• No results found

Banking union and alternative banking

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Banking union and alternative banking"

Copied!
26
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

Alternative Banking and Banking Union

Version 24 October 2014

Workshop on banking regulation, 15-11-2014, Maastricht. Shawn Donnelly

Faculty of Behavioural, Management and Social Sciences University of Twente

s.donnelly@utwente.nl

Banking Union and Alternative Banking: introduction

Does banking union in Europe lead to increased financialization of the economic sectors alternative banking traditionally serves by squeezing that part of the banking market? Table 1 shows that the share of alternative banking in the larger banking market declined between 2007 and 2012. Alternative banking covers private lending institutions such as cooperative banks, mutual societies and credit unions, but also (semi) public institutions ranging from nominally private banks with a public mission to banks owned, financed and controlled by government, to public-private hybrid institutions (Butzbach and Mettenheim 2013, Mettenheim and Butzbach 2014). Although they have a strong following by clientele opposed to big banks for political or ideological reasons, their principal function is to provide finance to sectors, regions and households of the economy that are

undersupplied by larger banks. Alternative banking provides credit for home ownership, business operations and local public sector operations (ranging from infrastructure to innovation and training programs to increase the quality and quantity of employment) that are not profitable enough or too risky to secure funding from commercial banks, where finance on equity (share) markets is not an option, and where bond markets are underdeveloped, too expensive or expose borrowers to

excessively volatile repayment conditions. Alternative banking provides a way for these borrowers to secure funding in a way that is of sufficient quantity, affordable and compatible with medium and long planning. It also plays a significant role in the constellation of public policies that attempt to pursue public interests and market failures (Epstein 2013, Spendzharova 2013, Goyer 2013, Donnelly 2012).

TABLE 1 HERE1

1 Total Assets and Deposits in differing banking sectors; Share of Total Bank Assets in different banking sectors. See example: http://www.nextnewdeal.net/bye-bye-bernankes-insidious-banks-end-too-big-fail-2-easy-steps

(2)

Banking union is a set of agreements to provide for regulation and supervision of banks at the European level, and to coordinate national mechanisms for winding down insolvent banks. It consists of a number of discrete parts. The most important are the Single Supervisory Mechanism (SSM), which establishes the ECB as the euro zone’s key bank regulator; and the Single Resolution

Mechanism, together with the European Stability Mechanism, which act as an additional layer on top of national efforts to recapitalize, restructure and resolve banks (close them) in the event of an emergency. Plans for a European deposit guarantee system as an integral part of banking union did not come to fruition.

Supervision, recapitalization, restructuring and resolution affect different kinds of banking in different ways, particularly if uniform standards are employed. In negotiations over banking union, several alternative bank associations raised concerns that regulatory standards designed to combat systemic risk in commercial and investment banks would disadvantage alternative banking, with negative impacts on both economic development and social policy. Some of these banking forms are private, in which the public policy element is limited to enabling and supporting them as positive alternatives to retail or universal banks (cooperative banks, building societies and credit unions in which the customers own the institutions), some are private, but with a mission to extend financing to public authorities at the municipal level (by holding large quantities of municipal bonds on their balance sheets, such as Dexia/Belfius) , while others are either fully public alternatives to retail or universal banking, providing services to both retail clients (Post Bank, Caisses des Depots) and governments (Landesbanken), or public-private entities with legal missions to support small and medium-sized enterprise (Sparkassen, Cajas). The argument of these banks was that additional regulatory measures and financial contributions to new insurance funds would constitute a transfer of resources from their own low-risk banking sub-sector to their larger brethren, who should rightly bear the full cost and consequences of their riskier business models. The collapse of some alternative banks supports, however, the ECB’s contention that alternative banking is not necessarily safe and that its banks should be regulated and taxed accordingly. It is in this context that European battles over the scope and depth of European powers over European banks have been and continue to be fought, and in which regulatory and financial pressures on alternative banks are a persistent reality. Banking union in Europe was nevertheless constructed partly, but not entirely with the intent to shield alternative banking from measures that would squeeze them unnecessarily. Most of banking union’s provisions apply to the largest 120 banks of the euro zone. As a consequence, most but not all alternative banks remain embedded in national supervisory and regulatory systems. However, there are three means by which banking union might extend its rules to smaller banks. First, as

(3)

alternative banks merge and acquire one another to compensate for decreasing profitability, particularly in the southern periphery of the euro zone that suffer the greatest economic hardship, the likelihood grows that they acquire sufficient weight to attract the attention of the ECB. Once on the list, more stringent rules and supervision apply that might accelerate pressure on alternative banks to reduce the kind of lending that they traditionally provide within the economy. In some situations, this could exacerbate an already-present trend that already places such lending under pressure. Second, the European Central Bank’s plan for leveraging cooperation from national supervisors in the SSM and setting supervisory standards for them will likely generate more harmonization pressure than one might expect at first sight, much as DG Competition has

successfully coordinated the standards of national competition authorities, and the ECJ has socialized national court systems in applying EU law.

Finally, banking union legislation on recapitalization and resolution systems provides room for the application of rules and burdens on alternative banks, despite the fact that rule design was intended for commercial banks with riskier business models. The failure of some alternative banks during the crisis increases the likelihood of banking union legislation being applied more broadly.

To the extent that these banking forms are squeezed, they may force their clientele to rely

increasingly on disintermediated financial markets and traditional commercial banks, with increased costs, reduced supply and more volatile, short-term conditions to them. This paper reviews the extent of squeeze on alternative banking, the mechanisms by which it might take place and the extent of liberalization that results. It works from the premise / tests the hypothesis that the effective squeeze on alternative banking felt in some parts of Europe is due to a combination of general macro-economic trends;2 a push by regulators toward deleveraging, which impacts some alternative banks more than others, and which is global in nature rather than specifically European; a push by regulators and lawmakers to demand increased security for all banks in the form of pre-paid deposit insurance and resolution funds, both of which are also global in nature rather than

specifically European. Nevertheless, the politics of banking union reinforce the protective power of more financially robust countries at the expense of others when it comes to establishing the legislative framework within which alternative banks operate.

(4)

ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK

The principal question of this paper is whether banking union is responsible for the lack of credit supply that SMEs face, exacerbates it, or has no discernible effect. There are a number of competing arguments that deal both with the question of how severe constraints on alternative banking are, and whether they are related to banking union or not. The mechanisms by which the relationship might be thought to work are: the scope argument, in which the main constraints are real and designed by the framers of EU legislation; the global standards argument, in which the main constraints of banking union are real but designed by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision; the market actor argument, in which banks themselves or their principal investors choose to

abandon the alternative mission of the institution; the secular trends argument, in which the decline of alternative banking is driven primarily by declining levels of economic growth that degrade the capacity of borrowers to repay loans, which hit alternative banks hard; and finally the political discretion argument, in which the ECB at the supranational level and member state governments at the national level (with the permission of the European Commission), exercise discretion in

determining whether to help alternative banks by decreasing the cost of capital and increasing demand. The first two arguments suggest that Banking Union’s impact on alternative banking is highly contingent on the rules set. In contrast, the last argument suggests that the discretion of political decision-makers in the grey areas left open by those rules are more important. Both of these generate quite different expectations than the third and fourth arguments, which expect a decline in alternative banking that varies directly with general economic decline. This paper takes a first look at the relative importance of these factors in three areas: financing local government, financing

household purchases, and financing the start-up and operation of small and medium-sized

enterprises. Testing the relative weight of these factors can give us insight into not only what impact banking union has, but to reflect on whether adjustments to banking union might improve

performance on lending and financial stability at the same time.

