  be  used  to   explain  the  behavior  of  the  Chinese  state  in  promoting  foreign  investments  of  its   SOEs.  But  what  does  this  mean?  

What  must  be  kept  in  mind  is  that  ‘[governments]  use  the  market  to   bolster  their  own  domestic  position,  SOEs  help  them  do  this  in  part  by  

consolidating  whole  industrial  sectors  (Bremmer,  2009:  40).  On  the  domestic   level  this  means  that  foreign  investors  always  have  to  cooperate  with  Chinese   (state-­‐owned)  businesses  if  they  want  to,  for  example,  set-­‐up  a  factory  in  one  of   the  SEZ’s  and  share  its  technological  knowhow  (Chang  and  Unger,  2009).    The   international  level  is  different  as  the  Chinese  government  is  not  in  the  position  to   make  such  demands.  What  happens  on  the  international  level  is  that  the  

government  supports  its  investing  SOEs  politically.  According  to  Breslin  foreign   investments  by  Chinese  SOEs  are  usually  supported  by  investments  of  other   SOEs  and  by  government  deals  (2011).  The  CCP  uses  state-­‐owned  banks  to   provide  loans  to  developing  countries  and  uses  government  development  aid   policies  to  secure  mostly  energy  deals  in  Latin  America,  Africa,  Asia  and  the   Middle  East  (Breslin,  2011:  1274).    

To  summarize,  it  seems  that  on  the  one  hand  the  CCP  tries  to  make  sure   that  SOEs  can  operate  effectively  on  the  international  market.  This  is  done  to  

(14)

make  these  SOEs  more  efficient  and  to  reap  the  benefits  of  the  international   market  to  its  own  advantage.  However,  at  the  same  time  the  CCP  provides  these   SOEs  with  a  competitive  advantage  over  other  enterprises  by  backing  these   investments  with  political  agreements,  development  aid  and  investments  made   by  other  Chinese  SOEs  that  occur  around  the  same  time.  According  to  this  theory   it  would  mean  that  Chinese  SOEs  are  not  investing  according  to  normal  business   strategies,  but  are  executing  the  foreign  policy  of  the  CCP.  The  question  remains   if  this  is  true,  because  there  are  scholars  that  believe  that  surplus  maximization   is  driving  the  investment  strategies  of  Chinese  SOEs  (Downs,  2011;  Zhang,  2004;   Breslin,  2013)  

 

2.2  Surplus  Maximization    

The  concept  of  Surplus  maximization  is  interesting  in  this  case,  because  its  goal   is  very  different  than  that  of  state  capitalism.  The  argument  made  by  Downs  and   Zhang,  among  others,  is  that  because  of  the  economic  reforms  in  China  of  the  last   thirty  years,  SOEs  are  behaving  more  and  more  like  normal  enterprises  and   therefore  try  to  maximize  their  economic  surplus  (Zhang,  2004;  Downs,  2011).   Instead  of  being  an  agent  of  state  policy  Zhang  and  Downs  claim  that  Chinese   SOE’s,  being  state  banks,  NOC’s  or  other  SOE’s,  are  becoming  more  and  more   independent  and  with  this  newly  gained  independence  adapt  to  become  proper   businesses.    

  Instead  of  following  the  policy  set  by  the  CCP  regarding  foreign  

investments  it  seems  that  the  maximization  of  economic  surplus  is  becoming   more  important  for  Chinese  SOE’s.  It  is  therefore  necessary  to  identify  which   factors  determine  decisions  regarding  foreign  investments  and  if  these  factors   play  a  role  in  the  decision  making  process  of  Chinese  SOE’s.  This  also  means  that   the  high  politics  of  geostrategic  and  geo-­‐economic  strategies  have  to  be  

separated  from  foreign  investments  maid  by  Chinese  SOE’s.  Instead  of  just   focusing  on  state  interest  with  regard  to  China’s  foreign  investments,  the   commercial  interest  of  the  SOE’s  come  in  to  play  as  well.  Another  important  

(15)

factor  regarding  surplus  maximization  are  strategic  economic  goals  as  these  help   to  secure  the  future  of  an  enterprise  (Breslin,  2013:1276).    

