• No results found

The willingness to pay for shop diversity : evidence from the Amsterdamhousing market

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "The willingness to pay for shop diversity : evidence from the Amsterdamhousing market"

Copied!
45
0
0

Bezig met laden.... (Bekijk nu de volledige tekst)

Hele tekst

(1)

                 

 

 

 

The  willingness  to  pay  for  shop  diversity  

Evidence  from  the  Amsterdam  housing  market  

                                        July,  2017   Yasmin  Buijs,  10647066  

University  of  Amsterdam  (UvA)    

MSc  Business  Economics:  Real  Estate  Finance  &    Finance     Master  thesis    

(2)

Abstract  

The   last   couple   of   years,   the   number   of   tourism-­‐related   shops   has   increased   enormously,   especially  in  the  city-­‐centre  of  Amsterdam.  This  boosts  the  local  economy,  however,  there  has   been  a  growing  controversy  about  the  side  effect  this  increase  might  have.  One  of  the  most   controversy   side   effect   is   that   the   diversity   of   shops   is   at   risk,   which   could   influence   the   surrounding  house  prices.  This  thesis  investigates  this  by  looking  at  the  effect  of  different  shop   diversity  measures  on  house  prices  using  data  over  a  period  from  2008  to  2016.  A  hedonic   price   model   is   used   for   this   analysis.   The   regressions   produce   both   positive   and   negative   results.  The  absolute  measures  suggest  a  positive  linear  effect  of  tourism-­‐related  shops  on   house  prices,  but  the  relative  measure  suggests  a  negative  one.  Nevertheless,  the  models  give   significant   negative   results   for   the   non-­‐linear   variables   from   which   the   conclusion   can   be   drawn  that  the  relationship  between  tourism-­‐related  shops  and  house  prices  in  areas  with  a   medium  number  of  tourism-­‐related  shops  is  negative.  This  relationship  becomes  even  more   negative  when  there  is  a  high  number  of  tourism-­‐related  shops.  However,  this  difference  in   coefficients  is  not  significant  for  the  density  variable.  Furthermore,  the  gravity  certification   index   show   that   distance   to   tourism-­‐related   shops   is   relevant,   and   that   if   the   number   of   tourism-­‐related  shops  reach  a  certain  threshold,  the  house  prices  are  negatively  related  to   tourism-­‐related  shops.    

   

Statement  of  originality    

This  document  is  written  by  student  Yasmin  Buijs,  who  declares  to  take  full  responsibility  for   the  contents  of  this  document.  I  declare  that  the  text  and  the  work  presented  in  this  document   is  original  and  that  no  sources  other  than  those  mentioned  in  the  text  and  its  references  have   been  used  in  creating  it.  The  Faculty  of  Economics  and  Business  is  responsible  solely  for  the   supervision  of  completion  of  the  work,  not  for  the  contents.    

(3)

Table  of  contents  

Abstract...  1    

Statement  of  originality...  1  

1.  Introduction...  3    

2.  Literature  review...  6  

       2.1  Tourism-­‐related  shops  and  externalities………  6  

                 2.1.1  Tourism-­‐related  shops  and  economy………  6  

                                     2.1.1.1  Economy  and  house  prices……….  7  

                 2.1.2  Tourism-­‐related  shops  as  non-­‐residential  land  use……….  7  

                 2.1.3  Tourism-­‐related  shops  and  shop  diversity……….  8  

                                     2.1.3.1.  Shop  diversity  and  house  prices……….  9  

       2.2  Tourist-­‐area  lifecycle………  9  

       2.3  Solutions………  10  

       2.4  Measures  for  diversity………  11  

       2.5  Relevance  ………  12  

3.  Methodology...13    

       3.1  Hypotheses...  15  

4.  Data…...  16  

5.  Results……...  21  

       5.1.  Effect  of  the  three  diversity  measures  on  house  prices……….  21  

                 5.1.1  Effect  market  share  tourism  related  shops  on  house  prices……….  21  

                 5.1.2  Effect  density  tourism  related  shops  on  house  prices………..  24  

                 5.1.3  Effect  of  the  gravity  certification  index  (GCI)  on  house  prices……….  26  

         5.2  Summarizing  the  results………  29  

6.  Robustness  checks……….  30  

       6.1  Gravity  certification  index  with  different  radii………..  30  

       6.2  Density  variable  with  different  radii……….  32  

       6.3  The  three  diversity  measures  with  interaction  term………   33  

7.  Implications  and  limitation...  35  

8.  Conclusion………  36   References...  39   Appendix...  41                                  

(4)

1.  Introduction  

The  Netherlands,  especially  Amsterdam,  is  a  popular  tourist  destination.  The  last  decades,   Amsterdam  has  experienced  a  significant  growth  of  tourism,  the  number  of  foreign  visitors   for  example  has  grown  with  25%  over  the  last  5  years  (Municipality  of  Amsterdam,  2016).  This   increase  in  the  number  of  tourists  also  leads  to  more  capital  inflow  in  tourist  destinations.   However,  a  research  recently  done  by  the  weekly  paper  ‘de  Groene  Amsterdammer’  and  the   research  platform  ‘Investico’  claims  that  the  economic  advantages  of  tourism  for  Amsterdam   are  overestimated,  and  the  costs  underestimated.  The  profits  end  up  at  a  small  group  of  large   entrepreneurs,  which  are  often  part  of  a  foreign  company.  They  argue  that  the  idea  that  the   bustle  and  nuisance  are  annoying  but  that  the  city  benefits  as  a  whole  from  the  visitor’s,  is  a   myth  (Milokowski  and  Maas,  2017).  

In   the   city-­‐centre   of   Amsterdam   the   influence   of   Amsterdam’s   growing   popularity   among   tourists   and   visitors   is   increasingly   visible   in   the   retail   and   supply   facilities.   More   entrepreneurs  sell  products  that  can  be  sold  in  large  quantities  and  have  a  high  profit  margin,   such  as  waffles,  ice  cream,  and  cheese.  This  potentially  high  profit  margin  combined  with  the   big  number  of  passers-­‐by  in  the  city-­‐centre,  makes  the  city-­‐centre  an  attractive  location  for   this  type  of  entrepreneurs.  The  consumer,  including  the  inhabitant  of  the  city,  is  also  looking   for   convenience   and   one-­‐stop   shopping.   With   the   increased   popularity   of   shopping   at   supermarkets,   the   traditional   neighbourhood   shop   (baker,   butcher,   greengrocer)   is   under   pressure.   Furthermore,   there   is   a   lack   of   follow-­‐up   for   older   entrepreneurs.   Due   to   the   increased   popularity   of   some   tourist   areas,   these   neighbourhood   stores   and   facilities   for   residents   and   other   specialty   stores   are   further   under   pressure   and   disappear   from   some   shopping  areas.  This  is  due  to  financially  attractive  acquisitions  and  entrepreneurs  who  adjust   their   range   to   the   new   opportunities   created   by   the   influx   of   large   groups   of   tourists.   Consequently,  in  some  busy  shopping  areas,  the  typical  diversity  of  the  retail  and  catering   sector  is  decreasing,  and  there  is  a  one-­‐sided  supply  of  fast-­‐food  stores,  facilities  (for  example   leisure)  and  catering  (Municipality  of  Amsterdam,  2017).    

