• No results found

Sitting on the money : an investigation into the role of the bank-lending channel and its theoretical and practical effectiveness in recent quantitative easing programs

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Sitting on the money : an investigation into the role of the bank-lending channel and its theoretical and practical effectiveness in recent quantitative easing programs"

Copied!
22
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

Sitting on the Money

An investigation into the role of the bank-lending channel and its

theoretical and practical effectiveness in recent quantitative easing

programs

Bachelor Thesis

University of Amsterdam

Absract

This thesis examines quantitative easing and the role that the bank-lending channel has played in recent programs. Little research has yet been done into this specific channel. Research has shown a small but significant increase in bank-lending growth in Japan and no increase in the United Kingdom. Research concerning the Federal Reserve’s programs has yet to be done. The efficacy of the bank-lending channel is one of many concerns that economists have about quantitative easing. This thesis looks into the programs implemented in Japan, the US and the UK and concludes that the different strategies that were applied resulted in different outcomes, though generally a small positive effect has been acknowledged. As for the effectiveness of the bank-lending channel: studies suggest that it is either small or non-existent. This thesis finds that the effect of the bank-lending channel is constrained, especially during crises, by pressure to deleverage banks balance sheets and flightiness of deposits. Furthermore it finds that the efficacy of the bank-lending channel might be dependent on the implementation strategy of the quantitative easing program and it gives suggestions for implementation strategies that might actively engage the bank-lending channel.

Date: June 11

th

2015

Program:BSc. Bèta-Gamma

Track: Major Economics

Name: M. Ruben de Roos

Student Number: 6056490

Supervisor: Egle Jakucionyte

(2)

Statement of Originality

This document is written by Ruben de Roos who declares to take full

responsibility for the contents of this document.

I declare that the text and the work presented in this document is original and

that no sources other than those mentioned in the text and its references have

been used in creating it.

The Faculty of Economics and Business is responsible solely for the supervision

of completion of the work, not the contents.

   

(3)

Content    

1. Introduction                     p.4   2. Quantitative  easing:  How  it  works               p.6   2.1 The  policy-­‐signalling  channel             p.6   2.2 The  expectations  channel               p.7   2.3 The  portfolio-­‐balancing  channel             p.7   2.4 The  bank-­‐lending  channel               p.8   2.5 The  liquidity  channel               p.8   3 The  concerns  about  quantitative  easing             p.8   3.1 Capital  flight                   p.9   3.2 Excessive  inflation                 p.9   3.3 Exit  strategy                   p.9   3.4 Unequal  distribution  of  wealth  effects           p.9   3.5 The  inefficacy  of  the  bank-­‐lending  channel         p.10   4 Past  implementations  of  quantitative  easing  policies         p.10   4.1 Quantitative  Easing  Policy  in  Japan           p.11   4.2 Quantitative  Easing  Policy  in  the  United  Kingdom       p.12   4.3 Quantitative  Easing  Policy  in  the  United  States         p.13   5 Historical  efficacy  of  the  bank-­‐lending  channel           p.14   5.1 The  bank-­‐lending  channel  in  Japan           p.15   5.2 The  bank  lending  channel  in  the  United  Kingdom       p.15   6 Analysis                       p.17   7 Conclusion                     p.19   8 References                     p.20   9 Appendix                       p.22  

(4)

1.  Introduction    

On   January   22th   2015,   the   director   of   the   European   Central   Bank   (ECB)   Mario   Draghi   announced  that  the  ECB  would  commence  with  a  large  asset-­‐purchasing  program.  This   program   would   entail   the   purchasing   of   assets,   including   bonds   issued   by   national   governments  and  EU  institutions  such  as  the  European  commission,  amounting  to  €60   billion  per  month.  It  will  continue  until  the  end  of  September  2016  and  will  total  €1.1   trillion  euro’s.    This  type  of  program  is  known  as  the  unconventional  monetary  policy   called   quantitative   easing   (QE).   This   policy   is   aimed   at   (in   the   European   context)   stimulating  inflation  (warding  off  deflation)  and  “kick-­‐starting”  the  economy.  How  does   this  policy  help  resolve  these  issues  and  why  would  the  ECB  consider  this  to  be  a  valid   policy  choice?    

 

QE,  although  unconventional,  has  had  several  test  runs  in  the  past  two  decades.  It  was   first   implemented   in   Japan   by   the   Bank   of   Japan   (BoJ)   in   2001   due   too   Japans   long-­‐ standing  issue  with  deflation.  After  that  is  was  adopted  in  the  United  States  in  2008  and   in   the   United   Kingdom   in   2009.   The   effectiveness   of   these   policies   is   still   in   dispute:   many   economists   are   doubtful   about   some   of   the   short-­‐   and   long-­‐term   effects   of   QE   policy.    

 

One  of  these  concerns  is  whether  bank  lending  contributes  to  the  positive  effects  of  QE   or   not.   The   bank-­‐lending   channel   is   a   transmission   channel   of   QE   that   entails   banks   using  the  extra  liquidity  injected  by  QE  to  expand  their  loans.  Thus  I  pose  the  question  in   this  thesis:  What  has  been  the  role  of  the  bank-­‐lending  channel  in  recent  QE  programs   and  what  were  its  constraints?  To  answer  this  question  we  look  into  research  done  on   this  topic  concerning  the  recent  ventures  in  Japan,  the  UK  and  the  US.  

 

It  should  first  be  noted  that  little  research  has  been  done  specifically  on  the  topic  of  the   bank-­‐lending   channel   in   QE   programs.   This   can   be   partially   attributed   to   the   fact   that   these  programs  have  only  just  recently  been  implemented1.  However  it  is  also  possible,  

                                                                                                               

1  As  commented  by  Joyce  et  al.  (2012):“There is inevitably uncertainty over the size and duration of

the effect and the precise channel through which it works, although this is perhaps to be expected given the relatively short historical period we have at our disposal and the extreme nature of the recession which makes thinking about counterfactuals challenging.”