  As  domestic  oil  reserves  in  China  are  depleting  an  important  strategic   economic  goals  of  Chinese  NOC’s  is  securing  access  to  foreign  oil  reserves  in   Africa,  Asia,  the  Middle  East,  and  in  North  and  South  America.  This  strategy  helps   them  with  securing  the  abilities  of  the  involved  SOE’s  to  maximize  economic   surplus  in  the  future.  Even  if  getting  access  to  these  ‘new’  reserves  is  not   profitable  in  the  short  term,  in  the  long  term  it  is  of  vital  importance  that  these   SOE’s  acquire  access  to  foreign  reserves  to  secure  the  continuation  of  their   business  (Breslin,  2013:  1279).  

  With  regard  to  the  commercial  interest  of  Chinese  SOE’s,  while  foreign   investments  of  SOE’s  are  often  supported  by  diplomatic  activities  and  financial   support  from  state  banks,  Downs  argues  that  ‘when  it  comes  to  choosing  where   to  invest,  the  companies  are  almost  always  in  the  driver’s  seat  and  the  Chinese   government  ....  is  often  just  along  for  the  ride  with  little  idea  of  the  final  

destination’  (2007:  48).  Brautigam  adds  to  this  argument  by  stating  that  overall   Chinese  companies  are  under  no  obligation  to  send  back  resources  to  China,  but   can  do  whatever  it  takes  to  make  profits  (2009).  The  same  goes  for  the  energy   infrastructure  projects  that  Chinese  companies  undertake  in  Africa  for  example.   Even  though  these  projects  make  it  easier  for  China  to  import  resources  from   those  countries  not  all  of  it  goes  to  China  (Breslin,  2013:  1277-­‐1278).  This  means   that  if  this  research  would  ignore  basic  profit  motives  the  answer  to  the  research   question  would  be  incomplete.  

  In  this  thesis  surplus  maximization  can  be  understand  as  the  

maximization  of  value  surplus:  the  surplus  value  of  an  investment  is  equal  to  the   return  on  the  capital  that  a  firm  invests  (Feenberg,  2010:  41).  With  this  

definition  the  goal  of  a  company  becomes  clear  as  maximizing  the  surplus  of  an   investment  means  that  the  company  will  maximize  its  profits.  It  also  holds   another  promise:  the  decision  to  invest,  made  by  a  company  that  wants  to   maximize  their  surplus  value,  is  likely  to  be  based  on  rational  thinking.  In  the   case  of  investments  made  by  a  NOC  this  means  that  the  relentless  hunger  for   resources  of  the  state  is  not  dominant  in  the  decision  making  process,  it  means   that  the  investments  made  by  the  NOC  are  made  under  more  or  less  the  same  

(16)

circumstances  as  is  the  case  with  Royal  Dutch  Shell  or  Exxon/Mobil.    

  The  most  important  thing  to  do  now  is  to  identify  the  factors  that  would   make  a  foreign  investment  in  the  interest  of  the  NOC’s  involved  and  not  in  the   interest  of  the  CCP.  This  can  be  done  by  looking  at  the  investment  climate  of  the   countries  that  receive  the  investments  made  by  Chinese  NOC’s.  For  example,  the   risk  of  an  investment  is  higher  in  Sudan  compared  to  an  investment  in  Canada.  If   it  is  the  case  that  over  time  the  NOC’s  invest  less  and  less  in  developing  countries   in  Africa  and  Latin  America  and  start  investing  more  and  more  in  Canada,  the   United  States  or  the  Middle  East  (better  quality  and  easier  accessible),  then  it   could  mean  that  corporate  interest  are  becoming  more  important  than  national   interest  (Calabrese,  2005).  It  also  means  that  state  capitalism  is  less  of  a  threat   than  Brenner  assumes  it  is,  as  even  though  the  NOC’s  are  owned  by  the  state,  it   does  not  completely  controls  the  NOC’s.  The  NOC’s  are  more  ore  less  

independent  actors  that  make  decisions,  which  are  good  for  the  company  and   not  necessarily  for  the  state.  

