• No results found

Crowdfunding real estate in the United States : is it also viable for commercial residential real estate in the Netherlands?

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Crowdfunding real estate in the United States : is it also viable for commercial residential real estate in the Netherlands?"

Copied!
127
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

Crowdfunding  Real  Estate  in  the  United  States:  Is  it  also  

viable  for  commercial  residential  real  estate  in  the  

Netherlands?  

 

 

  Source:  Canadian  Real  Estate  Magazine  

 

Thesis  

MSc  Entrepreneurship  

Gerrit  ter  Braake   VU  2566922  |  UvA  10854622    

 

Supervisor:  R.  C.  W.  van  der  Voort   July  01,  2015  

(2)

 

 

 

 

 

 

“Change  is  the  law  of  life  and  those  who  

look  only  to  the  past  or  present  are  certain  

to  miss  the  future”  

—John  F.  Kennedy—  

 

 

 

                         

(3)

Table  of  contents  

TABLE  OF  CONTENTS   3  

ABSTRACT   5  

1  INTRODUCTION   6  

1.1  CONTRIBUTION   10  

1.1.1  THEORY   10  

1.1.2  PRACTICE   10  

2  WHAT  IS  CROWDFUNDING?   11  

2.1  THE  ECONOMIC  MODEL   16  

2.2  MOTIVES   18  

2.2.1  INVESTORS’  MOTIVES   18  

2.2.2  MONEY  SEEKERS  MOTIVES   19  

2.3  INFORMATION  ASYMMETRY   21  

2.3.1  THE  AGENCY  PROBLEM   22  

2.3.2  MORAL  HAZARD   22  

2.3.3  ADVERSE  SELECTION   22  

2.4  POTENTIAL  PITFALLS  OF  CROWDFUNDING   23   3.  CROWDFUNDING  IN  THE  U.S.  AND  THE  NETHERLANDS   25  

3.1  CROWDFUNDING  IN  THE  U.S.   25  

3.1.1  LIMITATIONS  AND  REGULATIONS  BY  THE  GOVERNMENT   26   3.2  CROWDFUNDING  IN  THE  NETHERLANDS   28  

3.2.1  LIMITATIONS  AND  REGULATIONS  BY  THE  GOVERNMENT   30  

4.  THE  U.S.  REAL  ESTATE  MARKET   33  

4.1  COMMERCIAL  SECTOR   34  

5.  REAL  ESTATE  CROWDFUNDING  IN  THE  U.S.   37   5.1  ROLE  OF  CROWDFUNDING  PLATFORMS   41  

5.2  THE  FUTURE   43  

5.3  POTENTIAL  PITFALLS   43  

6.  THE  DUTCH  MODEL   46  

6.1  COSTS  OF  INVESTMENT   49  

6.2  RETURN  ON  INVESTMENT   50  

6.3  TARGETING  POTENTIAL  INVESTORS   51  

7.  RESEARCH  METHOD   54   8.  PRACTICAL  IMPLICATIONS   56   8.1  SCALABILITY   56   8.2  UNIQUENESS   57   8.3  COMPANY  STRUCTURE   58   8.4  REGULATIONS   59  

(4)

8.5  GETTING  AWAY  FROM  FINANCING  WITH  THE  BANK   60  

8.6  THE  MODEL  AFTER  THE  INTERVIEWS   61  

9.  CONCLUSION   64  

9.1  LIMITATIONS  AND  FUTURE  RESEARCH   65  

REFERENCES   66  

APPENDICES   75  

APPENDIX  A:  START  VALUE    DUTCH  MODEL   75  

APPENDIX  B:  CASH  FLOW  STATEMENT   76  

APPENDIX  C:  HOW  TO  START  A  CROWDFUNDING  CAMPAIGN?   77   APPENDIX  D:  MAARTEN  DE  JONG  –  ONEPLANETCROWD   78  

APPENDIX  E:  PETER  DE  VRIES  -­‐  RABOBANK   80  

APPENDIX  F:  KLAAS  KROOT  –  FOI  OPLEIDINGSINSTITUUT   87   APPENDIX  G:  AMRESH  BAJNATH  –  BELAGGIO  VASTGOED   91  

APPENDIX  H:  ROBERT  KAT  –  DTZ  ZADELHOFF   96   APPENDIX  I:  HANS  COEBERGH  –  COWHILL   102   APPENDIX  J:  BERT  WIJNVEEN  –  BERKHOUWE  VASTGOED   108  

APPENDIX  K:  WILLEM  KREULEN  –  MTH  ACCOUNTANTS   113  

APPENDIX  L:  BART  LEVER  –  LEVER  NETWERK  NOTARISSEN   117  

APPENDIX  M:  PROFESSOR  ARMIN  SCHWIENBACHER   122  

APPENDIX  N:  CASH  FLOW  STATEMENT  50%  MORTGAGE   126  

APPENDIX  O:  CASH  FLOW  STATEMENT  0%  MORTGAGE   127  

                                                 

(5)

Abstract  

 

This   study   addresses   the   viability   of   crowdfunding   commercial   residential   real   estate   in   the   Netherlands.   In   this   study,   commercial   residential   real   estate   is   defined   as   residencies   for   students   and   starters   on   the   labor   market   in   Amsterdam.  Crowdfunding  gives  a  manager,  an  individual  with  knowledge  and   experience  in  the  real  estate  market,  the  possibility  to  collect  capital  in  a  more   efficient   way.   In   this   study,   a   crowdfunding   model   for   the   Dutch   market   is   developed   by   combining   theoretical   insights   from   crowdfunding   and   asset   real   estate   studies,   and   recent   research   in   the   American   real   estate   crowdfunding   market  with  at  hand  research  data  gathered  from  the  Crowdfunding  day  and  the   professional  real  estate  fair  (PROVADA).  Subsequently,  this  model  was  tested  by   conducting  10  expert  interviews  with  individuals  that  are  active  in  one  of  four   pillars  that  make  up  the  model.  These  pillars  are  financing,  the  potential  investor,   the   manager,   and   the   real   estate   fund.   These   interviews   revealed   several   practical  implications;  two  of  the  practical  implications,  uniqueness  and  get  away   from   the   bank,   were   mentioned   by   most   interviewees.   Adding   them   advanced   the  model,  making  it  a  viable  basis  to  crowdfund  real  estate  in  the  Netherlands.                                          

(6)

1  Introduction  

 