(5)

as   we   are   able   to   surmise   from   the   literature,   that   the   bank-­‐lending   channel   as   a   transmission  mechanism  within  QE  has,  a  priori,  been  deemed  either  non-­‐existent  or  of   little   consequence.   This   is   also   the   estimation   of   Joyce   and   Spaltro   in   their   paper   Quantitative  Easing  and  bank  lending:  a  panel  data  approach  (Joyce  and  Spaltro,  2014).   In   their   conclusion   they   state:   “To   our   knowledge,   this   is   the   first   paper   to   try   and   quantify  the  effect  of  QE  on  bank  lending  in  the  UK  using  a  bank-­‐level  panel  dataset.”2  

This  brings  us  to  a  second  issue  that  we  encounter  when  researching  the  bank-­‐lending   channel:   To   accurately   study   changes   in   bank   lending   due   to   QE,   bank-­‐level   data   is   needed   to   perform   a   proper   regression.   The   problem   is   that   this   kind   of   data   is   only   accessible  to  central  bank  researchers  and  thus  not  publically  available.    This  might  also   partially   explain   why   little   research   has   yet   been   done   in   the   bank-­‐lending   channel.   Since  the  bank-­‐lending  channel  is  one  of  the  “key  transmission  channels”  (Benford  et  al.,   2009)  of  QE,  it  seems  advisable  that  more  research  should  be  done  into  this  topic.  

 

The  remainder  of  this  thesis  is  structured  as  follows.  First  I  will  describe  the  conceptual   workings   of   QE,   thus   establishning   a   theoretical   framework   wherein   we   can   view   the   bank-­‐lending  channel.  I  will  then  address  some  of  the  concerns  held  by  economists,  with   the   bank-­‐lending   channel   among   them.   This   will   give   us   some   perspective   on   the   problem  of  the  bank-­‐lending  channel.  I  then  take  a  look  at  the  historical  implementation   of  different  QE  programs  and  the  role  that  the  bank-­‐lending  channel  has  played.  Finally  I   will  analyse  these  programs  and  theories  and  give  some  suggestions  on  how  to  engage   the  bank-­‐lending  channel  more  actively.    

                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                       

2  “So far, the vast majority of research on QE has focused on its impact on economic growth and

financial markets, while the effect of QE on bank lending has received much less attention. This relative neglect reflects the fact that policymakers in the United Kingdom and elsewhere expected QE to affect demand mainly through its impact on asset prices, while the effect on bank lending was expected to be small because of banks’ incentives to deleverage and reduce the overall size of their balance sheets.”(Joyce and Spaltro, 2014)  

(6)

2.  Quantitative  Easing:  How  it  works  

 

In  order  to  supply  a  proper  context  for  the  so-­‐called  bank-­‐lending  channel  (Kaysap  and   Stein,  1994)  we  need  to  establish  what  place  it  has  within  the  QE  mechanism.    

To   stimulate   a   stable   economic   growth,   central   banks   use   their   policies   to   maintain   a   low  and  stable  inflation  of  around  2%.  In  normal  times  (in  the  economic  sense)  when   inflation  is  too  low,  central  banks  lower  the  interest  rate  for  which  they  lend  money  to   commercial  banks:  the  instrument  rate  (in  the  UK:  the  bank  rate,  in  the  US:  the  federal   funds  rate).  This  will  in  turn  raise  the  demand  and  also  the  supply  of  money,  thus  raising   the   inflation   level.   However,   in   times   of   economic   distress,   such   as   the   recent   global   credit   crisis   or   Japan’s   “Lost   Decade”,   this   policy   mechanism   may   turn   out   to   be   ineffective.  When  inflation  is  too  low  and  the  bank  rate  is  already  near  zero  any  further   adjustment  to  the  bank  rate  will  not  yield  higher  inflation.  This  is  known  in  economic   literature   as   the   liquidity   trap   (Krugman,   2000).   To   escape   this   liquidity   trap   central   banks   can   turn   to   QE:   QE   consists   of   large   asset   purchases   by   central   banks   over   an   extended   period   of   time.3  By   doing   so,   the   central   banks   directly   increase   the   money  

supply  of  the  economy,  thus  raising  expected  inflation.      

How   do   these   purchases   increase   the   money   demand?   Several   researches   identify   different   transmission   channels.   Benford   et   al.   (2009),   in   an   article   for   the   Bank   of   England’s   Quartarly   Bulletin,   identify   the   portfolio-­‐balancing  channel,   the   bank-­‐lending   channel   and   the   expectations   channel   as   the   three   “key   channels”   through   which   QE   operates.  Bell  et  al.  (2012),  also  for  the  Bank  of  England,  additionally  identify  the  policy-­‐ signalling   channel   and   the   liquidity   channel.   We   discuss   these   transmission   channels   here.  

 

2.1  The  policy-­‐signalling  channel  

These   policy   and   purchasing   announcements   are   made   explicitly   and   emphasize   the   central   banks   commitment   to   their   targets.   This   is   a   quote   from   Mario   Draghi’s   announcement:  “They  [purchases  of  €60  billion  per  month]  are  intended  to  be  carried   out  until  end-­‐September  2016  and  will  in  any  case  be  conducted  until  we  see  a  sustained                                                                                                                  

3  The  specific  types  of  assets  purchased  differ  per  program,  depending  on  the  specific  targets  of  

the  central  banks.  However  the  programs  usually  contain  low-­‐risk  long-­‐term  assets.  This  is  one   of  the  main  differences  between  QE  and  normal  Open  Market  Purchases  (Blinder,  2010).  

(7)

adjustment   in   the   path   of   inflation.”   Draghi   is   hereby   signalling   that   the   ECB   is   committed   to   this   policy   and   the   inflation   target.   This   kind   of   signalling   can   change   expectations  that  people  have  about  the  markets.  