 The  sharp  rise  of  especially  tourism-­‐related  shops  is  being  identified  by  a  growing  group  of   residents  and  entrepreneurs  as  a  threat  to  the  attractiveness  of  the  city-­‐centre.  There  are   petitions  and  other  initiatives  in  the  (social)  media  that  asks  for  attention.  From  the  reports  of   the  municipality  of  Amsterdam  (‘Stand  van  de  Balans’  and  ‘sturen  op  een  divers  winkelgebied’)  

(5)

can  be  concluded  that  residents  are  complaining  about  these  changes  and  they  argue  that  the   city  does  not  belong  to  the  residents  of  Amsterdam  anymore.  In  2016,  a  survey  was  used  as   an  instrument  to  measure  the  opinion  of  the  residents  about  the  diversity  of  shops.  The  survey   responses   indicate   that   43%   of   the   residents   of   the   district   Centre-­‐West   reason   that   the   diversity  of  shops  is  too  low.  This  dissatisfaction  is  probably  related  to  the  emergence  of  the   Waffles-­‐Ice-­‐Nutella  shops  and  other  tourism-­‐related  shops  and  the  increase  of  big  chain  stores   in  the  city  centre  (Municipality  of  Amsterdam,  2016).    

An  attractive,  mixed  city  is  good  for  Amsterdam.  Its  attractiveness  strongly  determines  the   image,   economic   strength   and   international   reputation.   Tourism-­‐related   shops   are   not   appealing  to  the  city-­‐centre  of  Amsterdam,  and  excessive  dominance  of  these  shops  can  have   an  opposite  effect  on  the  number  of  tourists  and  visitors.  In  the  long-­‐term  this  is  detrimental   to  the  attractiveness  of  the  city-­‐centre  (Municipality  of  Amsterdam,  2017).      

Since  the  increase  in  tourism-­‐related  shops,  a  debate  is  originated.  There  are  reports  written   about  the  dissatisfaction  of  the  different  stakeholders,  especially  that  of  residents.  Therefore,   the  aim  of  this  thesis  is  to  answer  the  following  question:  

What  are  residents  willing  to  pay  for  shop  diversity?    

This  is  investigated  by  using  high  grade  house  price  data  that  is  made  available  by  the  NVM,   and   data   of   tourism-­‐related   shops   which   is   made   available   by   Locatus.   With   this   data,   a   hedonic   price   model   is   used   to   investigate   the   research   question.   The   main   independent   variables   of   interest   are   the   tourism-­‐related   shops   density   measure,   the   tourism-­‐related   market  share  measure,  and  the  gravity  certification  index  of  tourism-­‐related  shops.  Expected   is   that   small   proportion   of   tourism-­‐related   shops   have   a   positive   effect   on   house   prices,   because  it  boosts  the  local  economy,  but  when  the  diversity  of  the  supply  of  shops  is  put  at   risk,  it  will  negatively  affect  the  surrounding  houses.  

The  relation  between  the  tourism  sector  and  the  economy  has  been  investigated  elaborately.   Lots  of  research  has  found  a  positive  linkage  between  tourism  and  economic  growth  in  both   the  short  and  long  term  (Bimonte  et  al.,  2012).  On  the  one  side,  the  tourism  growth  boosts   local  economy  and  make  residents  better  off.  On  the  other  side,  the  tourism  growth  generates   negative  environmental  and  social  externalities  that  make  residents  worse  off  (Biagia  et  al.,   2012).   Previous   literature   has   evaluated   the   effect   of   local   amenities   and   disamenities   on   tourism-­‐related  accommodations.  Other  studies  focused  on  the  effect  of  amenities  such  as  

(6)

open  spaces,  public  parks,  natural  areas,  golf  courses  and  other  types  of  amenities  on  property   values.  Also,  the  effect  of  disamenities  such  as,  noise,  HVTLs,  waste  sites,  crime  and  other   types  of  disamenities  on  property  values  has  been  investigated.  However,  these  studies  are   amenity-­‐specific  and  are  not  looking  at  the  effect  of  the  diversity  of  amenities.  Nevertheless,   some  reports  have  been  written  about  the  situation  in  Amsterdam,  regarding  the  increase  in   tourism-­‐related  shops.  They  have  concluded  that  the  different  stakeholders  (the  municipality,   the  residents,  the  entrepreneurs,  and  the  real  estate  investors)  are  dissatisfied.  However,  this   is  based  on  surveys,  where  this  analysis  will  use  actual  data  to  test  if  this  dissatisfaction  has   an  impact  on  house  prices.  Furthermore,  this  thesis  is  a  contribution  to  the  social  discussion   about  tourism-­‐related  shops  and  can  be  useful  by  determining  a  policy.  

The   results   imply   that   a   consistent   linear   relationship   between   house   prices   and   tourism-­‐ related  shops  is  missing:  the  density  measures  suggest  a  positive  relationship,  and  the  market   share  measure  a  negative  one.  However,  the  density  and  market  share  measure  show  that   there  is  a  negative  non-­‐linear  relationship  between  tourism-­‐related  shops  and  house  prices.     When  houses  are  in  an  area  with  a  medium  market  share  or  density  of  tourism-­‐related  shops,   house  prices  are,  on  average,  3.4%,  lower  than  houses  in  an  area  with  no  tourism-­‐related   shops.  The  dummies  for  high  market  share  and  density  of  tourism-­‐related  shops  are  even   bigger,  and  suggest  that  house  prices  in  these  areas  are,  on  average,  4.2%  lower  in  comparison   with   areas   that   have   no   tourism-­‐related   shops   in   the   area.   Furthermore,   the   gravity   certification   index   (GCI)   of   tourism-­‐related   shops   show   that   the   relationship   between   this   variable  and  house  prices  have  the  shape  of  a  downward  opening  parabola.  However,  the   value  of  the  turning  point  is  relatively  high,  which  implies  that  only  a  few  observations  have  a   value  that  exceed  the  value  of  the  turning  point.  