In   the   recent   years,   crowdfunding   has   become   a   novel   way   for   entrepreneurs,   individuals   and   charities   to   finance   new   projects   and   ventures.   Crowdfunding   provides  the  possibility  to  raise  capital  through  an  open  platform  on  the  Internet.   These   projects   can   be   very   diversified   in   their   goals   and   magnitude.   They   can   vary   from   small   artistic   projects,   through   raising   money   for   charity,   to   entrepreneurs   who   are   seeking   many   thousands   of   euros   in   seed   capital   as   an   alternative   to   traditional   venture   capital   investment   (Schwienbacher   and   Larralde,   2010).   Others   say   that   crowdfunding   should   only   be   for   purposes   of   philanthropy   and   not   for   raising   capital   for   ‘serious’   business   plans   (Couwenbergh,   2015).   Despite   increased   attention   from   founders,   investors,   lawmakers  and  policymakers,  the  concept  of  crowdfunding  is,  in  general,  not  yet   fully  understood  (Griffin,  2012).  However,  research  shows  that  this  new  concept   of  cooperative  investing  is  becoming  a  more  preferred  way  of  investing  wealth   driven   by   developments   such   as   the   rise   of   the   sharing   economy   (Turnbull,   2015).  Within  the  professional  accounting  and  consultancy  sector,  crowdfunding   is   becoming   a   legitimate   part   of   business,   since   Deloitte,   Accenture,   EY,   and   KPMG  describe  crowdfunding  as  a  top  trend  in  their  sector.  This  is  clearly  true;   in  2014,  over  $16  billion  has  been  raised  through  crowdfunding,  with  $1  billion   of  that  amount  being  raised  specifically  for  real  estate  (Massolution,  2015a).   The  idea  of  crowdfunding  is  grounded  in  the  concept  of  crowdsourcing.  This  is  a   way   of   using   individuals   to   obtain   ideas,   feedback,   and   solutions   for   the   development  of  corporate  activities  (Bayus,  2013;  Howe,  2008;  Kleemann  et  al.,   2008;  Poetz  &  Schreier,  2012).  According  to  Brabham  (2008),  Schwienbacher  &   Llarralde   (2010)   and   Belleflamme   et   al.   (2010),   crowdsourcing   achieved   worldwide   recognition   through   the   article   “The   rise   of   crowdsourcing”   from   Howe   (2006).   In   this   article,   Howe   (2006)   gives   the   following   definition   of   crowdsourcing:    

(7)

“Crowdsourcing  represents  the  act  of  a  company  or  institution  taking  a  function   once  performed  by  employees  and  outsourcing  it  to  an  undefined  (and  generally  

large)  network  of  people  in  the  form  of  an  open  call”.    

The  company  Peanuts  Planters  already  used  the  idea  of  crowdsourcing  in  1916.   They  invited  the  public  to  a  competition  for  designing  their  new  company  logo   (Gibbons,  2012).  Despite  the  huge  amount  of  research  that  has  been  conducted   on   social   networks   and   online   communities   in   the   field   of   Human   Computer   Interaction   (HCI),   only   a   few   scholars   have   examined   crowdfunding   (Gerber   et   al.,   2012).   The   primary   goal   of   crowdfunding   is   to   raise   capital   (Vliet,   2011).   However,   companies   nowadays   also   use   it   in   their   marketing   and/or   sales   strategy.  An  important  characteristic  of  crowdfunding  is  the  extra  benefits  that   crowdfunders   receive   for   participating.   The   benefits   for   crowdfunders   vary   in   different   forms   of   crowdfunding,   ranging   from   an   equity-­‐based   model,   profit   sharing  and  lending  schemes,  to  outright  donations  (Belleflamme  et  al.,  2014).     The   crowdfunding   market   should   not   be   evaluated   by   the   size   of   the   sector.   Instead,  it  should  focus  on  the  impact  the  sector  has  on  the  economic  growth  and   its   role   as   a   catalyst   in   spurring   entrepreneurial   initiatives   (Schwienbacher,   2014),  as  one  of  the  main  barriers  to  innovation  is  the  availability  of  early-­‐stage   funding   (Cosh,   et   al.,   2009).   One   of   the   most   well-­‐known   and   successful   crowdfunding  campaigns  was  the  smart  watch  Pebble.  With  their  first  campaign   in   2012,   they   raised   $10.3   million   and,   in   2015,   they   raised   another   $20.3   million,   leaving   the   company   with   a   total   of   $30.6   million   from   reward-­‐based   campaigns  (Dredge,  2015).  In  a  letter  to  the  government,  the  Dutch  Minister  of   Finance,   Mr.   Dijsselbloem   (2015),   also   illustrates   the   importance   of   crowdfunding  for  financing  and  growth  of  small  and  medium  enterprises  (SMEs)   in  the  Netherlands.    

The   crowdfunding   sector   in   the   United   States   (U.S.)   is   ahead   of   the   European   crowdfunding   sector.   Last   year,   the   total   capital   raised   through   crowdfunding   was   $9.46   billion   in   the   U.S.   and   $3.26   billion   in   Europe   (Massolution,   2015b).  

(8)

The   latest   trend   in   crowdfunding   in   the   U.S.   is   real   estate.   Real   estate   is   a   collective   noun   for   everything   that   has   to   do   with   buildings,   not   only   the   property   themselves   but   also   its   management.   Last   year,   venture   capitalists   invested   in   three   real   estate   platforms:   Realty   Mogul,   RealCrowd   and   Groundfloor   (Clifford,   2014).   In   2014,   venture   capitalists   invested   more   than   $250  million  in  real  estate  crowdfunding  platforms  (Massolution,  2015a).  At  the   beginning   of   2015,   BD   Bacatá   will   open   its   doors   in   Bogota   and   be   Colombia’s   tallest   skyscraper.   What   makes   this   project   so   unique   is   that   3,100   investors   financed   it,   investing   $171.8   million   (an   average   of   $55,419,35   per   investor)   through   crowdfunding   (Raskin,   2014),   making   it   the   largest   funded   project   to   date.1  According  to  a  report  from  Massolution  (2015a),  real  estate  crowdfunding  

was  a  $1  billion  industry  in  2014,  with  investments  ranging  between  $100,000   and   $25,000,000.   They   expect   that   this   will   grow   to   more   than   $2.5   billion   in   2015,  representing  a  growth  of  150%  in  one  year.    