CONSTRAINT ARGUMENTS: BANKING UNION, BASEL AND ALTERNATIVE BANKING

> BU squeezes small banks through one size fits all policies, more rigorous supervision and stress testing. Capital adequacy (asset quality, equity holdings). Liquidity and leverage ratios, plus a variety of other measures designed to prevent contagion in the case of a credit event (resolution plans and funds, deposit insurance).

(5)

> Or less so due to limited reach

> BU’s impact depends on power of national governments to protect their own banks in BU design (vs. proposals of COM, ECB)

The politics of banking regulation in the European Union have a number of friction points between functional demands to establish a banking union and political demands to protect national banks and credit institutions. Issues of bank supervision, restructuring, recapitalization, resolution, exposure to rigorous stress testing, scrutiny of government debt purchases and deposit guarantee systems are considered vital to restoring the European banking sector back to health, but uniform rules in all of these areas were not implemented. Significant gaps, which provide room for alternative banks to operate without being squeezed to raise and retain as much capital as might otherwise be the case, remain after the establishment for the Single Supervisory Mechanism and its complement, the Single Resolution Mechanism.

took until spring of 2014. Instead of a European Resolution Authority in charge of a robust European Resolution Fund, the Council agreed to establish a Single Resolution Board that would recommend resolution decisions involving cross-border banks to the Council within a two week period, and a 55 billion euro resolution fund that would be built up gradually until 2026. This innovation fell short of other resolution systems on three counts: the time required to make a decision (normally a weekend or long weekend), on the power to take an authoritative decision (transferred to the member states in the council), and in the capacity to match resolution decisions with sufficient funds to wind down banks without inflicting contagion on the rest of the financial system.3 These three weaknesses mean that national authorities and funds improved on the gridlock of the EBA, but fell far short of a

European authority or fund. National resolution authorities would remain in charge in practice. The agreement legalizes this state of affairs by indicating that the national resolution authority in charge when a bank becomes insolvent is the authority of the member state in which the bank is

headquartered. The SRB effectively acts then as an umpire in the event of disputes regarding how that authority decides to allocate funds across borders during an insolvency proceeding.

Germany maintained that treaty changes would be necessary if the EU directive were to place any binding obligations on the member states, even through the EBA, which would greatly complicate passage of significant powers. Even then, it was not clear that the German government would allow

(6)

restructuring and resolution to involve cross-border transfers of banks or their parts in the process. Germany sought not only to kill the possibility of cross-border changes in ownership unless approved by national authorities, but to eliminate the possibility of the EU contributing to the costs of

resolution fund. Spain, as a potential recipient, in contrast, pushed for the EU to cover 90 percent of such costs (Breidthardt and O’Donnell 2013). It also had strong objections to a robust resolution fund, noting that German banks had their own arrangements and did not wish to pay for the transgressions of others. Even then, the ECB’s AQR would be required to identify legacy problems going into the resolution agreement and bracket them from the agreement. German alternative banks of all sorts lobbied heavily to reject the SRM entirely, or at least their involvement in it.

The same calculations applied to proposals for a European Deposit Guarantee System. The Commission initially favoured a European Deposit Guarantee System, but facing German and Austrian opposition (Stahlhut 2012), tabled a draft directive in 2012 to coordinate national systems and add the right of national systems to borrow from one another. By April 2013, however, the right to borrow proposal had been retracted. (Source) This was followed by the German finance minister’s statement of Germany’s opposition to the EDGS entirely (Breidthardt and O’Donnell 2013).

For the most part, negotiations over banking union pitted countries expected to have to pay for common rescue funds against those that expected to be the principal recipients (Dyson 2010, Donnelly 2013). This means that the public backstop in case of problems remains the national government, and national funding systems. This was not only true in an absolute sense of funding bailouts, but also when it came to arguing for whether Europe should play a role in regulating banks. While agreement was universal that banks should fund the general economy better and SMEs in particular, creditor countries in northern Europe felt confident of the capacity to do it on their own, and viewed the EU as a threat to that capacity, while countries in more dire financial straits in southern Europe repeatedly pleaded for European funds to help out with such matters. The greater leverage of the creditor countries, and of Germany in particular, ensured that carve-outs were possible for these sensitive sectors of the banking economy.

The result of deciding to retain national support systems for deposit insurance and other support systems means that the pressure on the financial viability of alternative banks varies from country to country, in addition to from bank to bank. Because alternative banks are most heavily invested in those secotrs of the economy that are doing most poorly in the euro zone’s southern periphery, alternative banks in those countries are finding their business models under pressure, with attendant

(7)

pressures to merge or soften the alternative banking model in favour of more highly securitized loan system that they were originally meant to follow—hence alternative.

European Banking Union Negotiations and Social Purpose

Whereas the European Central Bank and European Commission envisaged that the ECB would be the supervisor for all banks in the single market, the German government ensured that all but the largest banks would remain under national supervision in the first instance. This meant that Sparkassen would be spared ECB scrutiny (Spiegel Online 2012), in accordance with strong demands from both the public Sparkassen and the private cooperative banks to be left out of the Commission’s plans (Kaiser 2012). Landesbanken, on the other hand, would be scrutinized. Similar demands were made in Austria (Stahlhut 2012). The role of the state in directing and guaranteeing Landesbank solvency, however, means that outside pressure to reform lending practices to government is not expected to be great.

For the German government, the intent of agreeing to the now mis-named single supervisor model is that the government was simultaneously under pressure to approve bailouts of systemically

important financial institutions in Spain through the European Stability Mechanism, but given problematic experiences in the European Banking Authority, didn’t trust the Spanish supervisory authorities to put pressure on Spanish banks to reform and restructure in return for financial assistance (Donnelly 2013). The ECB’s role as supervisor allowed them to ensure this (Kaiser 2012a). Given that the principal recipient of the loans, Bankia, was a savings bank with strong local

government connections (Garicano 2013), the sense in Berlin was that without such pressure, conditionality, and the suitability of candidates for future bailouts, could not be assured.