The  structure  of  this  thesis  is  as  follows:  section  2  gives  a  review  of  the  existing  literature   followed   by   the   relevance   of   this   thesis;   section   3   presents   the   methodology;   section   4   describes  the  datasets  that  are  used  with  some  descriptive  statics;  the  results,  and  robustness   checks  are  discussed  in  section  5  and  6;  and  section  7  and  8  poses  some  further  implications   and  concludes.  

       

(7)

 

2.  Literature  review  

This  section  begins  by  explaining,  using  different  theories,  which  effect  tourism-­‐related  shops   might  have  on  house  prices

.  

This  is  done  by  putting  it  into  perspective  with  the  situation  in   Amsterdam.   Then   some   potential   solutions   to   this   problem   are   addressed.   After   that,   the   three  different  diversity  measures  will  be  discussed.  This  section  is  concluded  by  an  analysis   about  the  relevance  of  this  research.  

 

2.1  Tourism-­‐related  shops  and  externalities  

2.1.1  Tourism-­‐related  shops  and  economy      

Tourist  destinations  worldwide  have  experienced  a  significant  growth  in  the  influx  of  money   and  visitors.  This  growth  has  been  the  result  of  some  socioeconomic  changes,  such  as  the   increase  in  disposable  income,  longer  periods  off,  more  money  is  spent  on  leisure  and  the   longer   life   expectancy.   Furthermore,   this   tourism   growth   has   been   aided   to   the   improved   transportation,  this  is  especially  the  case  for  international  tourism  (Biagi  et  al.,  2015).  Whereas   tourist  expenditures  are  an  important  source  of  funding  for  both  the  private  and  public  sector   as   it   generates   income   and   employment   for   retail   and   retail   area   development.   Lots   of   research  has  found  a  positive  linkage  between  tourism  and  economic  growth  in  both  the  short   and  long-­‐term  (Bimonte  et  al.,  2012).  Most  of  these  studies  argue  that  tourists  and  visitors   generates   economic   activity   directly   in   the   form   of   output   or   sales,   labour   earnings   and   employment.  They  also  use  the  ‘multiplier  impact’  of  tourism  expenditures.  This  measures   how  many  times  money  spent  by  a  tourist  circulates  through  a  country’s  economy  (Frechtling   and  Horvath,  1999).  Due  to  the  multiplier  effect,  many  studies  agree  that  tourism  generates   an  important  source  of  income  and  boosts  the  economy.  Whereas  shopping  is  the  second   most   important   expenditure   item   for   both   domestic   as   international   tourism,   after   accommodation.  Although,  shopping  is  not  often  mentioned  as  a  primary  reason  for  travel,  it   is  of  great  economic  importance  to  local  merchants  (Turner  and  Reisiger,  2001).  Furthermore,   several   researchers   have   concluded   that   for   many   tourists   a   trip   is   not   complete   without   having  spent  time  on  shopping  (e.g.  Hudman  and  Hawkins,  1989;  Kent  et  al.,  1983).  Tourists   often  make  their  experience  tangible  by  purchasing  souvenirs  and  acquiring  gifts  for  loved   ones.  Kent,  Shock  and  Snow  (1983)  argued  that  ‘to  be  able  to  peruse,  to  examine,  to  feel  and   to  think  of  the  joys  derived  from  purchasing  certain  merchandise  is  indeed  pleasurable  to  

(8)

millions  of  people,  and  for  them  is  a  minor,  if  not  a  major  reason  for  travel’.  Therefore,  it  is   more  attractive  for  entrepreneurs  to  produce  and  sell  products  for  tourists  and  visitors:  where   demand  is,  follows  supply.  Tourists  are  interested  in  souvenirs  and  quick  bites  that  can  be   cheap  and  simple  produced  or  prepared,  so  this  will  be  supplied.  Especially,  selling  of  large   amounts  with  a  large  profit  margin,  like  waffles,  ice  and  cheese,  has  become  attractive.        

2.1.1.1  Economy  and  house  prices  

Research  in  both  the  field  of  tourism  economics  and  housing  studies  recognize  that  tourism   and  tourism-­‐related  activities  can  affect  housing  markets  directly  as  well  as  indirectly.    Directly   via   the   ‘external’   demand   that   competes   with   the   local   for   land,   housing   and   services.   Indirectly  via  the  tourism-­‐related  amenities  and  disamenities  that  affect  the  market  price  of   all  surrounding  houses.  Kendall  and  Var  (1985)  suggest  that  the  positive  impacts  of  tourism   and  tourism-­‐related  activities  are:  more  and  better  leisure  facilities,  more  parks  and  gardens,   and  an  increase  in  employment  and  business  opportunities.  However,  tourism  and  tourism-­‐ related  activities  might  also  simultaneously  be  the  source  of  various  sorts  of  disamenities  that   can  be  a  large  disadvantage  to  residents  (Biagi  and  Detotto  2014;  Biagi  et  al.,  2012).  These   negative  impacts  include:  crowding,  congestion,  noise,  litter,  property  destruction,  pollution,   environmental  degradation,  general  resentment  to  the  wealth  of  tourists,  loss  of  wildlife  and   ad  hoc  development  (Kendall  and  Var,  1985).  As  such,  the  tourism-­‐house  price  relationship  is   expected  to  be  positive  when  tourism  and  tourism-­‐related  activities  boost  the  local  economy,   or  negative  when  the  negative  externalities  that  tourism-­‐activity  generates  predominate.    