The   reason   for   this   increase   in   crowdfunding   real   estate   could   be   because   real   estate  is  a  unique  commodity  due  to  its  durability.  According  to  Turnbull  (2015),   owning  quality  real  estate  is  one  of  the  best  investments  that  investors  can  make,   since  it  generally  increases  in  value  over  the  investment  period  while  generating   income   at   the   same   time..   This   increase   will   not   only   be   there   due   to   the   Jumpstart  Our  Business  Startups  (JOBS)  Act,  Title  II,  but  also  due  to  the  increase   of  institutional  investors  on  the  crowdfunding  market  (Massolutions,  2015).  The   JOBS  Act  and  its  implications  will  be  further  elaborated  on  in  the  second  chapter.   The   idea   of   collecting   capital   from   different   individuals   or   companies   is   not   a   new  concept.  In  the  1980s,  the  concept  of  a  Real  Estate  Investment  Trust  (REITs)   was  developed  as  a  vehicle  to  access  a  more  diversified  portfolio;  by  aggregating   several   investors   a   REIT   could   increase   its   purchasing   power   (Massolution,   2015).   In   April   2015   the   Dutch   crowdfunding   consultancy   company   Douw   &   Koren  (n.d.)  wrote  thattwo  real  estate  crowdfunding  platforms  (SamenInGeld  &   2fund.nl)  were  active  in  the  Netherlands  and  two  more  platforms  were  planning                                                                                                                  

1  De  dato  June  8th,  2015  

(9)

on  going  online  in  2015(Crowd  Building  &  BouwAandeel).  Already  in  June  2015,   more   than   six   real   estate   crowdfunding   platforms   were   available   online.   This   shows   that   rapid   adoption   the   idea   of   real   estate   crowdfunding   in   the   Dutch   market.   As   stated   before,   real   estate   is   an   all-­‐encompassing   word.   For   the   demarcation  of  the  research  the  focus  will  be  on  the  commercial  residential  real   estate  market  in  Amsterdam.  This  part  of  the  real  estate  market  is  interesting  to   invest  in  since  it  kept  its  value  during  the  financial  crisis  of  2008.  Therefore  only   the  commercial  residential  market  is  elaborated  on  in  this  thesis.  For  that  reason,   the  research  question  in  this  thesis  will  be:  

Could   crowdfunding   commercial   residential   real   estate   be   economically   viable  in  the  Netherlands?  

In   this   thesis,   the   concept   of   crowdfunding   is   elaborated   with   the   focus   on   the   real   estate   sector.   Within   the   real   estate   sector   I   address   the   commercial   residential   real   estate.   From   there   on   I   created   a   model   for   crowdfunding   real   estate  in  the  Dutch  real  estate  sector.  To  do  so,  firstly  I  elaborated  crowdfunding   by  explaining  the  concept,  potential  pitfalls,  the  motives  for  investors  and  money   seekers  to  use  crowdfunding,  and  possible  information  asymmetries  that  occur.   In  the  next  chapter  the  crowdfunding  sector  in  the  U.S.  and  the  Netherlands,  and   their   respective   rules   and   regulations   are   elaborated.   In   the   fourth   chapter   commercial  real  estate  as  an  asset  and  his  characteristics  are  described.  Then  the   U.S.   crowdfunding   real   estate   is   addressed   on   the   basis   of   the   industry   report   about   crowdfunding   real   estate   from   Massolution   (2015a).   Subsequently,   in   chapter  six,  I  will  establish  a  model  based  on  the  U.S.  real  estate  crowdfunding   market   and   experience   gathered   from   attending   the   Crowdfunding   Day   and   master  classes  during  the  Dutch  real  estate  fair  for  professionals  (PROVADA).  In   this  study  this  model  is  tested,  this  is  done  by  conducting  expert  interviews  with   managers   from   respected   real   estate   companies   like   DTZ   Zadelhoff,   Berkenhouwe  Vastgoed  and  Cowhill,  and  with  other  professionals  specialized  in   crowdfunding  and/or  real  estate  like  Bouwaandeel.nl,  an  accountancy  firm  and   notary.   These   interviews   will   generate   practical   implications   that   make   clear  

(10)

what  will  be  needed  to  make  the  model  a  success  in  the  Netherlands.  From  these   practical  implications  the  most  mentioned  implications  by  the  interviewees  are   added   into   the   model.   In   the   last   chapter   the   limitations   of   this   study   and   possibilities   for   future   research   are   elaborated.   Furthermore,   the   research   question  is  answered.  

  1.1  Contribution  

In  this  part,  I  discuss  the  theoretical  and  practical  contributions  that  this  thesis   will   make.   It   is   important   to   understand   the   concept   of   crowdfunding   because   the  (small)  contribution  of  individuals,  both  founder  and  investor,  can  lead  to  the   creation   of   new   projects   and   ventures,   the   realization   of   social   projects.   These   can  fundamentally  impact  how  the  economy  and  society  functions  as  it  changes   how,   why,   and   which   products   and   services   are   brought   into   the   market.   As   banks  are  increasingly  reluctant  to  invest  in  the  start-­‐up  phase  of  new  ventures,   the  importance  of  crowdfunding  can  increase  over  the  next  few  years.  

1.1.1  Theory  

Research  in  the  field  of  crowdfunding  is  relatively  recent,  and  in  the  specialized   field  of  real  estate  crowdfunding,  almost  no  research  has  been  carried  out.  This   research   aims   to   contribute   to   the   literature   by   analyzing   the   real   estate   crowdfunding  market  of  the  U.S.    and  subsequent  incorporating  this  knowledge   by   implementing   the   potential   success   of   American   real   estate   crowdfunding   platforms   in   the   Dutch   real   estate   sector,   I   develop   a   model   for   making   commercial  residential  real  estate  crowdfunding  possible  in  the  Netherlands.    

1.1.2  Practice  

The  practical  implications  of  this  research  are  that  the  knowledge  and  the  Dut  h   model  can  be  used  by  Dutch  real  estate  companies  as  a  new  way  of  financing  real   estate.   Furthermore   crowdfunding   platforms   can   use   it   to   set   up   platforms   for   the  real  estate  sector.  At  the  moment,  several  crowdfunding  platforms  struggle  in   the   selection   and   application   of   business   models.   Furthermore,   the   topic   is   getting   more   and   more   attention   from   institutional   investors   and   banks   like   Rabobank  and  ING  because  it  has  huge  potential.    