COUNTERVAILING ARGUMENTS: MEMBER STATES, THE ECB AND ALTERNATIVE BANKING

NATIONAL INITIATIVES

UK is stuck with a weak alternative banking sector and a traditional banking system that makes mortgages available (as a result of a renewed housing boom in the south-east around London), but insufficient loans to SMEs. The cabinet’s response in August 2014 was the Small Business, Enterprise

(8)

and Employment Bill.3 Rather than compel banks to meet mandated funding targets, it foresaw that banks would have to provide SME credit rating information to other banks through an authorized Credit Reference Agency. The intent was that by forcing banks to share proprietary information, they would decrease the information asymmetry between banks and businesses, allowing banks to conduct a risk assessment based on more extensive information, which hopefully would work in businesses’ favour. However, another assessment was that the bill would promote alternative finance, meaning the securitized bond, hedge fund and angel investor markets, by requiring banks who turn down loans to provide applicants with information on these alternatives (Prosser 2014). Government loan guarantees in many countries, inside and outside the euro zone. Subsidized interest rates in only a few (A, GR, H, P, UK), with SME banks in CZ, F, P, UK, and many more in venture capital/equity funding/business angels in A, B, DK, SF, F, GR, H, IRL, NL, N, P, E, UK and several non-EU countries (OECD 2014: 45).

Direct lending to SMEs in a smaller subset,

Lending to SMEs: Semi-Public Banks and National Incentives to Private Banks Similar in purpose to the Dexia/Belfius case, is the widespread state protection of Sparkassen (savings banks) as core institutions of the social market economy at the municipal level in Germany, Austria and Spain. The German doctrine of Daseinsvorsorge, or providing for existential need, remained the principal defence of such savings banks from Commission demands for privatization and liberalization before the onset of the crisis. It also proved to be the main rallying cry of the opposition Social Democratic Party against saddling small banks with costs designed to bail out the riskier behavior of smaller banks (Zoelmmer 2012), and bringing in various politicians at the local (Roters 2013)(Social Democrat, City of Cologne) and European levels (Collin-Langen 2013)(Chirstian Democrat/EPP, European Parliament) in defence of the principle.

Those countries squeezed hardest by economic contraction made demands for the EU to provide cross-border transfers to stimulate lending to SMEs. Spain and Italy both made demands in this area in a joint conference of the two governments (Kane 2013, O’Leary 2013), including demands on the ECB to provide liquidity for this purpose (Morris 2013b), and with the need to combat youth unemployment (Morris 2013a). That conference followed support from France on 1 May, and followed a trip by the Italian prime minister to lobby Brussels and Germany to provide more assistance for growth, which was not forthcoming (Mackenzie 2013).

(9)

Further movement in the opposite direction for programme countries receiving bailout assistance from the EU. Spain’s banks required to reduce their balance sheets by about 60% and close up to half of their branches as a condition of EU assistance in 2012 (Chee and Dowset 2012). This also leads to divestments of foreign holdings and assets, even where the sales booked losses (Blenkinsop 2012)

EUROPEAN INITIATIVES ECB flexibility: see above.4 And see further marc jones5 and finally6

There are indications that the ECB can apply the constraints of stress tests flexibly when conducting supervision, as evidenced in its handling of the AQR in fall of 2014. While the ECB made it a rule to base the AQR in 2014 on the basis of static balance sheets as they stood at the end of 2013, it first agreed to relax those conditions for Greek banks by examining dynamic balance sheets. This meant that measures intended to increase the strength of bank balance sheets could be undertaken over the course of 2014 and used to score banks better on the AQR, and on the subsequent stress tests to be undertaken alongside. It also meant that the ECB would take into account bank contingency plans for selling assets to raise cash in the future as a key component indicator of capital adequacy or capital shortfalls, rather than actual equity / capital ratios.7 This means that an affected bank that the ECB judged to have an acceptable dynamic balance sheet position would not have to raise additional equity capital even if it did not meet capital adequacy standards In this context, the ECB also agreed to incorporate dynamic balance sheet testing alongside static balance sheets as an additional assessment criteria for other banks in the euro zone (Noonan, Papadimas and Taylor 2014). In the case of Greek banks, the dynamic balance sheet approach allowed banks to report figures that included restructuring plans that had been agreed with the European Commission over the course of 2014, after the December 2013 deadline for 4 Greek banks.

Such a change in ECB supervision, and the precedent it sets of national supervisors, has the potential to ease conditions for alternative banks, and even all banks as well. The European Banking Authority, which coordinates national supervisors, indicates that national supervisors have the discretion to do so as a result of the ECB’s decision (Noonan, Papadimas and Taylor 2014).

4http://www.reuters.com/subjects/euro-zone?lc=int_mb_1001 5http://blogs.reuters.com/marc-jones/page/2/

6http://uk.reuters.com/search?blob=european+central+bank&pn=20

7 Accepting this approach reflects the model employed by Oliver Wyman in stress testing Spanish and Portuguese banks

(10)

Also ECB on other macro matters: cheap bank loans, lower interest rates and facility to purchase reparcelled debt (Jones 2014) in September, which helped end a crisis in Italian, Irish and Spanish bond markets (Lash 2014). The ECB’s plans of October 2014 involved the ECB buying senior and mezzanine tranches of ABS debt, and lobbying national governments to take over the junior tranches. The envisaged split was that the ECB would take on no more than 70% of the assets, with the exception of Greece and Cyprus, where it would take no more than 30% (ECB 2014). Both Germany and France rejected the latter proposal, while German actors inside and outside the ECB opposed the plan in its entirety, with the head of the IfO think tank, Sinn, declaring that it turned the ECB into a bad bank (Jones 2014).

EBRD investments in banks that have particular difficulty making up shortfalls. But these are not specifically targeted at SME lending or alternative banks. The EBRD invested in Bank of Cyprus in September 2014 in return for having at least one independent member on the bank’s supervisory board, and one independent bank director announced an intention to become involved in “the entire banking sector in Cyprus”. However, it noted that the legal structure of cooperative banks made it difficult for the EBRD to take on significant influence similar to that undertaken at Bank of Cyprus (Jones & Noonan 2014).

SECULAR TRENDS

ACTOR-LED FINANCIALIZATION > Liberalization through demutualization / carpet bagging (UK)

> Liberalization through banks’ shift to predatory practices in unrestrained municipal lending (F)

> Liberalization (generating ASBs) through bank’s shift to unrestrained mortgage lending (E, NL)

Banks tighten credit requirements, restrict loan programs, then suggest that weak demand is

responsible for low loan levels, despite public subsidies for loan generation. This is in the U.S. as well (Blake 2013).

(11)

Before the onset and extension of the financial crisis in Europe, the relationship between banks and the finance ministries of national and subnational governments was mutually supporting in a number of countries. The euro zone crisis challenged this relationship in a number of ways. First, national banks in the EU’s emerging market countries have traditionally been a principal source of state finance at the national level for a number of EU countries, as they purchase treasury bonds from their home governments. This has continued during the period in which the European Central Bank has purchased those bonds in return from the banks, to ensure that they are not dumped on the market. As national governments responded to the financial crisis by issuing more debt, and banks were backstopped by the ECB, the level public debt held by banks exploded (Garicano 2013). Two things have changed this relationship significantly. First, banks have turned from being an asset to a liability for many governments, so that they no longer can perform the function they once did as strongly as before. Second, when the EU sets up conditions for financial assistance in so-called programme countries such as Greece, Portugal, Spain, and Ireland, it demands conditions that ensure the banks cannot perform this function for government. Where neither of these two pressures is very strong (Germany, above all), banks continue to provide such advantages to the public sector.