This  satisfies  two  of  Svensson’s  (2003)  three  elements  for  “the  optimal  way  to  escape   from  a  liquidity  trap  and  deflation”,  which  he  formulated  based  on  literary  research  into   the   liquidity   trap   and   QE.   “(1)   an   explicit   central   bank   commitment   to   a   higher   future   price  level;  (2)  a  concrete  action  that  demonstrates  central  bank’s  commitment,  induces   expectations   of   a   higher   future   price   level   and   jump-­‐starts   the   economy;”(Svensson,   2003).  The  third  element  mentioned  by  Svensson  (2003)  will  be  discussed  later  during   our  analysis  of  the  concerns.  

 

2.2  The  expectations  channel  

In  the  article  by  Bell  et  al.  (2012)  the  expectations  channel  is  identified.  It  is  not  clear  in   what  sense  this  channel  essentially  differs  from  the  policy-­‐signalling  channel.  The  article   mentions  a  consumer  confidence  boost  due  to  changed  expectations  about  the  economic   future   because   of   the   QE   program   (Bell   et   al.,   2012).   It   does   not   elaborate   as   to   what   makes  it  different  from  the  policy-­‐signalling  channel  and  so  the  distinguishment  remains   vague.    

 

2.3  The  portfolio-­‐balancing  channel  

This  channel  operates  through  the  asset  purchases  made  by  recipients  of  QE  purchases.   When  the  central  bank  purchases  assets,  the  prices  of  these  assets  go  up  and  the  yields   go  down,  thus  reducing  the  cost  of  borrowing.  Also,  asset  owners  will  become  wealthier   due   to   these   price   increases.   This   should   encourage   them   to   spend   more.   When   asset   holders  sell  their  assets  to  the  central  bank,  they  have  an  excess  money  balance,  which   they  use  to  reinvest  in  other  assets  so  as  to  regain  the  same  risk-­‐profile  in  their  portfolio   as  before  (assuming  that  their  preferences  are  still  the  same  and  they  wish  to  retain  that   profile).  This  is  a  continuing  chain  of  buyers  and  sellers  until  finally  all  asset  prices  have   risen  and  the  amount  of  money  held  is  in  balance  with  the  portfolios.  Since  yields  are   dropping,  companies  and  households  will  likely  want  to  invest  in  assets  with  a  higher   risk   in   order   to   retain   their   risk   profile.   Furthermore,   because   of   the   extra   money   injected  into  the  economy,  money  is  more  readily  available  and  thus  becomes  cheaper  to   obtain.   Because   there   is   now   less   danger   to   run   out   of   liquidity,   this   might   encourage  

(8)

investors  to  hold  more  illiquid  assets  in  their  portfolio  (Benford  et  al.  2009).  According   to  Butt  et  al.  (2014),  in  their  empirical  research  into  the  bank-­‐lending  channel,  the  QE   program   in   the   United   Kingdom   worked   mainly   through   this   channel,   as   they   ascertained  through  the  variance  levels  of  bank  deposits.4    

 

2.4  The  bank-­‐lending  channel  

QE   programs   will,   whether   by   direct   purchases   or   indirect   purchases,   increase   the   reserves  of  commercial  banks.  Therefore,  there  is  an  increase  in  the  commercial  banks   liquidity.  Banks  need  to  retain  a  certain  balance  of  liquid  stock  in  order  to  meet  payment   demands   of   their   normal   dealings.   If   the   bank   has   more   liquidity   than   needed   for   its   balance,   it   can   use   this   extra   liquidity   to   extend   more   loans   than   it   would   have   done   before.   These   additional   loans   should   meet   the   demand   for   money   and   thus   increase   consumption  and  investment  (Benford  et  al,  2009).    

 

2.5  The  liquidity  channel  

The   liquidity   channel,   mentioned   by   the   BoE   report,   refers   to   the   effect   that   when   central  banks  inject  liquidity  into  the  markets,  thus  making  it  cheaper  to  obtain,  this  will   actively  encourage  trading  because  “Asset  prices  may  consequently  increase  as  a  result   of   lower   illiquidity   premia.”(Bell   et   al.,   2012).   Again   this   seems   to   be   a   part   of   the   aforementioned   portfolio-­‐balancing   channel,   wherein   investors   will   reinvest   in   assets   with  different  risk-­‐premia  due  to  changing  risks.  

 

An  overview  of  the  transmission  mechanisms  of  QE,  as  viewed  by  the  Bank  of  England,  is   graphically  represented  in  the  Figure  1,  which  can  be  found  in  the  appendix.  

   

3.  The  concerns  about  quantitative  easing      

Mario   Draghi’s   announcement   of   the   European   QE   program   was   preceded   by   a   long   period  of  heated  debates  between  the  ECB  council  members.    This  is  because  there  are   still  some  concerns  about  QE.  In  this  segment  I  discuss  the  main  concerns  :  capital  flight,   excessive  inflation,  exit  strategy  and  the  bank-­‐lending  channel.  

 

                                                                                                               

(9)

3.1  Capital  flight  

There   is   a   possibility   that,   when   liquidity   is   increased   by   central   banks,   investors   and   financial  institutes  have  the  option  to  reinvest  and  banks  have  the  option  to  expand  their   loans,  they  might  not  choose  to  invest  in  assets  or  loan  to  agents  within  the  country  of   the  central  bank  (or  in  Europe’s  case,  within  the  European  Union).  Instead,  considering   the  fragile  economy  of  the  homeland,  they  might  use  their  liquidity  to  invest  abroad  in   more  stable  countries.  According  to  Michael  Hudson  of  the  Levy  Economics  Institute  of   Bard  College,  this  effect  did  in  fact  occur  during  the  QE  program  of  the  Federal  Reserve   (Hudson,  2010).  