  A  second  factor  is  the  kind  of  investments  these  NOC’s  make.  Are  they  just   cooperating  with  foreign  companies  or  is  it  an  acquisition?  If  an  NOC  is  just   simply  buying  up  all  the  companies  that  it  can  to  acquire  new  oil  and/or  gas   reserves  than  it  means  that  the  strategic  interest  of  the  state  are  prevailing  over   the  interest  of  the  company  and  that  the  goal  of  the  NOC  is  probably  not  to   maximize  its  surplus  (Downs,  2011a).  However,  when  a  NOC  is  investing  in   partnerships  with  other  large  international  petro  companies  to  help  develop  oil   fields  in  Iraq,  it  becomes  less  clear  which  interest  are  prevailing.  In  this  case  it  is   more  likely  that  it  concerns  a  combination  of  state  and  corporate  interest.  But   when  Chinese  NOC’s  start  investing  in  oil  sands  projects  in  North  America,  which   are  mainly  operated  for  the  North  American  energy  market,  it  seams  that  NOC’s   see  this  as  a  good  investment  and  are  not  controlled  by  the  interest  of  the  CCP.       The  final  factor  that  should  be  taken  into  account  is  the  size  of  the  

company  involved.  As  pervious  research  has  shown  the  size  of  the  company  does   matter  in  how  independent  it  is  from  state  control  (Downs,  2007:  49).  As  the   profits  rise  and  the  firm  becomes  more  active  on  the  international  market  they   start  to  rely  more  on  their  ‘their  globalizing  senior  management,  and  ....  

(17)

ministerial  superiors  back  in  China’  (Breslin,  2013:  1282).  It  should  also  be  noted   that  competition  between  SOE’s  is  not  uncommon  and  that  they  operate  with   more  than  one  state  actor.  As  a  consequence  when  the  commercial  interest  of   two  competing  SOE’s  collide  with  each  other  this  often  results  in  them  pursuing   market  driven  relations  with  foreign  governments  and  firms  that  can  be  opposite   to  the  political  and  foreign  policy  interest  of  the  CCP  (Liou,  2009).

2.3  Summary    

The  theoretical  framework  that  is  used  in  this  paper  builds  on  two  concepts  that   are  on  two  very  different  sides  of  the  ideological  spectrum.  The  first,  state   capitalism  emphasizes  the  role  of  the  state  in  the  economies  of  authoritarian   states  that  are  trying  to  develop  their  economy.  You  don  not  have  to  read  articles   from  journals  to  observe  this  fact,  you  can  read  it  everyday  in  your  newspaper   and  see  it  on  the  news.  Regarding  to  China  this  is  not  any  different.  This  of  course   has  to  do  with  the  communist  history  of  the  state  but  also  with  economic  reforms   that  have  been  implemented  since  the  1980s.  These  reforms  were  always  

intended  to  find  a  balance  between  the  benefits  of  a  free  market  economy  and   the  benefits  of  state  control  over  the  economy  (Bremmer,  2009).  This  means  that   when  it  comes  to  foreign  investments  the  state  should  play  an  important  role  in   the  decision  making  process.  Therefore  these  investments  should  follow,  for  a   large  part,  the  strategic  interest  of  the  state  and  the  economic  interest  of  the  firm   are  less  important.  

The  second  part  of  the  theoretical  framework  focuses  on  the  power  of  a   free  market  system  and  only  takes  economic  interest  in  to  account.  In  this  case   the  role  of  the  state  is  less  important.  Therefore  the  economic  interest  of  the   companies  involved  should  prevail  over  the  strategic  interest  of  the  state.  What   could  be  expected  is  that  in  this  case  companies  go  for  saver  investment  

environments  and  not  only  invest  in  states  were  the  long-­‐term  future  is  not  clear   and  the  state  itself  is  very  unstable.  As  an  example:  Chinese  NOC’s  invest  less  and   less  in  South-­‐Sudan  and  start  to  invest  more  in  Canadian  oil  sands.    

  What  should  be  noted  is  that  although  the  two  concepts  belong  to  

(18)

research  question  should  be  either  state  capitalism  or  surplus  maximization.  It   could  be  that  in  China  the  CCP  provides  the  car  (capital,  but  also  diplomatic   support)  and  the  NOC’s  are  behind  the  wheel  (they  make  the  investment   decisions).  In  this  case  the  CCP  and  the  NOC’s  work  together  to  achieve  both   their  goals:  securing  the  economic  growth  rates  of  the  Chinese  economy   (strategic  interest  of  the  CCP)  and  the  future  profits  of  the  NOC  involved.  