For the governments of countries subject to acute financial distress, the financial crisis turned this asset into a liability. Rather than banks assisting governments with their finances, governments found themselves burdened by increased demand from the banks themselves for cash injections and debt guarantees in order to remain liquid (or even solvent). For the banks of countries subject to EU bailouts, haircuts (private sector involvement) further reduced the value of assets on balance sheets (including assets held as reserves), rendering them insolvent, and generating further demand for public assistance. In those countries, assistance could be provided, either through national authorities, or in the case of Spain, through the European Stability Mechanism, but in other cases, such as Cyprus’ Laiki bank, it was not, with the consequence that the bank was marked for closure. Either way, the capacity of such banks to provide finance was significantly diminished. Greece and Cyprus were two countries in which the typically national relationship acquired a transnational dimension, owing to Cyprus’ close ties with Greece. Cypriot banks were heavily invested in Greek public debt and were heavily hit by haircuts on Greek public debt imposed by the Troika in 2011. In Germany, which weathered the euro zone crisis relatively well, Landesbanken also turned into liabilities, due to their diversification into American asset-backed securities in the mid-2000s. These liabilities did not, however, not evolve into full-blown crises for the state. The reason for this is that as public institutions, they remained outside the reach of market pressure on management through

(12)

the share price, and through ultimate state guarantees for the losses of the banks. In other words, the lack of banking sector liberalization in Germany, through which Landesbanken and Sparkassen (local savings banks) remained public entities rather than private ones, contributed significantly to both financial stability broadly, and to the continued, if diminished capacity to hold public sector debt on the balance sheet.

In Belgium and France, regional and municipal governments have an even greater reliance on banks as purchasers of government debt than their national counterparts. This reliance turned into a liability as well during the euro zone crisis, without the entire country descending into actute financial distress. Dexia, now renamed Belfius for its ongoing retail customers, played a similar, but even stronger role as a national institution that serves the municipal bond markets of France, Belgium and Luxembourg, ensuring the flow of credit to public authorities in local communities for various purposes. Dexia arranged finance for municipal bonds that were then sold to private investors. Those investors then retained the option to hand them back to Dexia as the underwriting bank on a weekly basis. The idea was that that Dexia would serve as a shock absorber during moments of financial stress. When the market for these variable rate debt obligations (VRDOs) was weak or negative, Dexia would take back the VRDOs and put them on its own balance sheet, shielding municipalities from an immediate obligation to repay (Long 2011). Some of these loans, when they became non-performing, were then taken on by the French national government, to the extent of 9 billion euros in 2013 (Laurent 2013).

Unlike banks in other countries, however, Dexia deviated from its policy of providing low-cost loans to municipalities and shifting to financial instruments with variable interest rates, pegged to various indexes (such as exchange rates between two currencies), but not an actual interest rate. These interest rates rose significantly during the euro zone crisis, up to three times the initial interest rate for many municipalities, which then became unpayable. Dexia was attacked by municipalities for strongly increasing the interest rate on VRDOs, by as much as 20% in 2011 (Long 2011), leading to a conflict with its stated social purpose. The attacks turned into debtor strikes and eventually lawsuits by municipalities against Dexia for usurious loan terms. The first of these cases resulted in the municipality of X renegotiating the interest rate down from an increased rate of 14% to a renewed, lower rate of 4.5%, and the issue of new loans (Laurent 2013).

Due to insolvency, Dexia was split into a good bank and a bad bank. The good bank became known as Belfius, while the bad bank retained the name Dexia, described by EU competition commissioner Almunia as ‘the biggest bad bank in Europe’. It would be responsible for winding up assets over a

(13)

longer period of time and returning the proceeds to Belfius, up to 13.8 billion euros by 2016. It requested in December 2012 a state guarantee of 65 billion euros on assets of 250 billion euros (Carleer 2012). The national governments of France, Belgium and Luxembourg stood in as the ultimate guarantors of losses Dexia makes (Blekinsop and Bartunek 2013). Belgium paid 4 billion euros as part of the nationalization of Belfius, with a 55.5 billion euro guarantee against losses. The last capital injection by the French and Belgian governments took place in December 2012,

amounting to 5.5 billion euros. The bank’s job as a strong provider of jobs for the economy was also damaged, if not as strongly as in the private sector. On employment, one can contrast the demands of Belfius in 2013 for wage reductions from its staff with more aggressive cuts of entire branches and jobs at BNP Paribas Fortis, an entirely private bank (De Openbare Bank 2013). These developments, particularly the decision to save Dexia rather than let it collapse at great expense, give a sense of the dysfunctionality and unusual nature of Dexia as a private enterprise with a social purpose that turned advantage in finance into liabilities. Nevertheless, the bank repeatedly received extraordinary

support from the three national governments during the financial crisis, with the blessing of the European Commission, in the interest of financing basic public services.

Banks also caused an increase in public debt elsewhere rather than buying it up. The Spanish government acted to facilitate the merger of two regional savings banks to save an insolvent one in 2012 (Unicaja taking over Banco CEISS) (Chee 2013). The payment was made through the Spanish bank rescue fund, the FROB, to prevent an outright nationalization. (Rucinsky 2013). In Spain, restructuring involves reducing real-estate related assets by transferring them at low prices to a public resolution authority, which may still remain liable for losses (OECD 2012: 3).

At the same time that they pay for the immediate losses and capital requirements of banks,

governments are also exposed during a bailout to the potential losses in the future that banks cannot compensate due to poor economic growth, which is endemic in Europe and particularly so in

Southern Europe. Banks in Spain had assets at 28.5 times GDP in 2011 due to the high value of pre-crisis mortgages. Government required banks in 2012 to build buffers to cover 45% of this, given the grave state of the economy (OECD 2012: 11). Stress testing suggested that the bank sector bill for Spain alone could reach 60 billion euros in the event of an adverse credit event. The cost of asset separation to restore the banks to health falls on the government in the absence of private investors (OECD 2012: 12).

Despite the disappointment in banking that serves the interest of national, regional and municipal government, the interest in maintaining the banks and the services that they provide remains

(14)

enormous, which points to a social purpose so strong that it cannot be tampered with. In France, the collapse of Dexia’s capacity to lend to municipalities led to an increase in municipal lending by the state-owned postal bank (La Banque Postale), which officially took over Dexia’s role as an issuer of municipal debt in June 2012, and the country’s networks of savings institutions (CDC/ La Caisse des Dépôts et Consignations) at the behest of the French Minister of Finance (Vinocur 2012). Originally an ad hoc intervention, their role was permanently institutionalized in March 2013 and extended to lending for hospitals through the creation of a joint enterprise named the Banque Postale

Collectivités Locales, backstopped financially by a special purpose vehicle established in January 2013 (Figaro 2013), Société de financement local (SFIL). SFIL is owned 75% by the French state, and 25% by the two public banks (Standard and Poors 2013), and was created by transferring Dexia’s municipal bond division out of the company (Dexia 2013). Initial plans were to provide 23 billion euros of state funds to enable municipal bond purchases over five years (Le Monde 2013). Public support of Landesbanken and Sparkassen in Germany remains strong (Kaiser 2012), as it does for publicly supported Cajas in Spain and Caixas in Portugal. All are banks that would be exempt from supervision under the single supervisor mechanism under negotiation in Brussels. They would fall under the direct supervision of national authorities, and even then, German Sparkassen insist that they cannot be supervised by a European authority due to their incorporation under public law, which ultimately makes them state institutions, rather than private law, as normal banks.