2.1.2  Tourism-­‐related  shops  as  non-­‐residential  land  use  

Li  and  Brown  (1980)  have  investigated  the  theory  that  accessibility  at  a  micro  scale  increase   the   value   of   a   house.   They   argue   that   proximity   to   some   non-­‐residential   uses   can   be   accompanied  by  external  diseconomies  such  as  congestion,  noise,  and  air  pollution  that  affect   the  value  of  residential  properties.  Their  results  show  that  the  accessibility  to  non-­‐residential   land  uses  increase  residential  property  prices,  but  that  this  effect  is  more  significant  for  the   accessibility   to   commercial   establishments   than   for   the   accessibility   to   industries.   Furthermore,   the   negative   price   effect   of   the   related   externalities   is   less   significant   for   commercial   establishments   than   for   industries.   This   means   that   the   accessibility   to   commercial  areas  predominates  the  externalities  related  with  it,  this  is  not  the  case  for  the  

(9)

industrial  areas.  However,  Kain  and  Quigley  (1970)  argue  that  the  presence  of  commercial  and   industrial  uses,  results  in  a  statistically  significant  negative  effect  on  apartment  rents  and  on   the  values  of  single-­‐family  houses.  Stull  (1975)  argued  that  it  is  likely  that  a  small  proportion   of  commercial  activity  is  desirable,  because  of  the  shopping  convenience  it  affords.  However,   if  this  commercial  activity  reaches  a  certain  threshold,  it  becomes  a  community  liability  rather   than  an  asset,  because  the  disamenities  created,  outweigh  the  extra  shopping  convenience.   His   results   confirm   this   hypothesis,   as   he   finds   that   as   the   proportion   of   commercial   land   increases   the   value   of   the   single-­‐family   properties   tend   to   rise,   but   if   the   proportion   of   commercial  properties  in  a  community  exceeds  5%  the  value  of  single-­‐family  homes  tends  to   fall.   Grether   and   Mieszkowski   (1980)   used   data   from   16   market   experiments   in   the   New   Haven,  Connecticut  metropolitan  area.  They  measured  the  effect  of  non-­‐residential  land  uses,   such  as  industry,  commercial,  high-­‐density  dwellings,  and  high  ways  on  the  prices  of  nearby   dwellings.  However,  they  did  not  find  a  systematic  relationship  between  non-­‐residential  land   use  and  house  prices.  

 

2.1.3    Tourism-­‐related  shops  and  shop  diversity    

However,  on  the  other  side  of  this  contribution  to  the  economic  prosperity  are  the  negative   environmental  and  social  externalities  of  tourism  and  tourism-­‐related  shops.  Many  academic   literature   and   reports   picture   these   negative   effects,   that   can   make   residents,   property   owners  and  other  entrepreneurs  worse  off.    The  most  actual  negative  effect  of  the  increase   of  tourism-­‐related  shops  is  the  decrease  in  diversity  of  supply.  Since  the  policy  change  in  2009,   in  which  is  stated  that  ice  for  direct  consumption  can  be  sold  in  a  premise  without  hospitality   destination,  the  number  of  ice-­‐waffles-­‐Nutella  shops  has  increased  rapidly.  Furthermore,  as   mentioned  earlier,  the  supply  of  other  tourism-­‐related  shops,  cheese  and  souvenir  shops,  has   also  increased.  This  increase  has  resulted  in  a  debate  about  the  diversity  of  shops  in  the  centre   of   Amsterdam,   where   some   are   speaking   of   a   ‘monoculture’.   There   is   even   a   petition   launched,  called  ‘Red  de  Winkels’  (Save  the  shops),  to  combat  the  degradation  of  the  city-­‐ centre1.  The  adjustments  of  supply  to  the  change  of  demand  due  to  the  increase  of  tourists   and  visitors,  leads  to  busy  spots  in  the  city-­‐centre  and  the  overrepresentation  of  shops  and   facilities  that  are  mainly  focusing  on  the  ‘mass  tourism’,  with  low-­‐grade  products  and  fast  

(10)

consumption  (Municipality  of  Amsterdam,  2017).  A  good  mix  of  residents,  workers  and  visitors   is   important   for   the   attractiveness   of   Amsterdam.   The   breakdown   of   the   balance   to   dominance   of   the   tourists   can   push   away   residents   by   alienation   and   can   affect   the   attractiveness  of  the  city  in  the  long-­‐run  (municipality  of  Amsterdam,  2017).  Furthermore,   panellists  in  the  RMA  report  also  reasoned  that  the  municipality  of  Amsterdam  should  take   measures  to  prevent  a  monotone  supply,  and  decrease  the  number  of  tourism-­‐related  shops   where  waffles,  ice,  cheese,  souvenirs  are  sold.    

 

2.1.3.1  Shop  diversity  and  house  prices  

Places   with   overrepresentation   of   shops   and   facilities   that   focus   on   tourists   and   visitors,   combined  with  crowded  streets,  results  in  a  higher  risk  of  pollution  and  conflicts  about  the   use  of  public  spaces.  This  has  a  negative  effect  on  liveability  of  the  area.  Perception  is  more   important   for   tenants   and   homeowners   nowadays,   which   also   means   an   attractive   living   environment:   public   space,   security   etcetera   (Municipality   of   Amsterdam,   2017).   Much   academic  research  argues  in  their  turn  that  a  less  attractive  living  environment  results  in  lower   demand.    Ellis  (1967),  Stegman  (1969)  and  Richardson  (1971)  are  one  of  those  researchers   that  investigated  this,  and  they  confirmed  the  hypothesis  that  residential  site  choice  is  not  just   determined   by   accessibility   but   rather   by   environmental   attributes   of   the   area.   Ceteris   paribus,   favourable   environmental   attributes   increase   demand   for   these   particular   houses   and  this  boosts  prices,  conversely  unfavourable  attributes  reduce  the  number  of  potential   buyers  and  this  reduce  prices.      

 

2.2  Tourist-­‐area  lifecycle  

Butler  (1980)  introduced  the  tourist  area  lifecycle  (TALC).  The  basic  idea  of  the  model  is  that   residential   areas   move   through   five   stages.   The   five   stages   are:   exploration,   involvement,   development,  consolidation  and  stagnation.  Following  stagnation,  a  tourism  area  may  start  a   new  development  phase  (rejuvenation),  or  may  continue  to  stagnate  or  may  decline.  During   the  first  stage,  the  exploration  stage,  the  shopping  district  serves  the  needs  of  the  residents.   There   are   small   number   of   tourists   transiting   through   the   city   and   perhaps   purchasing   incidental  products.  In  the  next  stage,  involvement,  tourists  are  beginning  to  become  a  more   visible   part   of   the   community.   Retailers   are   still   serving   the   locals   but   are   enlarging   their   product   mix   to   start   targeting   tourists.   As   tourism   expands,   the   area   move   into   the  

(11)

development  stage.  In  that  stage  the  shopping  districts  becomes  more  attractive  to  tourists   and  targets  both  the  locals  and  the  tourists:  the  destination  benefits  from  increasing  rates  of   growth.  In  the  fourth  stage,  the  consolidation  stage,  the  stores  are  fully  targeting  on  tourists:   they  are  selling  mementos,  nonessentials  and  niceties  for  everyday  life.  The  shopping  district   is  no  longer  attractive  for  the  residents  (Snepenger  et  al.,2003).  Finally,  the  shopping  district   move  in  to  the  stagnation  stage.  In  this  stage  the  arrival  numbers  reach  a  peak,  because  the   city  is  now  seen  as  unfashionable.  This  makes  it  difficult  to  maintain  the  number  of  arrivals.   After  this  stage,  the  city  enters  a  decline  or  rejuvenates  (Moore  and  Whitehall,  2005).  The   model  of  Butler  is  useful  in  proposing  the  potential  of  a  decline  if  certain  problems  are  not   addressed.   Butler   argues   that   a   decline   may   be   the   result   from   a   lack   of   good   overall   management  of  tourism,  or  from  an  absence  of  long-­‐term  planning  for  the  destination  or  from   failure   to   recognize   that   there   are   limits   to   growth   (Hovinen,   2002).   From   this   can   be   concluded  that  it  is  necessary  for  the  municipality  of  Amsterdam  to  take  measures,  otherwise   the  potential  for  a  significant  decline  exists.  