(11)

 

2  What  is  crowdfunding?  

 

In   emerging   fields,   it   is   difficult   to   find   a   complete   definition.   In   several   overviews   of   crowdfunding,   the   most   widely   used   definition   is   taken   from   the   article   of   Kleemann   et   al.   (2008).   Schweinbacher   and   Larralde   (2010,   p.   588)   have  redefined  this  definition  as  follows:    

“An  open  call,  essentially  through  the  Internet,  for  the  provision  of  financial   resources  either  in  form  of  donation  or  in  exchange  for  some  form  of  reward  

and/or  voting  rights  in  order  to  support  initiatives  for  specific  purposes.”   Belleflamme   et   al.   (2014   p.   4)   defined   crowdfunding   in   almost   the   same   way,   with  minor  changes:    

“Crowdfunding  involves  an  open  call,  mostly  through  the  Internet,  for  the  provision   of  financial  resources  either  in  the  form  of  donation  or  in  exchange  for  the  future  

product  or  form  of  reward  to  support  initiatives  for  specific  purposes.”   According   to   Mollick   (2014),   however,   this   definition   potentially   leaves   out   examples  that  are  marked  as  crowdfunding  in  several  research  fields,  examples   such  as  peer-­‐to-­‐peer  lending  and  fundraising  for  music  groups.    

The   definitions   as   mentioned   above   supports   two   groups   of   money   seekers   in   financing  their  projects.  The  first  group  comprises  entrepreneurs  who  are  trying   to  make  their  dreams  come  true  and  establish  new  ventures.  The  second  group   comprises  small  business  owners  who  are  trying  to  keep  their  businesses  afloat   or  who  are  trying  to  let  them  grow  (Stemler,  2013).  In  this  chapter  the  concept  of   crowdfunding  is  elaborated  to  get  a  better  understanding  what  crowdfunding  is.   First   the   different   forms   of   crowdfunding   are   described.   Furthermore   the   economic   model,   the   motives   for   investor   and   money   seeker,   the   information   asymmetry  and  the  potential  pitfalls  will  be  elaborated  in  this  chapter.  

(12)

Several   crowdfunding   platforms   and   articles   give   four   different   forms   of   crowdfunding   (SterlingFunder,   n.d.;   Ryan,   2012;   Schwienbacher   &   Larralde,   2010;  AFM,  2014):  

1. Donation-­‐based   crowdfunding,   where   individuals   give   money   or   other   resources   to   the   project   because   they   want   to   support   the   cause   of   the   project.  

2. Reward-­‐based  crowdfunding,  where  in  exchange  for  a  reward  (often  the   product   or   service   that   the   new   venture   has   in   mind),   individuals   give   money   to   the   new   venture.   The   new   venture   often   uses   price   discrimination   between   individuals   who   pre-­‐order   and   those   who   will   buy   it   on   the   regular   market   in   order   to   attract   more   investors   (Belleflamme  et  al.,  2013).  

3. Equity-­‐based   crowdfunding,   where   individuals   get   a   part   of   the   equity   and   become   co-­‐owners   of   the   new   venture   in   exchange   for   their   investment.   In   2013,   less   than   5%   of   crowdfunding   was   equity-­‐based   (Massolution,  2013).  

4. Debt   crowdfunding,   where   individuals   borrow   money   from   the   venture   with   a   legally   binding   commitment   to   repay   the   loan   at   certain   time   intervals  and  at  a  certain  interest  rate.  

Some  include  a  fifth  form  of  crowdfunding:  royalty-­‐based  crowdfunding.  In  this   type   of   crowdfunding,   the   individuals   who   invest   in   a   new   venture   are   able   to   claim   a   percentage   of   the   revenue   once   the   new   venture   generates   revenue   (Outlaw,   2013).   Equity-­‐based   crowdfunding   is   especially   becoming   an   interesting   investment   vehicle.   According   to   the   Financial   Conduct   Authority   (2013,   p.8),   it   is   important   to   supervise   equity-­‐based   crowdfunding,   in   this   report  known  as  crowdinvesting,  more  strictly  than  crowdfunding’s  other  forms.   Figure  1  shows  the  financial  forms  of  crowdfunding:    

(13)

 

Figure  1:  Different  forms  of  crowdfunding  (SterlingFunder,  n.d.;  Ryan,  2012;  Schwienbacher  &   Larralde,  2010;  AFM,  2014;  Outlaw,  2013)  

Crowdfunding  became  popular  during  the  economic  crisis  of  2008  and  has  been   a  serious  way  of  financing  since  2013.  In  2013,  $6.1  billion  was  raised  through   crowdfunding;   in   2014,   it   became   $16.2   billion   and   the   prediction   for   2015   is   $34.4   billion   (Massolution,   2015b).   There   is   no   empirical   evidence   to   show   a   significant   relationship   between   the   rise   of   crowdfunding   and   the   economic   crisis   of   2008.   In   my   opinion,   however,   there   could   be   a   logical   relationship   between   these   two   events.   Due   to   the   economic   crisis   of   2008,   there   was   a   decrease  in  Venture  Capitalists  (VCs).  Figure  2  shows  on  the  next  page  that  the   amount  of  capital  invested  in  Europe  and  the  Netherlands  by  VCs  decreased  from   2007  to  2013.  

 

The  main  problem  is  that  it  is,  or  was,  harder  for  companies  with  a  lack  of  credit,   no  proven  track  record  of  sales,  and  no  performing  record  to  gain  capital  from   traditional  channels  (Fink,  2012).  Requiring  resources,  especially  finances,  is  one   of  the  most  important  factors  for  a  new  venture’s  success  (Gompers  and  Lerner,   2004;  Kortum  and  Lerner,  2000).  Thus,  new  ventures  must  seek  alternative  ways   of   financing   their   new   ventures.   Crowdfunding   could   be   a   new   way   to   make   it   possible  for  (new)  ventures  to  start  or  expand  their  businesses.    

 

Different  forms  of  crowdfunding  

non-­‐oinancial  

donation-­‐

based   reward-­‐based  

oinancial  

equity-­‐

(14)

 

Figure  2:  VC  investments  in  Europe  and  the  Netherlands  (Eurostat,  2014)  

There   are   several   reasons   that   (new)   ventures   want   to   use   this   new   form   of   raising   capital   according   to   the   report   by   Massolution   (2015a).   First   of   all,   the   method   of   getting   in   touch   with   potential   investors   is   very   efficient,   both   vertically  and  horizontally.  By  vertically  they  mean  that  money  seekers  can  not   only   give   potential   investors   a   brochure   of   their   project   but   that   can   also   use   videos,  photos,  interactive  tools  and  links  to  other  interesting  material  that  has   to  do  with  the  project.  By  horizontally,  they  mean  that  the  money  seeker  is  able   to  reach  out  to  the  entire  world  for  investment.  The  crowdfunder  is  now  not  just   confined  to  America  or  Europe,  but  instead  has  the  possibility  to  reach  any  and   every  investor  in  the  world.  The  second  reason  is  that  the  money  seeker  can  give   periodic  updates  to  his  or  her  investors  through  the  platform,  not  only  before  but   also  during  and  after  the  offer  periods.  The  third  reason  is  that  it  used  to  be  too   much  more  work  to  deal  with  a  number  of  small  investors,  meaning  that  in  the   past  they  would  often  set  a  minimum  investment  of  $100,000  or  higher.  With  the   introduction   of   the   crowdfunding   platforms,   this   negative   side   effect   disappeared,   as   they   were   able   to   have   efficient   communication   with   their   investors.   The   fourth   reason   is   that   with   more   potential   investors,   money  