 

3.2  Excessive  inflation  

QE   might   backfire:   The   goal   is   to   increase   inflation,   but   when   the   money   supply   is   so   vastly   expanded   there   is   a   danger   that   this   goal   might   be   overshot   and   lead   to   hyperinflation  (Meaning  and  Zhu,  2011).  “Because  with  the  excess  reserves  in  banks,  a   massive   increase   in   the   money   supply   through   significant   increase   in   their   lending   or   investing  could  create  a  galloping  inflationary  scenario.”(Mahajan,  2015)5    

3.3  Exit  strategy    

When  the  QE  program  has  been  successful  and  inflation  rates  are  up  again,  how  does  a   central  bank  reduce  its  balance  sheet  (which  is  now  hugely  inflated)  without  disrupting   the  market?  This  is  a  common  concern  raised  also  by  Joyce  et  al.  (2012).  Would  we  have   fixed  the  burst  of  one  bubble  just  by  creating  another?  This  is  also  tied  with  the  concern   of   whether   the   “purchasing   of   government   bonds   are   helping   to   contribute   to   unsustainable  levels  of  government  debt.”  (Joyce  et  al.,  2012).    This  is  where  I  arrive  at   Svensson’s  (2003)  third  element  of  the  optimal  way  to  escape  the  liquidity  trap:  “(3)  an   exit  strategy  that  specifies  when  and  how  to  get  back  to  normal.”(Svensson,  2003).6  

3.4  Unequal  distribution  of  wealth  effects    

Because  QE  focuses  on  lowering  yields  and  raising  asset  prices,  this  might  not  be  equally   beneficial   for   everyone.   Specifically   it   might   even   have   adversely   affected   some                                                                                                                  

5  Mahajan  (2015)  also  comments  that  this  risk  mostly  concerns  less  developed  economies:  “So  in  

case  of  developing  economy,  where  inflation  remains  a  major  concern  quantitative  easing  type   expansionary  monetary  policy  should  be  adopted  with  utmost  care.”(Mahajan,  2015)  

6  Under  the  leadership  of  Ben  Bernanke  the  Federal  Reserve  has  devised  a  seven-­‐point  exit  

strategy.  This  plan  also  contains  some  unorthodox  and  innovative  techniques  to  avoid  market   disruption.(Blinder,  2010)  

(10)

households  who  do  not  have  large  asset  investments  and  thus  could  not  benefit  from  the   increased  value  of  those  assets.  They  may  however  suffer  from  a  lowered  return  on  their   saving   deposits.   These   findings   are   based   on   an   empirical   study   done   for   the   Bank   of   England   by   Bell   et   al.   (2012).   Thus   the   bank-­‐lending   channel,   which   does   not   work   through   asset   prices,   may   more   effectively   target   households   (who   do   not   hold   many   assets).  

3.5  The  inefficacy  of  the  bank-­‐lending  channel    

The   recent   implementation   strategies   of   QE   policies   give   evidence   that   there   is   little   faith   in   the   efficacy   of   the   bank-­‐channel.   Economists   theorize   that   in   times   of   severe   economic   distress,   there   is   a   large   amount   of   pressure   on   banks   to   deleverage   their   balance   sheets.   Deleveraging   means   that   the   relative   amount   of   debt   on   the   balance   sheet   must   be   reduced   (or   the   relative   amount   of   capital   must   be   increased).   Banks   might  therefore  use  the  additional  liquidity  to  pay  of  their  debts  instead  of   expanding   their  lending.  “This  focus  on  the  importance  of  bank’s  balance  sheets  is  consistent  with   the  literature  on  the  so-­‐called  bank  capital  channel,  which  suggests  that  capital  can  be  an   important  driver  of  banks’  lending  decisions  particularly  in  periods  of  market  stress.”  7  

(Joyce  and  Spaltro,  2014).    

According   to   Benford   et   al.   (2009)   the   bank-­‐lending   channel   is   one   of   the   key   transmissions   channels   in   QE.   As   such   it   can   be   viewed   as   part   of   the   foundation   that   determines  the   success   of   a   QE  policy.  Additionally,  if  it  does  work,  it  would  probably   lessen   the   concern   of   unequal   distribution   of   wealth   effects.   That   is   why   this   thesis   is   focused  on  this  particular  concern.

4. Past Implementations of Quantitative Easing Policies

In this section I take a look at how the QE policies were implemented in Japan, the United Kingdom and the United States8

. Although all policies consisted of expanding the central banks balance sheets, there are some important differences between the implementation                                                                                                                

7  Joyce  and  Spaltro  refer  to  Kaysap  and  Stein  (1994),  van  den  Heuvel  (2002),  Jimenez  et  al.  

(2010)  and  Gambacorta  and  Marquez-­‐Ibanez  (2011).  

8  Although no literature has been found on the bank-lending channel in the US, I do add a description

of the implementation process in the US because it will broaden our understanding of the practical possibilities and limitations of QE, which may also affect our understanding of the bank-lending channel.

(11)

strategies. This will give us a sense of the scale and focus of the different programs, which might help us understand the resulting effects of the bank-lending channel.

4.1 Quantitative Easing Policy in Japan

In the 1990’s, Japan was struck by low economic activity and consumer price deflation after the asset-price bubble burst in 1991. This decade of economic depression is known as the “Lost Decade”. To combat this deflation, the Bank of Japan reduced its instrumental rate. By 1999 this rate was reduced to zero, yet it did not manage to stop deflation (Bowman et al., 2011). The Japanese economy was stuck in the liquidity trap. Then, in 2001, the global IT bubble burst. The Japanese economy had still not recovered from the Lost Decade. So the BoJ decided to use unconventional policy measures to boost the economy and launched the - “..the only relevant historical precursor.. [to the Federal Reserves Program]”(Blinder, 2010) - Quantitative Easing Policy (QEP).