 

2.3  Solutions  

To  reach  a  solution  for  encouraging  the  diversity  of  shopping  or  prevent  impoverishment  of   the  supply,  a  good  cooperation  between  stakeholders  is  essential.  The  four  most  important   stakeholders   for   a   shopping   area   are:   the   municipality,   the   entrepreneurs,   the   real   estate   investors,   and   the   residents.   The   municipality   has   various   interests   in   a   well-­‐functioning   shopping   area.   These   interests   are   physical,   social   and   economic:   the   municipality   is   held   responsible   for   an   overall   viability,   a   good   spatial   planning,   security,   local   economic   development  and  stimulating  employment.  A  decline  in  product  range  may  have  a  negative   impact  on  (all)  the  municipal  interests.  This  makes  the  municipality  an  important  stakeholder.   Entrepreneurs   are   also   important   stakeholders   as   they   have   a   very   strong   interest   in   the   proper  functioning  of  the  shopping  area.  An  attractive  shopping  area  increase  the  likelihood   of   achieving   their   two   main   objectives:   continuity   of   operations   and   profit   maximization.   Another  important  group  of  stakeholders  is  the  real  estate  investor.  They  are  also  interested   in  maintaining  or  increasing  the  attractiveness  of  the  shopping  area,  because  both  the  amount   and   continuity   of   the   rents   and   the   value   of   the   property   depends   on   this   attractiveness.   Finally,  the  residents  of  the  area.  They  have  both  as  residents  and  as  consumer  direct  interest   in  the  good  quality  of  life  in  the  shopping  area.  As  consumer  because  they  want  a  good  price  

(12)

and  a  great  diversity  of  products  and  both  residents  and  consumers  have  interest  in  a  well-­‐ functioning,  good  accessible  and  safe  shopping  area  (Municipality  of  Amsterdam,  2017).   As   mentioned   earlier,   a   good   mix   of   residents,   workers   and   visitors   is   important   for   the   attractiveness   of   Amsterdam.   To   limit   a   decrease   in   diversity   of   shops,   not   only   the   municipality,   but   also   the   other   stakeholders   should   take   their   responsibility,   because   achieving  a  certain  tenant  mix  is  not  easy.  Instruments  that  the  municipality  can  use  to  limit  a   decrease   in   diversity   is   the   adjustment   of   the   zoning   plan.   This   is   only   possible   for   spatial   reasons  or  to  promote  the  quality  of  life.  Furthermore,  they  could  buy  some  properties  in  the   city-­‐centre  of  Amsterdam  to  get  influence  on  the  tenants.  Real  estate  investors  or  owners  can   select   their   tenants   based   on   the   zoning   plan,   in   addition,   they   can,   if   desired,   use   lease   incentives.  Residents  influence  the  shopping  area  by  buying  more  locally  at  several  (small)   shops.   Furthermore,   entrepreneurs   could   change   the   shopping   area   by   influencing   the   shopping  behaviour  of  consumers  through  consumer  loyalty,  street  branding,  and  changing   their  supply  to  serve  the  needs  of  the  residents  and  consumers.  Another  instrument  that  the   can  be  used  is  by  encouraging  and  stimulating  stakeholders  in  a  specific  area  to  jointly  develop   a  vision  and  plan  about  the  tenant  mix.  Some  of  these  instruments  are  deployed.    In  November   2016,  all  stakeholders  that  have  interest  in  the  maintaining  and  increasing  the  attractiveness   of  the  city-­‐centre  in  Amsterdam  signed  ‘het  binnenstadakkoord’  (the  city-­‐centre  agreement).   The  purpose  of  the  agreement  is  to  develop  a  common  vision,  that  combines  the  interest  of   all  the  stakeholders,  which  can  create  a  vital,  diverse,  viable  and  attractive  supply  of  shops   (Municipality  of  Amsterdam,  2017).    Furthermore,  in  March  2017  the  municipality  decided  to   adjust  the  zoning  plan:  they  want  to  determine  per  street  which  shops  can  establish  their   selves  (‘De  jacht  op  Nutella’s  wordt  nu  toch  geopend’,  2017).    

 

2.4  Measures  for  diversity  

 

To  measure  the  effect  of  a  decrease  in  diversity  of  shops  on  the  surrounding  house  prices,  a   similar  approach  as  Linn  (2013)  is  used.  He  has  analysed  in  his  paper  the  effect  of  voluntary   brownfields  programs  on  nearby  property  values  and  as  brownfields  have  some  similarity  with   tourism-­‐related  shops,  his  analysis  is  useful.  The  similarity  between  brownfields  and  tourism-­‐ related  shops  is  that  both  have  multiple  entities  spread  over  the  city-­‐centre  and  that  there  are   multiple  entities  located  within  a  certain  area.  He  used  two  measurements  to  investigate  the   impact   of   brownfields.   The   first   one   measures   the   density   by   counting   the   number   of  

(13)

brownfields  within  a  given  radius  and  the  second  one  is  a  gravity  index  which  measures  the   sum  of  the  inverse  distance  of  all  brownfields:  this  index  places  greater  weight  on  nearby  sites   compare  to  those  further  away.  Where  the  first  measure  assumes  that  distance  is  irrelevant,  

the  second  measure  assumes  that  the  distance  influences  the  property  value  inversely.  These   two   measures   are   both   used.   Where   the   density   measure   will   use   a   one   kilometre   radius   around  the  property,  as  assumed  is  that  beyond  one  kilometre  the  effect  will  be  negligible,   and  the  surface  of  the  circle  will  otherwise  capture  a  too  big  part  of  the  city.  A  radius  below   one  kilometre  is  also  assumed  to  be  improper  as  this  will  bias  the  results  of  houses  with  a  low   number   of   tourism-­‐related   shops   in   their   surroundings.   Furthermore,   there   could   be   a   measurement   error   in   the   coordinates   of   both   the   houses   and   the   tourism-­‐related   shops   which  implies  that  a  radius  below  one  kilometre  could  be  imprecise.  