2007   2008   2009   2010   2011   2012   2013   the  Netherlands   2842799   1763203   805422   1326492   2101128   1362159   988828   Europe   70275941   51635540   22816323   40019079   44570265   35274672   35710081   0   10000000   20000000   30000000   40000000   50000000   60000000   70000000   80000000   In ve st ed  c ap it al  in  m il li on  $  

VCs  investment  

(15)

seekers   can   get   higher   prices   for   their   (new)   ventures   and   improve   their   own   deal  economics.  The  fifth  reason  is  that  crowdfunding  platforms  take  the  stress   of  ‘managing’  investors  away  from  the  money  seekers.  Often,  money  seekers  see   the   investor   as   an   extra   workload   with   which   they   have   an   obligation   to   communicate   and   inform   them   about   the   progress   of   the   firm.   By   giving   the   money   seekers   the   online   back   office   to   keep   their   investors   up   to   date   with   sheets,  business  updates  and  other  investor  information  it  becomes  much  more   easier   to   communicate   with   the   investors.   The   sixth,   and   final,   reason   is   that   some   of   the   real   estate   crowdfunding   platforms   fund   the   investment   upfront.   Hence,  the  money  seeker  immediately  has  the  requested  capital.  The  real  estate   crowdfunding  platform  incurs  the  risk  of  not  being  able  to  successfully  place  the   investment  on  their  platform.  Furthermore,  crowdfunding  can  be  a  way  to  test   the  desirability  of  your  product  or  business  in  the  consumer  market.  Also,  banks   are   more   willing   to   finance   the   rest   of   (new)   ventures   once   they   have   seen   evidence   of   money   seekers   achieving   their   goal   through   crowdfunding   (Key,   2014).    

According   to   Mollick   (2014),   projects   that   succeed   are   able   to   do   so   by   a   relatively  small  margin.  The  results  of  his  research  are  shown  in  Figure  3  below:    

 

Figure  3:  Histograms  of  funding  level  (Mollick,  2014)  

Both   figures   show   the   same   trend:   an   exponentially   decreasing   line.   However,   the   meaning   is   not   the   same   in   each.   The   line   in   the   figure   of   failed   projects   shows  that  almost  50%  of  failed  projects  get  0%  to  5%  of  their  funding.  The  line   ends  with  more  than  95%  of  the  failed  projects  that  receive  less  than  40%  of  the  

(16)

amount  they  need.  In  other  words,  it  seems  that  when  a  project  receives  more   than  40%  of  its  pledged  level,  there  is  a  significant  change  in  comparison  to  the   project   that   receives   at   least   the   full   amount   it   needs.   The   line   in   the   figure   of   successful  projects  shows  that  50%  of  the  projects  receives  up  to  10%  more  than   their   goal.   In   total,   124   projects   with   goals   over   $100   received   10   times   their   goal,  of  which  44  were  very  large  projects  (over  $100,000).  41  out  of  these  44   projects  were  hardware,  software,  games  or  product  design  projects.    

Furthermore,  the  influence  of  social  information  plays  an  important  role  in  the   success  of  the  campaign.  Kuppuswamy  and  Bayus  (2013)  researched  the  role  of   social   information   in   the   dynamic   behavior   of   investors   with   the   data   from   Kickstarter.  They  held  a  panel  on  successfully  and  unsuccessfully  funded  projects   that   were   listed   on   Kickstarter.   The   result   of   this   research   was   that   additional   backer   support   is   negatively   correlated   to   already   achieved   backer   support   of   the   project.   This   implies   that   backers   often   do   not   support   a   project   that   has   already  received  a  lot  of  support  because  they  think  that  the  project  will  get  its   capital   anyway.   This   result   does   not   support   the   results   shown   in   Figure   3   because  then  most  of  the  crowdfunding  campaigns  would  not  get  100%  of  their   required  funding.    

  2.1  The  economic  model  

 

Belleflamme   et   al.   (2013)   created   a   model   in   their   report   for   the   reward-­‐   and   equity-­‐based   form   of   crowdfunding.   The   economic   model   consists   of   two   assumptions   to   simplify   the   model:   1)   the   entrepreneur   enjoys   a   monopoly   position   in   their   market,   and   2)   consumers   know   the   characteristics   of   the   product   before   the   purchase.   The   model   from   the   report   has   two   different   formulas:   one   for   pre-­‐ordering   and   the   other   for   profit   sharing.   In   this   thesis,   only  the  profit  sharing  formula  will  be  used.  Table  1  illustrates  the  variables  of   the  model.  These  variables  will  be  further  elaborated  in  what  follows.    

 

Variable   Definition  

K   Fixed  amount  of  money  needed  to  start  production  

s   Baseline  quality  of  the  good  (normalized  to  1)  

(17)

that  this  variable  is  distributed  uniformly  between  [0,1]  for   consumers  

𝒏𝒄   Number  of  crowdfunders  

𝚷, 𝝅𝟏, 𝝅𝟐   Total  profits  of  the  entrepreneur  (Π), profits  of  the  entrepeneur  in   the  first  period  (𝜋!)  and  second  period  (𝜋!);  bij  definition  Π = 𝜋!+  𝜋!  

Variables  specific  to  the   model  of  profit  sharing    

𝚺   Community  benefits  for  crowdfunders  

∝   Share  of  profits  that  the  entrepreneur  will  distribute  to   crowdfunders  (with  0 ≤  ∝  ≥ 1)  

Table  1:  Definition  of  variables  

To  determine  if  the  consumers  want  or  do  not  want  to  invest  in  the  new  venture,   the  authors  distinguish  between  consumers  who  are  willing  and  consumers  who   are  not  willing  to  buy  the  product  or  service.  The  result  is  the  incentive  

constraint  for  investing:  

𝜃 −  1 2+   𝛼 𝑁!   1 4−   𝐾 𝑁! +  Σ   ≥ 0  

The  idea  behind  this  equation  is  that  the  left  side  (𝜃 −  !!)  is  the  net  utility  from   consuming   the   product.   The   next   term   (!!

!  

!