(19)

3.0  Research  Method  

 

The  sources  that  will  be  used  for  this  research  are  mostly  qualitative.  They  will   consist  of  annual  reports  of  CNOOC  limited,  CNPC/PetroChina  and  Sinopec.  As   the  CNPC,  the  CNOOC  and  the  Sinopec  Group  are  not  listed  and  are  completely   state-­‐owned  these  NOC’s  do  not  provide  the  public  with  annual  reports  and  the   news  articles  they  present  on  their  website  include  very  little  financial  

information  and  these  are  often  focused  on  domestic  affairs.  This  means  that  the   remainder  of  this  research  will  focus  on  the  subsidiaries  of  the  CNPC,  CNOOC  and   the  Sinopec  Group.  Which  are  respectively  PetroChina,  CNOOC  limited  and  

Sinopec  (the  inner  workings  of  the  companies  will  be  explained  in  chapter  4.0).   In  addition  to  the  annual  reports  the  news  articles  that  CNOOC  limited,  

PetroChina  and  Sinopec  publish  on  their  website  will  be  used  as  these  do  provide   enough  financial  information  and  many  of  these  articles  do  concern  with  the   foreign  investments  made  by  the  companies.    

  With  the  investments  made  by  Chinese  NOC’s  there  are  always  other   companies  involved,  may  it  be  a  utility  company  or  a  Chinese  investment  bank.  It   turns  out  that  most  investments  made  by  Chinese  NOC’s  are  backed  by  other   investments  made  by  state-­‐owned  investment  banks  (Downs,  2011).  The   investments  made  by  these  banks  mostly  include  energy-­‐backed  loans  (EBL’s).   The  most  important  provider  of  these  EBL’s  is  the  Chinese  Development  Bank   (CDB).  The  CDB  provides  roughly  the  same  information  as  the  NOC’s  concerning   its  business  performance,  annual  reports,  public  statements  and  news  articles,   on  its  website.  These  sources  will  be  added  to  the  ones  provided  by  the  NOC’s.     As  the  CCP  plays  an  important  role  in  this  research  the  MFA  is  also  an   important  actor  for  this  thesis.  By  looking  at  the  activities  and  statements  of  the   MFA  around  the  time  of  the  investments  it  is  possible  to  find  out  what  kind  of   support  by  the  state  is  provided  during  the  times  that  investment  deals  are  made.   The  website  of  the  MFA  reports  every  foreign  activity  made  by  any  ministry.  It   does  this  even  better  than  for  example  the  Ministry  of  Defense.  More  often  than   not  the  MFA  reports  that  the  Chinese  Minister  of  Defense  has  a  meeting  with  is   Saudi  counterpart  and  the  Ministry  of  Defense  does  not  mention  anything  at  all.   This  means  that  for  the  purpose  of  this  research  the  statements  made  by  the  

(20)

MFA  will  be  the  main  source  for  the  role  of  the  CCP  in  China’s  foreign  investment   strategy.    

The  problem  with  these  sources  provided  by  Chinese  SOE’s  and  ministries   is  that  it  is  not  entirely  clear  if  these  can  be  trusted  and  provide  all  the  

information  that  is  available  regarding  the  terms  that  have  been  agreed  upon   with  every  acquisition,  investment,  merger  or  take-­‐over.  To  overcome  this   information  gap  this  thesis  will  also  make  use  of  articles  that  have  been  

published  by  the  New  York  Times  and  the  Wall  Street  Journal.  These  articles  put   the  investments  into  a  broader  perspective  and  link  these  investments  to  other   investments  made  by  Chinese  government  and  other  Chinese  SOE’s  in  the  same   region  and  roughly  around  the  same  time.  This  will  help  showing  the  state   capitalism  side  of  the  research,  because  it  shows  that  the  CCP  is  pushing   investments  around  a  certain  oil  or  gas  field  to  secure  the  supply  of  energy   towards  the  Chinese  economy.    