Another  possibility  to  measure  the  effect  of  a  decrease  in  diversity  of  shops,  is  to  use  the   market  share  of  tourism-­‐related  shops.  The  last  couple  of  years,  the  total  number  of  retail   shops  in  the  city-­‐centre  of  Amsterdam  has  decreased  (Onderzoek,  Informatie  en  Statistiek,   2014).  When  using  the  market  share  of  tourism-­‐related  shop  as  proxy  for  diversity  of  shops,   the  trends  in  the  total  number  of  retail  shops  are  taken  into  account.  As  the  data  of  Locatus   only  contain  the  total  number  of  shops  per  four-­‐digit  zip  code,  the  market  share  of  tourism-­‐ related  shops  is  measured  per  four-­‐digit  zip  code.  

 

2.5  Relevance    

Since   the   significant   increase   in   tourism-­‐related   shops,   a   debate   is   originated.   There   are   reports   written   about   the   dissatisfaction   of   the   different   stakeholders,   especially   that   of   residents.  However,  this  dissatisfaction  is  based  on  surveys.  To  investigate  whether  this  leads   to  a  different  behaviour,  actual  data  should  be  used.  Using  a  survey  to  gather  empirical  data,   has  some  disadvantages  over  using  actual  data.  One  of  the  important  disadvantages  is  that   responses   to   surveys   may   not   reflect   the   true   beliefs,   attitudes,   or   behaviours   of   the   respondents  (Salant  and  Dillman,  1994).    By  using  data  of  actual  transaction  prices,  it  can  be   measured  if  residents  think  the  area  is  less  attractive.  If  that  is  the  case,  there  would  be  less   demand  which  results  in  lower  transaction  prices.  This  is  relevant  for  real  estate  investors,  but   also  for  policy  makers.  When  the  house  price  effect  of  a  lack  of  diversity  of  shops  is  known,   they  can  take  that  into  account  when  constructing  their  policies.    

(14)

3.  Methodology  

 

The  focus  of  this  thesis  is  to  investigate  the  effect  of  the  increase  of  tourism-­‐related  shops  on   the  surrounding  house  prices  in  Amsterdam.  The  analysis  uses  a  hedonic  price  model  including   control  variables  such  as  house  characteristics  and  fixed  effects.  The  hedonic  price  model  is   mostly  used  in  the  existing  literature  for  measuring  effects  on  the  housing  market.  Examples   of   studies   that   rely   on   the   hedonic   price   model   are   Theebe   (2004),   Koster   and   Ommeren   (2015),  and  Dekkers  and  Van  der  Straaten  (2009).  The  hedonic  approach  deducts  values  by   analysing   observed   market   data,   like   property   transaction   prices.   By   doing   a   regression,   a   hedonic   price   model   analyses   the   contribution   of   physical   and   locational   property   characteristics   to   property   transaction   prices   (Theebe,   2004).   The   diversity   of   shops   is   measured  in  three  ways:  the  density,  the  market  share  and  the  gravity  certification  index  of   tourism-­‐related  shops.  The  density  variable  measures  the  number  of  tourism-­‐related  shops  in   a  radius  of  one  kilometre  of  the  sold  property  in  the  year  of  the  transaction.    The  market  share   of  tourism-­‐related  shops  divides  the  number  of  tourism-­‐related  shops  by  the  total  number  of   shops  in  the  retail  sector  with  the  same  four  digits  in  their  zip  code  as  the  property  i  in  the   year  of  the  transaction  date  t.  The  gravity  certification  index  (GCI)  of  tourism-­‐related  shops  is   constructed  as  the  sum  of  the  inverse  distance  of  all  tourism-­‐related  shops.  The  summation  is   taken  over  all  shops  within  one  kilometre,  under  the  assumption  that  tourism-­‐related  shops   further  away  do  not  affect  house  prices.  The  dependent  variable  is  the  natural  logarithm  of   the  house  transaction  prices.  log  𝑝𝑖𝑡  refers  to  the  natural  logarithm  of  the  transaction  prices  

of  property  i  at  time  t  and  Diversityproxy  refers  to  one  of  the  three  measures  for  the  diversity   of  shops.  The  hedonic  model  looks  as  follows:  

 

log  𝑝𝑖𝑡  =  𝛼+  𝛾Diversityproxy𝑖t  +  𝛽’𝑥𝑖𝑡  +  𝜂𝑗  +  𝜃𝑡  +𝜖𝑖𝑡         (1)  

 

Where  𝛼  is  a  constant,  𝛾𝑖𝑡  is  the  main  independent  variable  of  interest,  and  measures  the  

house   price   effect   of   the   lack   of   diversity   of   shops   in   that   area.   Whereas   different   house   characteristics  can  influence  the  house  price,  𝑥𝑖𝑡  is  included  in  the  model  and  represents  a  

vector  of  house  characteristics  and  𝛽’  measures  the  impact  of  these  characteristics.  

House  characteristics  are  variables  such  as  the  size  of  the  house,  the  number  of  rooms,  house   type  dummies,  dummies  for  garage,  garden,  maintenance  quality,  whether  the  house  is  listed   as  cultural  heritage,  and  construction  year  dummies  (Dröes  &  Koster,  2016).  Furthermore,  

(15)

house   prices   can   be   influenced   by   neighbourhood   characteristics,   because   neighbourhood   residential   properties   share   locational   amenities.   For   example,   the   same   police   and   fire   departments,   access   to   the   same   public   schools,   the   same   accessibility   to   transportation   networks,  and  proximity  to  the  same  externalities  (Basu  and  Thibodeau,  1998).  Therefore,   level   six   zip   code   fixed   effects   are   included,   and   𝜂j   measures   this   effect2.   Additionally,   to  

control  for  time  trends,  𝜃𝑡  is  included  and  measures  the  year  and  month  fixed  effects.  Finally,  

𝜖𝑖𝑡  is  an  identically  and  independently  distributed  error  term.  The  error  term  is  clustered  on  a  

neighbourhood  level  to  capture  the  effect  of  differences  between  neighbourhoods  on  the   house  prices.  This  clustering  correct  for  heteroscedasticity  and  serial  correlation.  Clustering   on  six-­‐digit  zip  code  would  give  a  problem  as  there  are  often  only  a  few  observations  per  zip   code,  this  would  result  in  an  underestimation  of  the  standard  errors  and  an  overestimation  of   the  significance  (Correia,  2015).  Clustering  on  neighbourhoods  gives  enough  observations  per   neighbourhood   in   the   sample   and   assumed   is   that   there   is   enough   independence   across   clusters,  but  correlation  within  clusters.  