Mortgage Lending EU-SILC

> Lennartz et al (2014) find declines in home ownership, particularly in countries where mortgage credit varies more greatly. The observation in the UK that youth and others on the bottom of the socio-economic ladder are underserved in mortgage credit (compare Macartney) is not replicated across Europe evenly.

> Note that SME lending (short term) and mortgage lending (long term) are two different things. Lending to the public sector might be meant as long term, but might have short maturities (and the length of maturities might be affected by the fragility of public budgets—poverty trap.

> Schelkle (2012) notes the core nature of mortgage lending as social policy, in the UK, and particularly in the US, which have fewer social support systems than other countries.

Banks generally unwilling. See Armitstead 2014, outlining shift to alternative finance in UK despite Bank of England’s Funding for Lending Scheme.

(15)

SECULAR DECLINE AND FINANCIALIZATION > Declining profitability leads to mergers and closures

> Secular economic decline leads to consolidation, failure > Especially during an economic crisis (1970s wave)

> Related to non-performing loans, even when supply of credit is cheap (now) > BU may hasten trend by reducing forbearance of regulators, but no more

A contraction of credit can be expected to vary directly with the overall state of the economy, as economic decline increases the level of non-performing loans on bank balance sheets. This effect is strong in southern Europe within the euro zone, but also in eastern Europe, some of which lies outside the euro zone, but still takes part in stress tests overseen by the European Banking Authority (Jones 2014a).

See IMF (2013) and OECD (2014) on general challenges of SME funding. Includes allowing markets to give more benefit of the doubt, rather than a committee decision in a bank. Securitization as a viable alternative, just not in high octane variant that led up to the financial crisis (Economist 2009).

Coerced detachment in Program Countries

Asymmetric pressure also existed on banks in southern Europe forced to meet new minimum capital reserve requirements adopted by the European Union through the Capital Requirements Directive and the European Banking Authority. Riskier assets, which after the onset of the crisis include treasury bills from fiscally weak states in southern Europe, would have to be shed (exacerbating the inability of public authorities to rely on national banks to purchase treasury bills), or compensated by selling other assets or raising additional capital (both of which are difficult to realize in the

downward economic trajectory prevailing presently) (OECD 2013: 21). This requirement hurt small and medium-sized banks hardest (Jucca 2013). Raising additional capital was taken off the list due to demands from the EU Commission that subordinated bondholders bail in the banks and have their bonds replaced with bank shares (Chee and Dowset 2012), even where the initial debt was not of a hybrid nature (in which the possibility of such a change is explicitly written into the contract at point

(16)

of sale) (OECD 2012: 17). As part of the conditions for Spain’s bailout, banks were forced to reduce their balance sheets, which includes holdings of government bonds. One Spanish savings institution estimated that it would have to shed 25% of its holdings of government bonds (Chee and Dowset 2012). This meant that attracting new investors would be impossible. A knock-on effect is reduced lending to the private sector, prompting a further downward spiral, also with negative impacts for tax revenue (OECD 2013: 21)

FINANCIALIZED OUTCOMES in the ABSENCE OF THE ECB’S ABS PROGRAM

Venture capital: limited and volatile (OECD 2014: 43)8

Mezzanine finance9 which finances companies through hybrid debt-equity funds (OECD 2014: 62) is provided by EIB (European Investment Bank) in its capacity as the EIF; the MFG (Mezzanine Facility for Growth) since 2009; and the ERDF (Regional Development Fund)’s SME Guarantee Facility (Equity Guarantee Window). Germany has its own as of 2012. Banks have not been interested in loans under 2 million, leaving start ups undersupplied. France, Spain and Austria in the euro zone provided mezzanine finance directly from the state as a result. The funds invest in other funds, and provide them with a mandate (ibid).

Mezzanine finance common in the US from the 1980s, and grew in Europe until the crisis hit, but never recovered.

It allows companies to start up and operate using less leverage than before (dependent on bank loans), and improve the quality of balance sheets (equity rather than debt in the capital structure: OECD 2014: 67)

ANALYSIS: ALTERNATIVE BANKING

Alternative Banks as Assets and Liabilities in Public Finance

8 http://books.google.nl/books?id=jGdtBAAAQBAJ&pg=PA44&dq=sme+lending+financial+crisis&hl=en&sa =X&ei=8J0qVIS7O4ywPOrugKAK&ved=0CDEQ6AEwAQ#v=onepage&q=sme%20lending%20financial% 20crisis&f=false 9 http://books.google.nl/books?id=jGdtBAAAQBAJ&pg=PA44&dq=sme+lending+financial+crisis&hl=en&sa =X&ei=8J0qVIS7O4ywPOrugKAK&ved=0CDEQ6AEwAQ#v=onepage&q=sme%20lending%20financial% 20crisis&f=false

(17)

(CORRESPONDS TO SECULAR TRENDS AND PUBLIC INITIATIVES)

Although evidence is available that banks serve public policy purposes in a number of EU countries, and that intergovernmental rivalries paralyze progress toward a banking union (Veron 2011), little systematic comparative work has been done to illuminate the nature and variety of reasons why national resistance is so high or agreement is so elusive. What material public policy functions do banks fulfill? Which ideational factors, if any, are involved? In short, what are the social purpose elements to public policy that support economic nationalism and undermine a potential banking union, and how is it different from country to country? The following issues that have emerged in defending banks during the current financial crisis.

Deposit guarantee systems also posed a challenge, with the result that a European deposit guarantee system lacks intergovernmental support. German savings banks, and cooperative banks opposed the deposit guarantee system vociferously. They each have their own systems and funds for ensuring the solvency of a bank in the event of a run or other shock, and feared that they would be forced to establish and fund a second fund based on ensuring deposits. Whereas the German systems were designed to protect depositors indirectly, through the solvency and liquidity of the bank, the European plans focused on specific funds targeted directly at depositors. According to one report, the German government took these objections into account when deciding to block a European deposit guarantee scheme (Kaiser 2012, 2012a). This was instrumental in getting the ECB to modify its position that a deposit guarantee system would be necessary (Coussens 2012, Handelsblatt 2012). For the most part, negotiations over banking union pitted countries expected to have to pay for common rescue funds against those that expected to be the principal recipients (Dyson 2010, Donnelly 2013). This was not only true in an absolute sense of funding bailouts, but also when it came to arguing for whether Europe should play a role in regulating banks. While agreement was universal that banks should fund the general economy better and SMEs in particular, creditor countries in northern Europe felt confident of the capacity to do it on their own, and viewed the EU as a threat to that capacity, while countries in more dire financial straits in southern Europe

(18)

repeatedly pleaded for European funds to help out with such matters. The greater leverage of the creditor countries, and of Germany in particular, ensured that carve-outs were possible for these sensitive sectors of the banking economy.