  In  addition  to  the  articles  of  the  New  York  Times  and  the  Wall  Street   Journal  this  thesis  will  also  make  use  of  reports  that  are  published  by  the   International  Energy  Agency  (IEA),  the  World  Energy  Council  (WEC)  and  the   American  Energy  Information  Agency  (EIA).  The  reports  that  are  provided  by   these  institutions  help  explaining  the  long-­‐term  trends  in  Chinese  energy  

investments  or,  in  the  case  of  this  thesis,  the  investments  made  by  Chinese  actors   in  the  petro  sector.  In  addition,  these  reports  provide  also  vital  insights  into  the   connection  between  the  NOC’s  and  the  CCP.  

  This  thesis  is  mostly  build  on  the  foreign  investments  made  by  Chinese   NOC’s.  It  was  therefore  important  to  make  an  overview  of  the  most  important   investments  made  by  the  NOC’s  up  until  2014.  A  list  of  these  investments  is   provided  in  chapter  5.0.  This  lists  starts  with  the  first  foreign  investments  made   by  the  NOC’s  in  2002  and  the  most  recent  one  is  of  April  2014.  Due  to  the  

development  of  the  Chinese  petro  sector  since  the  1950s  and  the  structural   limits  the  NOC’s  had  to  deal  with  up  until  the  reforms  of  the  late  1990s  foreign   investments  made  by  the  NOC’s  were  not  possible  until  2002  (for  further   explanation  see  chapter  4.0).  

  The  list  of  foreign  investments  that  is  made  for  this  thesis  provides  the   opportunity  to  detect  certain  trends  and  also  provides  insights  regarding  the  

(21)

power  struggle  between  the  CCP  and  the  NOC’s.  Again  the  question  ‘who’s   behind  the  wheel?’  is  very  important.  Is  it  as  Bremmer  says  the  state  all  the  way,   or  is  Downs  argument  more  tempting  by  stating  that  the  state  is  in  the  backseat   and  therefore  is  not  in  total  control  of  the  investments  made  by  the  NOC’s      

(22)

4.0  The  evolution  of  the  Chinese  Petro  Sector:  ‘Going  Out’  

 

The  Chinese  petro  sector  has  experienced  some  major  institutional  changes  over   the  last  fife  decades.  In  December  1950  the  State  Council  promulgated  the  

‘Regulation  on  the  Mining  Industry  in  the  People’s  Republic  of  China’,   which  stated  that  all  domestic  natural  resources  were  property  of  the  state   and  would  be  managed  by  the  central  government.  With  the  discovery  of   the  first  oil  field  in  1955  the  Ministry  of  Petroleum  Industry  (MPI)  was   established  as  the  administrative  body  of  the  petro  industry  (Zhang  ,2004:   71).  Oil  was  perceived  as  a  vital  strategic  resource  for  economic  and  

national  security.  

With  the  Soviet  withdrawal  in  the  early  1960s,  the  CCP  experienced   an  imminent  threat  towards  its  energy  security  as  the  supply  of  Russian  oil   was  cut  of.  In  a  response  more  resources  were  allocated  for  the  

development  of  new  oil  fields  and  increased  production.  By  1970  China   became  a  net  exporter  of  oil  and  for  a  short  while  was  the  fourth  largest   producer  of  oil  outside  the  Middle  East  (Houser,  2008:  144).  

The  MPI  acted  as  the  headquarters  of  the  Chinese  petro  sector  and   made  strategic  decisions  about  the  exploration  of  new  fields  and  the   production  of  oil.    It  also  determined  the  price  of  oil,  and  controlled  the   production  process,  the  refinery  process,  and  the  distribution  process   (Zhang,  2004:  75).  

However,  as  the  set  price  of  oil  was  lower  than  the  international   market  price,  the  MPI  did  not  have  access  to  foreign  technology  because  it   was  too  expansive.  This  changed  in  1981  when  the  CCP  allowed  the  MPI  to   sell  oil  that  was  produced  after  the  set  targets  were  met  at  market  prices   (Zhang,  2004:  78;  Houser,  2008:  149).  The  income  that  was  created  by   selling  this  ‘extra’  oil  could  only  be  used  to  acquire  advanced  foreign   technology  and  equipment,  and  for  importing  pipelines  and  other  steel   products  exclusively  for  the  petro  sector.  This  created  a  major  incentive  

(23)

for  the  MPI  to  produce  more  oil  and  spurred  technological  advances  in  the   Chinese  petro  sector.  