The QEP was three-pronged: (1) The BoJ changed its main target from the instrument rate to the current account balances (CABs) held by financial institutions at the BoJ. (2) To do this the BoJ heavily increased its purchases of government bonds (including long-term JGBs) and some other assets. (3) The BoJ signalled that it was committed to “maintain the QEP until the core CPI {…} stopped declining” (Bowman et al., 2011). From 2001 to 2006 the BoJ expanded its holdings of Japanese Government Bonds (JGBs) by 63 trillion yen, which amounted to 4 percent of the GDP (Gagnon et al., 2011)9

.

According to Gagnon et al. (2011) it was the BoJ’s intention for the QEP program to operate mainly through the bank-lending channel. Gagnon   et   al.   (2011)   claim   that   the   BoJ’s   purchases  were  not  necessarily  focused  on  long-­‐term  JGBs:  “…the  BoJ  did  not  claim  that   purchases  of  JGBs  would  reduce  longer-­‐term  interest  rates.  Rather,  JGBs  were  viewed  as   an  appropriate  and  convenient  asset  for  the  BOJ  to  buy  in  order  to  supply  banks  with   liquidity.”   Because   of   this   attitude,   BoJ’s   holdings   of   JGBs   were   skewed   more   toward   short-­‐term   bonds.   This view is also supported by Joyce et al (2012). However, this contradicts an article by Blinder (2010) in which he states that, in contrast to the Federal Reserve, the BoJ focused on reducing term-premiums mainly by purchasing long-term

                                                                                                               

9  Martin  and  Milas  (2012)  also  support  this  claim  that  the  QEP  was  focused  on  short-­‐term  money  

(12)

JGBs.10

The literature’s judgment about whether the QEP was successful or not remains vague. Many articles mention that the QEP did have some positive effects on the Japanese economy, but that these were small and did not succeed in recovering Japans economy. “When gauging the effects of the QEP broadly, the results show limited effects on raising aggregate demand and prices” (Ugai, 2006).11

Girardin and Moussa (2011) suggest that for the QE to be effective, it needs to be maintained for a longer period than the QEP in Japan.

4.2 Quantitative Easing in the United Kingdom

After the global financial crises hit in 2008, the Bank of England followed the example of the Japan and the United States and announced its own QE program in 2009. It made purchases of UK government bonds, known as gilts, through the Asset Purchasing Facility, which was created on January 30th

2009 as “a legally separate entity run by the Bank of England but with indemnity assurances from the Treasury for any possible losses.”12 (Breedon et al. 2012).

During the period of March 2009 through January 2010 the BoE expanded its balance sheet, mainly by purchasing gilts with a maturity of over 3 years for 200 billion pounds. These purchases amount to 14 percent of the GDP and resulted in a 300 percent growth of the BoE balance sheet (Joyce et al., 2011). In 2011 the BoE did another round of QE amounting to 175 billion pounds by the end of 2012.

The focus of the program was on the portfolio-balancing channel, according to studies by Butt et al. (2014), Joyce and Spaltro (2014), Benford et al. (2009). As such the program consisted of long-term gilt purchases owned by non-bank financial institutes (e.g. pension funds, insurers). The Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) expected that the bank-lending channel would be ineffective and thus buying assets or gilts directly from banks would not result in an expansion of lending and of the money supply, because of the pressure on banks to deleverage their balance sheets. (Joyce et al. 2011).

                                                                                                               

10  In  any  case,  the  article  done  by  Gagnon  et  al.  (2011)  seems  to  have  more  validity  on  this  issue,  

as  they  are  able  to  reference  different  sources  supporting  their  claim,  while  Blinder  (2010)  does   not.  

11  Ugai  (2006)  also  concludes  that  the  biggest  effect  came  through  the  expectations  channel:  

“This  suggests  that,  in  conducting  monetary  policy  with  due  recognition  of  the  zero  bound   constraint  on  interest  rates,  communication  from  the  central  bank  to  the  private  sector  about   monetary  policy  is  critical  in  manifesting  policy  effects.”  

(13)

However, before QE was implemented in 2009, the BoE had already applied several policies to mitigate the dire economic situation, including the Special Liquidity Scheme of 2008. In this scheme the BoE purchased assets directly from banks (financed by issuing Treasury Bills, so strictly speaking there was no monetary expansion, because the money put in to the economy by purchasing assets was taken out of the economy by selling treasury bills) to provide them with extra liquidity. Combined with a loose regulation concerning bank reserve balances held at the BoE (banks were allowed to set their own target within a certain range) this actually did lead to some monetary expansion. “Thus, in some sense, a small measure of QE occurred over this period since some of the increase in the Bank of England’s assets was financed by an unusually large expansion of the monetary base.”(Breedon et al., 2012). If we indeed view this initial period as part of QE, one might argue that by directly providing banks with liquidity the bank-lending channel could have been more actively engaged.

Overall, the effectiveness of the BoE’s QE policy is still disputed. In their empirical research titled “The impact of QE on the UK economy – some supportive monetarist arithmic” Bridges and Thomas (2012) conclude that “the increase in the broad money supply induced by QE is likely to have had a positive effect on GDP and inflation”. However, Lyonett and Werner (2012), in their literary and empirical research into the QE program, found, that the QE policy was not significantly different from normal monetary policy (with the exception of the high media-profile of the announcements). They found that it was not helpful concerning the recovery of the economy. They further state that the BoE should have focused more directly on “the growth of bank credit for GDP-transactions” (Lyonett and Werner, 2012). They suggest that credit is the most important factor for economic growth. Thus maybe it was not wise of the BoE to negate the bank-lending channel.

4.3 Quantitative Easing in the United States

When the Lehman Brothers went bankrupt and the credit crisis unfolded, the Federal Reserve was quick to implement its own QE program. In the initial announcement, however, the Federal Reserves chairman Ben Bernanke called the program “credit-easing”, perhaps to differentiate it from the Bank of Japans program (which might not have had the best of reputations) (Blinder, 2010). As the crisis was developing in 2007, the Federal Reserve had already begun decreasing their instrument rate from 5.25 percent to 0.25 percent in 2008 (Gagnon et al., 2011).