FINANCIALIZATION AND THE ECB’s ABS PROGRAM

On 2 October 2014, the ECB announced that it would take extra measures to stimulate bank lending to SMEs. This would take place through the Asset-Backed Securities Purchase Programme (ABSP), which would purchase both senior and mezzanine tranches of asset backed securities, from both primary and secondary markets.

Mario Draghi suggested that the magnitude of the ABSP could be inject around 1 trillion euros into the euro zone economy. It would be the last measure the ECB could take to increase the money supply short of full-scale quantitative easing, which would not necessarily target funds for SMEs (Jones 2014).

CONCLUSIONS

There are three key reasons why member states are likely to persist in shielding certain sectors from European supervision, or the establishment of European restructuring, recapitalization, resolution or deposit guarantee responsibilities. The first is that some banks continue to provide finance to national, regional and municipal governments in many continental European countries. They are reliable purchasers of debt, and therefore key elements to long-term economic and social planning. The targeted focus on regional development, public works and social services is particularly strong at the municipal level, which often goes unnoticed in academic analysis, but proves to generate

remarkably strong and stable demand, and therefore is of great importance. Even where the banks involved failed to fulfill this function, national public authorities sought to ensure continuity through other banks to serve municipalities, to the extent that they could. In programme countries receiving financial assistance from the EU through the ESM or the EFSF, coerced detachment has significantly severed this relationship at the demand of the creditor states, as banks are forced to reduce the size of their balance sheets in return for loans. Given the continued high demand for such services in several of the creditor countries, particularly Germany, France and Belgium, the demand to scale back the provision of such financing services underlines the willingness of those countries to use loan conditionality as leverage to demand actions from debtor countries that the creditors themselves have shown no willingness to accept. On the contrary, the European Commission’s stance during the

(19)

financial crisis has been that state aid and financial guarantees to such banks for the purposes of securing economic growth and development is permissible, given the economic and social rewards envisaged. This has also been the reason why the Commission approves of state and and financial guarantees designed to nudge banks to lend more to growth-generating small and medium-sized enterprises. In practice, it is the same smaller savings banks which purchase municipal debt that are expected to extend such credit to the private sector as well.

The second key reason why member states are likely to shield certain sectors from banking union rests in the fragmented nature of the banking market, and the attendant appropriateness of various degrees of cost (above all for recapitalization, restructuring and resolution funds, some of which would flow across national borders in the event of a banking union), and of intrusiveness of regulation and supervision. The most vociferous objections across countries come from smaller banks, cooperative banks and credit unions, many of which argue that banking union imposes intrusive regulation and costly insurance schemes on all types of bank equally, meaning that safer institutions that eschew high-risk behavior pay high costs unnecessarily and subsidize the risky behavior of others, which damages their members and customers.

The third key reason is the fragmentation of deposit guarantee systems, coupled with strong disagreements on how a DGS should be designed and paid for. One key conflict of interest exists in which large banks may need to be serviced by larger deposit guarantees at higher cost than small savings banks and cooperative institutions. Another is that as consensus is emerging in deposit guarantee circles that DGS need to be funded more strongly in advance of a crisis (the so-called shift to ex ante funding), that banks themselves must set aside capital to put into that fund, and that states themselves serve as necessary lenders of last resort to the system. These emerging elements of consensus raise the expectation of moral hazard and distributional conflict in which the financially solid pay for the financially fragile, which the financially solid attribute to deliberately riskier

behavior. This generates conflicts within countries that resist resolution, but also between countries. In the European Union, the rejection of cross-border transfers for such purposes remains robust. The findings mean that neoliberal institutionalists and neofunctionalists were partly right: regarding incentives to create common institutions for banking union. There is a great deal of functional spillover involved in providing for financial stability in the EU. However, instead of making agreement easier, spillover in the area of banking union makes agreement more difficult by colliding with highly politicized banking sub-sectors that serve political ends. With the exception of those countries that have been forced to break this link by EU conditions on financial aid, there is no evidence of

(20)

countries scaling back their public support for exceptionality in these sectors. Even where the bank in question failed spectacularly to fulfill these functions or even survive, the state has stepped in to ensure a functional equivalent. These banks then enjoy natural political support for protection from rules or costs of banking union that might impinge on their ability to do so. It is in this light that the German demand that European banking supervision remain largely left up to the member states, and only be applied to the EU’s 25 largest banks, is best seen. It is also the reason why the undersupply of bank supervision in the EU is likely to persist in the future.

Literature

Armitstead, Louise (2014) ‘George Osborne to force banks to promote alternative lenders’,

Telegraph, 26 May, http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/10856425/George-Osborne-to-force-banks-to-promote-alternative-lenders.html

Baker, James (2009) ‘How Washington can prevent ‘zombie banks’’, Financial Times, 1 March. Bartunek, Robert-Jan and Blenkinsop, Philip (2012) ‘EU Commission approves Dexia bailout plan’, Reuters, 28 December.

http://www.reuters.com/article/2012/12/28/dexia-bailout-eu-idUSL5E8NS4WQ20121228

Bernauer, Thomas and Koubi, Vally (2003) Beyond the Level Playing Field: Determinants of Heterogeneity and Over-compliance in International Banking Regulation. Zurich: Center for Comparative and International Studies Working Paper 1-2003.

Blake, Brock (2013) ‘Small Business Lending: Banks and Credit Unions are Getting Left Behind’, Forbes, 21 October. http://www.forbes.com/sites/brockblake/2013/10/21/small-business-lending-banks-and-credit-unions/

Blenkinsop, Philip and Bartunek, Robert-Jan (2013) ‘Dexia asset sales weigh on first quarter results’, Reuters, 8 May.

http://www.reuters.com/article/2013/05/08/dexia-results-idUSL6N0DN2R920130508

Breidthardt, Annika and O’Donnell, John (2013) ‘Germany puts brakes on EU bank union with treaty call’, Reuters, 13 April.

Breznitz, Dan (2011) ‘Ideas, structure, state action and economic growth: rethinking the Irish miracle’, Review of International Political Economy 19, 1: 87-113.

(21)

Carleer, Danny (2013) ‘Dexia-miserie gaat ons nog een tijdje achtervolgen’, De Openbare Bank, 9 May. http://www.openbarebank.be/archives/21800

Carney, R.W. (2010) Contested Capitalism: the political origins of financial institutions. London: Routledge.

Chang, Michele and Leblond, Patrick, 2014. “All In: Market Expectations of Eurozone Integrity in the Sovereign Debt Crisis”, Review of International Political Economy, DOI:

10.1080/09692290.2014.941905 (Online 8 August).