Furthermore,   to   test   if   the   relationship   between   tourism-­‐related   shops   and   house   prices   changes   when   the   proportion   of   tourism-­‐related   shops   changes,   dummies   for   the   market   share  and  density  measures  are  included.  The  independent  variables  of  interest  are  divided   into   three   dummy   variables,   to   test   for   the   non-­‐linear   effect   of   diversity   of   shops   on   surrounding  house  prices.  In  this  way,  it  is  possible  to  check  whether  the  different  classes  of   the  independent  variable  have  a  different  effect  on  the  surrounding  house  prices.  To  avoid   perfect  multicollinearity,  the  ‘none’  dummy  is  excluded  from  the  model.  The  inclusion  of  the   dummies  will  give  the  following  model:  

 

log𝑝𝑖𝑡=𝛼+  𝛾Mediumdummy𝑖t  +  δHighdummy  𝑖𝑡  +  𝛽’𝑥𝑖𝑡  +  𝜃𝑡  +  𝜂𝑗  +  +𝜖𝑖𝑡,       (2)  

 

 To  test  if  a  tourism-­‐related  shops  are  desirable  till  a  particular  threshold,  a  squared  term  is   used  for  the  gravity  certification  index.  Furthermore,  using  a  squared  term  has  the  advantage   that   it   is   independent   of   the   bins   that   are   chosen,   which   is   not   the   case   for   the   dummy   variables.  Nevertheless,  a  squared  term  is  more  sensitive  to  outliers.  

2  The  results  remain  the  same  when  neighbourhood  fixed  effects  on  four-­‐digit  zip  code  level  

are  included  (Table  A3).  The  turning  point  of  the  GCI  variable  only  comes  at  a  slightly  lower   value.  

(16)

If  tourism-­‐related  shops  are  desirable  till  a  particular  threshold,  the  sign  of  the  GCI𝑖t  coefficient  

should  be  positive,  while  the  sign  of  the  squared  term  should  be  negative.  This  would  result   in  a  downward-­‐opening  parabola,  with  a  maximum  at  a  positive  proportion  of  tourism-­‐related   shops.  This  results  in  the  following  model:  

 

log𝑝𝑖𝑡=𝛼+  𝛾GCI  𝑖𝑡  +  δSquareofGCI𝑖𝑡  +  𝛽’𝑥𝑖𝑡  +  𝜃𝑡  +  𝜂𝑗  +𝜖𝑖𝑡,           (3)  

   

3.1  Hypotheses  

 

Using  this  approach,  the  hypothesis  that  the  lack  of  diversity  of  shops  due  to  the  increase  of   tourism-­‐related  shops  has  negatively  influenced  the  surrounding  house  prices  in  Amsterdam,   can  be  tested.  The  existing  literate  argues  that  tourism  can  boost  the  local  economy  or  that   the  negative  externalities  that  tourism  and  tourism-­‐related  activities  generate  predominate.   It  is  expected  that  more  tourism-­‐related  shops  bring  more  negative  externalities  as  crowding,   congestion   and   environmental   degradation   than   positive   ones.   Especially,   the   effect   of   environmental   degradation   is   expected   to   play   an   important   role   which   is   result   of   the   decrease  in  the  variety  of  shops.  However,  as  Stull  (1975)  finds  that  a  small  proportion  of   commercial  activity  is  desirable,  but  if  it  reaches  a  certain  threshold  when  the  disamenities   created  outweigh  the  extra  shopping  convenience,  house  prices  will  fall.  In  the  same  way,  a   small   proportion   of   tourism-­‐related   shops   is   expected   to   have   a   positive   effect   on   house   prices,  because  it  boosts  the  local  economy,  but  when  the  diversity  of  the  supply  of  shops  is   put  at  risk,  it  will  negatively  affect  the  surrounding  houses.  Therefore,  the  hypothesis  is  that  a   small  proportion  of  tourism-­‐related  shops  is  positively  related  with  house  prices,  however  if   the  diversity  of  shop  supply  is  at  risk,  house  prices  and  tourism-­‐related  shops  will  become   negatively  related.                

(17)

4.  Data  

This  analysis  uses  two  databases  to  answer  the  research  question  about  the  effect  of  tourism-­‐ related  shops  on  the  surrounding  prices  in  Amsterdam.  The  first  database  is  made  available   by  the  Dutch  Association  of  Realtors  (NVM)  and  contains  house  price  data  from  2008  to  2016.   The   second   database   is   made   available   by   Locatus,   which   is   a   company   that   collects   information  about  stores,  shopping  areas,  and  footfall.  From  this  database  data  is  collected   about  retail  stores  and  tourism-­‐related  shops  in  Amsterdam.  With  this  data,  the  market  share,   density  and  gravity  certification  index  of  tourism-­‐related  shops  can  be  calculated.  The  dataset   of  Locatus  covers  all  the  tourism-­‐related  shops  in  Amsterdam.  It  contains  2,042  observations   of   tourism-­‐related   shops   in   Amsterdam   of   which   1,526   are   located   the   city-­‐centre   of   Amsterdam,  over  the  period  2008-­‐2016.    Figure  1  and  2  show  the  density  of  tourism-­‐related   shops  per  four-­‐digit  zip  code  in  Amsterdam  in  2008  and  2016.  These  figures  show  that  most   tourism-­‐related  shops  are  clustered  in  the  city-­‐centre  and  that  only  a  few  areas  in  the  city-­‐ centre  experienced  a  growth  in  tourism-­‐related  shops.  

 

Figure  1  -­‐  Density  tourism-­‐related  shops  per  PC4  in  2008  

      100-150 tourism-related shops 75-100 tourism-related shops 25-75 tourism-related shops 10-25 tourism-related shops 2-10 tourism-related shops 1 tourism-related shop No tourism-related shops

(18)

Figure  2-­‐  Density  tourism-­‐related  shops  per  PC4  in  2016  

   

Another  thing  that  becomes  clear  is  that  every  sector  experienced  a  large  growth  in  the  city-­‐ centre  during  the  last  years  (Table  1).  For  example,  Waffle-­‐Ice-­‐Nutella  shops  went  from  12   shops  to  40  shops  in  the  city-­‐centre,  which  is  an  increase  of  more  than  230%.  Table  2  shows   the  growth  in  tourism-­‐related  shops  for  5  four-­‐digit  zip  codes  in  Amsterdam;  only  these  zip   codes  are  tabulated  as  they  only  experienced  a  significant  growth  during  2008-­‐2016.  Table  A1   in  the  appendix  shows  the  number  of  tourism-­‐related  shops  for  all  four-­‐digit  zip  codes.     The  tabulated  zip  codes  are  in  the  city-­‐centre  of  Amsterdam,  where  most  tourism-­‐related   shops  are  located.  Especially  the  areas  with  1017  and  1012  in  their  zip  code  have  experienced   a  substantial  increase  in  tourism-­‐related  the  last  years,  this  is  also  shown  in  figure  1  and  2.    