  In  1988  the  CCP  decided  that  the  MPI  should  be  abolished  and  was   restructured  into  the  Chinese  National  Petroleum  Company  (Zhang,  2004:  81).   Although  the  CNPC  was  set  up  to  act  more  like  an  enterprise  than  the  MPI,  it  still   had  to  undertake  most  of  the  functions  that  were  the  responsibility  of  the  MPI,   which  included  setting  of  production  targets,  quality  standards  and  

environmental  policies.  At  the  same  time  the  CCP  started  to  experiment  with   corporate  structures  in  the  petroleum  sector  to  make  it  competitive  on  the   international  market.  

  Even  though  these  reforms  put  more  emphasis  on  the  business  side  of  the   different  NOC’s,  it  was  not  until  1998  that  the  headquarters  of  the  CNPC  and   Sinopec  were  responsible  for  both  government  and  business  functions  (Houser,   2008:  155).  This  means  that  these  NOC’s  were  basically  ministries  determining   production  quotas  and  production  standards.  However,  the  government  was  still   in  control  when  it  came  to  determine  oil  prices,  investments,  and  the  profits  that   these  NOC’s  made  went  straight  to  the  state’s  treasury  and  only  a  small  

percentage  of  those  profits  could  be  used  for  research  and  development  of  new   oil  fields  and  new  production  techniques.    The  position  of  the  headquarters  of   the  CNPC  and  Sinopec  was  therefore  very  weak  (Zhang,  2004:  88).  

The  reform  process  that  the  CCP  started  in  the  oil  sector  during  the  1990s   had  two  objectives:  centralize  the  power  over  the  companies  in  their  respective   headquarters  and  modernize  the  corporate  structures  in  such  a  way  that  the   NOC’s  could  compete  on  the  international  market  (Nolan,  2002:  125).  During  this   period  the  oil  sector  made  major  technological  advances,  incorporated  modern   management  techniques,  raised  substantial  capital  on  the  international  market   through  so  called  Hong  Kong  Shares  flotation  and  carried  out  a  huge  internal   restructuring  of  the  CNPC,  CNOOC  and  Sinopec  to  prepare  them  for  a  limited   stock  market  launch.  This  stock  market  launches  were  limited  because  the   shareholders  of  these  NOC’s  are  either  the  Chinese  state  or  a  Chinese  national   bank  (see  annual  reports  from  both  Sinopec  and  the  CNPC).  

The  1998  reforms  implemented  new  corporate  structures  in  the  Chinese   oil  sector.  The  problem  remained  that  as  the  NOC’s  emerged  from  this  reform  

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

More specifically for our pur- poses, the place of substitution that is so prominent in Levinas’s ethics of responsibility can be seen as heterotopia, allowing us to (re)appraise

Geregistreer aan die H.P.K. Openbare H errie Die sukses wat die kerklike afvaardiging insake moedertaa londerwys in sy onderhoud met genl. Smuts behaal het, het die

Deze relatie werd niet gevonden tussen de intra-individuele variabiliteit van de reactiesnelheid op een simpele taak en ADHD-symptomen, leeftijd en cognitieve veroudering.. Ook

In cognitive science (Clark, 1997), as well as in human–computer interaction (HCI; Dourish, 2001), the theoretical framework of embodied embedded cognition has gained influence as a

Voortbordurend op dit hybride karakter pleit Gorbman voor een analyse van filmmuziek waarbij de combinatie met het beeld bekeken dient te worden, omdat het anders voorbij gaat aan

In order to reveal the continuing tension between race and emancipation visible in the Dutch reception of American blackface performances, Uncle Tom, and the Tom play, the first

In hierdie verband is dit dan ook belangrik om daarop te wys dat lede van ’n bestuursraad en ook die administrateurs van ’n fonds wat te goeie trou ooreenkomstig die reëls van die

Ce dernier peut être considéré comme étant de date plus récente, le même mortier ayant servi pour les deux pilastres accolés au mur sud-est du portique et flanquant une