Chee, Foo Yun (2013) ‘EU regulators approve Unicaja, Banco CEISS merger’, Reuters, 14 May.

http://www.reuters.com/article/2013/05/14/spain-banks-eu-idUSL6N0DV24R20130514

Chee, Foo Yun and Dowset, Sonya (2012) ‘Spain to overhaul rescued banks as condition of aid’, Reuters, 28 November.

http://www.reuters.com/article/2012/11/28/us-eu-spain-banks-idUSBRE8AR09S20121128

Collins-Langen, Birgit (2013) ‚Wirtschaftliche Betaetigung der Kommunen auch in Zukunft Unverzeichtbar‘, http://www.collin-langen.eu/parlament/35-wirtschaftliche-betaetigung-der-kommunen-auch-in-zukunft-unverzichtbar.html

Coussens, Wouter (2012) Presentation on the Euro Zone Crisis, European Central Bank, October. De Openbare Bank (2013) ‘De inleveringen van het bankpersoneel’, 22 February.

http://www.openbarebank.be/archives/20364

Dexia (2013) ‘Finalisation of the sale of Société de Financement Local’, Brussels and Paris, 31 January.

http://www.dexia.com/EN/journalist/press_releases/Documents/20130131_CP_closing_SFIL_EN.pdf

Donnelly, Shawn. 2011. “The Public Interest and the Economy in Europe in the Wake of the Financial Crisis”, European Political Science, vol. 10, no. 3, 384-92.

Donnelly, Shawn. 2014. “Power Politics and the Undersupply of Financial Stability in Europe”. Review of International Political Economy, vol. 21 no 4, 980-1005.

Dyson, Kenneth (2010) ‘Norman’s lament: the Greek and euro area crisis in historical perspective’, New Political Economy 15, 4: 597-608.

ECB (2014) ‘Technical Annex 1: ECB Announces Details of the Asset-Backed Securities Purchase Programme (ABSPP)’, 2 October.

(22)

https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/pr/date/2014/html/pr141002_1_Annex_1.pdf?c4144e9908c29df 066a053246f81d1ff

Economist (2009) ‘Market Fatigue: The Anglo-Saxon Model has Taken a Knock’, 1 October,

http://www.economist.com/node/14530138

Epstein, Rachel (2008) In Pursuit of Liberalism: international institutions in postcommunist Europe. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Ferri, G. and Liu, L.G. (2004) Government Guarantees Behind Banks: international evidence from the ratings. Unpublished Working Paper, University of Bari Dept of Economics.

Figaro (2013) ‘Coentreprise Banque Postale/CDC Créée’, 27 March.

http://www.lefigaro.fr/flash-eco/2013/03/27/97002-20130327FILWWW00545-coentreprise-banque-postalecdc-creee.php

Garicano, Luis (2013) ‘Banking union on the cheap will fail’, The Economist, 16 May

http://www.economist.com/blogs/freeexchange/2013/05/european-central-bank-2

Grossman, E. (2005) ‘European banking policy: between multi-level governance and Europeanization’, Governing Financial Globalization.

Handelsblatt (2012) ‘Sparkassen und Volksbanken atmen wegen Einlageversicherung auf‘, 7 November, http://www.handelsblatt.com/unternehmen/banken/draghi-zeigt-entgegenkommen-sparkassen-und-volksbanken-atmen-wegen-einlagensicherung-auf/7358534.html

Howarth, David and Quaglia, Lucia, 2013. “Banking Union as Holy Grail: Rebuilding the Single Market in Financial Services, Stabilizing Europe’s Banks and ‘Completing’ Economic and Monetary Union”, Journal of Common Market Studies, vol. 51, 103-23.

Howarth, David and Quaglia, Lucia, 2014. “The Steep Road to European Banking Union: Constructing the Single Resolution Mechanism”. Journal of Common Market Studies, vol. 52, special issue 1, 125-40.

IMF (2013) Global Financial Stability Report, October 2013: Transition Challenges to Stability.

http://books.google.nl/books?id=0QqcAQAAQBAJ&pg=PA84&dq=sme+lending+financial+crisis&hl=e n&sa=X&ei=8J0qVIS7O4ywPOrugKAK&ved=0CCsQ6AEwAA#v=onepage&q=sme%20lending%20financ ial%20crisis&f=false

Jabko, Nicolas and Massoc, Elsa (2012) ‘French capitalism under stress: how Nicolas Sarkozy saved the French banks’, Review of International Political Economy, XX.

(23)

Jones, Gavin (2014) ‘ECB targets bundled-debt market to boost economy’, Reuters, 2 October.

http://uk.reuters.com/article/2014/10/02/uk-ecb-rates-idUKKCN0HQ58D20141002

Jones, Marc (2014a) ‘EBRD sees shake-up of eastern Europe’s banks after stress tests’, Reuters 30 September, http://uk.reuters.com/article/2014/09/30/us-ebrd-banks-aqr-idUKKCN0HP1YB20140930 Jones, Marc and Noonan, Laura (2014) ‘EBRD looking to increase involvement in Cyprus’, Reuters, 30 September, http://www.reuters.com/article/2014/09/30/us-ebrd-cyprus-idUSKCN0HP1YH20140930 Jucca, Lisa (2013) ‘Insight: Mid-sized Italian banks face big bang for want of bucks’, Reuters 16 May.

http://www.reuters.com/article/2013/05/16/us-italy-banks-idUSBRE94F0AU20130516

Kaiser, Stefan (2012) ‘Anzeigeaktion gegen die Bankenunion: Kampf um die deutschen

Spargroschen‘, Spiegel Online, 13 September.

http://www.spiegel.de/wirtschaft/soziales/sparkassen-und-volksbanken-kaempfen-gegen-bankenunion-a-855706.html

Kaiser, Stefan (2012a)’Gipfel der Finanzminister: Europa soll zur Bankenrettungsunion werden‘, Spiegel Online, 12 December. http://www.spiegel.de/wirtschaft/soziales/gipfel-der-finanzminister-deutschlands-angst-vor-der-bankenaufsicht-a-872348.html

Kane, Claire (2013) ‘Spain’s Rajoy says EU must stick to bank reform calendar’, Reuters, 13 May.

http://www.reuters.com/article/2013/05/13/us-spain-rajoy-idUSBRE94C0FF20130513

Kapstein, Ethan. (1994) Governing the Global Economy: international finance and the state. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Keohane, Robert.O. and Nye, Joseph. (1984) After Hegemony: cooperation and discord in the world political economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Kindleberger, Charles (2005) Manias, Panics and Crashes, 5th ed. New York: Wiley.

Krasner, Stephen. (1976) 'State power and the structure of international trade', World Politics 28, 3: 317-47.

Krasner, Stephen (1999) Sovereignty: organized hypocrisy. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Lash, Herbert (2014) ‘Dollar slips, shares rebound after U.S. jobs data’, Reuters, 5 September

http://www.reuters.com/article/2014/09/05/us-markets-global-idUSKBN0H001120140905

Laurent, Lionel (2013) ‘French town renegotiates Dexia loan after debtor strike’, Reuters, 13 May.