(14)

QE1 consisted of 1.25 trillion dollars in Mortgage Backed Securities (MBS) purchases, 1.75 trillion dollars in agency-debt securities, and 300 billion dollars in long-term treasury bills. QE2 consisted of 600 billion dollars in long-term treasury bills. QE3 was an open-ended program, as there was no announcement as to when the program would be ended. It consisted of 40 billion dollar a month purchases of MBSs. In addition, the Federal Reserve started a Maturity Extension Program (known as Operation Twist) in which they purchased long-term treasury bonds financed by selling short-term bonds. This operation amounted to 400 billion dollars but, because it was financed by short-term bonds, it did not expand the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet. However, when the program stopped in December 2012 (due to a lack of short-term bonds), the Federal Reserve revised and extended the program to 45 billion dollars a month (open-ended), without it being financed by short-term bonds anymore (Rosengren, 2015). These programs together expanded the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet with about 6 trillion dollars. According to Gagnon et al. (2011), halfway trough QE2 these purchases already amounted to 12 percent of the GDP.

Although the implemented policies started of in a haphazard manner13

, the QE policy of the Federal Reserve ended up being the longest and largest in our historical review. As we can see by the purchase choices (mainly MBSs and agency-debt purchases in order to lower risk in that market, and less so long-term bonds purchases which should reduce long term interest rates), the Federal Reserve concentrated its efforts on risk-premia and not on term-premia (Blinder, 2010). Rosengren (2015) observes that the United States have managed to raise inflation rates slightly with their QE policies. They are not, however, back to pre-crisis levels. Furthermore, the exit-strategy will ultimately determine whether the programs will be successful.

5. Historical efficacy of the bank-lending channel

In this segment I will discuss research done into the bank-lending channel and place it within the context of the various implementations. Unfortunately, too my knowledge, there has been no study focused on the bank-lending channel in the United States. However, as noted before, the context of the United States QE implementation may help us understand the boundaries                                                                                                                

13  “The early stages of the quantitative easing policy were ad hoc, reactive, and institution based. The

Fed was making things up on the fly, often acquiring assets in the context of rescue operations for specific companies on very short notice (e.g., the Maiden Lane facilities for Bear Stearns and American International Group [AIG].” (Blinder, 2012)  

(15)

and possibilities of QE and give us a better sense of the viability of the bank-lending channel.

5.1 The bank-lending channel in Japan

Bowman et al. (2011) run a panel data-set regression to study the bank-lending channel during the quantitative easing program (QEP) of the Bank of Japan. In this study the amount of bank lending is regressed on a number of variables, including bank total assets, equity ratio, non-performing loan ratio and the bank type14

. Total bank-lending levels dropped during the QEP (see Figure 2 in the appendix). However, they do find “a robust, positive and statistically significant effect” of the QEP on bank-lending growth, suggesting that “the expansion of reserves associated with QEP likely boosted the flow of credit to the economy” (Bowman et al., 2011).

But this effect was very small and was overshadowed by the fact that banks reduced their liquid holdings in the form of loans held at other banks. According to Bowman et al. (2011) this is possibly because of the perceived risk and the regulatory capital requirements for such loans. The total liquidity of banks was thus reduced despite the liquidity boost from the BoJ.

Their research also shows that weaker banks (banks with lower equity ratios) showed a greater boost in bank lending than stronger banks. They did not find significant differences for bank size. These effects were only significant in the first years of the QEP after which bank health and confidence were restored. As such, the abrupt end of the QEP program did not lead to any deterioration in bank lending. These findings are corroborated by Inoue (2009), who also finds significant bank-lending growth due to the QEP, though he does contradict Bowman et al. (2011) by stating that smaller and healthier banks responded well to the QEP.

5.2 The bank-lending channel in the United Kingdom

As noted before, the Monetary Policy Committee had deemed the bank-lending channel ineffective before implementing QE. They believed that the pressure on banks to deleverage their balance sheets would prohibit the bank-lending channel to come into effect (Joyce et al., 2011). Joyce and Spaltro (2014) and Butt et al. (2014) (in rapid succession) both used panel                                                                                                                

14  An  interesting  variable,  which  controls  for  Japanese  bank  types,  the  characteristics  of  which  

are  beyond  the  scope  of  the  other  control  variables.  Such  a  variable  is  not  seen  in  the  research   done  into  bank  lending  in  UK  banks.  Bowman  et  al.  do  not  include  these  variables  in  their   regression  results,  however  they  do  state  that  regional  banks  seemed  to  have  higher  loan-­‐ growth  compared  to  other  types  of  banks  during  the  QEP  period.  

(16)

dataset regression studies to research the bank-lending channel in the QE program of the Bank of England. Joyce and Spaltro (2014) find a small but significant effect on bank lending growth, although these effects are likely to be even smaller because they assume “a full pass-through from QE deposits”(Joyce and Spaltro, 2014), which means they do not distinguish between different kind of deposits like the study by Butt et al. (2014).

They also found that small banks responded more to the QE program than large banks. They suggest this is because small banks are more liquidity constrained than larger banks and thus have a harder time acquiring liquidity. QE can thus be a real help to them, whereas large banks already have other means of acquiring liquidity. The bank-lending growth effect is also dependent on how well capitalized banks are. When banks have more capital, there is less pressure to deleverage.