!)  is   the   share   of   the   profit   that   potential  investors  (crowdfunders)  receive.  The  third  term  (!!

!)  is  the  amount  of  

capital   (money)   that   the   investors   (crowdfunders)   need   to   pay   to   the   entrepreneur  to  compensate  the  entrepreneur  for  the  equity  that  the  investors   (crowdfunders)   receive.   This   term   becomes   smaller   when   the   number   of   investors   increases   because   then   the   total   amount   of   capital   K   can   be   divided   between   more   investors.   The   last   term   (Σ)  is   the   community   benefit   for   the   investors  (crowdfunders).    

One  remark  for  this  equation  is  that  in  the  real  estate  sector  it  is  not  the  case  that   consumers  can  buy  the  product  or  service  in  the  second  period.  If  an  individual   invests,   then   you   are   part   of   the   investment   vehicle   and   it   is   not   the   case   that   there   will   be   a   result   from   this   vehicle   besides   buying   or   creating   real   estate.   Another  remark  is  that,  in  my  opinion,  the  variable  of  trust  should  also  be  given.   As  the  whole  process  is  online  and  investors  often  do  not  know  who  is  behind  

(18)

the  (new)  venture,  they  must  have  confidence  in  them  and  trust  them  with  their   capital.  

  2.2  Motives  

For  investors  and  money  seekers,  there  are  different  motives  behind  why  they   want  to  use  crowdfunding  platforms.  In  this  section,  their  motives  will  be  further   elaborated.  First,  the  motives  of  the  investors  will  be  provided  and,  after  that,  the   motives  of  the  money  seekers  will  be  addressed.  

2.2.1  Investors’  motives  

According  to  a  consumer  panel  of  the  Authority  for  Financial  Markets  (AFM)  in   the  Netherlands  (2014),2  investors  are  individuals  who  are  highly  educated  and  

have   a   higher   than   average   net   worth.   They   invest   in   crowdfunding   for   many   reasons:  it  is  a  direct  possibility  to  invest  in  (new)  ventures,  they  find  the  return   on  investment  attractive,  they  like  the  goals  of  the  (new)  ventures,  or  they  find  it   interesting  or  instructive  to  invest  through  crowdfunding.  Massolution  (2015a)   add   that   the   demographic   of   investors   is   shifting   toward   the   millennials   but,   even  so,  the  ones  with  above  average  income  and  net  worth.  The  psychological   reasons  as  to  why  individuals  give  money  are  sympathy  and  empathy  (Rick  et  al.,   2007),   guilt   (Cialdini   et   al.,   1981),   happiness   (Liu   &   Aaker,   2008)   and   identity   (Aaker   &   Akutsu,   2009).   Furthermore,   every   form   of   crowdfunding   brings   a   different   utility   to   the   investor.   With   donation-­‐based   crowdfunding,   investors   make  a  social  contribution  to  society;  often  this  is  an  intrinsic  motivation  (Collins   &   Pierrakis,   2012),   for   instance,   by   supporting   the   Red   Cross   or   an   artistic   movement.   With   reward-­‐based   crowdfunding,   investors   have   the   privilege   of   receiving   the   product   or   service   before   it   is   on   the   market,   a   first-­‐mover   advantage  of  investing  in  the  new  ventures  before  they  produce  anything.  They   also   have   social   and   intrinsic   motivations   for   investing   their   capital   (Collins   &   Pierrakis,  2012),  for  example,  a  new  venture  wants  to  start  a  new  clothing  brand.   They   attract   investors   with   reward-­‐based   crowdfunding   by   sending   them   the                                                                                                                  

2  The  consumer  panel  of  the  AFM  consists  of  an  interview  with  128  consumers  who  are  investing  

or  lending  money  through  crowdfunding  platforms  or  consumers  who  want  to  do  it  in  the  future.   This  panel  is  not  representative  for  the  whole  Dutch  population.  

(19)

first  T-­‐shirt  they  produce.  With  equity-­‐based  crowdfunding,  investors  receive  a   share  of  the  company  in  return  for  their  investment.  It  is  not  clear  if  they  become   consumers   themselves.   The   motivation   to   invest   is   financial,   and   sometimes   in   combination   with   social   benefits   (Collins   &   Pierrakis,   2012).   With   debt   crowdfunding,  investors  use  the  crowdfunding  platform  to  gain  a  higher  return   on   their   capital   by   taking   the   risk   of   lending   money   to   (new)   ventures.   Their   motivations   are   the   same   as   equity-­‐based   crowdfunding.   With   royalty-­‐based   crowdfunding,  it  is  not  about  a  share  in  the  company  but  the  investors  who  want   to  support  the  (new)  venture.  When  the  company  makes  a  profit,  the  investors   want   a   return   on   their   investment.   The   first   two   forms   of   crowdfunding   (donation-­‐   and   reward-­‐based)   are   for   the   personal   utility   of   the   investors   and   the  last  three  forms  of  crowdfunding  (equity-­‐based,  debt,  and  royalty-­‐based)  are   for  the  financial  utility  of  the  investor.    

Furthermore,   crowdfunding   gives   the   investor   access   to   more   diversified   investment   opportunities,   not   only   in   his   or   her   territory   or   country   but   also   globally.   In   addition,   investors   have   the   opportunity   to   invest   in   a   number   of   different   structures   and   return   possibilities   to   diversify   their   portfolio.   As   the   question  of  capital  is  on  the  crowdfunding  platform,  money  seekers  must  be  very   transparent.  Lastly,  the  investor  is  able  to  passively  participate  in  the  real  estate   project   because   the   crowdfunding   platform   or   money   seeker   is   doing   the   administration,  construction,  and  tenant  relations  (Massolution,  2015a).  Before   there  was  crowdfunding,  individuals  were  often  not  able   to  invest  in  start-­‐ups,   outside  very  wealthy  individuals  who  were  part  of  a  network  of  private  bankers.    

  2.2.2  Money  seekers  motives  

There  are  two  types  of  money  seekers  in  crowdfunding  activities:  1)  commercial   (profit)  money  seekers  who  want  to  start  a  new  venture  and  try  to  finance  their   ideas  through  crowdfunding,  and  2)  non-­‐commercial  (non-­‐profit)  money  seekers   who   want   to   start   a   project,   event   or   other,   often   artistic,   movement   for   the   utility   of   society.   First,   the   commercial   money   seekers’   motives   will   be   further   elaborated  and  the  non-­‐commercial  money  seekers’  motives  thereafter.  