(24)

Leblond, Patrick. 2014. “The Logic of a Banking Union for Europe”. Journal of Banking Regulation, doi: 10.1057/jbr.2014.11.

Le Monde (2013) ‘La banque des collectivités locales est créée’, 23 January.

http://www.lemonde.fr/economie/article/2013/01/23/la-banque-des-collectivites-locales-est-creee_1821438_3234.html

Lennartz, C., Arundel, R., & Ronald, R. (2014). Young People and Homeownership in Europe through the Global Financial Crisis.

Long, Cate (2011) ‘Dexia from the bottom up’, Reuters, 6 October.

http://blogs.reuters.com/muniland/tag/dexia/

Lyngen, N. (2012) Basel III: Dynamics of state implementation’, Harvard International Law Journal 53, 2: 519-35.

Macartney, Huw (2013) ‘From Merlin to OZ: the strange case of the UK SME lending 2007-2011’, Review of International Political Economy, forthcoming.

Mackenzie, James (2013) Italy’s Letta wins French backing for focus on growth’, Reuters, 1 May.

http://www.reuters.com/article/2013/05/01/us-italy-politics-idUSBRE9400PU20130501 Minsky, Hyman (1985) ‘Money and the lender of last resort’, Challenge 28, 1: 12-18.

Morris, Sarah (2013a) ‘Spain and Italy urge fast action on youth unemployment’, Reuters, 6 May.

http://www.reuters.com/article/2013/05/06/us-spain-italy-idUSBRE9450OT20130506 Morris, Sarah (2013b) ‘Spain’s Rajoy calls on ECB to help business funding’, Reuters, 6 May.

http://www.reuters.com/article/2013/05/06/us-spain-italy-financing-idUSBRE9450PJ20130506 Moschella, Manuela (2011) ‘Different varieties of capitalism? British and Italian recapitalization policies in response to the sub-prime crisis’, Comparative European Politics 9, 1: 76-99.

Noonan, Laura, Papadimas, Lefteris and Taylor, Eva (2014) ‘Greek banks win restructuring reprieve in ECB tests’, Reuters, 30 September.

http://uk.reuters.com/article/2014/09/30/uk-greek-bank-ecb-test-idUKKCN0HP1YJ20140930

OECD (2012) OECD Economic Surveys: Spain 2012. Paris.

(25)

OECD (2013) OECD Economic Surveys: Italy 2013. Paris.

http://www.keepeek.com/Digital-Asset-Management/oecd/economics/oecd-economic-surveys-italy-2013_eco_surveys-ita-2013-en

OECD (2014) Financing SMEs and Entrepreneurs 2014: An OECD Scoreboard

O’Leary, Naomi (2013) “Italy’s Letta sees anti-EU surge if no answers to crisis’, Reuters 6 May.

http://www.reuters.com/article/2013/05/06/us-spain-italy-letta-idUSBRE9450PZ20130506 Prosser, David (2014) ‘The big banks are right to feel nervous about alternative lenders as new legislation looms’, Independent, 10 August.

http://www.independent.co.uk/news/business/comment/david-prosser-the-big-banks-are-right-to-feel-nervous-about-alternative-lenders-as-new-legislation-looms-9660191.html

Quaglia, L. (2010) Governing Financial Services in the European Union: banking, securities and post-trading. London: Routledge.

Rucinsky, Tracy (2013) ‘Spain approves Unibanco, Banco CEISS merger’, Reuters, 10 May.

Roters, Juergen (2013) „Die Zukunft der kommunalen Daseinsvorsorge in der Metropolregion Köln“, Speech to the Cologne Network for Daseinsvorsorge, 18 January.

http://www.stadt-

koeln.de/mediaasset/content/pdf-ob/reden/2013/01/20130118_auftaktveranstaltung_netzwerk_daseinsvorsorge-eroeffnung.pdf

Schelkle, W. (2012). A crisis of what? Mortgage credit markets and the social policy of promoting homeownership in the United States and in Europe. Politics & society, 40(1), 59-80.

Spiegel Online (2012) Regierungserklaerung: Merkel verteidigt neuen Kurs bei Bankenunion‘, 13 December, http://www.spiegel.de/politik/deutschland/regierungserklaerung-von-kanzlerin-merkel-ja-zur-bankenunion-a-872637.html

Stahlhut, Annika (2012) Chances for Pan-European Deposit Insurance. University of Twente, unpublished thesis.

Standard and Poors (2013) ‘New French Public Sector Bank Societé de Financement Local Assigned ‘AA+/A-1+’ Ratings; Outlook Negative’, Paris: RatingsDirect.

http://www.standardandpoors.com/spf/upload/Ratings_EMEA/01Feb2013_NewFrenchPublicSector Bank.pdf

(26)

United States Congress (1990) Who is us? National interests in an age of global industry. Joint Economic Committee, 101st Congress. Washington D.C.

Verdier, D. (2001) Moving Money: banking and finance in the industrialized world. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Verdier, D. (2000) ‘The rise and fall of state banking in OECD countries’, Comparative Political Studies 33, 2: 283-318.

VERHELST, Stijn.2013. “Assessing the single supervisory mechanism: Passing the point of no return for Europe’s banking union”. Egmont Paper 58, June.

http://www.egmontinstitute.be/wp-content/uploads/2013/07/Egmont-papers-58.pdf

Vinocur, Nicolas (2012) ‘France’s Banque Postale doubles muni-loan capacity’, Reuters, 7 July.

http://www.reuters.com/article/2012/07/07/france-banquepostale-lending-idUSL6E8I72D320120707

Wade, Robert. and Sigurgeirsdottir, Silla (2010) ‘Lessons from Iceland’, New Left Review 65 (September): 5-29.

Zoellmer, Manfred (2013) ‚Europaeische Bankenunion und Bankentrennung‘, Speech to the Deutsche Bundestag, 17 May. http://www.manfred-zoellmer.de/aktuelles/meldung.htm?id=2145

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

In this subsection, we will discuss the potential costs and benefits of the different options of financing a USO: internal financing by banks (USO providers are forced to cover the

❖ The amount of investable assets, as the requirements were seen to vary for different wealth levels. For a growing number of segments such as those described above this approach

In view of the models for the 1: 1 FeMI Si02 catalysts several other interesting questions can be asked, such as the genesis of the bimetallic catalysts, the

In order to fill this gap in literature and to make a contribution to the limited body of knowledge about the Technology Readiness model and customer’s intention to share data with

2 Banks have increased salaries across Europe by 37% in the past four years in response to a crackdown on bonuses and pressure from.. regulators to claw back some rewards if bets

[r]

Abbey National was in 1989 the first building society to change its legal structure from a mutual to a public limited company (plc) status. In that same year on 12 July it floated

The literature study on the hospitality industry and of hotels, in particular, was explored by understanding hotel management, which was achieved by discussion aspects relating to