Table  1  -­‐  Descriptive  statistics:  number  of  tourism-­‐related  shops  in  city-­‐centre  of  Amsterdam  

    Number  of  tourism-­‐related  shops  

  2008   2009   2010   2011   2012   2013   2014   2015   2016   %  change   Cheese   14   15   15   14   22   24   29   35   39   179%   Souvenirs   108   115   121   131   132   138   132   127   139   29%   Waffle-­‐Ice-­‐ Nutella   12   11   15   18   11   20   26   23   40   233%   Total   134   141   151   163   165   182   187   185   218   63%   100-150 tourism-related shops 75-100 tourism-related shops 25-75 tourism-related shops 10-25 tourism-related shops 1-10 tourism-related shops 1 tourism-related shop No tourism-related shops

(19)

 

Table  2  -­‐  Descriptive  statistics:  growth  in  tourism-­‐related  shops  in  city-­‐centre  of  Amsterdam  over  the  period   2008-­‐2016  

PC4

 

1011   1012   1015   1016   1017  

Number  of  tourism-­‐

related  shops  2008   6   89   4   7   25  

Number  of  tourism-­‐

related  shops  2016

 

9   132   7   16   46  

Percentage  change   50%   48%   75%   129%   84%  

 

Figure  3  visualizes  the  numbers  of  Table  1  and  shows  that  the  total  number  of  tourism-­‐related   shops  in  the  city-­‐centre  of  Amsterdam  increased  significantly.  It  went  from  119  shops  in  2007   to  226  shops  in  2017,  which  is  an  increase  of  63%.  This  figure  also  shows  that  souvenir  shops   are   the   biggest   part   of   the   tourism-­‐related   shops,   however,   as   Table   1   shows,   this   sector   experienced  the  smallest  relative  change  in  number  of  shops.  While  Waffle-­‐Ice-­‐Nutella  shops   have  experienced  the  largest  relative  increase  of  233%.  

 

Figure  3  –  Number  of  shops  per  branche  in  the  city-­‐centre  of  Amsterdam  

 

From  the  above  figures,  it  can  be  concluded  that  the  number  of  tourism-­‐related  shops  in  the   city-­‐centre  of  Amsterdam  have  increased  in  all  sectors.  Figure  4  shows  that  the  total  number   of  shops  in  the  city-­‐centre  of  Amsterdam  have  decreased  with  more  than  300  shops,  which  

0 50 100 150 200 250 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 #   of    sh op s

(20)

is  approximately  6%.  This  has  resulted  in  an  increase  of  the  market-­‐share  of  tourism-­‐related   shops:  it  went  from  2%  to  4%.      

Figure    4  -­‐  Total  shops  and  market  share  tourism-­‐related  shops  in  the    city-­‐centre  of  Amsterdam  

 

 Table  3  shows  the  descriptive  statistics  of  the  main  independent  variables  and  of  the  database   that   is   supplied   by   the   NVM.   The   database   provides   a   variety   of   variables,   including   information  on  transaction  prices  and  house  characteristics  such  as  house  size,  house  type   and   construction   year.   The   sample   period   of   2008-­‐2016   gives   67,953   observations   in   Amsterdam   after   removing   some   outliers.   Observations   with   outliers   in   transaction   price,   house  size,  and  number  of  rooms  are  deleted.  Observation  with  a  transaction  price  below   50,000  euros  are  dropped.  Furthermore,  all  houses  with  more  than  25  rooms  are  dropped.   Finally,  some  observations  with  a  living  space  of  1  square  metre  are  excluded.    

From  this  database  are  also  some  control  variables  created.  These  include  dummies  for  house   type  and  construction  year  brackets.  Furthermore,  parking  and  cultural  heritage  dummies  are   created   and   these   equal   one   if   the   house   offers   a   parking   facility   or   is   marked   as   cultural   heritage.  The  maintenance  dummy  indicates  the  sum  of  the  ratings  from  inside  and  outside   maintenance   and   if   this   is   more   than   15,   the   dummy   equals   one.   The   inside   and   outside   maintenance  variables  are  both  on  a  scale  from  1-­‐10.  Finally,  some  year  and  neighbourhood   fixed  effects  are  included.  The  latter  include  level  six  zip  code  identifiers.  

Using   both   datasets,   the   main   independent   variables   are   created   and   divided   into   three   dummy   variables   to   test   for   the   non-­‐linear   effect.   The   first   variable,   the   market   share   of   tourism-­‐related  shops,  has  a  value  of  one  when  the  percentage  of  this  variable  is  0%.  This  was  

0,0% 0,5% 1,0% 1,5% 2,0% 2,5% 3,0% 3,5% 4,0% 4,5% 5500 5600 5700 5800 5900 6000 6100 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 %   m ar ke t  s ha re #   of  o bs er va tio ns

Referenties

GERELATEERDE DOCUMENTEN

In addition, the suitability of two specific methods (open- ended contingent valuation and choice-based conjoint analysis) for measuring WTP for a relatively high-priced,

It is showed that the WTP for the single elements (design and functional customization) is higher than the WTP for both elements combined. Women would pay 15.6 EUR

In deze studie is gekeken naar het verband tussen expliciete en impliciete associaties bij zowel trait anxiety als wiskundeangst.. Expliciete associaties bij trait anxiety werden

1) For each illegal image in the public database D, an extractor uses the helper data h in order to com- pute a hash-extract hext that is then matched (in a matching algorithm) with

MalekGhaini, “Effect of friction stir welding speed on the microstructure and mechanical properties of a duplex stainless steel,” Materials Science and

When the police officer has a dominant yet a↵ectionate stance, he will, according to our theory, use a positive politeness strategy combined with a negative impoliteness strategy (+P

But the content of the professional midwifery educational programme very seldom reflects cultural congruent maternity nursing care such as taboos, herbalism and traditional