(20)

Commercial   money   seekers   on   crowdfunding   platforms   are   mostly   (new)   ventures  and  individuals.  For  them,  crowdfunding  is:  a  relatively  easy  and  quick   way  of  financing,  an  alternative  because  they  are  not  able  to  receive  a  traditional   way   of   financing,   or   fitting   with   their   business   concept   (innovatory   or   durability).  It  can  also  be  a  beneficial  way  of  tapping  into  a  new  target  audience   (AFM,   2014).   Another   motive,   according   to   Belleflamme   et   al.   (2013),   is   that   price  discrimination  (reward-­‐based  crowdfunding)  results  in  an  expansion  of  the   money  seekers’  potential  market.  Mollick  (2014)  describes  it  as  demonstrating  a   demand  for  a  company’s  product  or  service.  For  example,  Pebble,  a  smart  watch,   was  rejected  for  venture  capital  funding.  After  that,  they  tried  it  on  Kickstarter,   raised   over   more   than   $20   million3  and   were   thereafter   able   to   receive   a   large  

amount  of  venture  capital  funding.  Therefore,  crowdfunding  could  be  seen  as  a   market  analysis  for  early  developers.  When  a  project  receives  the  amount  it  had   pledged,   or   even   more,   it   seems   that   there   will   be   a   market   for   the   product   or   service.    

Crowdfunding  can  also  be  used  for  marketing  purposes  by  creating  interest  from   the   crowd   in   the   early   stage   of   development.   Part   of   this   marketing   advantage   could   be   attention   in   the   press   and   other   companies   creating   compulsory   add-­‐ ons  or  applications  for  your  product  (Mollick,  2014).  

Non-­‐commercial   money   seekers   are   often   individuals   with   initiatives,   for   example,  one-­‐time  projects,  who  use  crowdfunding  as  a  unique  platform  to  raise   money  from  society;  this  is  often  less  than  $1000  (Mollick,  2014).  Otherwise  it   could  be  much  harder  for  the  organizer  to  increase  capital  for  the  event  from  his   social   and   commercial   circle.   Consider   a   barbeque   for   the   neighborhood,   or   a   movie  night  in  the  Vondelpark,  Amsterdam.  When  individuals  are  able  to  reach   the   crowd   that   has   gathered   for   a   one-­‐time   event   through   crowdfunding   platforms,  it  creates  a  new  fan-­‐base  for  future  events  and  their  organizers.  

                                                                                                               

3  De  dato  28  maart  (https://www.kickstarter.com/projects/597507018/pebble-­‐time-­‐awesome-­‐

(21)

  2.3  Information  asymmetry  

The   first   information   asymmetry   that   occurs   when   using   crowdfunding   is   that   the  (new)  ventures  do  not  know  which  of  the  active  users  of  the  crowdfunding   platform  has  the  highest  utility  for  investing  in  their  venture  (Belleflamme  et  al.,   2013).  It  could  be  the  case  that  in  the  process  of  financing,  the  money  seeker  is   not  giving  the  right  information,  or  that  he  knows  more  than  potential  investors.   It  could  even  be  that  the  money  seeker  provides  information  that  is  misleading   (AFM,  2014).  The  potential  problem  of  over-­‐  and  underestimating  new  ventures   is   that   the   best   new   ventures   will   stay   away   from   crowdfunding   platforms   because  of  the  high  possibility  that  the  crowd  will  underestimate  the  value  of  the   new  venture  (Dorff,  2014).  In  his  report,  Akerlof  (1970)  called  this  “the  lemons   problem”.   By   way   of   the   lemon   problem,   Akerlof   (1970)   explained   the   problematic  system  of  investing  in  a  good  car  –  there  will  always  be  a  possibility   that  one  will  invest  in  a  bad  car,  which  Akerlof  named  “the  lemon”.  The  lemon   problem  is  created  when  all  the  bad  cars  are  sold  and  the  good  cars  are  not  sold.   So,   the   bad   cars   tend   to   drive   out   the   good   car   competition.   As   described   by   Belleflamme   and   Lambert   (2014,   p.   293),   this   same   model   can   be   introduced   within  crowdfunding:    

“Platforms  only  manage  to  attract  low-­‐quality  projects  because  high-­‐quality   entrepreneurs  anticipate  that  they  will  not  be  identified  as  such  by  the  contributors  

and  will  therefore  fail  to  raise  the  capital  that  they  need.”  

Another   problem   that   can   occur   is   that   the   investors   have   no   idea   what   the   quality  of  the  product  is  because  crowdfunding  initiatives  often  rely  on  products   that  are  not  yet  on  the  market  in  finished  form  (Belleflamme  et  al.,  2013).  

In   their   report,   Belleflamme   et   al.   (2013)   state   two   situations   of   asymmetric   information:  1)  hidden  information,  when  the  understanding  of  quality  is  beyond   the  reach  of  the  entrepreneur  creating  adverse  selection,  and  2)  hidden  action,   when   the   entrepreneur   does   have   an   effect   on   the   level   of   quality,   creating   a   moral  hazard.  In  this  paragraph,  we  will  further  elaborate  these  two  situations   and  include  the  problematic  situation  of  agency.  

(22)

  2.3.1  The  agency  problem  

The   agency   theory   has   his   origin   in   the   late   ’60s   and   early   ’70s   when   Wilson   (1968)   and   Arrow   (1971)   introduced   the   problem   that   can   occur   when   cooperating   parties   have   different   approaches   toward   risk.   According   to   Eisenhardt   (1989),   there   are   two   main   problems   that   can   occur   in   the   agency   relationship.  The  first  agency  problem  that  can  arise  is  that  the  desires  or  goals   of   the   client   (principal)   and   the   contractor   (agent)   are   conflicted   and   that   it   is   difficult  and  expensive  for  the  principal  to  control  and  supervise  the  agent.  The   second   is   that   when   the   principal   and   the   agent   have   different   approaches   toward   risk   they   could   both   prefer   different   actions   because   of   their   risk   preferences.  An  agency  problem  that  can  occur  within  crowdfunding  is  when  the   money   seeker   (agent)   takes   more   risk   with   the   money   of   the   investors   (principals)  than  that  the  principals  want.  As  it  is  often  not  the  money  (capital)  of   the  money  seeker,  the  agent  is  willing  to  take  more  risks  because  the  potential   profit  lies  with  them.  

  2.3.2  Moral  hazard  

According  to  Belleflamme  et  al.  (2013),  the  situations  of  hidden  information  (i.e.   the   realization   of   quality   if   an   exogenous   event)   and   of   hidden   action   (i.e.   the   realization   of   quality   is   under   an   entrepreneur’s   quality)   are   in   general   within   the   information   asymmetries   that   are   in   favor   of   profit-­‐sharing   schemes.   With   crowdfunding,  the  potential  investor  has  no  idea  what  the  quality  of  the  product   is,  as  they  only  know  about  it  from  the  platform.  When  money  seekers  promise   that  they  will  create  an  A!  quality  product,  it  could  easily  be  that  they  make  a  B   quality  product  instead  to  save  money.  