In contrast, Butt et al. (2014) conclude that there is no significant increase in bank lending due to QE. By identifying the banks that participate in gilt sales by other financial corporations (OFCs), they show that only a portion of the resulting deposit remains at the bank after the sale, as OFCs use the liquidity to invest and re-balance their portfolio, exactly as described by the portfolio-balancing channel. As such Butt et al. (2014) do not assume a full pass-through of QE to deposits. Butt et al. (2014) put forth the hypotheses that the bank-lending channel is dependent on the type of deposits created: “flighty”(uncertainty about the future amount of the deposit) or “sticky”(certainty about the future amount of the deposit). When the central bank purchases gilts from an OFC, the OFC deposits the cash from the sale at a bank. The bank now has extra and cheap liquidity, which should induce it to increase its lending. If, however, these deposits are to be used for transactions with other OFCs holding deposits at other banks (as will happen when OFCs re-balance their portfolios), then the bank would have to resort to more expensive funding to back up its new lending. That is why, when banks receive deposits that are considered flighty, they will not be induced to expand their lending because the variance of their reserves likely increase and they will not be certain about the amount of liquidity they hold in the future. This suggests that bank-lending channel is rendered infective by the portfolio-balancing channel. They show that bank reserve variance did increase during the QE program and suggest that this might be the reason why bank-lending growth did not occur in the United Kingdom.

(17)

6. Analysis

As we have seen, QE is a monetary policy that is not yet very clearly defined. The general idea is clear: expand the money supply by purchasing a large amount of assets thereby increasing expected future inflation rates. Yet it does not define specifically what kind of assets should be purchased, where they should be purchased, how large the total amount of purchases should be, what duration the policy should have and through which channels it should work. This is evident when we look at the different implementations in Japan, the United Kingdom and the United States.

As a pioneer of QE, Japan unfolded a program that was relatively small and focused on the bank-lending channel, though it was mostly effective through expectations.

The United States, with the largest and longest succession of QE policies, initially focussed more on supporting certain industries (MBSs and agency-debt securities) but later turned more to providing general liquidity through long-term treasury bond purchases and then switching back to MBSs again.

The United Kingdom’s policy was more streamlined, in the sense that it focussed almost exclusively on long-term gilt purchases from OFCs and worked mainly through the portfolio-balancing channel. It was also the shortest program, though not the smallest.

Furthermore, leading up to and during these programs the central banks have taken other monetary measures that might also be seen as part of QE (e.g. the Special Liquidity Scheme). This further confuses our definition of QE, making it harder to isolate effects caused by QE.

The effectiveness of these programs is still debated. It seems clear, however, that QE is not as effective as we would wish it to be and “must be seen as a symptomatic treatment; it must be accompanied with a dramatic restructuring in the financial framework.” (Girardin and Moussa, 2011): The problems that caused the liquidity trap are not solved by QE. In order to solve the root of the problem other measures must be taken.

Concerning the bank-lending channel the research tells us that the effectiveness has either been little or none. But since implementation of QE is so diverse it seems probable that the effectiveness of the bank-lending channel can depend on the strategy chosen: The BoE did not have faith in the bank-lending channel and designed a strategy that in effect excluded it from

(18)

occurring, as we have seen in the article by Butt et al. (2014). They showed that the portfolio-balancing channel actually frustrated the bank-lending channel because of flighty deposits and the increased variance of bank reserves.

Knowing this, should central banks form their implementation strategies in such a way that they do engage the bank-lending channel? Lyonett and Werner (2012) would suggest that they should as they remind us of the importance of credit availability for economic recovery: “As credit for GDP-transactions is found to have highest significance in explaining economic growth, policy-makers need to consider the methods that may influence this variable.”

(Lyonett and Werner, 2012)

So what might we suggest to improve the effectiveness of this channel? To reduce flightiness, central banks should make QE purchases at commercial banks directly. This results in a direct increase in their reserves instead of an increase in flighty deposits, which happens when the central bank makes purchases at OFCs. We might also focus our resources on smaller and weaker banks, as it will be more effective there because those will be most in need of cheap, extra liquidity. Thus purchases of the same amount will yield more bank-lending growth when made solely at small and weak banks than when they are also made at large and strong banks. The total amount of liquidity injected must also be very large in order for the effect to be sizeable, as we have seen in Japan and the United Kingdom (Bowman et al., 2011; Joyce and Spaltro, 2014).

However, the portfolio-balancing channel has not been entirely ineffective in reviving the economy, as in the case of the United Kingdom. We might therefor consider that a central bank would want to use (at least) both channels to implement QE. In order to let QE operate effectively through multiple channels, I would suggest a multi-facetted program, with specialized purchases for each channel, is needed. This program should be large, long and have a clear exit strategy (Bowman et al., 2011; Girardin and Moussa, 2011; Svensson, 2003).

The QE rounds in the United States seem to approach these criteria, as they boast an expansive multi-facetted program focused on multiple channels. Because the Federal Reserve bought part of its assets directly from banks, it supplied liquidity directly, which may have led to bank-lending growth. The purchasing of long-term treasury bonds from banks and OFCs may have led to portfolio re-balancing, resulting in higher asset prices.

(19)

7. Conclusion

In this thesis I have examined QE and the role that the bank-lending channel has played in recent programs. The efficacy of the bank-lending channel is one of the main concerns that economists have about QE. As it is the only concern which relates to the functioning of QE rather than to its effects, it seems important that more research should be done into the bank-lending channel. The programs in Japan, the United States and the United Kingdom have been implemented with different strategies, which have resulted in different outcomes. As for the effectiveness of the bank-lending channel: studies suggest that it is either small or non-existent. (Unfortunately, there were no studies available for the Federal Reserve’s QE program.) Several studies find that the effect of the bank-lending channel is constrained, especially during crises, by pressure to deleverage banks balance sheets and flightiness of OFCs deposits. We suggest that the efficacy of the bank-lending channel might be dependent on the implementation strategy of the QE program. To actively engage the bank-lending channel, central banks should: (1) Purchase assets directly from banks so as to avoid flighty deposits, (2) focus their purchases on smaller and weaker banks who are more likely to be liquidity constrained and (3) increase the size of their program for larger effects. Additionally I suggest that in order to effectively engage all transmission channels a central bank needs to implement a large, long and multifaceted program with a clear exit strategy.

(20)

8.  References  

 

Bell, V., Joyce, M., Liu, Z., & Young, C. (2012). The Distributional Effects of Asset Purchases. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Q3.

Benford, J., Berry, S., Nikolov, K., Young, C., & Robson, M. (2009). Quantitative easing. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, 49(2), 90-100.

Blinder, A. S. (2010). Quantitative Easing: Entrance and Exit Strategies (Digest Summary). Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 92(6), 465-479.

Bowman, D., Cai, F., Davies, S., & Kamin, S. (2011). Quantitative easing and bank lending: evidence from Japan.

Breedon, Francis, Jagjit S. Chadha, and Alex Waters. "The financial market impact of UK quantitative easing." Oxford Review of Economic Policy 28.4 (2012): 702-728.

Bridges, J., & Thomas, R. (2012). The impact of QE on the UK economy–some supportive monetarist arithmetic.

Butt, N., Domit, S., McLeay, M., Thomas, R., & Kirkham, L. (2012). What can the money data tell us about the impact of QE?. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Q4.

Butt, N., Churm, R., McMahon, M. F., Morotz, A., & Schanz, J. F. (2014). QE and the bank lending channel in the United Kingdom.

Gagnon, J., Raskin, M., Remache, J., & Sack, B. (2011). The financial market effects of the Federal Reserve’s large-scale asset purchases. International Journal of Central Banking, 7(1), 3-43.

Gambacorta, L. and Marques-Ibanez, D. 2011. "The bank lending channel: lessons from the crisis", Economic Policy, Vol. 26 (66), 135-82.

Girardin, E., & Moussa, Z. (2011). Quantitative easing works: Lessons from the unique experience in Japan 2001–2006. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 21(4), 461-495.

Hudson, M. (2010). US 'Quantitative Easing' Is Fracturing the Global Economy. Bard College Levy Economics Institute Working Paper, (639).

Inoue, H. (2009). Bank Lending Channel during the Quantitative Monetary Easing Policy

Period (No. 09J004). Osaka School of International Public Policy, Osaka University.

Ito, T., & Mishkin, F. S. (2006). Two decades of Japanese monetary policy and the deflation problem. In Monetary Policy with Very Low Inflation in the Pacific Rim, NBER-EASE, Volume 15 (pp. 131-202). University of Chicago Press.

Jimenez, G., Ongena, S., Peydro, L., and Saurina, J. 2010. "Credit supply - Identifying balance-sheet channels with loan applications and granted loans", European Central Bank, Working Paper Series, No. 1179.

(21)

Joyce, M., Lasaosa, A., Stevens, I., & Tong, M. (2011). The financial market impact of quantitative easing in the United Kingdom. International Journal of Central Banking, 7(3), 113-161.

Joyce, Michael, Matthew Tong, and Robert Woods. "The United Kingdom’s quantitative easing policy: design, operation and impact." Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin (2011).

Joyce, Michael, et al. "Quantitative Easing and Unconventional Monetary Policy–an Introduction*." The Economic Journal 122.564 (2012): F271-F288.

Joyce, M., & Spaltro, M. (2014). Quantitative easing and bank lending: a panel data approach.

Kashyap, A. K., & Stein, J. C. (1994). Monetary policy and bank lending. In Monetary policy (pp. 221-261). The University of Chicago Press.

Krugman, P. (2000). Thinking about the liquidity trap. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 14(4), 221-237.

Lyonnet, V., & Werner, R. (2012). Lessons from the Bank of England on ‘quantitative easing’ and other ‘unconventional’ monetary policies. International Review of Financial Analysis, 25, 94-105.

Mahajan, A. (2015). Quantitative Easing: A Blessing or Curse. Advances in Management and Applied Economics, 5(2), 77.

Martin, C., & Milas, C. (2012). Quantitative easing: a sceptical survey. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 28(4), 750-764.

Meaning, J., & Zhu, F. (2011). The impact of recent central bank asset purchase programmes. BIS Quarterly Review, December.

Rosengren, E. S. (2015). Lessons from the US experience with quantitative easing (No. 94).

Svensson, L. E. (2003). Escaping from a liquidity trap and deflation: The foolproof way and others (No. w10195). National Bureau of Economic Research.

Ugai, H. (2007). Effects of the quantitative easing policy: A survey of empirical analyses. Monetary and Economic Studies-Bank of Japan, 25(1), 1.

Van den Heuvel, S. J. (2002). The bank capital channel of monetary policy. The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, mimeo.

(22)

9.  Appendix  

Figure  1.  (Benford  et  al.,  2009)  

   

Figure  2.  (Bowman  et  al.,  2011)  

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

The key coefficient from this regression is ∅ = ∑ ∅ , that measures to what extent the degree to which bank lending depends on the level of loan loss provisioning is sensitive

Since the average value of financial deepening is 48.20 percent (see Table 1), the marginal effect of central bank reform on the ratio between banks’ claims on the government and

Statistical evidence showed that the ratio of credit to domestic deposits (financial intermediation ratio) in South Africa is currently above 100 per cent, an

When we considered the impact of obesity on life expectancy in the 26 European countries, we found that without obesity, the increase in e 0 between 1975 and 2012 would have

ABSTRACT: Though 1,4-disubstituted 1,2,3-triazole rings have been utilized as electronic bridges in the solution phase, the use of a triazole ring to serve as an electronic bridge

Harmony in White and Blue, a painting with a similar history as the Girl in muslin dress and currently ascribed to Whistler, reportedly carries the same Grosvenor and United

In this research a model is presented that combines historical data on the number of children and the level of education to determine the best estimate provision for deferred

First, we present a Deep Belief Network for automatically feature extraction and second, we extend two standard reinforce- ment learning algorithms able to perform knowledge