  2.3.3  Adverse  selection  

The   money   seeker   can   create   adverse   selection   before   the   project   starts   by   introducing  the  project  on  a  crowdfunding  platform.  Money  seekers  could  inform   the  potential  investors  with  only  a  part  of  the  entire  proposition,  or  they  do  not   give  all  the  necessary  information  needed  to  accurately  evaluate  the  success  of   the  project.    

(23)

Yet   crowdfunding   platforms   can   also   have   adverse   selection.   In   a   report   from   Massolution   (2015a)   on   crowdfunding   in   the   real   estate   sector,   it   is   clear   that   several   real   estate   crowdfunding   platforms   have   used   due   diligence   to   give   advice  on  whether  or  not  the  investment  is  ‘safe’,  even  though  the  crowdfunding   platform  receives  a  fee  from  the  money  seeker  for  letting  them  use  the  platform.   In   this   case,   there   is   a   risk   that   the   due   diligence   is   not   the   truth   because   the   crowdfunding  platform  gets  fees  from  letting  money  seekers  use  their  platform.   Thus,   in   the   case   that   the   crowdfunding   platform   itself   needs   money,   the   platform  might  accept  campaigns  that  are  not  safe  but  who  do  nevertheless  get   the  seal  of  approval  from  the  platform.  

  2.4  Potential  pitfalls  of  crowdfunding  

 

The  potential  risk  for  investors  who  invest  through  equity-­‐based  crowdfunding   in   new   ventures   is   that   these   new   ventures   have   a   high   failure   rate   and   the   securities   are   unlisted.   Hence,   there   is   a   significant   change   of   potential   capital   loss,   risk   of   dilution,   fewer   possibilities   for   liquidation   and,   most   of   the   time,   there   is   limited   information   available   on   which   to   base   investment   decisions   (ESMA,   2014).   At   the   beginning   of   2014,   one   of   the   first   crowdfunded   projects   went   bankrupt   in   the   Netherlands.   Restaurant   Blauw,   which   already   had   restaurants   in   Amsterdam,   Rotterdam   and   Utrecht,   wanted   to   expand   to   Den   Hague.   For   their   restaurant   in   Rotterdam   they   had   already   crowdfunded   €250,000   in   2012.   So   when   they   had   the   plan   to   open   their   fourth   restaurant,   they  sought  crowdfunding  of  €125,000  under  the  condition  that  they  would  pay   10%  interest  to  their  investors  and  pay  back  the  loan  within  36  months.  Eighty   investors  invested  between  €100  and  €40,000  in  the  new  restaurant.  After  one   year,  the  restaurant  in  Den  Hague  went  bankrupt  (Beuters,  2014).  

A  potential  pitfall  for  crowdfunding  could  be  that  money  seekers  would  not  use   the   money   to   invest   but   embezzle   money   instead   (Hazen,   2012).   Seeing   as   the   screening   process   is   lighter   than   in   the   ‘standard’   financial   world,   fraudsters   could   be   attracted   to   this   market   in   order   to   embezzle   money.   In   the   Netherlands,   the   different   crowdfunding   platforms   do   not   communicate   with  

(24)

each   other   about   fraudsters   (AFM,   2014),   so   why   should   they   need   to   ask   for   money   on   a   crowdfunding   platform   instead   of   going   to   the   bank?   Another   potential   pitfall   could   be   that   crowdfunding   is   an   online   marketplace   for   individuals   who   want   to   launder   their   money.   The   chance   that   this   will   be   a   significant   problem   for   crowdfunding   is   low   because   investors   need   bank   accounts  at  almost  every  crowdfunding  platform  available  (AFM,  2014).  As  long   as   crowdfunding   platforms   do   not   accept   cash   money   from   investors,   this   will   not  be  a  problem.  

Another   potential   pitfall   could   be   that   the   lack   of   transparency.   For   example,   crowdfunding   platforms   could   ask   for   more   money   or   raise   their   fee   without   informing   the   money   seekers   (AFM,   2014).   When   investors   have   a   lack   of   awareness  of  these  risks,  this  could  lead  to  bad  investment  decisions  or  even  to   too  much  investment  in  failing  new  ventures  (Schwienbacher,  2014).  When  new   ventures  try  to  raise  capital  trough  crowdfunding,  they  must  reveal  their  ideas  of   innovation  to  investors  otherwise  they  will  not  invest.  The  potential  risk  for  the   new   ventures   is   that   competitors   or   other   individuals   will   copy   good   ideas   (O’Connor,   2014).   Several   of   the   pitfalls   as   aforementioned   have   a   legal   background.   According   to   Wolfson   &   Lease   (2011),   there   are   five   main   topics   that  must  be  discussed  and  need  definite  answers  for  new  legal  questions  that   arise  because  the  technological  innovation  is  often  ahead  of  the  law.  These  topics   are:   employment   law,   patent   inventorship,   data   security,   copyright   ownership,   and  security  regulations  of  crowdfunding.  

When  the  crowdfunding  market  keeps  on  growing,  the  potential  risk  is  that  the   pitfalls   of   crowdfunding   can   have   a   negative   effect   on   the   whole   economy   of   a   country  or  region.  It  can  also  reflect  financial  instability  in  the  market.  

     

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

Where, is a constant, , is the logarithm delinquency rate at level d in month t, reflects the Dutch residential property value in month t lagged by one, three and six months

Overall, we found that among the models included in the mixed model, the random forest model gave the best median out-of-sample predictions for terrace houses and detached houses,

On the investors side, portfolio allocation, diversification and diminishing return to scale theory are important explanations in the performance of real

Heaters are positioned above the buried waveguide and used to affect the effective refractive index of the waveguide (in the reference path) to compensate

Unfortunately,  these  results  are  not  new:  limited  use  is  a  common  problem  in  PHR  evaluations  [27].  Several  recent  systematic  reviews  focusing 

T he good relationships between the branches of catalysis can also be found in The Netherlands Institute for Catalysis Re- search (NIOK), of which almost all catalysis research

The applied filter path of these queries is analysed, can we see if certain filter paths, that represent certain law areas within the search engine, are more present in the DSAT

Therefore, considering the results presented above from antecedent studies and considering the supposition made based on the Social Identification Theory, there is a reason